Integrated Regional Econometric and Input-Output Modeling

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Load more

Integrated Regional Econometric and
Input-Output Modeling

Sergio J. Rey1 2

Department of Geography San Diego State University
San Diego, CA 92182

[email protected]

January 1999

1Part of this research was supported by funding from the San Diego State University Foundation Defense Conversion Center, which is gratefully acknowledged.
2This paper is dedicated to the memory of Philip R. Israilevich.

Abstract

Recent research on integrated econometric+input-output modeling for regional economies is reviewed. The motivations for and the alternative methodological approaches to this type of analysis are examined. Particular attention is given to the issues arising from multiregional linkages and spatial effects in the implementation of these frameworks at the sub-national scale. The linkages between integrated modeling and spatial econometrics are outlined. Directions for future research on integrated econometric and inputoutput modeling are identified.
Key Words: Regional, integrated, econometric, input-output, multiregional.

Integrated Regional Econometric+Input-Output Modeling

1

1 Introduction

Since the inception of the field of regional science some forty years ago, the synthesis of different methodological approaches to the study of a region has been a perennial theme. In his original “Channels of Synthesis” Isard conceptualized a number of ways in which different regional analysis tools and techniques relating to particular subsystems of regions could be integrated to achieve a comprehensive modeling framework (Isard et al., 1960). As the field of regional science has developed, the term integrated model has been used in a variety of ways. For some scholars, integrated denotes a model that considers more than a single substantive process in a regional context. Examples include models that combine regional economic components with environmental or ecological concerns (Briassoulis, 1986; Hafkamp and Nijkamp, 1981) or models that consider demographic and labor market interactions (Ledent and Gordon, 1981; Madden and Batey, 1980). These are referred to as substantively integrated regional models.
A second way in which a model can be considered integrated is if it treats multiple spatial scales and/or interacting regions within the same framework. Examples of these spatially integrated models include the work by Courbis (1979, 1980, 1982a,b) who developed a spatially hierarchical model for France that considers the interactions between the national, regional and urban scales. More recently, Jin and Wilson (1993) have suggested a multispatial integrated model which emphasizes interactions between urban zones within a larger interregional context. A further example of a spatially integrated model would be one where the interactions between multiple regions, at the same scale, are considered within the framework. This could include the so called interregional (IRIO) (Beyers, 1989; Oosterhaven, 1981) and multiple (MRIO) (Shao and Miller, 1990) input-output models as well as multiregional econometric models (Beaumont, 1989; Lienesch and Kort, 1992; Treyz et al., 1992).
The final manner in which a model can be considered integrated is if it combines more than a single modeling methodology in the same framework. This has been done in a wide variety of ways such as: extended inputoutput/demo-economic models (Madden and Batey, 1980); combined linear programing and input-output models (Anselin et al., 1990); optimization and spatial interaction models (Harris, 1988), among others.
In a recent update of his conceptualization Isard has identified the integration of econometric and input-output as a new approach to synthesis (Isard et al., 1998). This recognition stems from the recent heightened level of activity on integrated econometric and input-output (EC+IO) model-

Integrated Regional Econometric+Input-Output Modeling

2ing over the last two decades (Anselin and Madden, 1991; Beaumont, 1990; Rey, 1998). This paper presents an overview of recent research on integrating econometric and input-output models at the regional scale. The focus is mainly on efforts in the U.S., with an emphasis on the issues to be faced in the implementation of these frameworks in practice. As such the objectives of this paper are threefold. First, the paper will outline the main approaches that can and have been used to implement EC+IO models in practice. Secondly, a number of outstanding methodological issues associated with this type of modeling at the regional scale are discussed. Finally, a number of promising directions for future research are highlighted. Given these objectives, the paper is intended for regional analysts who may be considering the development of such models for their own regions, as well as for theoretical and applied regional modelers interested in recent developments in integrated EC+IO modeling.
In the following sections of the paper, I first discuss the motivations for integrated EC+IO modeling at the regional scale, where the focus is on both theoretical and practical concerns. Next, the different approaches that have been taken towards the implementation of integrated models are reviewed, with attention given to the relative merits of the alternative approaches. This is followed by the identification of a number of issues that arise in integrated modeling at the regional scale that are distinct from national efforts in that they are associated with multiregional linkages and other spatial issues. I then outline a series of promising new directions in integrated modeling, and I close with some more general remarks.

2 Motivations for Integrated Modeling

Given the wide variety of regional economic models that are available, it is important to properly situate integrated EC+IO within this larger field. EC+IO models can be viewed in a variety of ways. For example, some scholars (West and Jensen, 1995) see a competition arising between the EC+IO models and regional computable general equilibrium models (CGE),1 while others have tended to stress the similarity between EC+IO and CGE models (Treyz, 1993). Even within the field of EC+IO modeling there is some debate about the distinctions between the integrated EC+IO model and its individual components (i.e., EC and IO) (Beaumont, 1990). Therefore, as a way of trying to situate EC+IO models it is useful to focus on the mo-

1For an excellent survey of recent work on regional CGE models see Partridge and
Rickman (1999)

Integrated Regional Econometric+Input-Output Modeling

3
Table 1: Comparative Characteristics of IO, EC and IO+EC Models
Characteristic IO EC EC+IO

√√√√√

Dynamic
Disaggregate
Price Responsive Impact Analysis Demand Driven
Forecasting


√√√√√√
√√

Inferential
Multiregional
??

tivations for this type of modeling, which are of two types: theoretical and practical.

2.1 Theoretical Motivations for EC+IO Modeling

One of the main theoretical motivations for implementing EC+IO models largely stems from the restrictive assumptions of each component model (i.e, EC or IO) when used in isolation. To illustrate the key assumptions, Table 1 summarizes the characteristics of the econometric and input-output models, as well as those characteristics that are inherited by the integrated framework.
During the early development of the field of regional science the classic regional IO model became a mainstay of the analyst’s toolkit. Yet with this widespread application came a growing awareness of the limitations of the behavioral representation offered by IO models. Chief among these were the assumptions of linear production technologies; constant returns to scale; homogeneous consumption functions; and price inflexibility.
Compared to IO models, regional EC models have historically not enjoyed the same level of popularity. This is explained, in part, by the more extensive data and calibration requirements of these models. Moreover, from a theoretical perspective, the modeler is additionally responsible for specification of the underlying theory, in contrast to the case for an IO model where the theoretical basis is inseparable from the framework.
While both IO and EC models are macroeconomic in nature, a crucial difference between these models pertains to their respective views of regional economies. IO models are essentially general equilibrium in nature in the

Integrated Regional Econometric+Input-Output Modeling

4sense that the markets clear. This occurs through supply adjustments to demand shocks, while prices play no role in the market response. On the other hand, regional EC models often depict regional economies in a partial and/or disequilibrium context, where the focus is typically on the dynamic adjustment path of the economy to exogenous shocks. However, despite this fundamental theoretical difference between the IO and EC models, both are essentially demand driven when applied at the regional scale (Beaumont, 1990).
Some of the theoretical differences have served as key motivations for combining IO and EC models. Specifically, the lack of price responsiveness in IO models has been the focus behind many integrated IO+EC models. Because this price rigidity is present throughout the IO model there have been multiple channels of integration between the EC and IO components. Table 2 shows the input-output accounts for a single region, with n industries, which provides the context to view these channels. Central to the integration of the IO and EC models is the following identity:2

X = AX + Y

(1) where X is an n by 1 vector of industry output, Y is an n by 1 vector of final demands and A is an n by n regional input-output coefficients matrix with a typical element:

xij aij =

.

(2)

Xi

It is important to emphasize the role of aggregation in the integration. At the macroeconomic level, there are m elements of aggregate final demand: personal consumption C; investment I; government expenditures G; and net exports (NE = Exports − Imports). Each of these aggregate components is obtained as the sum of the industry specific values, for example:

n

X

C =

Ci

(3)

i=1

and total gross regional product is:

Y = C + I + G + NE.

(4)
One of the more common channels of integration has focused on personal consumption C. In regional IO models this has either been exogenous in

2Unless explicitly noted otherwise, all variables are intended to be measured at the regional scale. Later in the paper, when discussing multiregional linkages, locational superscripts are added for clarity.

Integrated Regional Econometric+Input-Output Modeling

5
Table 2: Single Region Input-Output Accounts
Interindustry
Sales
Final Demand
Total Output

  • X1
  • x11 x12 · · · x1n C1 I1 G1 NE1

  • x21 x22 · · · x2n C2 I2 G2 NE2
  • X2

...

  • .
  • .
  • .
  • .
  • .
  • .
  • .
  • .

  • .
  • .
  • .
  • .
  • .
  • .
  • .
  • .

  • .
  • .
  • .
  • .
  • .
  • .
  • .
  • .

xn1 xn2 · · · xnn Cn In Gn NEn
Xn

WOV

Wages Other Total

w1 w2 · · · wn ov1 ov2 · · · ovn

Outlays X1 X2 · · · Xn

  • C
  • I
  • G
  • NE

the so called household open models, or endogenous in the closed models. Both of these treatments of consumption suffer from theoretical shortcomings. In the open IO models there are no induced effects since the incomeconsumption link is severed. On the other hand, approaches towards endogenizing the household sector, while internalizing the income-consumption linkage, have a number of restrictive assumptions including: income homogeneity, failing to distinguish between marginal and average consumption propensities, and treating existing residents, migrants, as well as employed and unemployed individuals uniformly (Batey and Weeks, 1989). In response, a number of modelers (Treyz, 1993; West, 1994) have endogenized consumption in econometric equations which then are used to generate predictions of consumption, reflecting some of these distinctions, and to drive the input-output model.
Related to the use of the integrated approach to achieve a more theoretically satisfying representation of regional personal consumption behavior is the specification of additional elements of final demand in econometric equations. For example, investment, exports, and governmental expenditures have all been endogenized in various integrated models. This is in contrast to the stand-alone use of IO models for which each of the demand components is treated as exogenous, or is specified in some ad-hoc fashion (L’Esperance, 1981). While it is true that the aggregate components of final demand are often found in regional EC models, in the integrated EC+IO model the advantage of increased sectoral disaggregation is gained, as is discussed below. Thus, the integrated approach represents an improve-

Integrated Regional Econometric+Input-Output Modeling

6ment over the traditional IO and EC models with regard to the treatment of the final demand components of regional economies. This is a key distinguishing feature of the integrated approach given the growing recognition by regional analysts of the importance of these components for the growth and functioning of regional economies (Hewings and Jensen, 1986).
In addition to the relaxation of the assumptions regarding final demand, the integration of EC and IO models has also been used to address the assumption of a fixed employment-output relation in the IO model. This has been done by situating the labor demand equations in an econometric module, in which industry output, generated by the IO model, appears together with other determinants of labor demand (Conway, 1990; West, 1991).
In many cases the objective of exploiting the complementary nature of the EC and IO components has been successfully achieved in the sense that the resulting EC+IO model provides distinct advantages over the use of either model in isolation. However, as indicated at the bottom of Table 1, there are two instances where the integration of these two models raises a number of complications. The first pertains to the inferential framework that may be used for the integrated model. This arises because the traditional view of a regional IO model is a deterministic one in the sense that the coefficients are fixed parameters with no associated uncertainty. In contrast, EC models have a well developed framework for dealing with uncertainty. How these two perspectives are combined raises a number of methodological issues that require further attention. The second complication relates to the treatment of multiregional linkages in the integrated model. In this case both IO and EC models are capable of representing multiregional linkages, however in the integrated model both representations cannot coexist and some decisions about how best to model these interregional linkages must be made. The complications associated with inference and multiregional linkages in integrated models have not received much attention and are revisited in sections 3.2 and 4, respectively.

2.2 Practical Motivations for EC+IO Modeling

In addition to the theoretical gains that are made possible from integration, research on EC+IO models has also been motivated by a number of practical concerns. These motivations fall into three categories: improved forecast performance; more comprehensive impact analysis capabilities; and measurement error concerns.

Integrated Regional Econometric+Input-Output Modeling

7

Forecast Performance

There is now a modest body of literature suggesting that integrated EC+IO models can offer more accurate forecasts than the traditional structural econometric models (Glennon et al., 1987; Moghadam and Ballard, 1988; Rey, 1998). The same appears to be true of the time-series models (i.e., atheoretical) in which labor market models employing a vector autoregressive (VAR) approach are often dominated by Bayesian VAR (BVAR) models in which IO relations are used to specify employment determination equations (LeSage and Magura, 1991; Magura, 1987).
In addition to the benefits of increased forecasting accuracy, the use of prior restrictions, either in a frequentist or Bayesian approach, can increase the precision of the econometric estimators used to calibrate these models. This would result in improved inferences about the interindustry relationships in the region. It is also possible that some of the increased forecasting accuracy might reflect this increased precision, yet the issue has not been fully explored by integrated modelers.

Impact Analysis Capabilities

The integration of EC+IO methods has also improved the scope and capabilities of impact analysis, over what was available using either model alone. A long recognized limitation of regional IO models in impact analysis is that the time path for the estimated impacts to work themselves through the regional economy is largely unknown. This is due to the comparative-static nature of the IO model. Econometric models, in contrast, have dynamics as a central feature of their impact analysis capabilities. On the other hand, EC models are much more industrially aggregate than are IO models, so the representation of dynamics comes at a cost (see Table 1). However, by combining the two in an EC+IO model, a dynamic and industrially disaggregated impact analysis tool can be developed.
A second limitation of IO models relative to EC approaches in impact analysis is the estimated impacts of the former are point estimates lacking any measurement of uncertainty. Forecast confidence intervals, in addition to point estimates, of the impacts are commonly produced in EC analysis. Here again, the fusion of the two approaches offers the potential for the mitigation of a shortcoming of the IO framework, as well as the ability to increase the level of disaggregation over what is available in EC analysis.

Integrated Regional Econometric+Input-Output Modeling

8

Measurement Error

A third practical motivation for the integration of EC+IO models relates to the issue of accuracy in the regional IO literature. Given the prohibitive costs of implementing full survey IO tables, the vast majority of regional IO models have been estimated using regionalization techniques (Lahr, 1993). Many of these techniques adjust a national IO coefficients for the region’s degree self-sufficiency, for example using location quotients. While these models are widely used, the accuracy of the various regionalization techniques has been questioned by some (Stevens et al., 1989).
A number of integrated modelers have suggested that by incorporating the econometric component in the integrated framework, some adjustments to the IO relathionships/coefficients are made possible through the estimation process. Moghadam and Ballard (1988) argue that there is an implicit form of regionalization of the national IO table that occurs in the integration. Indeed, their integrated EC+IO model relies on a national rather than a regional IO table. Conway (1990) makes a similar argument about the adjustment for regional trade over time in an integrated model of Washington State.
A related motivation for the integration of EC+IO models from a practical perspective is that model validation becomes much more comprehensive. In the context of stand alone IO analysis, model validation is often limited to the analyst’s view of the reasonableness of the multipliers and estimated impacts since there is no objective measure available to compare these with. EC+IO models have the advantage of being compared to observable series (i.e., typically income and employment), so the accuracy of the resulting predictions can be measured much more rigorously than can predictions from an IO model.3 This is also a comparative advantage that EC+IO models have over regional CGE models, since the validation of the latter type of models is typically limited to how well the model fits the data on which it is calibrated.

3 Approaches Towards Integrated Modeling

A growing number of integrated models have been implemented at the regional scale in recent years. There are a number of dimensions that can be used to organize these efforts. Recently, Rey (1998) has suggested a

Recommended publications
  • 2015: What Is Made in America?

    2015: What Is Made in America?

    U.S. Department of Commerce Economics and2015: Statistics What is Made Administration in America? Office of the Chief Economist 2015: What is Made in America? In October 2014, we issued a report titled “What is Made in America?” which provided several estimates of the domestic share of the value of U.S. gross output of manufactured goods in 2012. In response to numerous requests for more current estimates, we have updated the report to provide 2015 data. We have also revised the report to clarify the methodological discussion. The original report is available at: www.esa.gov/sites/default/files/whatismadeinamerica_0.pdf. More detailed industry By profiles can be found at: www.esa.gov/Reports/what-made-america. Jessica R. Nicholson Executive Summary Accurately determining how much of our economy’s total manufacturing production is American-made can be a daunting task. However, data from the Commerce Department’s Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) can help shed light on what percentage of the manufacturing sector’s gross output ESA Issue Brief is considered domestic. This report works through several estimates of #01-17 how to measure the domestic content of the U.S. gross output of manufactured goods, starting from the most basic estimates and working up to the more complex estimate, domestic content. Gross output is defined as the value of intermediate goods and services used in production plus the industry’s value added. The value of domestic content, or what is “made in America,” excludes from gross output the value of all foreign-sourced inputs used throughout the supply March 28, 2017 chains of U.S.
  • Economics 2 Professor Christina Romer Spring 2019 Professor David Romer LECTURE 16 TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE and ECONOMIC GROWTH Ma

    Economics 2 Professor Christina Romer Spring 2019 Professor David Romer LECTURE 16 TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE and ECONOMIC GROWTH Ma

    Economics 2 Professor Christina Romer Spring 2019 Professor David Romer LECTURE 16 TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE AND ECONOMIC GROWTH March 19, 2019 I. OVERVIEW A. Two central topics of macroeconomics B. The key determinants of potential output C. The enormous variation in potential output per person across countries and over time D. Discussion of the paper by William Nordhaus II. THE AGGREGATE PRODUCTION FUNCTION A. Decomposition of Y*/POP into normal average labor productivity (Y*/N*) and the normal employment-to-population ratio (N*/POP) B. Determinants of average labor productivity: capital per worker and technology C. What we include in “capital” and “technology” III. EXPLAINING THE VARIATION IN THE LEVEL OF Y*/POP ACROSS COUNTRIES A. Limited contribution of N*/POP B. Crucial role of normal capital per worker (K*/N*) C. Crucial role of technology—especially institutions IV. DETERMINANTS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH A. Limited contribution of N*/POP B. Important, but limited contribution of K*/N* C. Crucial role of technological change V. HISTORICAL EVIDENCE OF TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE A. New production techniques B. New goods C. Better institutions VI. SOURCES OF TECHNOLOGICAL PROGRESS A. Supply and demand diagram for invention B. Factors that could shift the demand and supply curves C. Does the market produce the efficient amount of invention? D. Policies to encourage technological progress Economics 2 Christina Romer Spring 2019 David Romer LECTURE 16 Technological Change and Economic Growth March 19, 2019 Announcements • Problem Set 4 is being handed out. • It is due at the beginning of lecture on Tuesday, April 2. • The ground rules are the same as on previous problem sets.
  • A Better Measure of Economic Growth: Gross Domestic Output (Gdo)

    A Better Measure of Economic Growth: Gross Domestic Output (Gdo)

    COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS ISSUE BRIEF JULY 2015 A BETTER MEASURE OF ECONOMIC GROWTH: GROSS DOMESTIC OUTPUT (GDO) The growth of total economic output affects our assessment of current well-being as well as decisions about the future. Measuring the strength of the economy, however, can be difficult as it depends on surveys and administrative source data that are necessarily imperfect and incomplete. The total output of the economy can be measured in two distinct ways—Gross Domestic Product (GDP), which adds consumption, investment, government spending, and net exports; and Gross Domestic Income (GDI), which adds labor compensation, business profits, and other sources of income. In theory these two measures of output should be identical; however, they differ in practice because of measurement error. With today’s annual revision, the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) began publishing a new measure of U.S. output—the “average of GDP and GDI”—which the Council of Economic Advisers (CEA) will refer to as Gross Domestic Output (GDO).1 This issue brief describes GDO, reviews its recent trends, and explains why it can be a more accurate measure of current economic growth and a better predictor of future economic growth than either GDP or GDI alone. What is Gross Domestic Output (GDO)? The first estimate of quarterly GDP is released nearly a month after each quarter’s end. Owing to data lags, GDI What we are calling “GDO” is the average of two existing is generally first released nearly two months after series, the headline Gross Domestic Product (GDP) and quarter’s end, along with the second estimate of GDP.2 its lesser-known counterpart, Gross Domestic Income As a result, with today’s advance GDP release, GDI and (GDI).
  • Input-Output Models and Economic Impact Analysis: What They Can and Cannot Tell Us by Aaron Mcnay, Economist

    Input-Output Models and Economic Impact Analysis: What They Can and Cannot Tell Us by Aaron Mcnay, Economist

    Montana Economy at a Glance April 2013 Input-Output Models and Economic Impact Analysis: What they can and cannot tell us by Aaron McNay, Economist What economic impacts does a new business have in a region when it first opens its doors? What happens to business creation, or job growth, These questions have at when income taxes are increased or tax credits are least one thing in common, provided to businesses? they can each be examined in detail through a process How much does traffic decline on highways known as economic impact and roads when the price of gasoline increases? analysis. At a basic level, economic impact analysis examines the sectors in the area’s economy. For example, what happens economic effects that a business, project, governmental policy, when an automobile manufacturer increases the number of or economic event has on the economy of a geographic area. cars it produces each month? To increase production, the car At a more detailed level, economic impact models work by manufacturer will need to hire more workers, which directly modeling two economies; one economy where the economic increases total employment in the area. However, the car event being examined occurred and a separate economy manufacturer will also need to purchase more aluminum, steel, where the economic event did not occur. By comparing the and other goods that are used in the manufacturing process. two modeled economies, it is possible to generate estimates As the automobile manufacturer purchases more steel and of the total impact the project, businesses, or policy had on other inputs, the manufacturers of the goods, such as steel an area’s economic output, earnings, and employment.
  • Fully Dynamic Input-Output/System Dynamics Modeling for Ecological-Economic System Analysis

    Fully Dynamic Input-Output/System Dynamics Modeling for Ecological-Economic System Analysis

    sustainability Article Fully Dynamic Input-Output/System Dynamics Modeling for Ecological-Economic System Analysis Takuro Uehara 1,* ID , Mateo Cordier 2,3 and Bertrand Hamaide 4 1 College of Policy Science, Ritsumeikan University, 2-150 Iwakura-Cho, Ibaraki City, 567-8570 Osaka, Japan 2 Research Centre Cultures–Environnements–Arctique–Représentations–Climat (CEARC), Université de Versailles-Saint-Quentin-en-Yvelines, UVSQ, 11 Boulevard d’Alembert, 78280 Guyancourt, France; [email protected] 3 Centre d’Etudes Economiques et Sociales de l’Environnement-Centre Emile Bernheim (CEESE-CEB), Université Libre de Bruxelles, 44 Avenue Jeanne, C.P. 124, 1050 Brussels, Belgium 4 Centre de Recherche en Economie (CEREC), Université Saint-Louis, 43 Boulevard du Jardin botanique, 1000 Brussels, Belgium; [email protected] * Correspondence: [email protected] or [email protected]; Tel.: +81-754663347 Received: 1 May 2018; Accepted: 25 May 2018; Published: 28 May 2018 Abstract: The complexity of ecological-economic systems significantly reduces our ability to investigate their behavior and propose policies aimed at various environmental and/or economic objectives. Following recent suggestions for integrating nonlinear dynamic modeling with input-output (IO) modeling, we develop a fully dynamic ecological-economic model by integrating IO with system dynamics (SD) for better capturing critical attributes of ecological-economic systems. We also develop and evaluate various scenarios using policy impact and policy sensitivity analyses. The model and analysis are applied to the degradation of fish nursery habitats by industrial harbors in the Seine estuary (Haute-Normandie region, France). The modeling technique, dynamization, and scenarios allow us to show trade-offs between economic and ecological outcomes and evaluate the impacts of restoration scenarios and water quality improvement on the fish population.
  • PRINCIPLES of MICROECONOMICS 2E

    PRINCIPLES of MICROECONOMICS 2E

    PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS 2e Chapter 8 Perfect Competition PowerPoint Image Slideshow Competition in Farming Depending upon the competition and prices offered, a wheat farmer may choose to grow a different crop. (Credit: modification of work by Daniel X. O'Neil/Flickr Creative Commons) 8.1 Perfect Competition and Why It Matters ● Market structure - the conditions in an industry, such as number of sellers, how easy or difficult it is for a new firm to enter, and the type of products that are sold. ● Perfect competition - each firm faces many competitors that sell identical products. • 4 criteria: • many firms produce identical products, • many buyers and many sellers are available, • sellers and buyers have all relevant information to make rational decisions, • firms can enter and leave the market without any restrictions. ● Price taker - a firm in a perfectly competitive market that must take the prevailing market price as given. 8.2 How Perfectly Competitive Firms Make Output Decisions ● A perfectly competitive firm has only one major decision to make - what quantity to produce? ● A perfectly competitive firm must accept the price for its output as determined by the product’s market demand and supply. ● The maximum profit will occur at the quantity where the difference between total revenue and total cost is largest. Total Cost and Total Revenue at a Raspberry Farm ● Total revenue for a perfectly competitive firm is a straight line sloping up; the slope is equal to the price of the good. ● Total cost also slopes up, but with some curvature. ● At higher levels of output, total cost begins to slope upward more steeply because of diminishing marginal returns.
  • The Revenue Functions of a Monopoly

    The Revenue Functions of a Monopoly

    SOLUTIONS 3 Microeconomics ACTIVITY 3-10 The Revenue Functions of a Monopoly At the opposite end of the market spectrum from perfect competition is monopoly. A monopoly exists when only one firm sells the good or service. This means the monopolist faces the market demand curve since it has no competition from other firms. If the monopolist wants to sell more of its product, it will have to lower its price. As a result, the price (P) at which an extra unit of output (Q) is sold will be greater than the marginal revenue (MR) from that unit. Student Alert: P is greater than MR for a monopolist. 1. Table 3-10.1 has information about the demand and revenue functions of the Moonglow Monopoly Company. Complete the table. Assume the monopoly charges each buyer the same P (i.e., there is no price discrimination). Enter the MR values at the higher of the two Q levels. For example, since total revenue (TR) increases by $37.50 when the firm increases Q from two to three units, put “+$37.50” in the MR column for Q = 3. Table 3-10.1 The Moonglow Monopoly Company Average revenue Q P TR MR (AR) 0 $100.00 $0.00 – – 1 $87.50 $87.50 +$87.50 $87.50 2 $75.00 $150.00 +$62.50 $75.00 3 $62.50 $187.50 +$37.50 $62.50 4 $50.00 $200.00 +$12.50 $50.00 5 $37.50 $187.50 –$12.50 $37.50 6 $25.00 $150.00 –$37.50 $25.00 7 $12.50 $87.50 –$62.50 $12.50 8 $0.00 $0.00 –$87.50 $0.00 2.
  • Intellectual Property: the Law and Economics Approach

    Intellectual Property: the Law and Economics Approach

    Journal of Economic Perspectives—Volume 19, Number 2—Spring 2005—Pages 57–73 Intellectual Property: The Law and Economics Approach Richard A. Posner he traditional focus of economic analysis of intellectual property has been on reconciling incentives for producing such property with concerns T about restricting access to it by granting exclusive rights in intellectual goods—that is, by “propertizing” them—thus enabling the owner to charge a price for access that exceeds marginal cost. For example, patentability provides an additional incentive to produce inventions, but requiring that the information in patents be published and that patents expire after a certain time limit the ability of the patentee to restrict access to the invention—and so a balance is struck. Is it an optimal balance? This question, and the broader issue of trading off incentive and access considerations, has proved intractable at the level of abstract analysis. With the rise of the law and economics movement, the focus of economic analysis of intellectual property has begun to shift to more concrete and manage- able issues concerning the structure and texture of the complicated pattern of common law and statutory doctrines, legal institutions and business practices relating to intellectual property. Among the issues discussed in this paper are the length of protection for intellectual property, the rules that allow considerable copying of intellectual property without permission of the originator, the rules governing derivative works, and alternative methods of providing incentives for the creation of intellectual property. The emphasis is on copyright law, which, perhaps because of its complex legal structure and the relative neglect by economists of the arts and entertainment, has tended to be slighted in the conventional economic analysis of intellectual property, relative to patent law, where economic analysis can draw on an extensive literature concerning the economics of innovation.
  • Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6)

    Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6)

    Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6) Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6) Lectures 09-10 Feb 06/09 2017 Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6) Production The theory of the firm describes how a firm makes cost- minimizing production decisions and how the firm’s resulting cost varies with its output. The Production Decisions of a Firm The production decisions of firms are analogous to the purchasing decisions of consumers, and can likewise be understood in three steps: 1. Production Technology 2. Cost Constraints 3. Input Choices Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6) 6.1 THE TECHNOLOGY OF PRODUCTION ● factors of production Inputs into the production process (e.g., labor, capital, and materials). The Production Function qFKL= (,) (6.1) ● production function Function showing the highest output that a firm can produce for every specified combination of inputs. Remember the following: Inputs and outputs are flows. Equation (6.1) applies to a given technology. Production functions describe what is technically feasible when the firm operates efficiently. Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6) 6.1 THE TECHNOLOGY OF PRODUCTION The Short Run versus the Long Run ● short run Period of time in which quantities of one or more production factors cannot be changed. ● fixed input Production factor that cannot be varied. ● long run Amount of time needed to make all production inputs variable. Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6) 6.2 PRODUCTION WITH ONE VARIABLE INPUT (LABOR) TABLE 6.1 Production with One Variable Input Amount Amount Total Average Marginal of Labor (L) of Capital (K) Output (q) Product (q/L) Product (∆q/∆L) 0 10 0 — — 1 10 10 10 10 2 10 30 15 20 3 10 60 20 30 4 10 80 20 20 5 10 95 19 15 6 10 108 18 13 7 10 112 16 4 8 10 112 14 0 9 10 108 12 -4 10 10 100 10 -8 Microeconomics (Production, Ch 6) 6.2 PRODUCTION WITH ONE VARIABLE INPUT (LABOR) Average and Marginal Products ● average product Output per unit of a particular input.
  • ECON 200. Introduction to Microeconomics Homework 5 Part I

    ECON 200. Introduction to Microeconomics Homework 5 Part I

    ECON 200. Introduction to Microeconomics Homework 5 Part I Name:________________________________________ [Multiple Choice] 1. Diminishing marginal product explains why, as a firm’s output increases, (d) a. the production function and total-cost curve both get steeper. b. the production function and total-cost curve both get flatter c. the production function gets steeper, while the total-cost curve gets flatter. d. the production function gets flatter, while the total-cost curve gets steeper. 2. A firm is producing 1,000 units at a total cost of $5,000. If it were to increase production to 1,001 units, its total cost would rise to $5,008. What does this information tell you about the firm? (d) a. Marginal cost is $5, and average variable cost is $8. b. Marginal cost is $8, and average variable cost is $5. c. Marginal cost is $5, and average total cost is $8. d. Marginal cost is $8, and average total cost is $5. 3. A firm is producing 20 units with an average total cost of $25 and marginal cost of $15. If it were to increase production to 21 units, which of the following must occur? (c) a. Marginal cost would decrease. b. Marginal cost would increase. c. Average total cost would decrease. d. Average total cost would increase 4. The government imposes a $1,000 per year license fee on all pizza restaurants. Which cost curves shift as a result? (b) a. average total cost and marginal cost b. average total cost and average fixed cost c. average variable cost and marginal cost d.
  • Intensive Industries and Distributed Knowledge Bases.1

    Intensive Industries and Distributed Knowledge Bases.1

    What is the ‘knowledge economy’? Knowledge- intensive industries and distributed knowledge bases.1 Keith Smith STEP Group Oslo Norway May 2000 Prepared as part of the project “Innovation Policy in a Knowledge-Based Economy” commissioned by the European Commission 1 I would like to thank Daniele Archibugi, Robin Cowan, Paul David, Dominique Foray, Gert van de Paal, Luc Soete and members of the European Commission for comments on an earlier draft of this paper. Introduction: technology and competence Public policies for science, technology and innovation have always been aimed primarily at creating and diffusing knowledge. In recent years such policies have attracted increasing attention as a result of claims that knowledge-intensive industries are now at the core of growth, and that we are now entering a new type of knowledge-driven economy or even a completely new form of ‘knowledge society’. What does it mean to speak of a ‘knowledge-intensive’ industry or a ‘knowledge- based’ economy, however? These terms are often used in a superficial and uncritical way, and there is a real need to consider whether they are anything more than slogans. The objectives of this paper are firstly to assess some of the issues involved in the concept of a knowledge economy or learning economy, and to criticise the idea that the knowledge economy should be identified with high-technology industries (as conventionally defined). Against this background I describe some empirical dimensions of knowledge creation in Europe, and then turn to concepts and a methodology for mapping the knowledge base of an economic activity. The paper proposes the concept of a ‘distributed knowledge base’ for industries, and argues that the term ‘knowledge economy’ is only meaningful if we see it in terms of widely- spread knowledge intensity across economic activities, including so-called ‘low technology’ sectors.
  • Check Your Understanding: Input-Output Models February 1, 2018

    Check Your Understanding: Input-Output Models February 1, 2018

    Check your understanding: Input-output models February 1, 2018 Input-output models Input-Output and Social Accounting Matrices Input-output was partly inspired by the Marxian and Walrasian anal- ysis of general equilibrium via interindustry flows. It has been a mainstay of economics and economic policy and planning through- out the world for the past half-century and used for economic plan- ning throughout the developed and developing world. Leontief was raised in Russia and obtained his Ph.D. in Berlin. He developed input-output analysis at Harvard after 1932 and he bagan constructing an empirical example of his input-output system, his 1941 classic, Structure of American Industry. Leontief followed up this work with a series of classical papers on input-output economics. Simple Example Let there be two sectors agriculture and industry. Agriculture re- quires 2 units of industry to produce 10 units of output while indus- try requires 3 units of agriculture to produce 20 units of output. Each uses its output as an input, perhaps 10 percent of its gross output. The A matrix or input-output matrix in coefficient form " # 1/10 3/20 2/10 1/10 or " # 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.1 here the coefficient aij is the amount of good i used for the produc- tion of one unit of good j. The coefficient matrix must be distinguished " # 1 3 from the flow matrix A˜ = 2 2 " # 10 Here X is column vector of gross value of production X = 20 Product of A and X is AX is a quantity of intermediate use of both agriculture and industry as illustrated below.