The Electoral College : a Majority Efficiency Analysis

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Electoral College : a Majority Efficiency Analysis The Electoral College : A Majority Efficiency Analysis. Vincent R. Merlin,∗ Thomas G. Senn´ey Preliminary Version The 29th of January 2008 One of the main topics of voting theory is the assessment of paradox proba- bilities in order to compare different voting rules. These computations are based upon assumptions on the probability distribution of voters' preferences. The two principal hypothesis are the Impartial Culture assumption which stipulates that every voter picks his preference among a set of uniformly distributed orderings, and the Impartial Anonymous Culture which states that every voting situation has the same probability to occur. Their main disadvantage is that they are theoretical a priori models and they do not necessarily match the reality. In this paper we propose to calibrate these usual models in order to assess the probability of the referendum paradox, that is, the probability that the popular winner does not obtain a majority of delegates. Indeed, one of the motivation of this paper is to take part of the debate resulting from the criticisms instated by authors such as Gelman et alii [11, 12] and Regenwetter [26]. In this way, we provide a serie of estimations for the referendum paradox probability in the Electoral College according to a continuum of probabilistic models, which more and more match the real data. The second motivation is to use these different probability assumptions in order to study the current seat allocation method in comparison with apportionment methods. Keywords : Voting, IAC, IC, Referendum Paradox, Majority Efficiency, Electoral College. JEL classification : D71. ∗corresponding author : CREM, Universit´ede Caen, 14032 Caen Cedex, France (email: [email protected], tel: 02 31 56 62 49) yCREM, Universit´ede Caen, 14032 Caen Cedex, France (email: [email protected]) 1 1 Introduction During Summer 2000, just before the US presidential elections, at APSA's annual Meeting, numerous political scientists predicted a Democratic (Al Gore) victory by upwards of 6 percentage points. In November, the election outcome was a surprisingly close election. With 48.4% of the popular vote, A. Gore only won 21 States among 51, for a total of 267 electors in the Electoral College, while G. W. Bush got 271 electors with less support from the popular vote. This paradox is known in Social Choice literature as the referendum paradox (RP, see Nurmi [21], Saul [28], Feix, Lepelley, Merlin and Rouet [9]). The U.S. presidential elections displayed the paradox in 1876, 1888 and 2000, and close outcomes (the margin between the top two candidates is less than about 4%) have been observed 11 times since the bipartism was established1 (see Table 1). Table 1: The eleven closest U.S. presidential elections Year Popular Vote (%) Electoral Vote Margin (%) RP Dem. Rep. Dem. Rep. 1876 51.0 48.0 184 185 3.0 Yes 1880 48.3 48.2 214 155 0.1 No 1884 48.5 48.3 219 182 0.2 No 1888 48.6 47.8 168 233 0.8 Yes 1892 46.1 43.0 277 145 3.1 No 1916 49.2 46.1 277 254 3.1 No 1960 49.8 49.6 303 219 0.2 No 1968 42.7 43.4 191 301 0.7 No 1976 50.1 48.0 297 240 2.1 No 2000 48.4 47.9 267 271 0.5 Yes 2004 48.3 50.7 251 286 2.4 No This paradox belongs to a class of voting paradoxes characterized by the variability of choice sets in counterintuitive ways when we aggregate differently the same electoral data. Two other famous paradoxes belonging to this class are the Ostrogorski's paradox (see Ostrogorski [23], Nurmi [21, 22], Laffond and Lain´e[19], Saari and Sieberg [27]) and the Anscombe's paradox (see Ascombe [1], Wagner and Carler [29, 30], Saul [28], Nurmi [21]). The referendum paradox calls into question the institution of the consultative referendum in a representa- tive democracy. In a consultative referendum, the issues which are voted upon in the referendum are finally decided by the parliament. More generally the referendum paradox occurs when, for example, a majority of voters supports an 1The US presidential elections records the paradox once before, in 1824. Three candidates received Electoral College votes but as no presidential candidate received an electoral majority, the election was determined by the House of Representatives. John Quincy Adams won the vote with the support of 13 State delegations though he was not the popular vote winner. 2 issue while the members of parliament, or here the Electoral College, reverses the majority decision. The first motivation of this work is to answer the following question : Is the U.S. presidential election system a good two-tiers voting system ? Indeed, one of the most important question in a federal union is to design a good allocation of the mandates among the union members (here States). There exist several normative criteria to solve this problem. Most of them belong to power index literature (see Penrose [24, 25], Banzhaf [3], Felsenthal and Machover [8]). Re- cently, new ones, based on the total utility maximization, have been proposed in the literature (see Felsenthal and Machover [8], Barber`aand Jackson [6], Beis- bart, Bowens and Hartmann [7], Kirsch [17]). Close to this idea, Feix, Lepelley, Merlin and Rouet [9] suggested the concept of majority efficiency : the majority efficieny of a method corresponds to referendum paradox probability usind this model2. Ultimately, we want to maximize the probability that the candidate elected through a two-tiers voting rule reveals the popular choice. Then the following question is : how to compute as fairly as possible the referendum paradox probability ? In fact, in social choice theory, it is usual to set some a priori assumptions on the behavior of the voters. They permit to compare voting systems from a neutral point of view. They are not contingent to history : a voting system may be good for a certain voting pattern, at time t, but the time evolution may make it inadequate in the future. Hence, the probabilistic models used throughout the literature convey some notion of impartiality : they assume that each party is equally likely to win, and one can simulate the votes under different probability models without any reference to a precise political context. The two models often introduced in the Social Choice literature are the Impartial Culture (IC) and the Impartial Anonymous Culture (IAC) assumptions. With IC, all profiles of preference are equally likely. In our case of two candidates, it assumes that each voter selects a party with equal probability. When the number of voters in a State i is sufficiently large, the distribution of the votes follows a normal law. The IAC assumption considers that all voting situations have the same probability of occurrence. In our case, every final distribution of the votes between the two candidates is equally likely to occur. The main advantage of these two models is the notion of veil of ignorance they convey : without data they can assess the frequency numerous of paradoxes or evaluate the influence of voters via a power index, and enable the comparison of different voting rules from a normative point of view. However an important problem has recently been brought out. Electoral data give more information and do not match a priori models. Thus, any rec- ommendation based on a priori voting models may clash with reality. Two main works are at the origin of this critic. In their recent book, Regenwetter, Grofman, Marley, Tsetlin [26] develop conceptual, mathematical, methodolog- 2This concept is equivalent to the concept of Condorcet efficiency developed by Fishburn and Gehrlein for the analysis scoring rule. For three candidates and more, the Condorcet efficiency is the conditional probability that a voting rule selects the Condorcet winner, given that such a candidate exists. In our case, with two candidates only, a majority winner always exists. 3 ical and empirical foundations of behavioral social choice research. This last notion encompasses two major interconnected paradigms : the development of behavioral choice theory and the evaluation of that theory with empirical data on social choice behavior. In their book, studies of survey data do not at all look like random samples from a uniform distribution, i.e., from an Impartial Cul- ture. This reinforces the view that the Impartial Culture is unrealistic and non descriptive of empirical data on social choice behavior. Moreover, they show the propensity of IC model to overevaluate the frequency of majority cycles, which turn out to be very rare with random sampling. The second work has been made by Gelman, Katz and Bafumi [11] on voting power indices. They showed that the Straffin’s Independence assumption (game theory's equivalent of Impartial Culture) had to be rejected for the elections of the senators, the representatives and president in the United States; similar conclusions are drawn from the elec- toral data collected over Europe. This special case of model does not fit any of the empirical data they have examined. They indicate that voting power evaluations are based on an empirically falsified and theoretically unjustified model. For them, a more realistic and reasonable model could be affected by local, regional and national effects. The IAC model is not tested in these two preceeding works but we can think that it is not enough realistic too. Then, the resulting question is : if we still want to use a priori models (be- cause they are relatively easy to implement, can be interpreted normatively and give a neutral point of view for the evaluation of voting rules), which adap- tations are possible to make them more realistic ? Theoretical answers have been given by the literature (see Nurmi [20, 21, 22], Feix, Lepelley, Merlin and Rouet [9, 10]).
Recommended publications
  • Gerrymandering Becomes a Problem
    VOLUME TWENTY FOUR • NUMBER TWO WINTER 2020 THE SPECIAL ELECTION EDITION A LEGAL NEWSPAPER FOR KIDS Gerrymandering Becomes a Problem Battling Over for the States to Resolve How to Elect by Phyllis Raybin Emert a President by Michael Barbella Gerrymandering on a partisan basis is not new to politics. The term gerrymander dates back to the 1800s when it was used to mock The debate on how the President Massachusetts Governor Elbridge Gerry, who manipulated congressional of the United States should be elected lines in the state until the map of one district looked like a salamander. is almost as old as the country itself. Redistricting, which is the redrawing of district maps, happens every Contrary to popular belief, voters 10 years after the U.S. Census takes place. Whatever political party is do not elect the president and vice in power at that time has the advantage since, in most states, they president directly; instead, they choose are in charge of drawing the maps. electors to form an Electoral College “Partisan gerrymandering refers to the practice of politicians where the official vote is cast. drawing voting districts for their own political advantage,” During the Constitutional Convention says Eugene D. Mazo, a professor at Rutgers Law School and of 1787, a an expert on election law and the voting process. few ways to Professor Mazo explains that politicians, with the use of advanced computer elect the chief technology, use methods of “packing” and “cracking” to move voters around to executive were different state districts, giving the edge to one political party.
    [Show full text]
  • I'll Have What She's Having: Reflective Desires and Consequentialism
    I'll Have What She's Having: Reflective Desires and Consequentialism by Jesse Kozler A thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Bachelor of Arts with Honors Department of Philosophy in the University of Michigan 2019 Advisor: Professor James Joyce Second Reader: Professor David Manley Acknowledgments This thesis is not the product of solely my own efforts, and owes its existence in large part to the substantial support that I have received along the way from the many wonderful, brilliant people in my life. First and foremost, I want to thank Jim Joyce who eagerly agreed to advise this project and who has offered countless insights which gently prodded me to refine my approach, solidify my thoughts, and strengthen my arguments. Without him this project would never have gotten off the ground. I want to thank David Manley, who signed on to be the second reader and whose guidance on matters inside and outside of the realm of my thesis has been indispensable. Additionally, I want to thank Elizabeth Anderson, Peter Railton, and Sarah Buss who, through private discussions and sharing their own work, provided me with inspiration at times I badly needed it and encouraged me to think about previously unexamined issues. I am greatly indebted to the University of Michigan LSA Honors Program who, through their generous Honors Summer Fellowship program, made it possible for me to stay in Ann Arbor and spend my summer reading and thinking intentionally about these issues. I am especially grateful to Mika LaVaque-Manty, who whipped me into shape and instilled in me a work ethic that has been essential to the completion of this project.
    [Show full text]
  • The 2020 Presidential Election: Provisions of the Constitution and U.S. Code
    PREFACE The National Archives and Records Administration (NARA) is proud to acknowledge its role in the Presidential election pro- cess. NARA’s Office of the Federal Register (OFR) acts as the administrator of the Electoral College and carries out the duties of the Archivist. In this role, the OFR is charged with helping the States carry out their election responsibilities, ensuring the completeness and integrity of the Electoral College documents submitted to Congress, and informing the public about the Presidential election process. The Electoral College system was established under Article II and Amendment 12 of the U.S. Constitution. In each State, the voters choose electors to select the President and Vice President of the United States, based on the results of the Novem- ber general election. Before the general election, the Archivist officially notifies each State’s governor and the Mayor of the District of Columbia of their electoral responsibilities. OFR provides instructions and resources to help the States and District of Columbia carry out those responsibilities. As the results of the popular vote are finalized in each state, election officials create Certificates of Ascertainment, which establish the credentials of their electors, that are sent to OFR. In December, the electors hold meetings in their States to vote for President and Vice President. The electors seal Certificates of Vote and send them to the OFR and Congress. In January, Congress sits in joint session to certify the election of the President and Vice President. In the year after the election, electoral documents are held at the OFR for public viewing, and then transferred to the Archives of the United States for permanent retention and access.
    [Show full text]
  • Review of Paradoxes Afflicting Various Voting Procedures Where One out of M Candidates (M ≥ 2) Must Be Elected
    Dan S. Felsenthal Review of paradoxes afflicting various voting procedures where one out of m candidates (m ≥ 2) must be elected Workshop Paper Original citation: Felsenthal, Dan S. (2010) Review of paradoxes afflicting various voting procedures where one out of m candidates (m ≥ 2) must be elected. In: Assessing Alternative Voting Procedures, London School of Economics and Political Science, London, UK. This version available at: http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/27685/ Available in LSE Research Online: April 2010 © 2010 Dan S. Felsenthal LSE has developed LSE Research Online so that users may access research output of the School. Copyright © and Moral Rights for the papers on this site are retained by the individual authors and/or other copyright owners. Users may download and/or print one copy of any article(s) in LSE Research Online to facilitate their private study or for non-commercial research. You may not engage in further distribution of the material or use it for any profit-making activities or any commercial gain. You may freely distribute the URL (http://eprints.lse.ac.uk) of the LSE Research Online website. Review of Paradoxes Afflicting Various Voting Procedures Where One Out of m Candidates (m ≥ 2) Must Be Elected* Dan S. Felsenthal University of Haifa and Centre for Philosophy of Natural and Social Science London School of Economics and Political Science Revised 3 May 2010 Prepared for presentation in a symposium and a workshop on Assessing Alternative Voting Procedures Sponsored by The Leverhulme Trust (Grant F/07-004/AJ) London School of Economics and Political Science, 27 May 2010 and Chateau du Baffy, Normandy, France, 30 July – 2 August, 2010 Please send by email all communications regarding this paper to the author at: [email protected] or at [email protected] * I wish to thank Rudolf Fara and Moshé Machover for helpful comments, and Hannu Nurmi for sending me several examples contained in this paper.
    [Show full text]
  • The Electoral College: a System “For the People?”
    The University of Maine DigitalCommons@UMaine Honors College Spring 5-2018 The Electoral College: A System “for the People?” Maria Maffucci University of Maine Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.library.umaine.edu/honors Part of the Political Science Commons Recommended Citation Maffucci, Maria, "The Electoral College: A System “for the People?”" (2018). Honors College. 350. https://digitalcommons.library.umaine.edu/honors/350 This Honors Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by DigitalCommons@UMaine. It has been accepted for inclusion in Honors College by an authorized administrator of DigitalCommons@UMaine. For more information, please contact [email protected]. THE ELECTORAL COLLEGE: A SYSTEM “FOR THE PEOPLE?” by Maria Maffucci A Thesis Submitted in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for a Degree with Honors (Political Science) The Honors College University of Maine May 2018 Advisory Committee: Mark Brewer, PhD, Professor of Political Science and Honors, Advisor Melissa Ladenheim, PhD, Honors College Associate Dean, Honors Preceptor Richard Powell, PhD, Professor of Political Science Harold Daniel, PhD, Associate Professor of Marketing Stefano Tijerina, PhD, Lecturer in Management, Maine Business School ABSTRACT This research project investigates the thoughts and opinions of the University of Maine faculty and undergraduate students regarding the Electoral College system. I chose to collect this information through an online survey of twenty questions that I created on the software, Qualtrics, and sent it to the various classes and faculty who gave approval. Once I got a sufficient number of results, it was then time to analyze it all. Overall, my results were mostly what I had predicted; most undergraduates and faculty are in favor of replacing the Electoral College with either a direct popular voting system or a candidate ranking system.
    [Show full text]
  • How an Outdated Electoral Structure Has Led to Political Polarization in the United States
    The United States Election System: How an Outdated Electoral Structure has led to Political Polarization in the United States by Jake Fitzharris A THESIS submitted to Oregon State University Honors College in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Honors Baccalaureate of Science in Political Science and Psychology (Honors Associate) Presented January 24, 2019 Commencement June 2019 AN ABSTRACT OF THE THESIS OF Jake Fitzharris for the degree of Honors Baccalaureate of Science in Political Science and Psychology presented on January 24, 2019. Title: The United States Election System: How an Outdated Electoral Structure has led to Political Polarization in the United States. Abstract approved:_____________________________________________________ Christopher Nichols Political Polarization in the United States is at a level higher today than at any point in the past few decades. Possible causes of this rise in polarization have been provided from various sources, including explanations such as mass media and income inequality. Through historical analysis and a wide literature review, this thesis explores a major factor in political polarization, the United States election system. The thesis argues that the election system in the United States exacerbates the intensely polarized political climate of the modern day United States in three main ways: the electoral college, which produces the persisting two party system, primary elections, which reinforce extreme candidate views, and districting, which tends to increase politically uniform districts and lead candidates to position themselves at the poles rather than in the center. The thesis concludes that the only way to eliminate political polarization stemming from all of these sources would be to implement a unique proportional representation system for the United States.
    [Show full text]
  • Oakland City Council Resolution No. 86 5 £1 C.M.S
    FILED OFFICE OF THE ern CLERK Approved as to Form and Legality OAKLAND 16 DEC-8 PM/li'IS City\Attorney's Office OAKLAND CITY COUNCIL RESOLUTION NO. 86 5 £1 C.M.S. INTRODUCED BY COUNCILMEMBERS DAN KALB AND REBECCA KAPLAN RESOLUTION (1) IN SUPPORT OF SENATOR BARBARA BOXER'S BILL TO ABOLISH THE ELECTORAL COLLEGE AND (2) DIRECTING THE CITY ADMINISTRATOR AND CITY LOBBYIST TO WORK WITH ALL RELEVANT STATE AND FEDERAL ELECTED OFFICIALS TO (A) DEVELOP AND RATIFY AN AMENDMENT TO THE UNITED STATES CONSTITUTION TO REPLACE THE ELECTORAL COLLEGE WITH A NATIONAL POPULAR VOTE FOR PRESIDENT OF THE UNITED STATES OR, ALTERNATIVELY, TO APPROVE THE NATIONAL POPULAR VOTE INTERSTATE COMPACT, (B) ADDRESS GERRYMANDERING IN CONGRESSIONAL APPORTIONMENT BY REQUIRING REDISTRICTING REFORM, SUCH AS BY HAVING INDEPENDENT STATE REDISTRICTING COMMISSIONS CONDUCT REDISTRICTING INSTEAD OF STATE LEGISLATURES, AND (C) ELIMINATE BARRIERS TO VOTING WHEREAS, as provided by Article II of the United States Constitution, the President and Vice President are selected by the Electoral College, comprised of a slate of Electors from each state and the District of Columbia, with each state having a number of Electors equal to its number of congresspersons (total Representatives plus two Senators) and the District of Columbia having three Electors; and WHEREAS, U.S. citizens casting votes in the general election for a presidential candidate are actually not directly voting for that candidate but instead vote for a slate of Electors in their state representing the candidate, with the
    [Show full text]
  • Trump, Condorcet and Borda: Voting Paradoxes in the 2016 Republican Presidential Primaries
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive Trump, Condorcet and Borda: Voting paradoxes in the 2016 Republican presidential primaries Kurrild-Klitgaard, Peter University of Copenhagen 15 December 2016 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/75598/ MPRA Paper No. 75598, posted 15 Dec 2016 16:00 UTC Trump, Condorcet and Borda: Voting paradoxes in the 2016 Republican presidential primaries1 PETER KURRILD-KLITGAARD Dept. of Political Science, University of Copenhagen Abstract. The organization of US presidential elections make them potentially vulnerable to so-called “voting paradoxes”, identified by social choice theorists but rarely documented empirically. The presence of a record high number of candidates in the 2016 Republican Party presidential primaries may have made this possibility particularly latent. Using polling data from the primaries we identify two possible cases: Early in the pre-primary (2015) a cyclical majority may have existed in Republican voters’ preferences between Bush, Cruz and Walker—thereby giving a rare example of the Condorcet Paradox. Furthermore, later polling data (March 2016) suggests that while Trump (who achieved less than 50% of the total Republican primary vote) was the Plurality Winner, he could have been beaten in pairwise contests by at least one other candidate—thereby exhibiting a case of the Borda Paradox. The cases confirm the empirical relevance of the theoretical voting paradoxes and the importance of voting procedures. Key words: Social choice; Condorcet Paradox; Borda Paradox; US presidential election 2016; Jeb Bush; Chris Christie; Ted Cruz; John Kasich; Marco Rubio; Donald Trump; Scot Walker; voting system. JEL-codes: D71; D72. 1. Introduction Since the 1950s social choice theory has questioned the possibility of aggregating individual preferences to straightforward, meaningful collective choices (Arrow [1951] 1963).
    [Show full text]
  • 5.8 Electing a President Explain How the Different Processes Work in a U.S. Presidential Election. Explain How the Electoral College Impacts Democratic Participation
    Room 2B HIVE mrreview.org 5.8 Electing a President Explain how the different processes work in a U.S. presidential election. Explain how the Electoral College impacts democratic participation. Institutional rules along with campaign norms go a long way in explaining American government and politics. The outcomes of federal elections are greatly impacted by process. The impact of federal policies on campaigning and electoral rules continues to be contested. With representative democracy as the standard, many political scientists wonder if our current electoral process delivers the best results. To win an election here, candidates must navigate through a maze of rules, regulations and practices many of which are rooted in traditions rather than best practice. Nevertheless, many would argue today that the process of federal elections has grown increasingly democratic. This too is contested. The federal election process has two important stages. The first stage of any electoral process is winning a political party’s nomination. Party candidates used to be selected by the party bosses in small caucuses. Party caucuses were nothing more and nothing less than conversations between small groups of empowered citizens. Benefits were doled out by and for party loyalists. This was called a spoils system. Everyday citizens were left out of the process. Early elites were fearful of common passions. The average person was not trusted to make important party decisions. It did not take long for this to change. As suffrage rights expanded voters demanded more and more power in voicing their candidate preferences. This first manifested itself in political party conventions. These conventions were held so that many more citizens could participate in the nominating process.
    [Show full text]
  • The Electoral College & Gerrymandering
    The Electoral College & Gerrymandering A Mathematical Exploration of Issues of Representation in the United States Callie Gardella Overview 1. How is representation determined? 2. What is Gerrymandering? 3. What is the Electoral College? Guiding Question: Is there a mathematical method that could be used to address issues of representation and bias in determining apportionment and redistricting? The Federal Legislative Branch Senate: 100 seats, 2 per state House of Representatives: 435 seats, assigned according to population Apportionment Dividing the 435 seats of congress between the 50 states Occurs every ten years, coinciding with the Census Rules: 1. Every state gets at least 1 representative 2. The Census must provide the state populations within 9 months of collection 3. The President must inform Congress of these numbers within one week of their next session 4. Congress has 15 days to determine the number of representatives per state Historical Methods The Hamilton/Vinton Method: Assign each surplus seat: to the state with the highest fractional component The Jefferson Method: Assign each surplus seat to the state with the largest critical divisor The Webster Method: Round up if the fractional component is ≥.5, round down otherwise Current Mathematical Method Huntington-Hill Method, used since 1941 mathematically determined priority listing of states Priority calculated by dividing the population of each state by the geometric mean of its current and next seats P - represents a state's total population n - represents the current
    [Show full text]
  • Psephology with Dr
    Psephology with Dr. Michael Lewis-Beck Ologies Podcast November 2, 2018 Oh heyyyy, it's that neighborhood lady who wears pantyhose with sandals and hosts a polling place in her garage with a bowl of leftover Halloween candy, Alie Ward! Welcome to this special episode, it's a mini, and it's a bonus, but it's also the first one I've ever done via telephone. Usually, I drag myself to a town and I make an ologist meet me in a library, or a shady hotel, and we record face to face, but time was of the essence here. He had a landline, raring to chat, we went for it. I did not know this ology was an ology until the day before we did this interview. Okay, we're gonna get to it. As always, thank you, Patrons for the for fielding my post, “hey, should I record a really quick voting episode this week?” with your resounding yeses. I love you, thank you for supporting the show. OlogiesMerch has shirts and hats if you need ‘em. And thank you everyone for leaving reviews and ratings, including San Rey [phonetic] who called this podcast, “Sherlock Holmes dressed in street wear.” I will take that. Also, you're assuming that I'm wearing pants... Quick plug also, I have a brand new show on Netflix that dropped today! It's called Brainchild, it's produced by Pharrell Williams and the folks at Atomic Entertainment. I’m in every episode popping up to explain science while also wearing a metallic suit and a beehive.
    [Show full text]
  • Counting Electoral Votes: an Overview of Procedures at the Joint Session, Including Objections by Members of Congress
    Counting Electoral Votes: An Overview of Procedures at the Joint Session, Including Objections by Members of Congress Updated December 8, 2020 Congressional Research Service https://crsreports.congress.gov RL32717 Counting Electoral Votes: An Overview of Procedures at the Joint Session, Including Objections by Members of Congress Summary The Constitution and federal law establish a detailed timetable following the presidential election during which time the members of the electoral college convene in the 50 state capitals and in the District of Columbia, cast their votes for President and Vice President, and submit their votes through state officials to both houses of Congress. The electoral votes are scheduled to be opened before a joint session of Congress on January 6, 2021. Federal law specifies the procedures for this session and for challenges to the validity of an electoral vote. This report describes the steps in the process and precedents set in prior presidential elections governing the actions of the House and Senate in certifying the electoral vote and in responding to challenges of the validity of electoral votes. This report has been revised and will be updated on a periodic basis to provide the dates for the relevant joint session of Congress and to reflect any new, relevant precedents or practices. Congressional Research Service Counting Electoral Votes: An Overview of Procedures at the Joint Session, Including Objections by Members of Congress Contents Actions Leading Up to the Joint Session ........................................................................................
    [Show full text]