Financial Mathematics

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Financial Mathematics Financial Mathematics Rudiger¨ Kiesel February, 2005 0-0 1 Financial Mathematics Lecture 1 by Rudiger¨ Kiesel Department of Financial Mathematics, University of Ulm Department of Statistics, LSE RSITÄT V E U I L N M U · · S O C I D E N N A D R O U · C · D O O C D E c Rudiger¨ Kiesel N 2 Aims and Objectives • Review basic concepts of probability theory; • Discuss random variables, their distribution and the notion of independence; • Calculate functionals and transforms; • Review basic limit theorems. RSITÄT V E U I L N M U · · S O C I D E N N A D R O U · C · D O O C D E c Rudiger¨ Kiesel N 3 Probability theory To describe a random experiment we use sample space Ω, the set of all possible outcomes. Each point ω of Ω, or sample point, represents a possible random outcome of performing the random experiment. For a set A ⊆ Ω we want to know the probability IP (A). The class F of subsets of Ω whose probabilities IP (A) are defined (call such A events) should be be a σ-algebra , i.e. closed under countable, disjoint unions and complements, and contain the empty set ∅ and the whole space Ω. Examples. Flip coins, Roll two dice. RSITÄT V E U I L N M U · · S O C I D E N N A D R O U · C · D O O C D E c Rudiger¨ Kiesel N 4 Probability theory We want (i) IP (∅) = 0, IP (Ω) = 1, (ii) IP (A) ≥ 0 for all A, (iii) If A1,A2,..., are disjoint, S P IP ( i Ai) = i IP (Ai) countable additivity. (iv) If B ⊆ A and IP (A) = 0, then IP (B) = 0 (completeness). A probability space, or Kolmogorov triple, is a triple (Ω, F, IP ) satisfying Kolmogorov axioms (i),(ii),(iii), (iv) above. RSITÄT E U A probability space is a mathematical model of a random experiment. IV L N M U · · S O C I D E N N A D R O U · C · D O O C D E c Rudiger¨ Kiesel N 5 Probability theory Let (Ω, F, IP ) be a probability space. A random variable (vector) X is a function X :Ω → IR(IRk) such that X−1(B) = {ω ∈ Ω: X(ω) ∈ B} ∈ F for all Borel sets B ∈ B(B(IRk)). For a random variable X {ω ∈ Ω: X(ω) ≤ x} ∈ F for all x ∈ IR. So define the distribution function FX of X by FX (x) := IP ({ω : X(ω) ≤ x}). Recall: σ(X), the σ-algebra generated by X. RSITÄT V E U I L N M U · · S O C I D E N N A D R O U · C · D O O C D E c Rudiger¨ Kiesel N 6 Probability theory • Binomial distribution: Number of successes n IP (S = k) = pk(1 − p)n−k. n k • Geometric distribtion: Waiting time IP (N = n) = p(1 − p)n−1. • Poisson distribution: λ IP (X = k) = e−λ . k! • Uniform distribution: 1 RSITÄT f(x) = 1 . V E U {(a,b)} I L N M b − a U · · S O C I D E N N A D R O U · C · D O O C D E c Rudiger¨ Kiesel N 7 Probability theory • Exponential distribution: −λx f(x) = λe 1{[0,∞)}. The expectation E of a random variable X on (Ω, F, IP ) is defined by Z Z E X := XdIP, or X(ω)dIP (ω). Ω Ω The variance of a random variable is defined as 2 2 2 V (X) := E (X − E (X)) = E X − (E X). RSITÄT V E U I L N M U · · S O C I D E N N A D R O U · C · D O O C D E c Rudiger¨ Kiesel N 8 Probability theory If X is real-valued with density f, Z E X := xf(x)dx or if X is discrete, taking values xn(n = 1, 2,...) with probability function f(xn)(≥ 0), X E X := xnf(xn). Examples. Moments for some of the above distributions. Random variables X1,...,Xn are independent if whenever Ai ∈ B for i = 1, . n we have n ! n \ Y IP {Xi ∈ Ai} = IP ({Xi ∈ Ai}). RSITÄT V E U i=1 i=1 I L N M U · · S O C I D E N N A D R O U · C · D O O C D E c Rudiger¨ Kiesel N 9 Probability theory In order for X1,...,Xn to be independent it is necessary and sufficient that for all x1, . xn ∈ (−∞, ∞], n ! n \ Y IP {Xi ≤ xi} = IP ({Xi ≤ xi}). i=1 i=1 Multiplication Theorem If X1,...,Xn are independent and E |Xi| < ∞, i = 1, . , n, then n ! n Y Y E Xi = E (Xi). i=1 i=1 RSITÄT V E U I L N M U · · S O C I D E N N A D R O U · C · D O O C D E c Rudiger¨ Kiesel N 10 Probability theory If X, Y are independent, with distribution functions F , G Z := X + Y, let Z have distribution function H. Call H the convolution of F and G, written H = F ∗ G. Suppose X, Y have densities f, g. Then Z H(z) = IP (X + Y ≤ z) = f(x)g(y)dxdy, {(x,y):x+y≤z} Thus Z ∞ Z z−x Z ∞ H(z) = f(x) g(y)dy dx = f(x)G(z − x)dx. −∞ −∞ −∞ RSITÄT V E U I L N M Example. Gamma distribution. U · · S O C I D E N N A D R O U · C · D O O C D E c Rudiger¨ Kiesel N 11 Probability theory If X is a random variable with distribution function F , its moment generating function φX is Z ∞ tX tx φ(t) := E (e ) = e dF (x). −∞ The mgf takes convolution into multiplication: if X, Y are independent, φX+Y (t) = φX (t)φY (t). Observe φ(k)(t) = E (XketX ) and φ(0) = E (Xk). For X on nonnegative integers use the generating function ∞ X X k γX (z) = E (z ) = z IP (Z = k). SITÄ ER T k=0 V U I L N M U · · S O C I D E N N A D R O U · C · D O O C D E c Rudiger¨ Kiesel N 12 Probability theory Conditional expectation For events: IP (A|B) := IP (A ∩ B)/IP (B) if IP (B) > 0. Implies the multiplication rule: IP (A ∩ B) = IP (A|B)IP (B) Leads to the Bayes rule IP (Ai)IP (B|Ai) IP (Ai|B) = P . j IP (Aj)IP (B|Aj) RSITÄT V E U I L N M U · · S O C I D E N N A D R O U · C · D O O C D E c Rudiger¨ Kiesel N 13 Probability theory For discrete random variables: If X takes values x1, . , xm with probabilities f1(xi) > 0, Y takes values y1, . , yn with probabilities f2(yj) > 0, (X, Y ) takes values (xi, yj) with probabilities f(xi, yj) > 0, then the marginal distributions are n X f1(xi) = f(xi, yj). j=1 m X f (y ) = f(x , y ). 2 j i j RSITÄT V E U I L N M i=1 U · · S O C I D E N N A D R O U · C · D O O C D E c Rudiger¨ Kiesel N 14 Probability theory IP (X = xi,Y = yj) IP (Y = yj|X = xi) = IP (X = xi) f(xi, yj) f(xi, yj) = = Pn . f1(xi) j=1 f(xi, yj) So the conditional distribution of Y given X = xi f(xi, yj) f(xi, yj) fY |X (yj|xi) = = Pn . f1(xi) j=1 f(xi, yj) RSITÄT V E U I L N M U · · S O C I D E N N A D R O U · C · D O O C D E c Rudiger¨ Kiesel N 15 Probability theory Its expectation is X E (Y |X = xi) = yjfY |X (yj|xi) j P j yjf(xi, yj) = P . j f(xi, yj) RSITÄT V E U I L N M U · · S O C I D E N N A D R O U · C · D O O C D E c Rudiger¨ Kiesel N 16 Probability theory Density case. If (X, Y ) has density f(x, y), R ∞ X has density f1(x) := −∞ f(x, y)dy, R ∞ Y has density f2(y) := −∞ f(x, y)dx. The conditional density of Y given X = x is: f(x, y) f(x, y) f (y|x) := = . Y |X f (x) R ∞ 1 −∞ f(x, y)dy Its expectation is Z ∞ E (Y |X = x) = yfY |X (y|x)dy −∞ R ∞ −∞ yf(x, y)dy = R ∞ . f(x, y)dy RSITÄT V E U −∞ I L N M U · · S O C I D E N N A D R O U · C · D O O C D E c Rudiger¨ Kiesel N 17 Probability theory General case. Suppose that G is a sub-σ-algebra of F, G ⊂ F If Y is a non-negative random variable with E Y < ∞, then Z Q(B) := Y dIP (B ∈ G) B is non-negative, σ-additive – because Z X Z Y dIP = Y dIP B n Bn if B = ∪nBn, Bn disjoint – and defined on the σ-algebra G, so is a measure on G.
Recommended publications
  • Contingent-Claim-Based Expected Stock Returns∗
    Contingent-Claim-Based Expected Stock Returns∗ Zhiyao Chen Ilya A. Strebulaev ICMA Centre Graduate School of Business University of Reading Stanford University and NBER ∗We thank Harjoat Bhamra, Chris Brooks, Wayne Ferson, Vito Gala, Andrea Gamba, Jo˜ao Gomes, Patrick Gagliardini, Chris Hennessy, Chris Juilliard, Nan Li, Rajnish Mehra, Stefan Nagel, Stavros Panageas, Marcel Prokopczuk, Michael Roberts, Ravindra Sastry, Stephan Siegel, Neal Stoughton, Yuri Tserlukevich, Kathy Yuan, Jeffrey Zwiebel and participants at the ASU Sonoran 2013 Winter Finance Conference, the European Financial Associations 2013 annual meetings and the American Financial Associations 2014 annual meetings for their helpful comments. Zhiyao Chen: ICMA Centre, University of Reading, UK, email: [email protected]; Ilya A. Strebulaev: Graduate School of Business, Stanford University, and NBER, email: [email protected]. Contingent-Claim-Based Expected Stock Returns Abstract We develop and test a parsimonious contingent claims model for cross-sectional returns of stock portfolios formed on market leverage, book-to-market equity, asset growth rate, and equity size. Since stocks are residual claims on firms’ assets that generate operating cash flows, stock returns are cash flow rates scaled by the sen- sitivities of stocks to cash flows. Our model performs well because the stock-cash flow sensitivities contain economic information. Value stocks, high-leverage stocks and low-asset-growth stocks are more sensitive to cash flows than growth stocks, low- leverage stocks and high-asset-growth stocks, particularly in recessions when default probabilities are high. Keywords: Stock-cash flow sensitivity, structural estimation, implied-state GMM, financial leverage, default probability, asset pricing anomalies JEL Classification: G12, G13, G33 2 1 Introduction Equity is a residual claim contingent on a firm’s assets that generate operating cash flows.
    [Show full text]
  • Upper and Lower Snell Envelopes and Robust Partial Hedging
    American Options in incomplete Markets: Upper and lower Snell Envelopes and robust partial Hedging DISSERTATION zur Erlangung des akademischen Grades doctor rerum naturalium (Dr. rer. nat.) im Fach Mathematik eingereicht an der Mathematisch-Naturwissenschaftlichen Fakultät II Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin von Herr Dipl. Math. Erick Treviño Aguilar geboren am 24.03.1975 in México Präsident der Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin: Prof. Dr. Christoph Markschies Dekan der Mathematisch-Naturwissenschaftlichen Fakultät II: Prof. Dr. Wolfgang Coy Gutachter: 1. Prof. Dr. Hans Föllmer 2. Prof. Dr. Peter Imkeller 3. Prof. Dr. Frank Riedel eingereicht am: 14. Dezember 2007 Tag der mündlichen Prüfung: 9. Juni 2008 Abstract This thesis studies American options in an incomplete financial market and in continuous time. It is composed of two parts. In the first part we study a stochastic optimization problem in which a robust convex loss functional is minimized in a space of stochastic integrals. This problem arises when the seller of an American option aims to control the shortfall risk by using a partial hedge. We quantify the shortfall risk through a robust loss functional motivated by an extension of classical expected util- ity theory due to Gilboa and Schmeidler. In a general semimartingale model we prove the existence of an optimal strategy. Under additional compactness assumptions we show how the robust problem can be reduced to a non-robust optimization problem with respect to a worst-case probability measure. In the second part, we study the notions of the upper and the lower Snell envelope associated to an American option. We construct the envelopes for stable families of equivalent probability measures, the family of local martin- gale measures being an important special case.
    [Show full text]
  • Contingent Claims Valuation When the Security Price Is a Combination of an 11"O Process and a Random Point Process
    Stochastic Processes and their Applications 28 (1988) 185-220 185 North-Holland CONTINGENT CLAIMS VALUATION WHEN THE SECURITY PRICE IS A COMBINATION OF AN 11"O PROCESS AND A RANDOM POINT PROCESS Knut K. AASE Norwegian School of Economics and Business Administration, Institute of Insurance, Helleveien 30, N-5035 Bergen.Sandviken, Norway Received 18 September 1986 Revised 30 November 1987 This paper develops several results in the modern theory of contingent claims valuation in a frictionless security m~rket with continuous trading. The price model is a semi-martingale with a certain structure, making the return of the security a sum of an Ito-process and a random, marked point process. Dynamic equilibrium prices are known to be of this form in an Arrow- Debreu economy, so there is no real limitation in our approach. This class of models is also advantageous from an applied point of view. Within this framework we investigate how the model behaves under the equivalent martingale measure in the P*-equilibrium economy, where discounted security prices are marginales. Here we present some new results showing how the marked point process affects prices of contingent claims in equilibrium. We derive a new class of option pricing formulas when the Ito process is a general Gaussian process, one formula for each positive La[0, T]-function. We show that our general model is complete, although the set of equivalent martingale measures is not a singleton. We also demonstrate how to price contingent claims when the underlying process has after-effects in all of its parameters. contingent claims valuation * security market • semi-martingale model * option pricing formulas 1.
    [Show full text]
  • Fair Value Management: a Case Study of Employee Stock Option Pricing Models
    Fair Value Management: A Case Study of Employee Stock Option Pricing Models Loïc Belze EMLYON Business School Francois Larmande HEC Paris Lorenz Schneider EMLYON Business School 3 October 2014 ABSTRACT: This paper examines the fair value management of Employee Stock Options (ESOs). Departing from earlier literature focused on input estimates, we study the management of the pricing model itself, which is sometimes freely interpreted by companies. Relaxing certain assumptions of the Black-Scholes-Merton (BSM) model can lead to a range of possible prices. We first show that when estimating the ESO cost for the company, only prices equal to or above the BSM model price should be considered, whereas discounts are in fact observed at issuance. Second, based on a specific class of listed ESO in an IFRS context, our empirical study finds an overall average discount of 64% on our model price after controlling for ESO-specific characteristics. The discount results mainly from model management. These results provide interesting insights into the scope for model management under different accounting standards, and are also relevant for authorities in charge of enforcement. Keywords: Fair value – ESO – Transaction costs – IFRS 2 – SFAS 123R Data: All data are available from public sources 1 I. INTRODUCTION Implementing fair value principles is not a straightforward task. Standard setters have progressively refined the notion of fair value, as evidenced by the recent efforts of the FASB1 (e.g. the update of Topic 820 for US GAAP2) and the IASB3 (e.g. the recent implementation of IFRS 134) to produce new guidance on this issue. In the specific case of share-based compensation both standard setters (SFAS 123R5 for US GAAP and IFRS 26 for IFRS) determined in 2004 that, in order to improve accountability and transparency towards shareholders, share-based compensation instruments should be recognized as a cost by firms and expensed in the income statement at their fair value.
    [Show full text]
  • Employee Stock Options and Equity Valuation
    DOI: 10.1111/j.1475-679x.2005.00164.x Journal of Accounting Research Vol. 43 No. 1 March 2005 Printed in U.S.A. Employee Stock Options, Equity Valuation, and the Valuation of Option Grants Using aWarrant-Pricing Model ∗ FENG LI AND M.H.FRANCOWONG† Received 5 January 2004; accepted 11 July 2004 ABSTRACT We investigate the use of a warrant-pricing approach to incorporate em- ployee stock options (ESOs) into equity valuation and to account for the di- lutive effect of ESOs in the valuation of option grants for financial reporting purposes. Our valuation approach accounts for the jointly determined nature of ESO and shareholder values. The empirical results show that our stock price estimate exhibits lower prediction errors and higher explanatory powers for actual share price than does the traditional stock price estimate. We use our valuation approach to assess the implications of dilution on the fair-value es- timates of ESO grants. We find that the fair value is overstated by 6% if we ignore the dilutive feature of ESOs. Furthermore, this bias is larger for firms that are heavy users of ESOs, small, and R&D intensive, and for firms that have a broad-based ESO compensation plan. ∗ University of Michigan; †University of Chicago. We thank Ray Ball, Dan Bens, Phil Berger, Clement Har, Steve Kaplan, Doron Kliger, S. P. Kothari, Susan Krische, Richard Leftwich, Thomas Lys, James Myers, Dennis Oswald, Joe Piotroski, Doug Skinner, Abbie Smith, K. R. Subramanyam, Shyam V. Sunder, Brett Trueman, Martin Wu, Peter Wysocki, an anonymous referee, and workshop participants at Chicago, MIT, Northwestern, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, and the London Business School 2004 Accounting Symposium for their comments and suggestions.
    [Show full text]
  • Optimal Stopping, Smooth Pasting and the Dual Problem
    Introduction Preliminaries Main Theorems Questions Applications Optimal Stopping, Smooth Pasting and the Dual Problem Saul Jacka and Dominic Norgilas, University of Warwick Imperial 21 February 2018 Saul Jacka and Dominic Norgilas, University of Warwick The Compensator of the Snell Envelope Introduction Preliminaries Main Theorems Questions Applications The general optimal stopping problem: Given a ltered probability space (Ω; (Ft ); F; P) and an adapted gains process G, nd def St = ess sup E[Gτ jFt ] optional τ≥t Recall, under very general conditions I S is the minimal supermartingale dominating G def I τt = inffs ≥ t : Ss = Gs g is optimal I for any t, S is a martingale on [t; τt ] I when Gt = g(Xt ) (1) for some (continuous-time) Markov Process X , St can be written as a function, v(Xt ). Saul Jacka and Dominic Norgilas, University of Warwick The Compensator of the Snell Envelope Introduction Preliminaries Main Theorems Questions Applications Remark 1.1 Condition Gt = g(Xt ) is less restrictive than might appear. With θ being the usual shift operator, can expand statespace of X by appending adapted functionals F with the property that Ft+s = f (Fs ; (θs ◦ Xu; 0 ≤ u ≤ t)): (2) The resulting process Y def= (X ; F ) is still Markovian. If X is strong Markov and F is right-cts then Y is strong Markov. e.g if X is a BM, Z t Z s 0 Yt = Xt ; Lt ; sup Xs ; exp − α(Xu)du g(Xs ) ds 0≤s≤t 0 0 is a Feller process on the ltration of X .
    [Show full text]
  • The Harrison-Pliska Story (And a Little Bit More)
    The Harrison-Pliska Story (and a little bit more) Stanley R Pliska Professor Emeritus Department of Finance University of Illinois at Chicago Fields Institute February 2010 Table of Contents 1. Some continuous time stock price models 2. Alternative justification of Black-Scholes formula 3. The preliminary security market model 4. Economic considerations 5. The general security market model 6. Computing the martingale measure 7. Pricing contingent claims (European options) 8. Return processes 9. Complete markets 10. Pricing American options Key References We Used • J.M. Harrison and D.M. Kreps, Martingales and arbitrage in multiperiod securities markets, J. Economic Theory 20 (1979), 381-408. • J. Jacod, Calcul Stochastique et Problèmes de Martingales, Lecture Notes in Mathematics 714, Springer, New York, 1979. • P.-A. Meyer, Un cours sur les integrales stochastiques, Seminaire de Probabilité X, Lecture Notes in Mathematics 511, Springer, New York, 1979, 91-108. 1. Some Continuous Time Stock Price Models 1a. Geometric Brownian motion dS t = µStdt + σStdW (and multi-stock extensions) Reasonably satisfactory, but… • Returns can be correlated at some frequencies • Volatility is random • Big price jumps like on October 19, 1987 1b. A point process model St = S 0 exp {bN t – µt}, where N = Poisson process with intensity λ > 0 b = positive scalar µ = positive scalar J. Cox and S. Ross, The valuation of options for alternative stochastic processes, J. Financial Economics 3 (1976), 145- 166. 1c. Some generalizations and variations • Diffusions ( µ and σ are time and state dependent) • Ito processes (µ and σ are stochastic) • General jump processes • Jump-diffusion processes • Fractional Brownian motion • Etc.
    [Show full text]
  • A Complete Bibliography of Electronic Communications in Probability
    A Complete Bibliography of Electronic Communications in Probability Nelson H. F. Beebe University of Utah Department of Mathematics, 110 LCB 155 S 1400 E RM 233 Salt Lake City, UT 84112-0090 USA Tel: +1 801 581 5254 FAX: +1 801 581 4148 E-mail: [email protected], [email protected], [email protected] (Internet) WWW URL: http://www.math.utah.edu/~beebe/ 20 May 2021 Version 1.13 Title word cross-reference (1 + 1) [CB10]. (d; α, β) [Zho10]. (r + ∆) [CB10]. 0 [Sch12, Wag16]. 1 [Duc19, HL15b, Jac14, Li14, Sch12, SK15, Sim00, Uch18]. 1=2 [KV15]. 1=4 [JPR19]. 2 [BDT11, GH18b, Har12, Li14, RSS18, Sab21, Swa01, VZ11, vdBN17]. 2D [DXZ11]. 2M − X [Bau02, HMO01, MY99]. 3 [AB14, PZ18, SK15]. [0;t] [MLV15]. α [DXZ11, Pat07]. α 2 [0; 1=2) [Sch12]. BES0(d) [Win20]. β [Ven13]. d [H¨ag02, Mal15, Van07, Zho20]. d = 2 [KO06]. d>1 [Sal15]. dl2 [Wan14]. ≥ ≥ 2 + @u @mu d 2 [BR07]. d 3 [ST20]. d (0; 1) [Win20]. f [DGG 13]. @t = κm @xm [OD12]. G [NY09, BCH+00, FGM11]. H [Woj12, WP14]. k [AV12, BKR06, Gao08, GRS03]. k(n) [dBJP13]. kα [Sch12]. L1 1 2 1 p [CV07, MR01]. L ([0; 1]) [FP11]. L [HN09]. l [MHC13]. L [CGR10]. L1 [EM14]. Λ [Fou13, Fou14, Lag07, Zho14]. Lu = uα [Kuz00]. m(n) [dBJP13]. Cn [Tko11]. R2 [Kri07]. Rd [MN09]. Z [Sch12]. Z2 [Gla15]. Zd d 2 3 d C1 [DP14, SBS15, BC12]. Zn [ST20]. R [HL15a]. R [Far98]. Z [BS96]. 1 2 [DCF06]. N × N × 2 [BF11]. p [Eva06, GL14, Man05]. pc <pu [NP12a].
    [Show full text]
  • Approximation of the Snell Envelope and American Options Prices in Dimension One
    ESAIM: Probability and Statistics March 2002, Vol. 6, 1–19 URL: http://www.emath.fr/ps/ DOI: 10.1051/ps:2002001 APPROXIMATION OF THE SNELL ENVELOPE AND AMERICAN OPTIONS PRICES IN DIMENSION ONE Vlad Bally1 and Bruno Saussereau2 Abstract. We establish some error estimates for the approximation of an optimal stopping problem along the paths of the Black–Scholes model. This approximation is based on a tree method. Moreover, we give a global approximation result for the related obstacle problem. Mathematics Subject Classification. 49L20, 60G40, 65M15, 91B28. Received February 15, 2001. Revised November 13, 2001. Introduction The purpose of this article is to estimate the rate of convergence of the approximation scheme of an optimal stopping problem along Brownian paths, when the Brownian Motion is approximated by a random walk. F F P We consider a standard Brownian Motion (Bt)t≥0 defined on a filtered probability space (Ω, , ( t)t≥0, ) and we denote x ∈ R Xt = x + bt+ aBt, a,b,x ,a>0. Given a function h which is assumed to be (at least) Lipschitz-continuous, our aim is to compute x E x |F Yt =sup (h(τ,Xτ ) t) , τ∈Tt,T where Tt,T is the set of all the stopping times taking values in [t,T ]. This is the Snell Envelope of the process x (h(t, Xt ))t∈[0,T ]. Our results apply to standard American Options. Recall, for example, that an American Put on a stock is the right to sell one share at a specified price K (called the exercise price) at any instant until a given future date T (called the expiration date or date of maturity).
    [Show full text]
  • Optimal Stopping and Applications
    Optimal Stopping and Applications Alex Cox March 16, 2009 Abstract These notes are intended to accompany a Graduate course on Optimal stopping, and in places are a bit brief. They follow the book ‘Optimal Stopping and Free- boundary Problems’ by Peskir and Shiryaev, and more details can generally be found there. 1 Introduction 1.1 Motivating Examples Given a stochastic process Xt, an optimal stopping problem is to compute the following: sup EF (Xτ ), (1) τ where the supremum is taken over some set of stopping times. As well as computing the supremum, we will also usually be interested in finding a description of the stopping time. For motivation, we consider three applications where optimal stopping problems arise. (i) Stochastic analysis. Let Bt be a Brownian motion. Then classical results tell us that for any (fixed) T 0, ≥ πT E sup B = | s| 2 0≤s≤T r What can we say about the left-hand side if we replace the constant T with a stopping time τ? To solve this problem, it turns out that we can consider the (class of) optimal stopping problems: V (λ) = sup E sup Bs λτ . (2) τ s τ | | − 0≤ ≤ Where we take the supremum over all stopping times which have Eτ < , and λ > 0. (Note that in order to fit into the exact form described in (1), we∞ need 1 Optimal Stopping and Applications — Introduction Amg Cox 2 to take e.g. Xt = (Bt, sups≤t Bs , t)). Now suppose we can solve this problem for all λ > 0, then we can use a Lagrangian-style| | approach to get back to the original question: for any suitable stopping time τ we have E sup Bs V (λ)+ λEτ s τ | | ≤ 0≤ ≤ inf (V (λ)+ λEτ) ≤ λ>0 Now, if we suppose that the infimum here is attained, and the supremum in (2) is also attained at the optimal λ, then we see that the right-hand side is a function of Eτ, and further, we can attain equality for this bound, so that it is the smallest possible bound.
    [Show full text]
  • Discrete-Type Approximations for Non-Markovian Optimal Stopping Problems: Part I 3
    DISCRETE-TYPE APPROXIMATIONS FOR NON-MARKOVIAN OPTIMAL STOPPING PROBLEMS: PART I DORIVAL LEAO,˜ ALBERTO OHASHI, AND FRANCESCO RUSSO Abstract. In this paper, we present a discrete-type approximation scheme to solve continuous- time optimal stopping problems based on fully non-Markovian continuous processes adapted to the Brownian motion filtration. The approximations satisfy suitable variational inequalities which allow us to construct ǫ-optimal stopping times and optimal values in full generality. Explicit rates of convergence are presented for optimal values based on reward functionals of path-dependent SDEs driven by fractional Brownian motion. In particular, the methodology allows us to design concrete Monte-Carlo schemes for non-Markovian optimal stopping time problems as demonstrated in the companion paper by Bezerra, Ohashi and Russo. 1. Introduction An important and well-developed class of stochastic control problems is related to optimal stopping time. The goal is to find stopping times, at which an underlying stochastic process Z should be stopped in order to optimize the values of some given functional of interest. Essentially, the optimal stopping time problem is completely described by the so-called supermartingale Snell envelope (1.1) S(t) := ess sup E [Z(τ) |Ft] , 0 ≤ t ≤ T, τ≥t written w.r.t a given filtration F = (Ft)0≤t≤T , where esssup in (1.1) is computed over the class of all F-stopping times located on [t,T ]. The literature on probabilistic techniques in optimal stopping problems is vast. We refer for instance to the expositions of [26, 14] and other references therein for a broad overview of the techniques in this area.
    [Show full text]
  • SPA OSAKA 2010 Schedule Table
    Last modified on September 12, 2010 SPA OSAKA 2010 Schedule Table On Monday, the conference office will open at 7:30 in the morning Monday, 6th Tuesday, 7th Wednesday, 8th Thursday, 9th Friday, 10th 9;56.:;11 8 Opening (Life Hall) :;11.:;56 :;11.:;56 :;11.:;56 :;11.:;56 :;11.:;56 Lawler Wilson Sturm Miermont Hino 9 (Doob Lecture) (Life Hall) (Life Hall) (Life Hall) (Life Hall) (Life Hall) coffee break :;66.21;51 :;66.21;51 :;66.21;51 :;66.21;51 Atar Kumagai 21;16.21;61 Biskup Tang 10 (Life Hall) (Life Hall) Lyons (IMS Medallion (Life Hall) (Life Hall) Lecture) (Life Hall) coffee break coffee break coffee break coffee break 21;61.22;26 22;16.22;61 22;16.23;41 Event of Bernoulli 22;16.22;61 22;16.22;61 Society (Life Hall) 11 Rogers SS04, SS06, SS13, Hairer Jacod (Life Hall) (Life Hall) (Life Hall) SS26, SS27, CS04, lunch CS07, CT06, CT11, CT16, CT18 23;11.23;56 (Parallel sessions) 23;11.23;56 23;11.23;56 Khoshnevisan Jeanblanc Landim 12 (Life Hall) (Life Hall) (Lévy Lecture) (Life Hall) lunch lunch 23;61. lunch lunch Excursion 25;21.26;46 14 25;31.26;56 SS09, SS12, SS14, 25;31.26;16 25;31.26;56 SS10, SS18, SS20, SS23, SS25, CS08, Taylor SS01, SS03, SS11, SS21, CS09, CS10, CS14, CT07, CT09, (Life Hall) SS15, SS16, CS03, CS12, CT02, CT03, CT12, CT19 CS05, CS11, CT04, CT10, CT15 (Parallel sessions) CT05, CT13, CT17, 26;26.27;11 15 (Parallel sessions) CT22 Seppäläinen (Parallel sessions) coffee break (Life Hall) coffee break PS I core time 27;11.
    [Show full text]