Economic Insecurity and the Institutional Prerequisites for Successful Capitalism Author(S): Hyman P

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Economic Insecurity and the Institutional Prerequisites for Successful Capitalism Author(S): Hyman P Economic Insecurity and the Institutional Prerequisites for Successful Capitalism Author(s): Hyman P. Minsky and Charles J. Whalen Source: Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, Vol. 19, No. 2 (Winter, 1996-1997), pp. 155-170 Published by: M.E. Sharpe, Inc. Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/4538526 Accessed: 09/06/2010 11:36 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=mes. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. M.E. Sharpe, Inc. is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of Post Keynesian Economics. http://www.jstor.org HYMAN P. MINSKY AND CHARLESJ. WHALEN Economic insecurity and the institutional prerequisites for successful capitalism Fifty years ago, PresidentTruman signed into law the EmploymentAct that committedthe U.S. governmentto the goal of employmentoppor- tunitiesfor all Americans.The act representeda pledge to avoid another GreatDepression. It acknowledgedthat governmenthas a vital role to play in establishingnational economic stabilityand prosperity. U.S. economic performanceduring the past fifty years can be divided into two periods of roughlyequal duration.The first was characterized by a successful economy: cyclical instability was controlled; public investmentand human resource development were supported;and flaws in selected marketswere corrected.It was a period of robusteconomic growth, rising workerincomes, and falling inequality. The second period broughta reversal of fortune. We have avoided another depression but suffer from a return of financial instability. Economic growth has been sustained for the near term, but public infrastructureis neglected and family earningsare stagnant.Corporate profits have been stabilized,but inequalityhas increasedconsiderably and economic insecuritynow pervadesthe work force. Ourcurrent difficulties make it necessaryto considernot only how we measurethe success of an economy but also the institutionalprerequi- sites for a successful twenty-first-centurycapitalism. But first we must ask: What accounts for the split in the United States' economic experi- ence duringthe post-World War II era? When this articlewas written,the authorswere DistinguishedScholar and Resident Scholar,respectively, at the JeromeLevy Economics Instituteof BardCollege. HymanMinsky died on October24, 1996. CharlesWhalen is currentlySenior Econo- mist at the Institutefor IndustryStudies, an entity within the School of Industrialand LaborRelations at Cornell University.An early version of this articlewas presented at "The EmploymentAct: Fifty Years Later,"a session of the EasternEconomic As- sociation Annual Meeting, Boston, March15, 1996. Valuableassistance and/or com- ments were providedby Don Goldstein,Triveni Kuchi,Jonathan Neale, Ronnie Phillips, Bob Pollin, SamiraRajan, Jim Tobin, and RandyWray. Journal of Post KeynesianEconomics / Winter 1996-97, Vol. 19,No. 2 155 156 JOURNALOF POST KEYNESIANECONOMICS Money-manager capitalism Numerousexplanations have been proposed to accountfor the falling worker incomes and rising instability,inequality, and insecurityof the past two decades.Increases in taxes,government spending, and regulation are not to blame.The United States' income problems can be tracedto pretaxeamings; governmentshares of total employmentand expenditurehave not been growingsince 1979;and regulatory costs havedeclined (Mishel, 1995).' Other explanationsfocus on one or more of the following develop- ments: the shift of jobs from goods-producingsectors to the service sector; a long period of slow overall productivity growth, despite significanttechnological change (especially in the realmof information processing);public-sector privatization and corporatedownsizing and outsourcing;increased immigration; the erosion of the minimumwage andthe decline of unions;the growthof contingentwork; the appearance of persistenttrade deficits; and increasedcapital mobility, trade liberal- ization, and global competition.While some have sought to calculate the relative impact of these developments, Barry Bluestone (1995) seems to emphasize the most essential aspect of the matter when he suggests that the solution to this mystery is the same as in Agatha Christie'sMurder on the OrientExpress- they all did it. Despite the relevance of the aforementionedfactors, one crucial ele- ment has been left out-the evolution of the financial structure.Capi- talism is a dynamic, evolving system that comes in many forms. Nowhere is this dynamismmore evident than in its financialstructure. The financial structureof the American economy has undergone significantevolution over the historyof the republic.In the initialera of commercialcapitalism, external finance was used primarilyto facilitate commerce by financing goods in process or in transit. The present period,in contrast,is one of money-managercapitalism,where financial marketsand arrangementsare dominatedby institutionalinvestors.2 Three financial stages, industrial,financial, and managerial capital- ism, were dominantbetween the eras of commercialand money-man- ager capitalism. The shift away from commercialcapitalism came as financing for productionand trade purposes became dwarfed by the I While there is little evidence linking contemporaryeconomic problemsto tax in- creases, Wolfson ( 1993) identifies a numberof business tax breaksenacted since the 1980s that have providedstrong incentives for corporaterestructuring. 2 As the name "commercial"capitalism suggests, merchantand commercialbanks were the dominantfinancial institutions of this early capitalistera. ECONOMICINSECURITY AND SUCCESSFULCAPITALISM 157 reliance on external funds to finance long-term capital development. Thus, industrialcapitalism was characterizedby the rise of industries thatrequired vast resourcesfor projects such as railroads,utilities, mills, and mines. This createda marketfor the services of investmentbanks thatnot only arrangedto financesuch investmentsbut also financedthe rise of trusts and cartels. The largely unregulated era of financial capitalism that emerged was broughtto an end by the United States' economic contraction and eventual financial-system collapse in the period 1929-33. The managerial era was ushered in by the economic policies and reformsof the New Deal. Importantaspects of the managerialperiod's financialsystem included: * Countercyclicalfiscal policy, which sustained profits when the economy faltered;3 * Low interestrates and interventionsby the FederalReserve uncon- strainedby gold-standardconsiderations; * Deposit insurancefor banks and thrifts; * An infusionof governmentequity into transportation, industry, and finance throughthe ReconstructionFinance Corporation(a tem- porary,national investment bank); * Restrictionson competition(including geographic barriers to mar- ket entry, compartmentalizationof financialinstitutions by func- tion, and interest-rateregulation); and * Interventionsby specializedorganizations (such as the Agricultural AdjustmentAdministration and the FederalHousing Administra- tion) createdto addresssectoral concerns. Anotherimportant aspect of themanagerial period was thenature of indebt- edness.From 1933 through the end of WorldWar II, government represented themain source of extemalfinancing for the economy. By 1946,a broadset of householdsowned financial assets mainly in the formof governmentdebt or as interestsin insurancepolicies and bank deposits that were in turnlargely offsetby governmentdebts. Business and household indebtedness was mini- mal;many ofthe great corporations had large net positions in govemment debts and bankdeposits--and many working-class households held substantially largernet financialasset positions than hitherto. 3For a discussion of how the National LaborRelations ("Wagner") Act was also de- signed to contributeto macroeconomicstabilization, see Kaufman(1996). 158 JOURNALOF POST KEYNESIANECONOMICS Money-managercapitalism emerged out of this initial postwar posi- tion. In part, it was the result of the evolution of financial practices toward more speculative endeavors. But money-managercapitalism was also a consequence of institutionalinnovations and the growth of privatepensions that supplemented social security.As the label"money- manager"capitalism suggests, centralto this new stage are institutions that manage large portfoliosof financialinstruments. Economic activity in the early postwar setting began with a cautious use of debt.But, as the periodof economicprosperity began to lengthen, marginsof safety in indebtednessdecreased and the systemevolved: not only
Recommended publications
  • Consumerism in the 1920S: Collected Commentary
    BECOMING MODERN: AMERICA IN THE 1920S PRIMARY SOURCE COLLECTION ONTEMPORAR Y HE WENTIES IN OMMENTARY T T C * Leonard Dove, The New Yorker, October 26, 1929 — CONSUMERISM — Mass-produced consumer goods like automobiles and ready-to-wear clothes were not new to the 1920s, nor were advertising or mail- order catalogues. But something was new about Americans’ relationship with manufactured products, and it was accelerating faster than it could be defined. Not only did the latest goods become necessities, consumption itself became a necessity, it seemed to observers. Was that good for America? Yes, said some—people can live in unprecedented comfort and material security. Not so fast, said others—can we predict where consumerism is taking us before we’re inextricably there? Something new has come to confront American democracy. Samuel Strauss The Fathers of the Nation did not foresee it. History had opened “Things Are in the Saddle” to their foresight most of the obstacles which might be expected The Atlantic Monthly to get in the way of the Republic—political corruption, extreme November 1924 wealth, foreign domination, faction, class rule; . That which has stolen across the path of American democracy and is already altering Americanism was not in their calculations. History gave them no hint of it. What is happening today is without precedent, at least so far as historical research has discovered. No reformer, no utopian, no physiocrat, no poet, no writer of fantastic romances saw in his dreams the particular development which is with us here and now. This is our proudest boast: “The American citizen has more comforts and conveniences than kings had two hundred years ago.” It is a fact, and this fact is the outward evidence of the new force which has crossed the path of American democracy.
    [Show full text]
  • Prosperity Economics Building an Economy for All
    ProsPerity economics Building an economy for All Jacob S. Hacker and Nate Loewentheil ProsPerity economics Building an economy for All Jacob S. Hacker and Nate Loewentheil Creative Commons (cc) 2012 by Jacob S. Hacker and Nate Loewentheil Notice of rights: This book has been published under a Creative Commons license (Attribution-NonCom- mercial-NoDerivs 3.0 Unported; to view a copy of this license, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/ by-nc-sa/3.0/). This work may be copied, redistributed, or displayed by anyone, provided that proper at- tribution is given. ii / prosperity economics About the authors Jacob S. Hacker, Ph.D., is the Director of the Institution for Social and Policy Studies (ISPS), the Stanley B. Resor Professor of Political Science, and Senior Research Fellow in International and Area Studies at the MacMil- lan Center at Yale University. An expert on the politics of U.S. health and social policy, he is author of Winner-Take-All Politics: How Wash- ington Made the Rich Richer—And Turned Its Back on the Middle Class, with Paul Pierson (September 2010, paperback March 2011); The Great Risk Shift: The New Economic Insecurity and the Decline of the American Dream (2006, paperback 2008); The Divided Welfare State: The Battle Over Public and Private Social Benefits in the United States (2002); and The Road to Nowhere: The Genesis of President Clinton’s Plan for Health Security (1997), co-winner of the Brownlow Book Award of the National Academy of Public Administration. He is also co-author, with Paul Pierson, of Off Center: The Republican Revolution and the Erosion of American Democracy (2005), and has edited three volumes, most recently, Shared Responsibility, Shared Risk: Government, Markets and Social Policy in the Twenty-First Century, with Ann O'Leary (2012).
    [Show full text]
  • A Consumers' Republic: the Politics of Mass Consumption in Postwar
    A Consumers’ Republic: The Politics of Mass Consumption in Postwar America The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters Citation Cohen, Lizabeth. 2004. A consumers’ republic: The politics of mass consumption in postwar America. Journal of Consumer Research 31(1): 236-239. Published Version doi:10.1086/383439 Citable link http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:4699747 Terms of Use This article was downloaded from Harvard University’s DASH repository, and is made available under the terms and conditions applicable to Other Posted Material, as set forth at http:// nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:dash.current.terms-of- use#LAA Reflections and Reviews A Consumers’ Republic: The Politics of Mass Consumption in Postwar America LIZABETH COHEN* istorians and social scientists analyzing the contem- sumer market. A wide range of economic interests and play- H porary world unfortunately have too little contact and ers all came to endorse the centrality of mass consumption hence miss some of the ways that their interests overlap and to a successful reconversion from war to peace. Factory the research of one field might benefit another. I am, there- assembly lines newly renovated with Uncle Sam’s dollars fore, extremely grateful that the Journal of Consumer Re- stood awaiting conversion from building tanks and muni- search has invited me to share with its readers an overview tions for battle to producing cars and appliances for sale to of my recent research on the political and social impact of consumers. the flourishing of mass consumption on twentieth-century If encouraging a mass consumer economy seemed to America.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Prosperity Element
    ECONOMIC PROSPERITY LIVE GOALS, OBJECTIVES, AND POLICIES GOAL ECP 1 TALENT & HUMAN CAPITAL GOAL ECP 2 INCLUSIVE ENTREPRENEURSHIP WORK GOAL ECP 3 INDUSTRY CLUSTERS GOAL ECP 4 BUSINESS CLIMATE & COMPETITIVENESS GOAL ECP 5 EQUITY AND ECONOMIC INCLUSION PLAY GOAL ECP 6 ECONOMIC PLACEMAKING GOAL ECP 7 ECONOMIC LEADERSHIP & PARTNERSHIP GOAL ECP 8 COMMUNITY LIFE GROW Comprehensive Plan | 2019 ECONOMIC PROSPERITY ELEMENT WHAT IS THE ECONOMIC PROSPERITY ELEMENT? The Economic Prosperity Element is new to the City’s Comprehensive Plan and provides context for policy, resource allocation and guidance as to how the City will seek to promote prosperity as the Delray Beach’s economy develops and evolves. The International Economic Development Council defines economic development as “a process that influences growth and restructuring of an economy to enhance the economic well-being of a community.” Community benefits from a successful economic development approach and strategy including: 1) new business activity; 2) higher incomes; 3) wealth-building; and 4) tax revenues to fund public services and community life investments. Effective economic development involves a coordinated cross-disciplinary approach to business attraction, business development, business retention, workforce capacity-building, tourism, and infrastructure investments, as drivers of economic growth. The City has focused on growing local businesses, business retention and expansion, redevelopment and revitalization, downtown development, tourism and sports, arts and culture, special events, and community development as economic development strategies. While this approach has been effective, investments in people, place, and industry development are necessary to fill gaps in the city industries and economic outcomes. Additionally, Delray Beach’s prior economic success does not yet mean prosperity for all.
    [Show full text]
  • Is Globalization a Source of Prosperity and Progress Or the Main Cause of Poverty? What Has to Be Done to Reduce Poverty?
    Journal of Social Sciences, 1(1):13-17,2012 ISSN:2233-3878 Is Globalization a Source of Prosperity and Progress or the Main Cause of Poverty? What has to be done to Reduce Poverty? Valeri MODEBADZE* Abstract This article analyses globalization process and its positive and negative sides. Globalization is a double-edged phenomenon. This research is based on comparative method. Two contradictory approaches to understanding globalization are compared with each other. On the one hand, advocates of globalization argue that globalization is a positive phenomenon which promotes greater prosperity and increases living standards of people. On the other hand, opponents of globalization see it as the main cause of impoverishment and economic crisis. The problem of describing the effects of globalization is closely linked with these two contradictory approaches to understanding globalization. Keywords: globalization, positive and negative sides of globalization, transnational institutions, environmental degradation, global warming Introduction – Definition of Globalization national trade and international business operations. Thus, economic life has been progressively globalized. National Before we start comparing two contradictory ap- economies have been integrated into global economy and proaches to globalization, we have to define it. Globali- they have become so interdependent that they cannot func- zation refers to the growing interconnectedness of differ- tion separately from each other. One of the consequences of ent parts of the world. It is a process which gives rise to globalization is the emergence of multinational companies a complex form of interaction and interdependency. The and transnational corporations. These are very powerful world is becoming a global village and interdependence organizations that produce output in more than one state.
    [Show full text]
  • Prosperity Without Growth?Transition the Prosperity to a Sustainable Economy 2009
    Prosperity without growth? The transition to a sustainable economy to a sustainable The transition www.sd-commission.org.uk Prosperity England 2009 (Main office) 55 Whitehall London SW1A 2HH without 020 7270 8498 [email protected] Scotland growth? Osborne House 1 Osbourne Terrace, Haymarket Edinburgh EH12 5HG 0131 625 1880 [email protected] www.sd-commission.org.uk/scotland Wales Room 1, University of Wales, University Registry, King Edward VII Avenue, Cardiff, CF10 3NS Commission Development Sustainable 029 2037 6956 [email protected] www.sd-commission.org.uk/wales Northern Ireland Room E5 11, OFMDFM The transition to a Castle Buildings, Stormont Estate, Belfast BT4 3SR sustainable economy 028 9052 0196 [email protected] www.sd-commission.org.uk/northern_ireland Prosperity without growth? The transition to a sustainable economy Professor Tim Jackson Economics Commissioner Sustainable Development Commission Acknowledgements This report was written in my capacity as Economics Commissioner for the Sustainable Development Commission at the invitation of the Chair, Jonathon Porritt, who provided the initial inspiration, contributed extensively throughout the study and has been unreservedly supportive of my own work in this area for many years. For all these things, my profound thanks. The work has also inevitably drawn on my role as Director of the Research group on Lifestyles, Values and Environment (RESOLVE) at the University of Surrey, where I am lucky enough to work with a committed, enthusiastic and talented team of people carrying out research in areas relevant to this report. Their research is evident in the evidence base on which this report draws and I’m as grateful for their continuing intellectual support as I am for the financial support of the Economic and Social Research Council (Grant No: RES-152-25-1004) which keeps RESOLVE going.
    [Show full text]
  • Local Interpretations of Degrowth—Actors, Arenas and Attempts to Influence Policy
    sustainability Article Local Interpretations of Degrowth—Actors, Arenas and Attempts to Influence Policy Katarina Buhr 1, Karolina Isaksson 2,3,* ID and Pernilla Hagbert 3 1 IVL Swedish Environmental Research Institute, Climate and Sustainable Cities Unit, 10031 Stockholm, Sweden; [email protected] 2 VTI, the Swedish National Road and Transport Research Institute, Division of Mobility, Actors and Planning Processes, 10215 Stockholm, Sweden 3 KTH Royal Institute of Technology, Department of Urban Planning and Environment, 10044 Stockholm, Sweden; [email protected] * Correspondence: [email protected]; Tel.: +46-766-334-328 Received: 3 May 2018; Accepted: 4 June 2018; Published: 6 June 2018 Abstract: During the last decade, degrowth has developed into a central research theme within sustainability science. A significant proportion of previous works on degrowth has focused on macro-level units of analysis, such as global or national economies. Less is known about local interpretations of degrowth. This study explored interpretations of growth and degrowth in a local setting and attempts to integrate degrowth ideas into local policy. The work was carried out as a qualitative single-case study of the small town of Alingsås, Sweden. The results revealed two different, yet interrelated, local growth discourses in Alingsås: one relating to population growth and one relating to economic growth. Individuals participating in the degrowth discourse tend to have a sustainability-related profession and/or background in civil society. Arenas for local degrowth discussions are few and temporary and, despite some signs of influence, degrowth-related ideas have not had any significant overall impact on local policy and planning.
    [Show full text]
  • Neoliberal Metaphors in Presidential Discourse from Ronald Reagan to Donald Trump
    Angles New Perspectives on the Anglophone World 8 | 2019 Neoliberalism in the Anglophone World Neoliberal Metaphors in Presidential Discourse from Ronald Reagan to Donald Trump Jérôme Viala-Gaudefroy Electronic version URL: http://journals.openedition.org/angles/625 DOI: 10.4000/angles.625 ISSN: 2274-2042 Publisher Société des Anglicistes de l'Enseignement Supérieur Electronic reference Jérôme Viala-Gaudefroy, « Neoliberal Metaphors in Presidential Discourse from Ronald Reagan to Donald Trump », Angles [Online], 8 | 2019, Online since 01 April 2019, connection on 28 July 2020. URL : http://journals.openedition.org/angles/625 ; DOI : https://doi.org/10.4000/angles.625 This text was automatically generated on 28 July 2020. Angles. New Perspectives on the Anglophone World is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution- NonCommercial-ShareAlike 4.0 International License. Neoliberal Metaphors in Presidential Discourse from Ronald Reagan to Donald T... 1 Neoliberal Metaphors in Presidential Discourse from Ronald Reagan to Donald Trump Jérôme Viala-Gaudefroy 1 Neoliberalism is an ambiguous and complex concept. Unlike Keynesianism, it is not a unified doctrine (Davies 2017: 19). It is sometimes employed without any clear definition, or its meaning reduced to laissez-faire economics. The difficulty in defining neoliberalism may come partly from the asymmetry of its usage. Today, it is used almost exclusively in the negative sense, and no one self-identifies as a “neoliberal” (Boas and Gan-Morse 2009: 138-40). Its meaning is also context-dependent and the result of a complicated historical development (Coles 2017: 21). 2 The word itself goes back to the 1890s (Oxford English Dictionary), but the idea of a new form of economic liberalism really emerged in the 1930s.
    [Show full text]
  • Sustainability and Economic De-Growth
    Brief for GSDR 2015 Sustainability and economic de-growth Maria Rita Guercio - University of São Paulo* A major problem that permeates human degradation of the environment happens development today are the limits that the only to meet the needs of the wealthier Earth's ecosystem imposes on efforts to half of the world population, while the persist in an increasing economic growth. poorest are suffering from environmental With the end of t the Cold War the degradation and are still priced out of environmental issue gained relevance but material blessings. The poorest countries the economic interests still speak louder. suffer from drought, soil desertification, The pattern of development based on the floods, dumping of toxic products and model of the Industrial Revolution still other environmental disasters. remains and is structured as unsustainable. Sustainability means, of course, social But this unbridled growth resulted in inclusion and rational use of natural speculative bubbles and crises which resources. further harm the ecosystem and do not cooperate in a sustainable and more Michael Renner says the Green Economy is equitable society. Michael Renner of World the tendency to ally development Watch Institute says: "In general, respecting the natural limits of the environmental governance was relegated ecosystem, creating social welfare reducing to the sidelines in search of economic environmental risks. Emerging countries globalization driven by corporate interests are somewhat resistant when carbon - a process that has been marked by emission containment measures are deregulation and privatization and the required, and may represent a limitation to relative weakening of political institutions their development. However, it is the task of the emerging countries, which have not national "(Renner, 2012).
    [Show full text]
  • WORLD URBAN FORUM 6 Prosperity for Sustainable Cities: Balancing Ecology, Economy and Equity Version 3.0
    WORLD URBAN FORUM 6 Prosperity for Sustainable Cities: Balancing Ecology, Economy and Equity Version 3.0 BACKGROUND DOCUMENT Urbanization: a Truly Global Experience Urbanization is inevitable. It makes countries change from a rural to an urban experience. Yet more than a transitional process, urbanization is a transformative process. As countries urbanize they become more advanced, developed and richer, in most cases. Urbanization is part of an old ‘recent’ history. Narratives of urban biographies tell us of human preference to get together to exchange, learn, produce and protect each other in an environment that was rather hostile. As towns and cities grew bigger more and more people came to them in search of jobs, opportunities and different forms of prosperity. Moving to a city is an objective desire to have a better life. The search of prosperity is therefore one of the main causes of the existence of cities. They are the places where humanity realizes needs, ideas, ambitions and aspirations. Cities over time and throughout the world have developed in unique ways, and no single history can account for them all. Yet, it is clear that places where human beings can flourish, feel happy and healthy, and where business, trade and different forms of productivity can thrive, develop and generate wealth are prosperous places. Prosperity is the essence of progress and the way development materializes. In 2008, the world reached an invisible but momentous milestone: for the first time in history, more than half of its human population, 3.3 billion people, was living in urban areas. By 2030, this number is expected to increase to 5 billion, when 6 out of every 10 people in the world will be urbanites.1 Urbanization has become, to a large extent, synonymous with modernization, industrialization and development.
    [Show full text]
  • Hayek, Arrow, and the Problems of Democratic Decision-Making
    Working Paper 15 Hayek, Arrow, and the Problems of Democratic Decision-Making * PETER J. BOETTKE AND PETER T. LEESON Abstract Both Hayek and Arrow provide argume nts about the inability of the vote process to yield a coherent social choice. Hayek demonstrated that planning is incompatible with democracy; its c oherence requires dictatorship. Arrow demonstrated that voting fails to pr oduce rational social choices; social rationality can be assured only when there is a single will. In both, the substitution of a single will for the many wills is ruled as incompatible with a free society. Because market socialism relies upon either the existence of a meaningful, stable social welfare function or democratic decision-making to allocate resources, the complimentary arguments of Hayek and Arrow imply that market socialism requires dictatorship to achieve coherence. * Peter J. Boettke is Professor of Economics at George Mason University, Deputy Director of the James M. Buchanan Center for Political Economy, Senior Research Fellow at the Mercatus Center, and Faculty Director of the Mercatus Center’s Global Prosperity Initiative. Peter T. Leeson is a Mercatus Center Social Change Graduate Fellow, and a PhD student in Economics at George Mason University. The ideas presented in this research are the authors' and do not represent official positions of the Mercatus Center at George Mason University. Hayek, Arrow, and the Problems of Democratic Decision-Making* Abstract: Both Hayek and Arrow provide arguments about the inability of the vote process to yield a coherent social choice. Hayek demonstrated that planning is incompatible with democracy; its coherence requires dictatorship. Arrow demonstrated that voting fails to produce rational social choices; social rationality can be assured only when there is a single will.
    [Show full text]
  • Post-War Reconstruction and Development in the Golden Age of Capitalism
    Chapter II Post-war reconstruction and development in the Golden Age of Capitalism Key messages • The World Economic and Social Survey was an early proponent of development as a process of large-scale struc- tural and institutional change for the promotion of high standards of living, full employment and social progress. Starting from the first edition, issued in January 1948, the Survey recognized the need for coordinated interna- tional action to accelerate economic growth, facilitate the cross-border flow of goods and services and support effective utilization of resources in the context of an expanding and integrated world economy. • The expansion of international trade and a functioning payments system were recognized as two critical factors for development in the post-Second World War period. However, large fluctuations in commodity prices and, cor- respondingly, in foreign exchange earnings were a source of economic instability for many developing countries back then and this has continued to be the case right up to the present. • In the 1950s, the flexibility that European countries were afforded in meeting their International Monetary Fund- related obligations enabled the successful creation of the multilateral international payments system. Six years after the initial commitment, most Western Europe countries had eliminated foreign exchange restrictions and established current account convertibility. A similar flexibility in debt negotiations was important for the facilita- tion of a rapid recovery in Europe in the post-Second World War period as well as in Latin America in the 1930s. • International solidarity has played an important role in development and reconstruction. Western European countries received resources equivalent to 1 per cent of the gross national product of the United States of Amer- ica in the period from 1948 to 1952 through the Marshall Plan.
    [Show full text]