Neuroeconomics and the Governance of Choice in Time

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Neuroeconomics and the Governance of Choice in Time Social Studies of Science 41(4) 515–538 The shortsighted brain: © The Author(s) 2011 Reprints and permission: sagepub. Neuroeconomics and the co.uk/journalsPermissions.nav DOI: 10.1177/0306312710397689 governance of choice in time sss.sagepub.com Natasha Dow Schüll Program in Science, Technology & Society, MIT, Cambridge, MA, USA Caitlin Zaloom Department of Social & Cultural Analysis, NYU, New York, NY, USA Abstract The young field of neuroeconomics converges around behavioral deviations from the model of the human being as Homo economicus, a rational actor who calculates his choices to maximize his individual satisfaction. In a historical moment characterized by economic, health, and environmental crises, policymakers have become increasingly concerned about a particular deviation for which neuroeconomics offers a biological explanation: Why do humans value the present at the expense of the future? There is contentious debate within the field over how to model this tendency at the neural level. Should the brain be conceptualized as a unified decision-making apparatus, or as the site of conflict between an impetuous limbic system at perpetual odds with its deliberate and provident overseer in the prefrontal cortex? Scientific debates over choice-making in the brain, we argue, are also debates over how to define the constraints on human reason with which regulative strategies must contend. Drawing on ethnographic and archival research, we explore how the brain and its treatment of the future become the contested terrain for distinct visions of governmental intervention into problems of human choice-making. Keywords economics, epistemology, governance, liberalism, neuroeconomics, neuroscience, policy, rationality An undergraduate in jeans and a ponytail doffs her winter parka and climbs onto the bed of an fMRI [functional magnetic resonance imaging] machine. Joseph Kable, neuroscience postdoctoral researcher and economics neophyte, helps position the student’s head and body so that she will be able to keep absolutely still through the hundreds of choice trials she will Corresponding author: Natasha Dow Schüll, Program in Science, Technology, and Society, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 77 Massachusetts Avenue, E51-185, Cambridge, MA 02139, USA. Email: [email protected] Downloaded from sss.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on October 17, 2015 516 Social Studies of Science 41(4) undergo over the next hour and a half. He hands the young woman earplugs from a half-empty industrial-size box and positions a mirror above her eyes to reflect a computer screen placed at the back of the machine. Kable leaves the room and shuts the door. The lights go out and the machine begins its roar. Outside the magnet room, where we watch through a glass panel alongside Kable, another screen flashes the first choice presented to the student inside the scanner: $212 in six months or $53 in two. Her answer is marked with a check: $212 six months from now. The next choice: $20 today or $50 in two months. Her answer: $20 today. (Authors’ fieldnotes, 2006) Since the late 1990s, a new space of scientific expertise has been emerging in the labo- ratories of elite universities, at the meetings of scientists and their public policy col- leagues, in Science and Nature and other academic journals, and in the popular media. Located at the intersection of neuroscience, economics, and psychology, the field of neuroeconomics converges around behavioral deviations from the model of the human being as Homo economicus, a rational actor who calculates his choices to maximize his individual satisfaction. Neuroeconomists look to the biological substrate of the brain for clues to the puzzles of consumer action – why people often make decisions to buy, sell, invest, and trade in ways that seem to go against their best interest. Going a step farther than behavioral economists, who argue that policy designers need to take seemingly ‘irrational’ choices into account, neuroeconomists insist that they need to understand how such choices get made in the brain. In this article we focus on neuroeconomic research into ‘future discounting’, or the tendency forego future well-being for immediate gratification.1 This particular puzzle, a longstanding concern of liberal governance, has become a flash point for the young field. In experiments such as Kable’s, above, neuroeconomists design tasks that can isolate and make legible the brain’s evaluations of rewards in and over time, operationalizing the future in the form of ‘inter-temporal choice’, or a choice between something now and something later. Inside the scanner, the subject weighs her preferences. How long is she willing to wait for a given amount of cash? As she trades off the value of money against time, the scanner takes pictures of her brain activity. In these images, neuroeconomists attempt to discern the neural mechanisms by which human beings value – and often undervalue – the future. In a historical moment when American policymakers increasingly link the short- sightedness of citizens’ microeconomic decisions to urgent problems – from individual conditions such as addiction and obesity to collective conditions such as the credit crisis and even global warming – there are high stakes to probing the neurobiological mecha- nisms underlying humans’ calculations (and miscalculations) about the future.2 Why do Americans spend today when the financial demands of retirement require saving for the future? Why do they keep reaching for candy bars and fried food when they know that heart disease can result from high calorie diets? Ongoing crises of economy, health, and environment challenge the notion that individuals can be expected to comport themselves according to the tenets of rational action; the model of human beings as prudent choice makers conflicts too starkly with the actual behavior that has triggered contemporary calamities. Although policymakers continue to encourage citizens to pursue their own self- interests as a path to maximizing collective well-being, they have begun to look to Downloaded from sss.sagepub.com at Bobst Library, New York University on October 17, 2015 Schüll and Zaloom 517 neuroeconomics for a model of the human being that can lend conceptual support to economic, social, and health policies designed to address a subject different from the traditional rational actor. By arming themselves with an understanding of citizens as fundamentally calculating, but also neurologically ill-suited to the contemporary land- scape of choice, lawmakers from Washington’s heights to the corridors of state agen- cies hope to design policy interventions that can accommodate both the capacities and limitations of human decision-making. But how exactly should these capacities and limitations be modeled? Within the field of neuroeconomics, there is heated debate around the mechanisms of future discounting, and the kind of model of the brain that best represents those mechanisms. Does future discounting reflect the constitutional myopia of a single value system within the brain, or an inner contest between impulsive and rational brain systems? In other words, should the brain be conceptualized as a unified decision-making apparatus, or as the site of conflict between an impetuous limbic system at perpetual odds with its deliberate and provident overseer in the prefrontal cortex? Does the problem lie with the brain as a whole, or in the balance between opposed neural systems? Although this debate does not neatly divide the field into its constituent disciplines, with all neuroscientists taking one side and all economists the other, it does fracture along epistemological lines: neurosci- entists trained in the experimental methods of natural science tend to favor a ‘single system’ model that can accommodate the complex morphological and functional con- straints of the brain, while economists’ strong theoretical tradition leads them to favor a ‘dual systems’ model that can reduce the brain and its functions into mathematically manageable formulae.3 As it turns out, each model of the biology underlying future dis- counting endorses a different vision of the human actor, different sites of accountability, and, potentially, different kinds of governance and remediation. When the neuroeconomics of future discounting is drawn into policy debates, what becomes of its impassioned internal debate? How do differing models of the brain influ- ence thinking about how, and whether, the government should regulate citizens’ choices in the long-term interest of individuals and the nation? Does it matter to policy whether choices derive from a unified or split valuation system? In other words, do epistemologi- cal politics bear any relationship to wider governmental politics, and if so, what kind of a relationship is it? These queries extend longstanding discussions among social scientists regarding the relationship between science and the broader social and political environment in which it is practiced. In the late 1970s, historians and sociologists of science argued that contexts of political insecurity and the clashing of rival beliefs in society at large could create conditions for novel and sometimes controversial scientific ideas to emerge, and that these ideas could loop back into public debate. Steven Shapin, for instance, showed how social and political concerns and values were debated and sometimes reconfigured in the so-called ‘phrenology disputes’ of 19th century brain science (Shapin, 1979). Our own
Recommended publications
  • 1 Uncertainty
    Econ 206: Decisions Christopher P. Chambers Econ 304 Monday 4:00-7:00 This course is on economic decision making and the empirical content of economic models. The approach will be to understand when choice behavior is consistent with some economic model of decision making. Topics covered will include classical and modern choice theory, as well as the theory of decisions (the theory of behavior under uncertainty). Other topics include the empirical content of classical behavioral models (say, the work extending Afriat). The focus here is on understanding what we can say with a given model and observable primitives (usually some form of choice). Many (difficult) open questions exist on the empirical content of classical models of decision and game theory. My plan is to distribute a set of notes (co-authored with Federico Echenique) on the subject. Below is a partial list of readings. I obviously don't plan to cover these all. Grades will be based on attendance and in-class presentations. 1 Uncertainty Useful books L.J. Savage. The foundations of statistics. Dover Pubns, 1972 D.M. Kreps. Notes on the Theory of Choice. Perseus Books, 1988 I. Gilboa. Theory of decision under uncertainty. Cambridge University Press, 2009 Subjective probability and a few generalizations F.J. Anscombe and R.J. Aumann. A definition of subjective probability. Annals of mathematical statistics, pages 199{205, 1963 I. Gilboa and D. Schmeidler. Maxmin expected utility with non-unique prior. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 1989 D. Schmeidler. Subjective probability and expected utility without additivity. Econo- metrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, pages 571{587, 1989 P.
    [Show full text]
  • For Better Or for Worse: Default Effects and 401(K) Savings Behavior
    This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Perspectives on the Economics of Aging Volume Author/Editor: David A. Wise, editor Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-90305-2 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/wise04-1 Conference Date: May 17-20, 2001 Publication Date: June 2004 Title: For Better or for Worse: Default Effects and 401(k) Savings Behavior Author: James J. Choi, David Laibson, Brigitte C. Madrian, Andrew Metrick URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c10341 2 For Better or for Worse Default Effects and 401(k) Savings Behavior James J. Choi, David Laibson, Brigitte C. Madrian, and Andrew Metrick 2.1 Introduction Seemingly minor changes in the way a choice is framed to a decision maker can generate dramatic changes in behavior. Automatic enrollment provides a clear example of such effects. Under automatic enrollment (also called negative election), employees are automatically enrolled in their company’s 401(k) plan unless the employees elect to opt out of the plan. This contrasts with the usual arrangement in which employees must ac- tively choose to participate in their employer’s 401(k). Standard economic theory predicts that automatic enrollment should not influence the employee’s saving decision, because automatic enroll- ment does not change the economic fundamentals of the planning prob- lem. But several studies and anecdotal accounts suggest that automatic enrollment has succeeded in dramatically increasing 401(k) participa- James J. Choi is a Ph.D. candidate in economics at Harvard University. David Laibson is professor of economics at Harvard University and a research associate of the National Bu- reau of Economic Research.
    [Show full text]
  • Neuroeconomics: the Neurobiology of Decision-Making
    Neuroeconomics: The Neurobiology of Decision-Making Ifat Levy Section of Comparative Medicine Department of Neurobiology Interdepartmental Neuroscience Program Yale School of Medicine Harnessing eHealth and Behavioral Economics for HIV Prevention and Treatment April 2012 Overview • Introduction to neuroeconomics • Decision under uncertainty – Brain and behavior – Adolescent behavior – Medical decisions Overview • Introduction to neuroeconomics • Decision under uncertainty – Brain and behavior – Adolescent behavior – Medical decisions Neuroeconomics NeuroscienceNeuronal MentalPsychology states “asEconomics if” models architecture Abstraction Neuroeconomics Behavioral Economics Neuroscience Psychology Economics Abstraction Neuroscience functional MRI VISUAL STIMULUS functional MRI: Blood Oxygenation Level Dependent signals Neural Changes in oxygen Change in activity consumption, blood flow concentration of and blood volume deoxyhemoglobin Change in Signal from each measured point in space at signal each point in time t = 1 t = 2 t = 3 t = 4 t = 5 t = 6 dorsal anterior posterior lateral ventral dorsal anterior medial posterior ventral Anterior The cortex Cingulate Cortex (ACC) Medial Prefrontal Cortex (MPFC) Posterior Cingulate Cortex (PCC) Ventromedial Prefrontal Cortex (vMPFC) Orbitofrontal Cortex (OFC) Sub-cortical structures fMRI signal • Spatial resolution: ~3x3x3mm3 Low • Temporal resolution: ~1-2s Low • Number of voxels: ~150,000 High • Typical signal change: 0.2%-2% Low • Typical noise: more than the signal… High But… • Intact human
    [Show full text]
  • Volatility As Link Between Risk and Memory in Economics, Econometrics and Neuroeconomics: an Application for the Bolivian Inflation Rate 1938 - 2012
    Volatility as link between risk and memory in Economics, Econometrics and Neuroeconomics: an application for the Bolivian Inflation Rate 1938 - 2012 María Edith Chacón B. [email protected] Teacher and researcher CIDES – UMSA. La Paz, Bolivia. Ernesto Sheriff B. [email protected] Teacher and researcher CIDES – UMSA and UPB. La Paz, Bolivia. Experimental and Behavioral Economics: Other Neuroeconomics Econometrics: Time Series ABSTRACT This paper provides an indicator that measures memory as a stock. Memory affects economic decisions thus the memory indicator is useful to help in applied work, it was built according to the state of the art in Psychology and Neuroeconomics and it is presented as a time series; it is a recursive one and it is represented by an accumulated measure of the volatility. Many theories of risk have used volatility indicators to represent risk in the applied work. Risk valuation is associated to volatility and it is very sensitive to periods in which it is measured; it is very sensitive too to the type of data associated to volatility. In this paper we found that the memory affects risk valuations and the link between them is a special kind of volatility i.e. accumulated volatility with an endogenous initialization period and compatible with many Psychological hypotheses. The developed indicator is compatible with the econometrics of stationary series, integrated series and fractional integrated series. These contributions help to improve the study of hysteresis in applied economics, to develop more consistent links between memory and risk in Neuroeconomics and, to obtain more confident time series models in econometrics using the new indicator.
    [Show full text]
  • Brigitte C. Madrian Curriculum Vitae February 2016
    BRIGITTE C. MADRIAN CURRICULUM VITAE FEBRUARY 2016 CONTACT INFORMATION Harvard Kennedy School Phone: (617) 495-8917 Harvard University Fax: (617) 496-5960 79 John F. Kennedy Street e-mail: [email protected] Cambridge, MA 02138 EDUCATION 1993 Ph.D., Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge, MA 1989 M.A., Economics, Brigham Young University, Provo, UT 1989 B.A., Economics, Brigham Young University, Provo, UT CURRENT POSITIONS/AFFILIATIONS 2006-present Aetna Professor of Public Policy and Corporate Management, Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University 2016-present Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (CFPB) Academic Research Council 2016-present Vestigo Ventures Advisory Board 2015-present Editor, Review of Economics and Statistics 2015-present DoubleNet Pay Advisory Board 2014-present FINRA Board of Governors 2014-present Bipartisan Policy Center Personal Savings Initiative (commission member) 2013-present American Economic Association Committee on Economic Education 2013-present Center for Financial Studies (CFS) Research Advisory Council for the Center for Sustainable Architecture for Finance in Europe (SAFE) 2010-present Co-director, NBER Working Group on Household Finance 2010-present SSRN Household Finance eJournal Advisory Board 2010-present Wheatley Institution Fellow, Brigham Young University 2009-present Sloan/Sage Behavioral Economics and Consumer Finance Working Group 2007-present National Academy of Social Insurance 2010-present Editorial board, Journal of Pension Economics and Finance 2005-present
    [Show full text]
  • David Laibson RAND Summer 2006
    David Laibson RAND Summer 2006 All readings are recommended. Starred readings will be particularly useful complements for the lecture. George Akerlof "Procastination and Obedience," The Richard T. Ely Lecture, American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, May 1991. *George-Marios Angeletos, David Laibson, Andrea Repetto, Jeremy Tobacman and Stephen Weinberg,“The Hyperbolic Consumption Model: Calibration, Simulation, and Empirical Evaluation ” Journal of Economic Perspectives, August 2001, pp. 47-68. Shlomo Benartzi and Richard H. Thaler "How Much Is Investor Autonomy Worth?" Journal of Finance, 2002, 57(4), pp. 1593-616. Camerer, Colin F., George Loewenstein and Drazen Prelec. Mar. 2005. "Neuroeconomics: How neuroscience can inform economics." Journal of Economic Literature. Vol. 34, No. 1. Colin Camerer, Samuel Issacharoff, George Loewenstein, Ted O'Donoghue, and Matthew Rabin. Jan 2003. "Regulation for Conservatives: Behavioral Economics and the Case for 'Assymetric Paternalism.'" University of Pennsylvania Law Review. 151, 1211- 1254. *James Choi, David Laibson, and Brigitte Madrian. $100 Bills on the Sidewalk: Suboptimal Saving in 401(k) Plans July 16, 2005. *James Choi, Brigitte Madrian, David Laibson, and Andrew Metrick. Optimal Defaults and Active Decisions December 3, 2004. James Choi, David Laibson, and Brigitte C. Madrian “Are Education and Empowerment Enough? Under-Diversification in 401(k) Plans” forthcoming, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. *James Choi, David Laibson, Brigitte Madrian, and Andrew Metrick “Optimal Defaults” American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, May 2003, pp. 180-185. Dominique J.-F. de Quervain, Urs Fischbacher, Valerie Treyer, Melanie Schellhammer, Ulrich Schnyder, Alfred Buck, Ernst Fehr. The Neural Basis of Altruistic Punishment Science 305, 27 August 2004, 1254-1258 Shane Frederick, George Loewenstein, and O'Donoghue, T.
    [Show full text]
  • Economists As Worldly Philosophers
    Economists as Worldly Philosophers Robert J. Shiller and Virginia M. Shiller Yale University Hitotsubashi University, March 11, 2014 Virginia M. Shiller • Married, 1976 • Ph.D. Clinical Psychology, University of Delaware 1984 • Intern, Cambridge Hospital, Harvard Medical School, 1980-1 • Clinical Instructor, Yale Child Study Center, since 2000 • Private practice with children, adults, and families Robert Heilbroner 1919-2005 • His book The Worldly Philosophers: Lives, Times and Ideas of the Great Economic Thinkers, 1953, sold four million copies • Adam Smith, Henry George, Karl Marx, John Stewart Mill, John Maynard Keynes, Thomas Malthus Example: Adam Smith • Theory of Moral Sentiments, 1759 • The Wealth of Nations, 1776 • Did not shrink from moral judgments, e. g., frugality Example: John Maynard Keynes • Economic Consequences of the Peace • The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, 1936 Economics as a Moral Science • The kinds of questions economists are asked to opine on are inherently moral • Moral calculus requires insights into the complexities of human behavior • A plea for behavioral economics and a broader focus for economic research Kenneth Boulding 1910-1993 • “We cannot escape the proposition that as science moves from pure knowledge toward control, that is, toward creating what it knows, what it creates becomes a problem of ethical choice, and will depend upon the common values of the societies in which the scientific culture is embedded, as well as of the scientific subculture.” Boulding on the Theory that People Maximize Utility of their Own Consumption • That there is neither malevolence nor benevolence anywhere in the system is demonstrably false. • “Anything less descriptive of the human condition could hardly be imagined.” (from American Economics Association Presidential Address, 1968).
    [Show full text]
  • 2 Cognitive Load Increases Risk Aversion 5 2.1 Introduction
    Essays in Experimental and Neuroeconomics DISSERTATION zur Erlangung des akademischen Grades Dr. rer. pol. im Fach Volkswirtschaftslehre eingereicht an der Wirtschaftswissenschaftlichen Fakultät der Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin von Diplom-Volkswirt Holger Gerhardt geboren am 17. Januar 1978 in Arnsberg Präsident der Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin: Prof. Dr. Jan-Hendrik Olbertz Dekan der Wirtschaftswissenschaftlichen Fakultät: Prof. Oliver Günther, Ph. D. Gutachter: 1. Prof. Lutz Weinke, Ph. D. 2. Prof. Dr. Hauke R. Heekeren eingereicht am: 9. Mai 2011 Tag des Kolloquiums: 20. Juni 2011 Contents 1 Introduction 1 Bibliography . 3 2 Cognitive load increases risk aversion 5 2.1 Introduction . 5 2.2 Related literature . 7 2.2.1 Introductory remarks . 7 2.2.2 Overview of dual-system and “dual-self” approaches . 7 2.2.3 Subjective expected-utility theory as a unitary-process model of decision making under risk . 10 2.2.4 Dual-process approaches to decision making under risk . 11 2.2.5 Empirical evidence on dual processes in decision making under risk . 12 2.3 Experimental design . 17 2.3.1 Introduction: Advantages of our design over alternative designs . 17 2.3.2 Trial setup . 18 2.3.3 Additional measures of individual differences . 24 2.4 Results . 24 2.4.1 Introductory remarks . 24 2.4.2 Were the tasks adequate? . 25 2.4.3 How did subjects allocate attention to the two simultane- ous tasks? . 25 2.4.4 Preference reversal?—How often did subjects choose the riskier lottery? . 26 2.4.5 Structural regressions: the influence of additional cognitive load on subjects’ degree of relative risk aversion .
    [Show full text]
  • The Future of Economics in a Lakatos–Bourdieu Framework
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive The Future of Economics in a Lakatos–Bourdieu Framework. Heise, Arne University of Hamburg 2014 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/80024/ MPRA Paper No. 80024, posted 05 Jul 2017 05:42 UTC The Future of Economics in a Lakatos-Bourdieu framework Prof. Arne Heise University of Hamburg Dep. of Socioeconomics VMP 9 D-20146 Hamburg [email protected] Abstract The global financial crisis has clearly been a matter of great consternation for the busi- ness-as-usual faction of mainstream economics. Will the World Financial Crisis turn out to be that ‘experimentum crucis’ which triggered a scientific revolution? In this paper, we seek to assess the likelihood of a paradigm shift towards heterodox approaches and a more pluralist setting in economics emerging from the academic establishment in the U.S. – that is, from the dominant center of knowledge production in the economic disci- pline. This will be done by building the analysis on a combined Lakatosian framework of ‘battle of research programmes’ and a Bourdieuian framework of ‘power struggle’ within the academic field and highlighting the likelihood of two main proponents of the mainstream elite to become the promulgator of change? Keywords: Paradigm, heterodox economics, scientific revolution JEL codes: A 11, E 11, E 12 1 1. The Keynesian Revolution and Pragmatic Pluralism – A Fruitful Competition Between Theories or a Crisis in Economics? John Maynard Keynes concludes ‘The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money’ (1936: 383-84) with the following, now-famous words: „At the present moment people are unusually expectant of a more funda- mental diagnosis; more particularly ready to receive it; eager to try it out, if it should be even possible.
    [Show full text]
  • John Von Neumann Oskar Morgenstern
    Neuroeconomics: From The Failures of Expected Utility to the Neurobiology of Choice Paul Glimcher PhD Julius Silver Professor of Neural Science, Economics and Psychology Director, Institute of the Study of Decision Making New York University Blaise Pascal Genius: Expected Value Theory Expected Probability x Value = Value #1 0.5 100 50 #2 1.0 45 45 Pascal's Wager If God Exists If God Doesn't Exist (Prob 3 Value) + (Prob 3 Value) = Exp. Value Believe in God >0 3 `$++ 0 3 0 = ` Do not Believe >0 3 2` ++ $0 3 0 = 2` in God Problem: The Beggar’s Dilemma Daniel Bernoulli Genius: Expected Utility Theory Beggar’s Dilemma 4.3 3.8 Beggar’s Utility (utils) Beggar’s 0 7000 20,000 Rich Man’s Choice Beggar’s Wealth (florins) 6.0056 6.0 5.9969 Rich Man’s Utility (utils) Rich Man’s Problem: 0 losses wins Value ($) Bentham, Pareto, Samuelson 993,000 1,013,000 1,000,000 Jeremy Bentham Vilfredo Pareto Paul Samuelson The Calculus of Utility The Intrinsic Arbitrariness of Utility Ordinal Objective Utility John von Neumann Oskar Morgenstern Genius: Modern Expected Utility Theory 0 < a <1 a $ s = Expected 35til u Utility weight s.w. = prob Subjective 0 Utility (utils) 0 Probability Dollars ($) Critcal Advantages: • Precise • Compact • Normative (people Problem: make sense) Maurice Allais Maurice Allais People Do Not Obey EU all the time 0 < a <1 a $ s = Expected 35til u Utility weight s.w. = prob Subjective 0 Utility (utils) 0 XProbability Dollars ($) Critcal Questons: • How to Predict People? • Are People Dumb? • Why? Amos Tversky Danny Kahneman Prospect Theory Critcal Advantages: • Predictive Critcal Disadvantages: • Bulky • No Why Behavioral Traditional Social-Natural Science Boundary Economics vs.
    [Show full text]
  • Subsidizing Health Insurance for Low-Income Adults: Evidence from Massachusetts: Dataset.” American Economic Review
    American Economic Review 2019, 109(4): 1530–1567 https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20171455 Subsidizing Health Insurance for Low-Income Adults: Evidence from Massachusetts† By Amy Finkelstein, Nathaniel Hendren, and Mark Shepard* How much are low-income individuals willing to pay for health insurance, and what are the implications for insurance markets? Using administrative data from Massachusetts’ subsidized insurance exchange, we exploit discontinuities in the subsidy schedule to esti- mate willingness to pay and costs of insurance among low-income adults. As subsidies decline, insurance take-up falls rapidly, drop- ping about 25 percent for each $40 increase in monthly enrollee pre- miums. Marginal enrollees tend to be lower-cost , indicating adverse selection into insurance. But across the entire distribution we can observe approximately the bottom 70 percent of the willingness to pay distribution( enrollees’ willingness to pay is always less than half of their own) expected costs that they impose on the insurer. As a result, we estimate that take-up will be highly incomplete even with generous subsidies. If enrollee premiums were 25 percent of insur- ers’ average costs, at most half of potential enrollees would buy insurance; even premiums subsidized to 10 percent of average costs would still leave at least 20 percent uninsured. We briefly consider potential explanations for these findings and their normative impli- cations. JEL G22, H51, H75, I13, I18 ( ) Governments spend an enormous amount of money on health insurance for low-income
    [Show full text]
  • Still Preliminary and Incomplete
    EQUALIZING SUPERSTARS: THE INTERNET AND THE DEMOCRATIZATION OF EDUCATION DARON ACEMOGLU, DAVID LAIBSON, AND JOHN A. LIST Abstract. Educational resources distributed via the Internet are rapidly proliferating. One prominent concern associated with these potentially transformative developments is that, as many of the leading technologies of the last several decades have been, these new sweeping technological changes will be highly disequalizing, creating superstar teachers, a wider gulf between different groups of students and potentially a winner-take-all educational system. In this paper, we argue that, these important concerns notwithstanding, a major impact of the superstars created by web-based educational technologies will be the democ- ratization of education: not only will educational resources be more equally distributed, but also lower-skilled teachers will be winners from this technology. At the root of our results is the observation that for web-based technologies to exploit the comparative advantage of skilled lecturers, they will need to be complemented with opportunities for face-to-face discussions with instructors, and web-based lectures will increase the quantity and quality of teaching services complementary to such instruction, potentially increasing the marginal product and wages of lower-skill teachers. Still Preliminary and Incomplete. 1. Introduction Educational resources distributed via the Internet are rapidly proliferating. These new re- sources include lecture videos, on-line teaching notes, Internet chat groups, on-line interactive problem sets with instantaneous feedback/grading, educational games, and many other de- veloping technologies. Numerous institutions have created fully autonomous software that grades student essays.1 In the popular press, MOOC’s(massive open on-line courses) have received the most fanfare, though the social value of these courses is as yet unproven and the high drop-out rates (in excess of 90%) have been fodder for much debate (see Ahmad et Date: December 26, 2013.
    [Show full text]