<<

Forecasting the Effects of Reduced Defense Spending

Peter Irel’and and Chtitopher Omk ’

I. INTRODUCTION $1 cut in defense spending acts to decrease the total demand for in each period by $1. The end of the Cold War provides the United Of course, so as the has access to States with an opportunity to cut its defense the same production technologies that are available spending significantly. Indeed, the Bush Administra- to the private sector, this prediction of the tion’s 1992-1997 Future Years Defense Program neoclassical model does not change if instead the (presented in 1991 and therefore referred to as the government produces the defense services itself.’ “1991 plan”) calls for a 20 percent reduction in real defense spending by 1997. Although expenditures A permanent $1 cut in defense spending also related to Operation Desert Storm have delayed the reduces the government’s need for revenue; it implementation of the 199 1 plan, policymakers con- implies that can be cut by $1 in each period. tinue to call for defense cutbacks. In fact, since Bush’s Households, therefore, are wealthier following the plan was drafted prior to the collapse of the Soviet cut in defense spending; their permanent income in- Union, it seems likely that the Clinton Administra- creases by $b1. According to the permanent income tion will propose cuts in defense spending that are hypothesis, this $1 increase in permanent income even deeper than those specified by the 1991 plan. induces households to increase their by This paper draws on both theoretical and empirical $1 in every period, provided that their labor supply economic models to forecast the effects that these does not change. cuts will have on the U.S. . However, the wealth effect of reduced defense A. Economic Theory spending may also induce households to increase the amount of leisure that they choose to enjoy. If Economic theory suggests that in the run, households respond to the increase in wealth by cuts in defense spending are likely to have disrup- taking more leisure, then the increase in consump- tive effects on the U.S. economy. Productive tion from the wealth effect only amounts to $( 1 -a) resources-both labor and -must shift out of per period, where cy is a number between zero and defense-related industries and into nondefense in- one: That is, the increase in wealth is split between dustries. The adjustment costs that this shift entails an increase in consumption and an increase in leisure. are likely to restrain as the defense In general, therefore, the wealth effect of a cut in cuts are implemented. defense spending acts to increase private consump- Economic theory is less clear, however, about the tion, and hence total demand, by $( 1 -a) per period. likely long-run consequences of reduced defense The increase in leisure from the wealth effect, spending. The neoclassical macroeconomic model meanwhile, translates into a decrease in labor (a simple version of which is presented by Barro, supply. This decrease in labor supply, in turn, 1984) assumes that all goods and services are pro- translates into a decrease in the total supply of goods duced by the private sector. Rather than hiring labor, and services. In fact, the increase in leisure acts to accumulating capital, and producing defense services decrease the total supply of goods by $a per period itself, the government simply purchases these ser- (Barro, 1984, Ch. 13). Thus, the number o! measures vices from the private sector. Thus, according to the neoclassical model, the direct effect of a permanent r See Wynne (1992), however, for a more general version of the neoclassical model in which the government may have l The authors would like to thank Mike Dotsey, Mary Finn, access to different technologies from those used by the private Marvin Goodfriend, Tom Humphrey, Jeff Lacker, Max Reid, sector. Wynne’s model also distinguishes between the goods and Stephen Stanley, and Roy Webb for helpful comments and services that the government produces itself and those that it suggestions. purchases from the private sector.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND 3 . the magnitude of the wealth effect’s impact on leisure government today simply means that tax’cuts and the supply of goods relative to itsimpact on con- of more than $1 per period will come in the future. sumption and the demand for goods. The higher a Under , household wealth does is, the larger the decrease in supply and the smaller not depend on the precise timing of the tax cuts. The the increase in demand. \ _ magnitude of the wealth effect, and hence the changes in aggregate supply and demand, are the. Combining the direct effect of the permanent same whether the cut in defense spending is used $1 cut in defense spending, which decreases total to reduce the federal debt or to reduce taxes. demand by $1 per period, with the wealth effect, which increases total demand by $( 1 - 4 per ‘period, Central to the Ricardian equivalence theorem is shows that the permanent cut in defense spending the assumption that households experience the same decreases the total demand for goods by $a per change in wealth from a reduction in government period. Likewise, the direct effect implies no change debt as they do from a cut in taxes. If this assump- in supply, while the wealth effect implies a decrease tion is incorrect, then a cut in defense spending can in supply of $cr per period; when combined, the two have very different long-run effects from those effects imply a decrease in supply of $(Y per period. predicted by the neoclassical model under Ricardian Altogether, both total demand and total supply equivalence. decrease by $cy in each period, so that the perma- nent cut in defense spending reduces realoutput by Most frequently, the relevance of the Ricardian $a in each period. equivalence theorem is questioned based upon the observation that households have lifetimes of finite Before moving on, it is important to emphasize that length (Bernheim, 1987). Suppose, for instance, that although the neoclassical model predicts that total while individuals recognize that a reduction in govern- output (GNP) will fall in response to a permanent ment debt today implies that taxes will be lower in cut. in defense spending, this result does not imply the future, they also expect that the future tax cuts that households would be better. off without the will occur after they have died. In this extreme case, spending cut. While the permanent $1 cut in defense individuals who are alive today experience no change spending reduces total GNP by $a per period,,it also in wealth if,the cuts in defense spending are used makes available to households $1 per period that to reduce the government debt. Only the direct would otherwise be allocated to defense. Private effect of the defense cut is present; the wealth GNP, defined as total GNP less all government effect is missing. Since households do not experience spending, therefore increases by $( 1 - ~4 per period. an increase in permanent income, neither their con- Since private GNP.accounts for the goods and ser- sumption nor their labor supply changes. The vices that are available to the private sector, it is a decrease in total demand resulting from the direct better measure of than total GNP; the rise effect of the spending cut leads to a condition of in private GNP indicates that households are better excess supply. off after the defense cuts, even though total GNP is lower. In fact, the increase in private GNP In response to excess supply, output falls in the underestimates the welfare gain from reduced defense short run, and the real rate falls as well. In spending since it does not ,take into account the in- the long run, however, the lower real crease in leisure resulting from the wealth effect of leads to increases in both investment and output. the spending cut. Thus, a departure from Ricardian equivalence can explain why cuts in defense spending might increase, So far, the a na 1ysis has assumed that the cut in rather than decrease, total GNP in the long run, defense spending will be used to reduce taxes. provided that the cuts are used to reduce the govern- Provided that the Ricardian equivalence theorem ment debt. applies, however, the results do not change if instead the cuts are used to reduce the government debt. Whether or not the Ricardian equivalence theorem Suppose that, in fact, the permanent $1 cut in applies to the U.S. economy is a controversial issue. defense spending is initially used to reduce the There are many theoretical models in which house- government debt. According to the Ricardian hold wealth is affected by a decrease in government equivalence theorem, households recognize that by debt in exactly the same way that wealth is affected reducing its debt, the government is reducing its need by a decrease in taxes, so that Ricardian equivalence for future tax revenues by an equal amount. Thus, applies (see Barre, 1989, for a survey of these using the cut in defense spending to reduce the models). On the other hand, there are many other

4 ECONOMIC REVIEW. NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1992 models in which the wealth effect from a cut in these forecasts will be on target only to the extent government debt differs from the wealth effect from that their underlying-and controversial-assumption a cut in taxes, so that Ricardian equivalence does not about Ricardian equivalence is correct. hold (see Bernheim, 1987, for a survey of these models). Overall, economic theory provides no clear C. An Alternative Forecasting Strategy answer as to the relevance of the Ricardian equiva- This paper takes an approach to forecasting the lence theorem. Consequently, economic theory does effects of reduced defense spending that differs not provide a clear answer as to the long-run effects significantly from the approach taken by the CBO. of cuts in defense spending either. Instead, empirical Rather than using a large-scale econometric model, models must be used to forecast the effects of re- it uses a much smaller vector autoregressive (VAR) duced defense spending. model like those developed by Sims (Jan. 1980, May 1980). As emphasized by Sims (Jan. 1980), VAR B. Previous Empirical Estimates models require none of the strong theoretical A detailed study by the Congressional Budget assumptions that the DRI and MSG models rely on Office (CBO, 1992) forecasts the effects of the 199 1 so heavily. The approach taken here, therefore, plan for the U.S. economy. The CBO’s conclusions recognizes that economic theory provides no clear are based on results from two large-scale macro- answer as to the likely long-run effects of reduced economic forecasting models: the Data Resources, defense spending. Moreover, as documented by Inc. (DRI) Quarterly Macroeconomic Model and the Lupoletti and Webb (1986), VAR models typically McKibbin-Sachs Global (MSG) Model. Both of these perform as well as the larger models when used as econometric models incorporate short-run djustment forecasting tools, especially over long horizons. Thus, costs of changes in defense spending and long-run there are both theoretical and practical reasons to non-Ricardian effects of changes in the government prefer the VAR approach to the CBO’s. debt into their forecasts for real economic activity. The models predict, therefore, that the cuts proposed Forecasts from the VAR model, like those from by the 1991 plan will reduce growth in the U.S. the CBO’s models, show that the 199 1 plan will lead economy in the short run. The models also predict to weakness in aggregate output in the short run. that if the cuts in defense spending are used to reduce Unlike the CBO’s models, however, the VAR does the federal debt, then the real interest rate will fall not predict that there will be a long-run increase in and investment and output will increase in the long total GNP resulting from the cuts in defense spend- run as the non-Ricardian effects kick in. Thus, while ing, even if the cuts are used to reduce the federal the CBO predicts that the 199 1 plan will reduce total debt. This result, which is consistent with the neo- GNP by approximately 0.6 percent throughout the classical model under Ricardian equivalence, suggests mid-1990s their forecasts also show positive effects that the larger models rely on the incorrect assump- on total GNP by the end of the decade, leading to tion that there are strong non-Ricardian effects of a long-run increase in total GNP of almost 1 percent. changes in the government debt in the U.S. economy.

The Congressional Budget Office’s econometric Although the VAR forecasts for total GNP are models draw heavily on economic theory to obtain considerably more pessimistic than the CBO’s fore- their conclusions. As noted above, however, there casts, they do not imply that the defense cuts called is considerable debate in the theoretical literature for by the 199 1 plan are undesirable. Private GNP, concerning the possible channels through which in contrast to total GNP, is forecast by the VAR to defense spending influences aggregate activity in the increase in the long run as a result of the 199 1 plan. long run. Models that assume that the Ricardian This result, which is again consistent with the neo- equivalence theorem holds indicate that cuts in classical model under Ricardian equivalence, indicates defense spending will reduce output in the long run. that the 199 1 plan will make more resources available On the other hand, models in which Ricardian to the private sector in the long run. As noted by equivalence does not apply predict that defense cuts Garfinkel (1990) and Wynne (1991), this gain in may increase output in the long run, provided that resources can be used to increase private consump- the proceeds from the cuts are used to reduce the tion and investment, making American households government debt. The CBO’s models both assume better off in the long run. that Ricardian equivalence does not hold in the U.S. economy. Hence, their forecasts show significant The VAR is introduced in the next section. Sec- long-run gains in total GNP from the 199 1 plan. But tion III presents the forecasts generated by the VAR

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND 5 and compares them to the forecasts given by the that affect defense spending and the government CBO. Section IV summarizes and concludes. debt, but before , prices, or output are ob- served. Money, prices, and output are then deter- II. DESCRIPTION OF THE MODEL mined in succession, given that has determined RDEF and RDEBT and The basic model is an extension of the four-variable has determined R.2 VAR developed by Sims (May 1980) and is de- signed specifically to capture the effects of defense III. FORECASTSFROMTHE VAR spending on aggregate economic activity. There are six variables in the model: the growth rate of real The VAR results are foreshadowed in Figure 1, defense spending (RDEF), the growth rate of real which plots the series Y, RDEF, and RDEBT over U.S. government debt.(RDEBT), the nominal six- the 60-year sample period. Panel B reveals that there month commercial paper rate (R), the growth rate were significant cuts in defense spending following of the broad monetary aggregate (MZ), the growth World War II, the Korean War, and the Vietnam War. rate of the implicit price deflator for total GNP (P), In each case, the defense cuts were accompanied by and the growth rate of real total GNP (Y). All of the slow growth in total GNP (panel A). In light of this variables except for the interest rate are expressed past relationship, it seems likely that the VAR will as growth rates so that all may be represented as sta- associate the defense cuts called for by the 199 1 plan tionary stochastic processes. Using growth rates for with slower total GNP growth, at least in the short these variables avoids the problems, discussed by run. Stock and Watson (1989), associated with including nonstationary variables in the VAR. By comparing the behavior of RDEBT (panel C) to that of Y (panel A), however, it is difficult to see Using vector notation, the model can be written as the negative long-run relationship between output and government debt predicted by models in which the Xt = ;: B,Xt-, +ut, (1) Ricardian equivalence theorem does not apply. s=l Growth in the real of U.S. government debt was negative for much of the 1950s and 1960s and where the 6x1 vector Xt is given by positive for much of the 1970s and all of the 1980s.

Xt = [RDEFt,RDEBT,,R,,MZ,,Pt,Ytj ’ (2) 2 More formally, the variables in equation (2) are organized as a Wold causal chain to produce the impulse response functions. and where the B, are each 6x6 matrices of regres- See Sims (1986) for a detailed discussion of the Wold causal sion coefficients. In order to obtain information about chain approach as well as other strategies for identifying impulse the long-run effects of changes in defense spending, response functions in VAR models. the system (1) is estimated using a long data set that extends from 193 1 through 199 1. All data are Figure 1A annual (quarterly data are unavailable for dates prior to World War II); their sources are given in the GROWTH RATE OF REAL GNP appendix. The lag length k = 4 is chosen on the basis 20 of the specification test recommended by Doan 16 - (1989). n-

Once the system (1) is estimated, impulse response functions can be used to trace out the effects of changes in defense spending and the government debt on total GNP and, in particular, to forecast the 4 effects of the 199 1 plan. For the purpose of gener- ating impulse response functions, the ordering of variables shown in equation (2) reflects the assump- -8 tion that policy decisions that change defense spending are made before the contemporaneous -1i values of the other variables are observed. Monetary -16 policy actions, which are best captured as changes -20 Ll in Rt (McCallum, 1986), are made after decisions 1931 1940 1950 1960 1970 ‘I980 1990

6 ECONOMIC REVIEW. NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1992 Figure 1B GROWTH RATE OF REAL DEFENSE SPENDING 500

400

300

F 8 2 200 -20 ,,,,1,11,'111,,1111'1,1,,,,,,',11,1,,1,' 1952 1960 1970 1980 1990

100

0

-100 1931 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990

Figure 1C GROWTH RATE OF REAL GOVERNMENT DEBT 90 I I 20' I 80 - I 15 - 70 - 10 - 60 - 5- 50 -

1948 1958 1968 1978 1988

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND 7 Yet it does not appear that the growth rate of output Figure 2A was substantially different before and after 1970, as CUMULATIVE RESPONSE OF GROWTH RATE OF these models predict. Thus, it seems likely that the REAL GNP TO GROWTH RATE OF VAR will not find strong non-Ricardian effects of REAL DEFENSE SPENDING changes in government debt in the U.S. economy. (with 95 percent confidence interval) 4, Figure 2, panel A, shows the cumulative impulse .- / / response function of Y to a one-time one-standard 2 c / i- deviation (20 percent) decrease in RDEF, computed using the VAR described by equations (1) and (‘Z).3 The graph shows the cumulative change in the level of total GNP through the end of each year that results from a decrease in RDEF in the first year. It indicates that the decrease in RDEF yields a contemporaneous decrease in total GNP of approximately 1.5 percent. \ ,--1 -8 - LJ \ The effect of the shock to RDEF peaks at 5.5 per- \ cent after four years before settling down to a long- -10 - \ . run decrease of about 2.5 percent. The confidence . -12 ’ ’ ’ ’ ’ ’ ’ ’ ’ ’ ’ ’ ’ ’ ’ interval reveals that the initial decrease in total GNP 1 2 3.4.5.6 7 8 9101112 131415 due to the decrease in defense spending is statistically significant. In fact, the hypothesis that changes in RDEF do not influence Y (more formally, the hy- pothesis that changes in RDEF do not Granger-cause Forecasts from the VAR are generated by con- changes in Y) can be rejected at the 99 percent straining future values of RDEF and RDEBT as confidence level.4 Thus, the model indicates that called for by the 199 1 plan. The constrained values in response to a decrease in defense spending, total of RDEF and RDEBT translate into constrained GNP will fall in both the short run and the long run. values of the shocks to these two variables. Hence, the VAR forecasts are essentially linear combinations Figure 2, panel B, plots the cumulative impulse of the impulse response functions shown in Figure response function of Y to a one-time one-standard ‘2. The impulse response functions suggest that the deviation (3 percent) decrease in RDEBT. Con- short-run forecasts from the VAR will be similar to sistent with the non-Ricardian assumptions that are those given by the CBO’s models, but the long-run embedded in the DRI and MSG models, this im- forecasts will be quite different. All of the models pulse response function indicates that a decrease in RDEBT will increase total GNP in the long run. In addition, the hypothesis that changes in RDEBT do not influence changes in Y can be rejected at the Figure 2B 98 percent confidence level. However, at no time CUMULATIVE RESPONSE OF GROWTH RATE OF are the effects of RDEBT on Y very large; except REAL GNP TO GROWTH RATE OF in period 2, the confidence interval always includes REAL GOVERNMENT DEBT zero. Overall, therefore, Figure 2 is consistent with (with 95 percent confidence interval) the neoclassical model under Ricardian equivalence, which predicts that a reduction in the size of the 5 federal debt will not have a large effect on output 4 -- .- and that a reduction in defense spending will perma- I--- 3 1 / nently reduce total GNP.

3 Note that each of the impulse response functions in Figure 2 traces out the effects of a decrease in one of the variables on GNP. Impulse response functions more typically examine the effects of an increase in one of the model’s variables. Here, however, it is the effects of decreases in defense spending and -2 - \ government debt that are of interest, so the direction of the shock is reversed. \ -3 - \ -/------4 Here and below, the likelihood ratio test for block exogeneity described by Doan (1989) is used to test for the absence of -4 ’ ’ ’ ’ ’ ’ ’ ’ ’ ’ ’ ’ ’ ’ ’ Granger causality. i 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14’15

8 ECONOMIC REVIEW. NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1992 predict that cuts in defense spending will reduce total Forecasts of the Effects of the 1991 Plan on GNP

GNP in the short run. But the VAR forecasts none Model of the long-run gains in total GNP that the large-scale DRI MSG VAR VAR models do. Year (total GNP) (total GNP) (total GNP) (private GNP)

The table (right) compares the forecasts of the 1992 -0.2 -0.3 -0.4 -0.2 effects of the 199 1 plan on total GNP generated by 1993 -0.7 -0.6 - 1.0 -0.3 the VAR model to those generated by the DRI and 1994 -0.6 -0.5 -1.4 -0.5 MSG models. All three sets of forecasts compare the 1995 -0.6 -0.5 -1.8 -0.4 predicted behavior of total GNP under a base case, 1996 -0.6 -0.3 -2.2 -0.4 in which real defense spending is essentially held con- 1997 -0.6 -0.2 -2.4 -0.3 stant as a fraction of total GNP (except for the small 2000 0.0 0.5 -2.0 -0.1 decreases called for by the Budget Enforcement Act), 2010 N/A 0.8 - 1.9 0.3 to the behavior of total GNP when defense spend- 2015 N/A 0.9 - 1.9 0.3 ing is cut as called for by the 1991 plan and the proceeds are used to reduce the federal debt. The Notes: The effects are expressed as percentage differences between GNP figures in the table represent the predicted differ- under the 1991 plan for reductions in defense spending and GNP under the base case of no change in real defense spending. ences, in percentages, between the level of total GNP DRI is the Data Resouces Model, MSG is the McKibbin-Sachs under the 1991 plan and the level of total GNP in Model, and VAR is the vector autoregressive model. Details about the two alternative paths for defense spending, as well as the the base case. Details about these two alternative forecasts from the DRI and MSG models, are taken from CBO paths for defense spending are provided in the CBO’s (1992). N/A indicates that the forecast is not available. report (1992, Table 3, p. lo), as are the forecasts from the DRI and MSG models (Figure 3, p. 14 and Table 4, p. 15). results change if nondefense or Barro and Sahasakul’s (1986) marginal tax rate The table shows that the VAR model is consistent- series is added as a seventh variable. Since Figure ly more pessimistic than the CBO’s models about 1 reveals that the behavior of the model’s variables both the short-run and long-run effects of the 1991 was most dramatic during and shortly after World plan. While the DRI and MSG models predict that War II, it is useful to know the extent to which the the short-run costs of reduced defense spending will results depend on the data from these years. When be 0.5 to 0.7 percent of total GNP, the VAR the six-variable VAR is reestimated with quarterly estimates these costs at 1 to 1.8 percent of total data from 1947 through 199 1, the 1991 plan is pre- GNP. While the DRI and MSG models expect long- dicted to reduce total GNP in the long run by 2.7 run benefits from the debt reduction to begin off- percent, a figure that is even larger than that setting the short-run costs in the mid-1990s the VAR generated by the original model. Finally, the forecasts predicts that the costs of the 1991 plan will peak at are insensitive to changes in the lag length from k = 4 2.4 percent of total GNP in the late 1990s. Finally, to k = 3, 5, or 6. The VAR forecasts, therefore, are while both the DRI and MSG models predict gains quite robust to changes in model specification; in all in total GNP by the year 2000, the VAR model cases, cuts in defense spending are predicted to predicts that there will be a permanent loss of 1.9 reduce total GNP substantially in the long run, even percent of total GNP from the 1991 plan. when cuts are used to reduce the federal debt. In order to check the robustness of the VAR To emphasize the point that the VAR forecasts, forecasts, several kinds of alternative model specifica- although considerably more pessimistic than the tions can be considered. Although the causal order- CBO’s forecasts, do not imply that the defense cuts ing used in equation (2) is to be preferred based on called for by the 199 1 plan are undesirable, the table economic theory, it would be troublesome if other also presents forecasts from a VAR model that is orderings yielded vastly different results. Similar identical to model (l), except that the growth rate forecasts are obtained, however, when RDEF and of total GNP is replaced by the growth rate of private RDEBT are placed last, rather than first, in the order- GNP. Private GNP, like total GNP, is predicted to ing. The model does not include some variables that fall in the short run as the 199 1 plan is implemented. may nonetheless be useful in forecasting GNP In the long run, however, private GNP is expected growth. Following the suggestion of Dotsey and Reid to increase by 0.3 percent. The 1991 plan reduces (1992), an oil price series can be added to the model, total GNP, but it also makes available to the private but again the results do not change. Nor do the sector resources that would otherwise be allocated

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND 9 to defense. The VAR forecasts show that on net, As an alternative to the CBO’s large-scale models, private GNP increases, making American households this paper uses a much smaller VAR model to forecast better off from the 1991 plan in the long run. the macroeconomic effects of the 199 1 plan. Unlike the larger models, the VAR requires no strong theoretical assumption about whether or not Ricar- IV. SUMMARYANDCONCLUSIONS dian equivalence holds in the U.S. economy. The VAR, therefore, recognizes that economic theory The Bush Administration’s 1992-1997 Future provides no clear answer as to the likely long-run Years Defense Program (the “1991 plan”) calls for effects of reduced defense spending. the first significant cuts in defense spending in the since the end of the Vietnam War. In fact, results from the VAR suggest that the Economic theory indicates that these defense cuts Ricardian equivalence theorem does apply to the are likely to restrain economic growth in the short U.S. economy. Changes in government debt are run as productive resources shift out of defense- found to have only small effects on aggregate related activities and into nondefense industries. output. Forecasts from the VAR, which show that Economic theory is less clear, however, about the the 1991 plan is likely to reduce total GNP in both long-run consequences of reduced defense spending. the short run and long run, are more consistent with Models that assume that the Ricardian equivalence the neoclassical model presented by Barro (1984), theorem holds find that a permanent decrease in in which Ricardian equivalence holds, than with those defense spending decreases aggregate output in the of competing models in which Ricardian equivalence long run. On the other hand, models that assume does not apply. that Ricardian equivalence does not apply predict that Although the VAR forecasts are considerably more a permanent decrease in defense spending increases pessimistic than the CBO’s forecasts, they do not output in the long run, provided that the proceeds imply that the defense cuts called for by the 1991 from the spending cut are used to reduce the federal plan are undesirable. In fact, both the neoclassical debt. model and the VAR forecasts suggest that as the cuts The large-scale econometric models employed by in defense spending are implemented, growth in total the Congressional Budget Office (1992) rely on the GNP is likely to be a misleading measure of house- theoretical assumption that Ricardian equivalence hold welfare. Although the 1991 plan reduces total does not hold in the U.S. economy. Thus, the CBO’s GNP, it also makes available to the private sector models predict that while the 1991 plan will reduce resources that. would otherwise be allocated to total GNP in the short run as the economy adjusts defense. The VAR forecasts show that on net, private to a lower level of defense spending, they also predict GNP increases. As noted by Garfinkel (1990) and that the non-Ricardian effects of reducing the govern- Wynne (199 l), this net gain can be used to increase ment debt will generate an increase in total GNP in private consumption or private investment, making the long run. American households better off in the long run.

10 ECONOMIC REVIEW, NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1992 APPENDIX REFERENCES

DATASOURCES Barro, Robert J. Macmeconomics. : John Wiley and Sons, 1984. Data for 1930 through 1938 Defense Spending: “The Ricardian Approach to Budget Deficits,” are national outlays reported in Table A-I Journal if Economic Perspectives, vol. 3 (Spring 1989), of Kendrick (1961). Data for 1939 to 1991 are pp. 37-54. government purchases of goods and services, national Barro, Robert J. and Chaipat Sahasakul. “Average Marginal defense, from Table 3.7a of the &rwey of Carrent Tax Rates from Social Security and the Individual Income Business, Department of Commerce, Bureau of Tax,” Journal of Business, vol. 59 (October 1986), pp. Economic Analysis. The nominal data are deflated 555-66. using the implicit price deflator for GNP reported Bernheim, B. Douglas. “Ricardian Equivalence: An Evaluation in Table 7.4 of the same publication. of Theory and Evidence,” NBER Macmeconomics Annual 1987. Cambridge: MIT Press, 1987. Government Debt: Debt before 1941 is total gross Congressional Budget Office, the Congress of the United debt at the end of the fiscal year reported in the States. Th Economic Effects of Reduced Defense Spending. February 1992. Bzdl’etin of the Treasury. Debt for 1941-1991 is total outstanding debt, also at the end of the fiscal year, Doan, Thomas A. User’s ManuaL: RATS V,ion 3.02. Evanston: reported in the same publication. Nominal debt was VAR Econometrics, 1989. deflated to real terms using the implicit price deflator Dotsey, Michael and Max Reid. “Oil Shocks, Monetary Policy, for GNP. and Economic Activity,” Federal Reserve Bank of Rich- mond Economic Review, vol. 78 (July/August 1992), pp. 14-27. Interest Rate: The six-month commercial paper rate is taken from Table H 1.5 of the Statkticai Reha.w, Friedman, ‘Milton and Anna J. Schwartz. Monetary StarisEis of New York: National Bureau of Economic Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. the United States. Research, 1970. Garfinkel; Michelle R. “The Economic Consequences of Moneta y Aggregate: The series Reducing Military Spending,” Federal Reserve Bank of before 1959 is the M4 aggregate reported in Table St. Louis Revho, vol. 7’2 (November/December 1990), 1 of Friedman and Schwartz (1970). The money pp. 47-58. series for 19.59 to 1991 is the M’Z series reported Kendrick, John W. Productivity Trends in the United States. in Table 1.2 1 of the Federal Reserve BaDetin, Board New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1961. of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Lupoletti, William M. and Roy H. Webb. “Defining and Im- proving the Accuracy of Macroeconomic Forecasts: Con- Price Deflutor: The implicit price deflator for GNP tributions from a VAR Model,” JoumaL ofBusiness, vol. 59 is from Table 7.4 of the Sur~q of &rent Business, (April 1986), pp. 263-85. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic McCallum, Bennett T. “A Reconsideration of Sims’ Evidence Analysis. Concerning Monetarism,” Economics Letters, vol. 13 (1986), pp. 167-71.

Gross National Product: Nominal figures for GNP Sims, Christopher A. “Macroeconomics and Reality,” Econo- are taken from Table 1.1 of the Su~ey of Current metrica, vol. 48 (January 1980), pp. l-48. Business, Department of Commerce, Bureau of . “Comparison of Interwar and Postwar Business Economic Analysis. Nominal GNP was deflated to Cycles: Monetarism Reconsidered,” American Economic real terms using the implicit price deflator for GNP. Review, vol. 70 (May 1980), pp. 250-57. . “Are Forecasting Models Usable for Policy Nondefense Nondefense Government Spending: Analysis?” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quar&&y spending is government purchases of goods and Review, vol. 10 (Winter 1986), pp. 2-16. services from Table 1.1 of The Nationa/ Income and Stock, James H. and Mark W. Watson. “Interpreting the (Department of Commerce, Bureau Pmduct Accounts Evidence on Money-Income Causality,” Journal of Econo- of Economic Analysis), less the defense spending metiks, vol. 40 (January 1989), pp. 161-81. series described above. Wynne, Mark A. “The Long-Run Effects of a Permanent Change in Defense Purchases,” Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Economic Rewiew, January 1991, pp. 1-16. . “The Analysis of Fiscal Policy in Neoclassical Models.” Research Paper No. 9212. Dallas: Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, Research Department, August 1992.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND 11 A Simple Model of Irving Fisher’s Price-Level Stabilization Rule

Thomas M. Hump/lrey

which would establish .the money stock at a fixed level when output’s growth rate is zero, is perhaps-. It is now well understood that a price-level stabihza- the best known example of this type of rule. The tion policy is more ambitious than a zero-inflation second includes activist feedback rules which dic- policy. Targeting zero inflation means that the cen- tate predetermined corrective responses of the- ‘tral bank brings inflation to a halt but leaves the price money supply and/or central-bank interest rates to level where it is at the end of the inflation. By con- price deviations from target. The proposals of David trast, targeting stable prices means that the central Ricardo, Knut Wicksell, and Irving Fisher exemplify bank ends inflation and also rolls back prices to this type of rule. Given England’s 18 10 regime of some fixed target level. By reversing inflated prices inconvertible paper and floating exchange and restoring them to their preexisting level, a price- rates, Ricardo (18 10) advocated lock-step money- stabilization policy eradicates the upward drift of stock contraction in proportion to price-level’ in- prices that can occur under a zero-inflation policy. creases as proxied by exchangerate depreciation and: It follows that a stable-price policy is more stringent the premium (excess of market price over mint price) than a zero-inflation policy. on gold. Wicksell (1898, p. 198) proposed an The history of monetary thought abounds with interest-rate feedback rule: raise the bank interest- price-level (as opposed to inflation-rate) stabilization rate when prices are rising, lower it when prices are. rules. Not all of these policy rules. were sound; falling, and keep it steady when prices are neither some would have destabilized prices rather than rising nor falling. Fisher suggested not one rule but stabilizing them. Notoriously flawed was ’s two. His 1920 compensated dolcOrplan called for the 1705 proposal to back the quantity of money dollar policymakers to adjust the gold weight of the dollar for dollar with theLnominal value of land. His rule equiproportionally to changes in the preceding guaranteed that changes in the price of land would month’s ‘general price index. In essence, he posited’ induce equiproportional changes in the money stock. the relationship: dollar price of goods = dollar price Equally flawed was the celebrated feat bills doimine of gold x gold price of goods. Official adjustments. advanced by the antibullionist writers during the Bank in the dollar price of gold, he thought, would offset Restriction period of the Napoleonic’ Wars. It tied fluctuations in the world gold price of goods (as money’s issue to the “needs of trade” as represented proxied by the preceding month’s general price by the nominal quantity of commercial bills presented index), thus stabilizing the dollar price of goods. to banks as collateral. It failed to note that since His second rule (1935) was more conventional. Much the nominal volume of bills supplied (or like stabilization rules proposed today, it dictated demanded) varies directly with general prices, accom- automatic variations in the money stock to correct modating the former with meant price-level deviations from target. accommodating prices as well. Seen by their pro- ponents as price-stabilizing, both rules in fact would This article examines Fisher’s second policy rule, have expanded or contracted the money supply in particularly its dynamic properties. Fisher himself response to shock-induced price-level changes, thus failed to investigate these properties. He provided underwriting or validating those changes (see Mints, no analytical model in support of his rule. Such a 1945, pp. 30, 47-48). model is needed to show (1) that the rule would indeed force prices to converge to target, (2) how Ruling out such inherently fallacious schemes fast they would converge, and (3) whether the leaves the remaining valid ones. These fall into two resulting path is oscillatory or monotonic. Lastly, only categories. The first consists of non-activist policy the model can demonstrate rigorously whether rules that fix the money stock or its rate of change Fisher’s rule is capable of outperforming rival rules at a constant level. Milton Friedman’s k-percent rule, such as the constant money-stock rule.

12 ECONOMIC REVIEW, NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1992 The following paragraphs attempt to provide the He reasoned that price movements stem from missing model underlying Fisher’s scheme. In so excess money supplies or demands. Since money is doing, they contribute three to the employed for spending, these excess supplies spill stabilization literature. First, they express Fisher’s, over into the in the form of scheme in equations, something not done before. excess aggregate demand for goods, thus putting They represent his proposal in the form of price- upward pressure on prices. Prices continue to rise change equations and policy-reaction functions sug- until the surplus money is absorbed by higher gested by A. W. Phillips’ (1954, 1957) classic work balances needed to purchase the same real output on closed-loop feedback control mechanisms. at elevated prices. Likewise, excess money demands, manifested in increased hoarding and decreased Second, they thus extend Phillips’ analysis to spending, cause aggregate demand contractions and encompass monetary models of price-level stabiliza- downward pressure on prices in the goods market. tion. Heretofore, Phillips’ work has been applied Prices and the associated need for transaction exclusively to the design of output-stabilizing fiscal balances continue to fall until money demand equals rules in Keynesian multiplier-accelerator models. money supply. In either case, appropriate variations (See the texts of Allen, 1959, 1967; Meade, 1972; of the money stock could, Fisher thought, correct Nagatani, 1981; and Turnovsky, 1977, for ex- the resulting price-level deviations from target. In amples.) In finding a new use for Phillips’ work, other words, the Federal Reserve expands the money the article incorporates his notions of proportional, stock when prices fall below target and the , and integral control into Fisher’s policy- money stock when prices rise above target. Clearly, response functions. The result is to show how money constitutes the policy instrument and the price the money stock in Fisher’s scheme can be pro- level the goal variable in Fisher’s scheme. grammed to respond’ automatically (1) to the dis- crepancy between actual and target prices, (2) to A policy instrument of course is only as good as the speed with which that discrepancy is rising or the Fed’s ability to’ control it. In Fisher’s view this falling, and (3) to the cumulative value of the ability was absolute-or at least it could be ,made so discrepancy over time beginning with the inaugu- by the 100 percent reserve regime advocated in his ration of his scheme. book. As he saw it, the Fed exercises direct control over the high-powered monetary.base. And since a Last but not least, the article compares within a 100 percent reserve regime renders the base and the single model the relative performance of Fisher’s money stock one and the same aggregate, it follows activist feedback rule with that of a non-activist that tight command of the one constitutes perfect constant money-stock rule. Policymakers of course regulation of the other. In sum, when deposit money must be convinced that Fisher’s rule dominates rival is backed dollar for dollar with as candidate rules before they would consider adopting prescribed in his book, there can be no in it. A related issue concerns the doctrinal accuracy money-stock control to disqualify money as the policy of the model. To ensure that the model faithfully instrument. For that matter, little slippage would captures Fisher’s thinking, one must outline his occur in a fractional reserve system or even a system scheme to determine the appropriate variables and of no reserve requirements as long as deposit money equations to use. bore a stable relationship to high-powered money. Nor did Fisher see policy lags as a problem. FISHER'SSCHEME He knew that his rule to be effective required two things: prompt direct response of prices to money Fisher presented his proposal in his 1935 book and equally prompt feedback response of money to 200% Money. He argued that the monetary authorities prices. He was sanguine about both, although less could stabilize prices at a fixed target level via open so about the former. In Stabilizing the Dolfar (1920), market operations. he stated that prices seem to follow money with “a If money became scarce, as shown by a tendency of the lag of one to three months” (p. 29). As for money’s price level to fall, more could be supplied instantly; and if corrective response to price misbehavior, he found superabundant, some could be withdrawn with equal virtually no lag at all. Money, he insisted, can be “sup- promptness. . . . The money management would’ thus plied instantly” or “withdrawn with equal promptness” consist . . of buying [government securities] whenever the price level threatened to fall below the stipulated par in reaction to price deviations from target. His and selling whenever it threatened to rise above that par. scheme admits of no significant delays to retard the (P. 97) Fed from achieving its desired target setting of the

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND 13 money stock. Such setting occurs immediately. PROPORTIONAL, DERIVATIVE, AND Accordingly, the model below omits all policy lags. INTEGRAL POLICY On this point he was quite clear. Price Gap (P-P4 / He was not so clear on other matters, however. For example, he did not specify the exact price + indicator to which the Fed should react. Should it adjust the money stock in response to the differen- tial between actual and target prices? To changes in ime that differential? To both? Suppose it has missed the target in every period since it initiated its policy. Should it forgive these past misses? Or should it allow them to influence current policy by linking the money Proportional policy contracts the money stock in proportion to the stock to the cumulative sum of the past price errors? price gap t,a. Derivative policy contracts the money stock in pro- Which price indicator and associated policy response portion to the rate of price rise as indicated by the slope of the tangent to the curve at point a. Integral policy contracts the money stock in yields the smoothest and quickest path to price proportion to the cumulative value of the price gap over time as stability? Fisher did not say. Moreover, as noted indicated by the shaded area under the curve. above, he offered no proof that his feedback rule could in fact deliver price stability or that it would outperform other candidate rules. propoftion to the shaded area under the curve up to time t,. In short, proportional policy focuses on MODELINGFISHER'SSCHEME current price gaps, derivative policy on the direction of movement of such gaps, and integral policy on the Addressing these issues requires an explicit sum of all gaps, past and present. Once applied, each analytical framework. The one supplied here employs policy produces a different policy-corrected path for the four-step technique pioneered by A. W. Phillips prices;- (1954, 1957) in his celebrated analysis of stabiliza- tion policy. Step three solves the model for these alternative policy;corrected paths. Step four uses a loss func- Step one models how the price level would behave tion to measure the cost (in terms of reputational if uncorrected by policy. Consistent with Fisher’s damage suffered by the Fed when prices deviate from exposition, the model treats prices as moving in target) of adhering to each path. This procedure response to excess money supplies and demands. allows, one to rank the alternative policy rules ac- cording to how smoothly and quickly they stabilize Step two incorporates policy-response functions prices. As shown below, at least one of the feedback embodying elements of and pmpotiional, derivative, rules dominates the fixed money-stock rule. integralcorm& A proportional feedback control rule adjusts the money stock in response to current price PRICE-CHANGE EQUATION deviations from target. Derivative control adjusts money in response to the deviation’s rate of change. The first step is to model the non-policy deter- Integral control adjusts money in response to the minants of price-level behavior. To Fisher, price cumulative sum of deviations over time. It seeks to changes emanated from excess money supplies and correct the time integral of all past misses from target. demands caused, say, by policy mistakes and/or For example, suppose prices since the inauguration shifts in the amount of money people want to hold of corrective policy have fluctuated about target. Or, at existing prices and real incomes. In his words, what is the same thing, the discrepancy between prices fall when money is “scarce” relative to the actual and target prices p -p, has fluctuated about demand for it and rise when money is “superabun- zero, as shown in the figure. The application of pro- dant” relative to demand. Accordingly, one seeks the portional policy at time t, requires money-stock simplest equation that captures his hypothesis. contraction in proportion to the price gap t,a. Derivative’policy contracts the money stock by a That equation is fi =cr(m -kpq), where the time fixed proportion of the rate of price rise indicated derivativei denotes a change in prices, m denotes by the slope of the tangent to the curve at time t,. the money supply, the product kpq denotes money Finally, integral policy aimed at correcting cumulative demand consisting of velocity’s inverse or the Cam- deviations from target contracts the money stock in bridge R times the price levelp times real output q,

14 ECONOMIC REVIEW. NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1992 and CYis a positive goods-market reaction coefficient else. Thus the money-stock equation is simply expressing the speed of response of prices to excess m, =mT, where m, denotes constant money-stock money supply. ’ Let the model’s time unit be a policy. calendar quarter. Define T=Z/CY as the number of quarters required for prices to adjust to clear the Activist feedback rules attempt to improve upon market for money balances. Then Fisher’s 1920 the constant money-stock rule. Thus under a pm- finding that prices follow money with a lag of close portiona/jedback rub the Fed adjusts the money stock to three months implies that both Q and T are above or below the desired long-run equilibrium level approximately equal to unity in magnitude. As for mT as prices are below or above their target level. the other items in the equation, output q and the In other words, the money stock is set to counter Cambridge k are taken as given constants at their price gaps or deviations from target. The resulting long-run equilibrium values. In his 1935 book, Fisher policy-response equation is m, =mT -fl@ -PT), where mentioned no other money-demand determinants m, denotes proportional policy and /3 is the propor- such as interest rates or price-change expectations. tional correction coefficient. For that reason they are omitted here.2 With a derivative feedback nde the Fed adjusts the money stock in response to the speed with which POLICYRULES the price gapp -pT is increasing or decreasing in size. The next step is to specify the alternative policy- Or, what is the same thing (since the target price response functions the Fed might use to bring prices levelp, is fixed), it adjusts the money stock above to target in the model. These functions are absolutely or below money’s long-run equilibrium level to essential. Without them, prices p would adjust in counter falls or rises in the price level d. The response to an excess money supply until they resulting policy-response equation is ?&=mT-+, reached an equilibrium level p =m/kq different from where m, denotes derivative policy and y is the the target levelp=. Permanent price gaps would result. derivative correction coefficient.

Under a constant money-stock G&J the Fed merely With an integralfeedback mle the Fed adjusts the sets the money stock at the level mT=kGT that money stock to correct cumulative price gaps or the equilibrates money supply and demand at the target sum of all past policy misses over time. The Fed price level pT and then leaves it there. Other than learns from these price errors. It uses the informa- setting mT consistent with &-, the Fed does nothing tion given by their integral to determine the current setting of the money stock. Accordingly, the policy I This equation admits of a straightforward derivation. Define an excess supply of money x as the surplus of money m over equation iS ??Zi=mT - 6 i (p -pT)dt, where mi denotes the demand for it Rpq,or x=m -Rpq. Assume this excess money t 0 supply spills over into the commodity market to underwrite an integral policy, 5 ( )dt denotes the integral oper- excess demand for goods g. In short, x =g. The excess demand 0 for goods in turn puts upward pressure on prices, which rise in ator, and 6 is the integral correction coefficient. proportion to the excess demand, or b=czg, where CYis the factor of proportionality. Substitution of x for g and m -Rpq for This rule can be given an alternative expression. x yields the equation of the text. When differentiated to get rid of the integral, it * It is tempting to write Fisher’s equation in expectations- becomes 7iz= -6(p -pT), stating that the Fed sets augmented form as d = c&z - (kpq- @)I where the term - rb the money stock’s rate of c/zange opposite to the captures the effect of price-change expectations B’ on money direction that prices are currently deviating from demand. This term says that people expecting money tb deoreciate in value will hold smaller cash balances than thev target. w&Id if they expected no such depreciation. One could furthe; assume that people form their expectations rationally such that Finally, the Fed may employ a mixedfeedback nde expected price changes equal actual ones @=@ in this non- involving various combinations of the foregoing equa- stochastic model and the equation reduces to D =/ol/ff -UT)/ (m-&q). But such an equation would be inionsistent with tions. For example, a mixed proportional-derivative Fisher’s own views on the subject. True, in his The Pudzasing rule would the policy-response function PowerofMorzq (191 l), he recognized that inflation perceptions 111,=mT - p(p -PT) -rb embodying gap and gap- affect money demand. When money “is depreciating,” he wrote, “holders will eet rid of it as fast as oossible” (D. 63). But he did change terms together with their policy correction not spell out Low such perceptions are formgd or how they get coefficients. incorporated into money demand functions. Nor did he believe in rational expectations. He held that people are subject to money illusion and so revise their expectations slowly in the face of PRICETIMEPATHSANDLOSSFUNCTTIONS actual price changes such that when those changes occur expec- tations lag behind. Indeed, he coined the phrase “money illu- The third step is to substitute each of the fore- sion” and used it as the title of his 1928 book. going policy rules into the Fisherian price-change

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND 1.5 equationb =cr(m -kpq). Doing so produces expres- assuming the proportional correction coefficient fl= 2 sions whose solutions are the policy-corrected time and the constants CY,k, q, pO, and pT possess their paths of prices. values as assigned above. This loss compares favorably with the corresponding loss of l/100 Thus substitution of the constant money-stock rule associated with the constant money-stock rule. Given into the price-change equation yields d = c&q@, -p). a choice between the two rules, the Fed will select Solving this first-order expression for the time path the proportional rule. of prices gives p =pT + @jO-p# ‘, where p, denotes the (perturbed) price level at time t=O, t denotes A word of warning is in order here. The propor- time, e is the base of the natural logarithm system, tional rule’s superiority rests heavily on Fisher’s and the parameter a =akq denotes speed of con- assumption of no policy lags. By slowing convergence vergence to target. This expression says that prices to target, policy lags could reverse the ranking of the converge to target at a rate of a = c&q per unit of time. two rules. Such lags would delay the Fed’s adjust- In short, as time passes and t gets large, the last term ment m of the money stock m to its desired propor- on the right-hand side of the equation goes to zero tional setting m,. A new equation ~~==X(VZ*-m), so that only the first term pT remains. In this way where the positive coefficient X represents the policy the path to price stability terminates when p =pT. lag, would have to be added to the model. The resulting reduced-form expression for 5 would be a Associated with the path are certain costs to the second-order differential equation whose solution- Fed. The Fed’s objective is to keep prices as close the time path of prices-would be more,complicated to target as possible over time. Society penalizes than before. Overshooting and oscillations would it for failing to do so. It suffers losses in reputation, be a distinct possibility; slower convergence a cer- credibility, and prestige that vary directly and dis- tainty. These considerations highlight the importance proportionally with the duration and size of its of Fisher’s assumption of zero policy lags. Embodied policy errors. These losses can be measured by in the model, his assumption ensures the superior- the quadratic cost function expressing the Fed’s ity of the proportional rule such that the Fed will reputational loss L as the cumulative squared devi- select it. ation of prices from their desired target level, or OPTIMALVALUEOFTHE~~ COEFFICIENT L = r(p -p#dt. Substituting the price path into this Given the proportional rule’s capability of out- loss Function and integrating yields the cost of adher- performing the constant money-stock rule, a natural ing to the non-activist constant money-stock rule, question to ask next is whether the proportional or L, = (p,-p#/Za. As a hypothetical numerical ex- correction coefficient /3 has been assigned its optimal ample, let pT = I, p, = 2, c~= I, k = Z/Z, .q = ZOO, and value. The preceding numerical example assumed a = 50. Then the quantitative measure of the loss is p = 2. But a glance at the proportional rule’s loss L, = z/zoo. measure L,, = (p,-p#/Zcx(kq+@) suggests that the Fed should make /3 as large as possible (@- 00) and EFFECTIVENESSOFTHEACTIVIST negligibly small. That is, optimality considerations PROPORTIONALRULE Lp would seem to compel instantaneous monetary con- To compare the foregoing loss with those of the traction in amounts sufficient to force prices to target activist feedback policy rules, one must derive the immediately. price paths and loss measures associated with the latter rules. Thus the proportional feedback rule Fisher, however, would have rejected this implica- yields the price path p =pT + (pO-pT)emb ’ with asso- tion of the mathematical formulation of his scheme. ciated loss measure L,= (p,-p#/Zb. Here b= He would have condemned the violent monetary cy(kq + fi) is the speed-of-convergence parameter. contraction implied by high values of 0. To him such Since parameter b is larger than parameter a com- contraction spelled devastating losses to output and puted above, prices under the proportional rule employment. In his The Purchasing Power tf Money converge to target faster than they do under the (1911) and his 1926 paper on price changes and constant money-stock rule. It follows that prices unemployment, he ascribed these losses to the failure deviate from target for a shorter time under the of sticky nominal wage and interest rates to respond proportional rule. Consequently that rule yields the as fast as product prices to monetary shocks. He smallest loss of the two and thus dominates the con- attributed nominal wage rigidities to fixed contracts stant money-stock rule. Numerically, L, = Z/202, and the inertia of custom; nominal interest rate

16 ECONOMIC REVIEW, NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1992 rigidities to price misperceptions and sluggishly Integral policy in this case would push the price adjusting inflation expectations. Because of these level below target. And if the same past misses were inhibiting forces, a sharp fall in money and prices exactly counterbalanced by a current miss of -5, would transform sticky nominal wage and interest integral policy would fail at that moment to put rates into rising real rates, thus depressing economic corrective pressure on prices. Of course continu- activity. In his 1933 debt-deflation theory of great ation of the current miss would eventually activate depressions, he cited still another reason to fear corrective pressure. But this pressure would be slow violent monetary contraction. He argued that price in coming. Thus while stabilizing prices in the long deflation could, by raising the real burden of nominal run, integral policy might do so sluggishly and via debt, precipitate a wave of business with damped oscillatory paths. all its adverse repercussions for the real economy. To avoid these consequences, Fisher would have Integral policy yields the time path p =pT +A, 8’ recommended relatively gradual monetary contrac- +A,@‘. Here A,, A, are constants of integration tion implied by moderate values of /3 (such as fl= 2). determined by initial conditions. And r,, r, = Consistent with his views, p’s value here is restricted (- crkq/Z) f J(cxkq)‘- 4&/Z are the characteristic to unity. roots of the left-hand or homogeneous part of the second-order expression 5 + (c&q)j + crhp = c&5pT,ob- RELATIVEEFFECHVENESSOFTHE tained by differentiating the Fed’s policy-reaction DERIVATIVERULE function to eliminate the integral and substituting the As for the other candidate rules, the Fed will result into the Fisherian price-change equation. The reject as inferior to proportional policy the derivative roots r,, r, possess negative real parts (-c&/Z) thus rule. That rule calls for money-stock adjustments ensuring convergence. Damped oscillations about target opposite to the direction prices are moving. It occur if (cxkqf<4c& or, in other words, if the inte- exerts stabilizing pressure when prices are moving gral correction coefficient 6 is larger than olR*q*/4. away from target; less so when they are moving Monotonic convergence results from smaller values toward target. When prices fall toward target, the of that coefficient. But convergence, whether cyclical derivative rule interferes perversely by expanding or monotonic, is slower under the integral rule than the money stock. In so doing, it retards convergence under the proportional and constant money-stock and becomes a relatively unattractive . In sym- rules. The above-mentioned characteristic roots re- bols, derivative policy results in the price path p = veal as much. Dwarfed by the speed-of-convergence p, + (pO-pT)emCr and loss function L, = (Pa-p#/Zc, parameters of the other rules, their relatively small with speed of convergence denoted by the parameter size renders the integral rule inferior to its rivals. c=cxkql(Z +cry). This parameter is smaller than its Confirmation comes from the loss function, which counterparts a and b, signifying slower convergence shows a large reputational loss associated with the and larger reputation loss with a derivative rule than integral rule. One computes the integral policy’s loss with a constant or proportional rule. Numerically, the function as Li = - /A,Z/ZrJ - /ZA, A, l(r, + rJ/ derivative rule’s loss is L,, =2/50, assuming the - lA,zIZrJ, where A, = /‘$, - r&, -pT) jl(rl -r-J and derivative correction coefficient y is assigned a value A,=lr,(p,-pT) -fiJl(r, -rJ. Although hard to of one and the other constants possess the same evaluate analytically, this function yields to numer- magnitudes as defined above. This loss is twice that ical computation. Let cr = 6 =pT = I, j, = - I, p. = 2, of the constant money-stock rule and more than twice k = Z/Z, and q = ZOOas before. Then the function in that of the proportional rule. The Fed, therefore, this hypothetical illustrative example produces a would hardly opt for a derivative rule. numerical value of 26, several hundred times the RELATIVEEFFECIWENESSOFTHE losses under the other rules. INTEGRALRULE RELATIVEEFFECTIVENESSOFA Nor would the Fed opt for an integral rule that MIXEDRULE seeks to correct the sum of all past and present misses of target. The past misses would continue to influence Finally, the Fed might try a mixed rule embody- policy even when the current price level was close ing proportional and derivative elements. The to target. Too strong a response to them would cause mixed rule yields the price path p =p, + (p, -pT)emdt overshooting. Conversely, too weak a response would and associated loss function L, = (PO-pJ ’/Zd, cause prices to move too slowly to target. Suppose where the speed-of-convergence parameter d= past misses totaled 5 when the current miss was 0. cx(fl+kq)l(Z +cry). With the coefficient values as

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND 17 assigned above, the loss L, is 21102, ranking the that converge to target, albeit at different speeds. mixed rule inferior to the proportional and constant Proportional policy yields the quickest and smoothest money-stock rules, but superior to the derivative and path, followed by mixed, derivative, and integral integral rules. This ranking, however, depends on policies in that order. Of these four activist feedback the values assigned to the coefficients. Giving y a rules, only the proportional always outperforms the value of l/52 instead of 1 would reverse the order nonactivist constant money-stock rule. For this of the mixed and constant money-stock rules. In reason, proportional policy’s loss measure is the general, the mixed rule ranks below the constant smallest of the lot. Indeed, one can rank the loss money-stock rule if y >/3/&q and above it if that measures to show that the proportional feedback rule inequality is reversed. dominates the constant money-stock rule, which in turn dominates the derivative and integral rules. CONCLUSION While the mixed rule may, at certain values of the y coefficient, outrank the constant money-stock Fisher’s feedback policy rule delivers price stability rule, it can never dominate the proportional rule. in the simple money-demand-and-supply model Provided policy lags are short or nonexistent, these presented here. And it does so whether the rule is results create a presumption in favor of a proportional expressed in terms of proportional, derivative, feedback rule. integral, or mixed control. All the rules yield paths

REFERENCES

Alien, R. G. D. Mathematical Economics. London: Macmillan, Meade, J. E. The ContmIed Economy. Albany: State University 1959. of New York Press, 1972.

Macmeconomic Theory: A Mathematics/ Treatment. Mints, Lloyd W. A History of Bank-ing Theory. Chicago: London:‘Macmillan, 1967. University of Chicago Press, 1945.

Fisher, Irving. The Pa~hasing Power of Money. New York: Nagatani, Keizo. Macmeconomic Dynamics. Cambridge: Cam- Macmillan, 1911. New and revised edition, 1913. Re- bridge University Press, 1981. printed New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1963. Phillips, A. W. “Stabilisation Policy in a Closed Economy,” Stabiking the Dolar. New York: Macmillan, vol. 64 (June 1954), pp. 290-323. 1920. . Economic Joamal, “A Statistical Relation between Unemployment “Stabilisation Policy and the Time-Forms of and Price Changes,” International Loboar Review, vol. 13 Lagged Responses,” EconomicJoumaC, vol. 67 dune 1957), (June 1926), pp. 78592. Reprinted as “I Discovered the pp. 265-77. Phillips Curve,” Journal of PoLitical Economy, vol. 81 (March/April 1973), pp. 496-502. Ricardo, David. The High Price of BaLion, A Pmof of the Depreciation of Banknot&, 1810. In P. Sraffa and M. Dobb, . The Money Ik’usion. New York: Adelphi, 1928. eds . , Th Wok and Correspondence ofDa&d Ricardo, vol. II I. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 195 1. “The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depres- sions,” Econometrica, vol. 1 (1933), pp. 337-57. Turnovsky, Stephen J. Macmeconomic Analysis and Stabilization Pokies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1977. . 200% Money. New York: Adelphi, 1935.

Friedman, Milton. A Pmgram for Monetary Stabikty. New York: Wicksell, Knut. Znterzst and Prices, 1898. Translated by R. F. Fordham University Press, 1959. Kahn, London: Macmillan, 1936. Reprinted New York: A. M. Kelley, 1965. Law, John. Money and Trade Considered: With a Proposal for Sapplying the Nation With Money, 1705. Reprinted New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1966.

18 ECONOMIC REVIEW. NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1992 Futures

Anatoh Kuptianov ’

INTRODUCTION spot market prices follows. The concluding section examines the economic function of futures markets. Money market futures are futures contracts based on short-term interest rates. Futures contracts for financial instruments are a relatively recent innova- tion. Although futures markets have existed over 100 Futures Contracts years in the United States, futures trading was limited Futures contracts traditionally have been charac- to contracts for agricultural and other commodities terized as exchange-traded, standardized agreements before 1972. The introduction of foreign currency to buy or sell some underlying item on a specified futures that year by the newly formed International future date. For example, the buyer of a Treasury Monetary Market (IMM) division of the Chicago bill futures -who is said to take on a “long” Mercantile Exchange (CME) marked the advent of futures -commits to purchase a 13-week trading in financial futures. Three years later the first Treasury bill with a face value of $1 million on some based on interest rates, a contract specified future date at a price negotiated at the time for the future delivery of mortgage certificates issued of the futures transaction; the seller-who is said to by the Government National Mortgage Association take on a “short” position-agrees to deliver the (GNMA), began trading on the floor of the Chicago specified bill in accordance with the terms of the con- Board of Trade (CBT). A host of new financial futures tract. In contrast, a “cash” or “spot” market trans- have appeared since then, ranging from contracts on action simultaneously prices and transfers physical money market instruments to stock index futures. ownership of the item being sold. Today, financial futures rank among the most actively traded of all futures contracts. The advent of cash-settled futures contracts such as Eurodollar futures has rendered this traditional Four different futures contracts based on money definition overly restrictive, however, because actual market interest rates are actively traded at present. delivery never takes place with cash-settled contracts. To date, the IMM has been the site of the most Instead, the buyer and seller exchange payments active trading in money market futures. The three- based on changes in the price of a specified under- month U.S. Treasury bill contract, introduced by the lying item or the returns to an underlying security. IMM in 1976, was the first futures contract based For example, parties to an IMM Eurodollar contract on short-term interest rates. Three-month Eurodollar exchange payments based on changes in market time deposit futures, now one of the most actively interest rates for three-month Eurodollar deposits- traded of all futures contracts, started trading in 198 1. the underlying deposits are neither “bought” nor More recently, both the CBT and the IMM intro- “sold” on the contract maturity date. A more general duced futures contracts based on one-month interest definition of a futures contract, therefore, is a rates. The CBT listed its 30-day interest rate futures standardized, transferable agreement that provides contract in 1989, while the Chicago Mercantile for the exchange of cash flows based on changes in Exchange introduced a one-month LIBOR futures the market price of some commodity or returns to contract in 1990. a specified security.

This article provides an introduction to money Futures contracts trade on organized exchanges market futures. It begins with a general description that determine standardized specifications for traded of the organization of futures markets. The next contracts. All futures contracts for a given item specify section describes currently traded money market the same delivery requirements and one of a limited futures contracts in some detail. A discussion of the number of designated contract maturity dates, called relationship between futures prices and underlying dates. Each futures exchange has an affiliated clearinghouse that records all transactions * This paper has benefited from helpful comments by Timothy and ensures that all buy and sell trades match. The Cook, Ira Kawaller, Jeffrey Lacker, and Robert LaRoche. organization also assures the financial

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND 19 integrity of contracts traded on the exchange by Moreover, forward contracts are not traded on guaranteeing contract performance and supervising organized exchanges as are futures contracts and the process of delivery for contracts held to ma- carry no independent clearinghouse guarantee. As a turity. A futures clearinghouse guarantees contract result, a party to a faces the risk performance by interposing itself between a buyer of nonperformance by the other party. For this and seller, assuming the role of counterparty to the reason, forward contracting generally takes place contract for both parties. As a result, the original among parties that have some knowledge of each parties to the contract need never deal with one other’s creditworthiness. Unlike futures contracts, another again-their contractual obligations are with which can be bought or sold at any time before the clearinghouse. maturity to liquidate an open futures position, for- Contract standardization and the clearinghouse ward agreements, as a general rule, are not guarantee facilitate trading in futures contracts. transferable and so cannot be sold to a third party. Contract standardization reduces transactions costs, Consequently, most forward contracts are held to since it obviates the need to negotiate all the terms maturity. of a contract with every transaction-the only item negotiated at the time of a futures transaction is the Futures Exchanges futures price. The clearinghouse guarantee relieves In addition to providing a physical facility where traders of the risk that the other party to the con- trading takes place, a futures exchange determines tract will fail to honor contractual commitments. the specifications of traded contracts and regulates These two characteristics make all contracts for the same item and maturity date perfect substitutes for trading practices. There are 13 futures exchanges in one another. Consequently, a party to a futures con- the United States at present. The principal exchanges tract can always liquidate a futures commitment, or are in Chicago and New York. open position, before maturity through an offsetting transaction. For example, a long position in Treasury Each futures exchange is a corporate entity bill futures can be liquidated by selling a contract for owned by its members. The right to conduct trans- the same maturity date. The clearinghouse assumes actions on the floor of a futures exchange is limited responsibility for collecting funds from traders who to exchange members, although trading privileges can close out their positions at a loss and passes those be leased to nonmembers. Members have voting funds along to traders with opposing futures positions rights that give them a voice in the management of who liquidate their positions at a profit. Once any the exchange. Memberships, or “seats,” can be gains or losses are settled, the offsetting sale cancels bought and sold: futures exchanges routinely make the commitment created through the earlier purchase public the most recent selling and current offer price of the contract. Most futures contracts are liquidated for a seat on the exchange. in this manner before they mature. In recent years less than 1 percent of all futures contracts have been Trading takes place in designated areas, known as held to maturity, although delivery is more common “pits,” on the floor of the futures exchange through in some markets.’ a system of open outcry in which traders announce bids to buy and offers to sell contracts. Traders on Forward agreements resemble futures contracts the floor of the exchange can be grouped into two in that they specify the terms of a transaction to be broad categories: floor brokers and floor traders. undertaken at some future date. For this reason, the Floor brokers, also known as commission brokers, terms “forward agreement” and “futures contract” are often used synonymously. There are important execute orders for off-exchange customers and other differences between the two, however. Whereas members. Some floor brokers are employees of futures contracts are standardized agreements, for- commission firms, known as Futures Commission ward agreements tend to be custom-tailored to the Merchants, while others are independent operators needs of users. While a good deal of contract stan- who contract to execute trades for brokerage firms. dardization exists in forward markets, items such as Floor traders are independent operators who engage delivery dates, deliverable grades, and amounts can in speculative trades for their own account. Floor all be negotiated separately with each contract. traders can be grouped into different classifications according to their trading strategies. “Scalpers,” for example, are floor traders who perform the function I Based on data from the AnnualReport 1991 of the Commodity Futures Trading Commission. of marketmakers in futures exchanges. They supply

20 ECONOMIC REVIEW, NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1992 liquidity to futures markets by standing ready to buy Requirements or sell in an attempt to profit from small temporary Margin deposits on futures contracts are often price movements.2 mistakenly compared to stock margins. Despite the similarity in terminology, however, futures margins Futures Commission Merchants differ fundamentally from stock margins. Stock A Futures Commission Merchant (FCM) handles margin refers to a down payment on the purchase orders to buy or sell futures contracts from off- of an equity security on , and so represents exchange customers. All FCMs must be licensed by funds surrendered to gain physical possession of a the Commodity Futures Trading Commission security. In contrast, a margin deposit on a futures (CFTC), which is the government agency respon- contract is a performance posted to ensure that sible for regulating futures markets. An FCM can be traders honor their contractual obligations, and not a person or a firm. Some FCMs are exchange a down payment on a credit transaction. The value members employing their own floor brokers. FCMs of a futures contract is zero to both the buyer and that are not exchange members must make arrange- the seller at the time it is negotiated, so a futures ments with a member to execute customer orders transaction involves no exchange of money at the on their behalf. outset. The practice of collecting margin deposits dates Role of the Exchange Clearinghouse back to the early days of trading in time contracts, As noted earlier, each futures exchange has an as the precursors of futures contracts were then affiliated exchange clearinghouse whose purpose is called. Before the institution of margin requirements, to match and record all trades and to guarantee con- traders adversely affected by price movements fre- tract performance. In most cases the exchange quently defaulted on their contractual obligations, clearinghouse is an independently incorporated often simply disappearing as the delivery date on their organization, but it can also be a department of the contracts drew near. In response to these events, exchange. The Board of Trade Clearing , futures exchanges instituted a system of margin the CBT’s clearinghouse, is a separate corporation requirements, and also began requiring traders to affiliated with the exchange, while the CME Clear- recognize any gains or losses on their outstanding ing House Division is a department of the exchange. futures commitments at the end of each trading session through a daily settlement procedure known Clearing member firms act as intermediaries be- as “marking to market.” tween traders on the floor of the exchange and the clearinghouse. They assist in recording transactions Before being permitted to undertake a futures and assume responsibility for contract performance transaction, a buyer or seller must first post margin on the part of floor traders and commission merchants with a broker, who, in turn, must post margin with who are their customers. Although clearing member a clearing agent. Margin may be posted either by firms are all members of the exchange, not all ex- depositing cash with a broker or, in the case of large change members are clearing members. All trans- institutional traders, by pledging collateral in the form actions taking place on the floor of the exchange must of marketable securities (typically, Treasury securi- be settled through a clearing member. Brokers or ties) or by presenting a issued by a floor traders not directly affiliated with a clearing bank. Brokers sometimes pay interest on funds member must make arrangements with one to act deposited in a margin account. as a designated clearing agent. The clearinghouse As noted above, clearing member firms ulti- requires each clearing member firm to guarantee mately are liable to the clearinghouse for any losses contract performance for all of its customers. If a incurred by their customers. To assure the financial clearing member’s customer defaults on an outstand- integrity of the settlement process, clearing member ing futures commitment, the clearinghouse holds the firms must themselves meet margin requirements in clearing member responsible for any resulting losses. addition to meeting minimum capital requirements set by the exchange clearinghouse. 2 A good description of trading strategies employed by different floor traders can be found in Hieronymus (1971). In addition, Daily Settlement detailed descriptions of different trading strategies can also be found in almost any good textbook on futures markets such as The practice of marking futures contracts to market Chance (1989), Merrick (1990), or Siegel and Siegel (1990). Silber (1984) presents a comprehensive analysis of scalper trading requires all buyers and sellers to realize any gains or behavior. losses in the value of their futures positions at the

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND 21 end of each trading session, just as if every position Final Settlement were liquidated at the closing price. The exchange Because buying a futures contract about to mature clearinghouse collects payments, called variation margin, from all traders incurring a loss and transfers is equivalent to buying the underlying item in the the proceeds to those traders whose futures positions spot market, futures prices converge to the underlying have increased in value during the latest trading spot market price on the last day of trading. This session. If a trader has deposited cash in a margin phenomenon is known as “convergence.” At the end account, his broker simply subtracts his losses from of a contract’s last trading session, it is marked to the account and transfers the variation margin to the market one final time. In the case of a cash-settled clearinghouse, which, in turn, transfers the funds to contract, this final daily settlement retires all out- the account of a trader with a ‘short position in the standing contractual commitments and any remain- contract. Most brokers require their customers to ing margin money is returned to the traders. If the maintain minimum balances in their margin accounts contract specifies delivery of the underlying item, the in excess of exchange requirements. If a trader’s clearinghouse subsequently makes arrangements for margin account falls below a specified minimum, delivery among all traders with outstanding ‘futures called the maintenance margin, he faces a margin call positions. The delivery, or invoice price, is based requiring the deposit of additional margin money. In on the closing price of the last day of trading. Any cases where collateral has been posted in the form profit or loss resulting from the difference between of securities rather than in cash, the trader must pay the initial futures price and the final settlement price the variation margin in cash. Should a trader fail to meet a margin call, his broker has the right to is realized through the transfer of variation margin. liquidate his position. The trader remains liable for The gross return on the futures position is reflected any resulting. losses. in accumulated total margin payments, which must equal the difference between the final settlement Marking a futures contract to market has the price and the futures price determined at the time effect of renegotiating the futures price at the end the futures commitment was entered into. of each trading session. Once the contract is marked to market, the trader begins the next trading session with a commitment to purchase the under- Regulation of Futures Markets lying item at the previous day’s closing price. The The Commodity Futures Trading Commission is exchange clearinghouse then calculates any gains or an independent federal regulatory agency estab- losses for the next trading session on the basis of this lished in 1974 to enforce federal laws governing the latter price. operation of futures exchanges and futures commis- The following example involving the purchase of sion brokers. By law, the CFTC is charged with the a Treasury bill futures contract illustrates the responsibility to ensure that futures trading serves mechanics of the daily settlement procedure. a valuable economic purpose and to protect the in- Treasury bill futures prices are quoted as a price terests of users of futures contracts. The CFTC must index determined by subtracting the futures discount approve all futures contracts before they can be listed yield (stated in percentage points) from 100. A 1 basis for trading by the futures exchanges. It also enforces point change in the price of the Treasury bill con- laws and regulations prohibiting unfair and abusive tract is valued at $2.5.3 Thus, if a trader buys a trading and sales practices. futures contract at a price of 96.25 and the closing price at the end of the trading session falls to 96.20, The futures industry attempts to regulate itself he must pay $125 (5 basis points x $2.5 per basis through a private self-regulatory organization called point) in variation margin. Conversely, the seller in the National Futures Association, which was this transaction would earn $125, which would be formed in 1982 to establish and help enforce deposited to his margin account. The buyer would then begin the next trading session with a commit- standards of professional conduct. This organization ment to buy the underlying Treasury bill at 96.20, operates in cooperation with the CFTC to protect and any gains or losses sustained over the course of the of futures traders as well as those of the the next trading session would be based on that price. industry. As noted earlier, the futures exchanges themselves can be viewed as private regulatory bodies organized to set and enforce rules to facilitate the 3 Price quotation and contiact specifications for Treasury bill futures are discussed in more detail in the next section. trading of futures contracts.

22 ECONOMIC REVIEW. NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1992 CONTRACT SPECIFICATIONSFOR Treasury bill futures prices are quoted as an MONEYMARKETFWTURES index determined by subtracting the discount yield of the deliverable bill (expressed as a percentage) Treasury Bill Futures from 100: The Chicago Mercantile Exchange lists 13-week Index = 100 -Futures Discount Yield. Treasury bill futures contracts for delivery during the months of March, June, September, and December. Thus, a quoted index value of 95.25 implies a Contracts for eight future delivery dates are listed futures discount yield for the deliverable bill of at any one time, making the furthest delivery date 100 -95.25 = 4.75 percent. This convention was for a new contract 24 months. A new contract begins adopted so that quoted prices would vary directly trading after each delivery date. with changes in the future delivery price of the bill.

&live y Rec#rements The Treasury bill contract Final Settlement Price The final settlement price, requires the seller to deliver a U.S. Treasury bill with also known as the delivery price or invoice cost of a $1 million face value and 13 weeks to maturity. a bill, can be expressed as a function of the quoted Delivery dates for T-bill futures always fall on the futures index price using the formulas given above. three successive business days beginning with the For a bill with a face value of $1 million, the resulting first day of the contract month on which (1) the expression is Treasury issues new 13-week bills and (2) previ- ously issued 52-week bills have 13 weeks left to s = !$1,000,000 maturity.4 This schedule makes it possible to satisfy - $1,000,000(100-Zndex)(O.Ol)(Days/360), delivery requirements for a T-bill futures contract with either a newly issued 13-week bill or an original- where (loo-Index)(O.Ol) is just the annualized issue 26- or 52-week bill with 13 weeks left to ma- futures discount yield expressed as a decimal. The turity. Deliverable bills can have 90, 91, or 92 days CME determines the days to maturity used in this to maturity, depending on holidays and other special formula by counting from the first scheduled con- circumstances. The last day of trading in a Treasury tract delivery date, regardless of when actual delivery bill futures contract falls on the day before the final takes place.‘This means that calculation of the in- settlement date. voice cost is based on an assumed 9 l-day maturity, except in special cases where holidays interrupt the Price Quotation Treasury bills are discount instru- regular Treasury bill auction and delivery schedules. ments that pay no explicit interest. Instead, the interest earned on a Treasury bill is derived from the To illustrate, suppose that the final index price of fact that the bill is purchased at a discount relative a traded contract is 95.25 and the deliverable bill has to its face or redemption value. Treasury bill yields 9 1 days to maturity as of the first scheduled delivery are quoted on a discount basis-that is, as a per- date. Then, the final delivery price would be centage of the face value of the bill rather than as a percentage of actual funds invested. Let S denote $987,993.06 = $l,OOO,OOO the current spot market price of a bill with a face - $1,000,000(0.0475)(91/360). value of $1 million. Then, the discount yield is calculated as Minimum Price Fluctuation The minimum price fluctuation permitted on the trading floor is 1 basis Yiefd = [(l,OOO,OOO-S)/1,000,000](360/D& point, or 0.01 percent. Thus, the price of a Treasury bill futures contract may be quoted as 95.25 or 95.26, where Day.r refers to the maturity of the bill. As but not 95.255. The exchange values a 1 basis point with other money market rates, calculation of the change in the futures price at $25. Note that this discount yield on Treasury bills assumes a 360-day valuation assumes a 90-day maturity for the deliver- year. able bill.

Three-Month Eurodollar 4 The Treasury auctions 13- and 26-week bills each Monday (except for holidays and special situations) and issues them on Time Deposit Futures the followine Thursdav: X-week bills are auctioned everv four weeks. Auczons for o&-year bills are held on a Thursdai and Three-month Eurodollar futures are traded actively the bills are issued on the following Thursday. on three exchanges at present. The IMM was first

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND 23 to list a three-month Eurodollar time deposit futures interest paid on the face amount of such a deposit contract in December of 1981. Futures exchanges is termed an add-on yield because the depositor in London and soon followed suit by listing receives the face amount of the deposit plus an similar contracts. The London International Finan- explicit interest payment when the deposit matures. cial Futures Exchange (LIFFE) introduced its three- Like other money market rates, the add-on yield for month Eurodollar contract in September of 1982, Eurodollar deposits is expressed as an annualized rate while the Singapore International Monetary Exchange based on a 360-day year. Eurodollar futures prices (SIMEX) introduced a contract identical to the IMM are quoted as an index determined by subtracting the contract in 1984. A special arrangement between the futures add-on yield from 100. IMM and SIMEX allows for mutual offset of Eurodollar positions initiated on either exchange. Final Settlement Price Contract settlement is based Thus, a trader who buys a Eurodollar futures con- on the 90-day London Interbank Offered Rate tract at the IMM can undertake an offsetting sale on (LIBOR), which is the interest rate at which major SIMEX after the close of trading at the lMM.5 international banks with offices in London offer to The Tokyo International Financial Futures Exchange place Eurodollar deposits with one another. To deter- began listing a three-month Eurodollar contract in mine the final settlement price for its Eurodollar 1989, but that contract is not traded actively at pre- futures contract, the CME clearinghouse randomly sent. The IMM contract remains the most actively polls a sample of banks active in the London traded of the different Eurodollar contracts by a wide Eurodollar market at two different times during the margin. last day of trading: once at a randomly selected time The IMM Eurodollar contract is the first futures during the last 90 minutes of trading, and once at contract traded in the United States to rely exclu- the close of trading. The four highest and lowest price sively on a cash settlement procedure. Contract quotes from each polling are dropped and the remain- settlement is based on a “notional” principal amount ing quotes are averaged to arrive at the LIBOR of $1 million, which is used to determine the change used for final settlement. in the total interest payable on a hypothetical under- To illustrate the settlement procedure, suppose lying time deposit. The notional principal amount that the closing price of a Eurodollar futures contract itself is never actually paid or received. is 96.10 on the day before the last trading day. As months for listed contracts are March, with Treasury bill futures, each 1 basis point change June, September, and December. A maximum of 20 in the price of a Eurodollar futures contract is valued contracts are listed at any one time, making the at $25. Thus, if the official final settlement price is furthest available delivery date 60 months in the 96.16, then all traders who carry open long positions future. from the previous day have $150 ($25 per basis point x 6 basis points) credited to their margin accounts Contract Settlement When a futures contract con- while traders with open short positions from the tains provisions for physical delivery, market forces previous day have $150 subtracted from their ac- cause the futures price to converge to the spot market counts. Since the contract is cash settled, traders with price as the delivery date draws near. Actual delivery open positions when the contract matures never bear of the underlying item never takes place with a cash- the responsibility of placing or accepting actual settled futures contract, however. Instead, the futures deposits. exchange forces the process of convergence to take place by setting the final settlement price equal to Minimum Price Fluctuation The minimum price the spot market price prevailing at the end of the fluctuation permitted on the floor of the exchange last day of trading. Final settlement is achieved by is 1 basis point, which, as noted above, is valued at marking the contract to market one last time based $25. on the final settlement price determined by the exchange. One-Month LIBOR Futures

Price Quotation Eurodollar time deposits pay a One-month LIBOR futures began trading on the fixed rate of interest upon maturity. The rate of IMM in 1990. The one-month LIBOR contract resembles the three-month Eurodollar contract 5 See Burghardt et al. (1991) for a more detailed discussion of described above, except that final settlement is the LIFFE and SIMEX contracts. based on the 30-day LIBOR.

24 ECONOMIC REVIEW. NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1992 Table 1 Three-Month Interest Rate Futures: Contract Specifications

Contract Three-Month Treasury Bill Three-Month Eurodollar Time Deposit

Exchange International Monetary Market Division International Monetary Market Division of the Chicago Mercantile Exchange of the Chicago Mercantile Exchange

Contract Size $1,000,000 $1,000,000

Delivery Requirements U.S. Treasury bills with 13 weeks Cash settlement with clearing to maturity corporation

Delivery Months March, June, September, December March, June, September, December

Price Quotation Index: 100 minus discount yield Index: 100 minus add-on yield

Minimum Price Fluctuation $25 per basis point $25 per basis point

Last Day of Trading One day before first delivery date Second London business day before the third Wednesday of the delivery month

Delivery Days Three successive business days Last day of trading beginning with the first day of the contract month on which a 13-week bill is issued and an original-issue one-year bill has 13 weeks left to maturity

Table 2 One-Month Interest Rate Futures: Contract Specifications

Contract One-Month LIBOR Thirty-Day Interest Rate

Exchange International Monetary Market Division Chicago Board of Trade of the Chicago Mercantile Exchange

Contract Size $3,000,000 $5,000,000

Delivery Requirements Cash settlement Cash settlement

Delivery Months First five consecutive months starting First seven calendar months and the with current month next two months in the March, June, September, December trading cycle following the spot month

Price Quotation Index: 100 minus the LIBOR for Index: 100 minus the monthly average one-month Eurodollar time deposits federal funds rate

Minimum Price Fluctuation $25 per basis point $41.67 per basis point

Last Day of Trading The second London bank business day The last business day of the delivery immediately preceding the third month Wednesday of the contract month

Delivery Days Last day of trading Last day of trading

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND 25 Contract Settlement Like the three-month - 100 -Index = (20/3O)(awmage of the daily federal dollar contract, the one-month LIBOR contract is finds rate for the previoz~s 20 days) cash settled. Settlement is based on a notional + (10/3O)(ter~n federalbnds rate fbr principal amount of $3 million. 10 days beginning April 2 1).

Price Quotation and Minimum Price Fluctuation At the same time, the price of the May contract Prices on one-month LIBOR futures are quoted as would correspond approximately to the forward rate an index virtually identical to that used for three- on a 30-day term federal funds deposit beginning month Eurodollar futures. The index is calculated May 1. The correspondence to the 30-day rate is by subtracting the 30-day futures LIBOR from 100. only approximate, however, because the settlement The minimum price increment is 1 basis point, which price for the contract is based on a simple arith- is valued at $25. metic average, which does not incorporate daily compounding. Final Settlement Price As with the three-month Eurodollar contract, the final settlement price for one- Minimum Price Fluctuation The minimum price month LIBOR contract is based on the results of a fluctuation is 1 basis point, valued at $41.67. survey of primary market participants in the London Eurodollar market. Trading Activity in Money Market Futures Charts 1 and 2 display a history of trading ac- Thirty-Day Interest Rate Futures tivity in the four money market futures contracts discussed above. Chart 1 displays total annual trading The Chicago Board of Trade’s 30-day interest rate volume, which is a count of the total number of con- futures contract is a cash-settled contract based on tracts (not the dollar value) traded for all delivery a 30-day average of the daily federal funds rate. The months. Each transaction between a buyer and a CBT lists contracts for six consecutive delivery seller counts as a single trade. Chart 2 plots total months at any one time. month-end for all contract delivery months. Month-end open interest is a count of the Contract Settlement The 30-day interest rate number of unsettled contracts as of the end of the futures contract differs from other interest rate futures last trading day of each month. Each contract in- in that the settlement price is based on an average cluded in the open interest count reflects an out- of past interest rates. Final settlement is based on standing futures commitment on the part of both a an arithmetic average of the daily federal funds rate buyer and a seller. for the 30-day period immediately preceding the con- tract maturity date, as reported by the Federal Trading activity in the Treasury bill futures con- Reserve Bank of New York. The notional principal tract grew steadily from the time the contract was amount of the contract is $5 million. first listed in 1976 through 1982, falling thereafter below 20,000 contracts per day on average. The trading history depicted in Charts 1 and 2 suggests Price Quotation As with all other money market that the introduction of the Eurodollars futures con- futures, prices for 30-day interest rate futures are tract attracted some trading activity away from quoted as an index equal to 100 minus the futures Treasury bill futures. rate. For deferred month contracts-that is, contracts maturing after the current month’s settlement date- In recent years, the IMM Eurodollar futures con- the futures rate corresponds approximately to a for- tract has become the most actively traded futures ward interest rate on one-month term federal funds. contract based on money market rates and is now one of the most actively traded of all futures con- In theory, the futures rate for the nearby contract tracts. Three factors have contributed to the popu- should reflect a weighted average of (1) the average larity of Eurodollar futures. First, most major inter- funds rate for the expired fraction of the current national banks rely heavily on the Eurodollar market month, plus (2) the term federal funds rate for the for short-term funds and act as marketmakers in unexpired fraction of the month. To illustrate, Eurodollar deposits. Eurodollar futures provide a suppose the date is April 21. Twenty days of the means of hedging interest rate risk arising from these month have passed, so the index value for the April activities. Second, the phenomenal growth of the contract would reflect market for interest rate swaps during the last decade

26 ECONOMIC REVIEW. NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1992 Chart 1 AVERAGE MONTH-END OPEN INTEREST U.S. Money Market Futures Thousands 1400

1200

m Treasury Bills 1000

800 m 30-Day Interest Rate

600

T

1976 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 92

Chart 2 TOTAL ANNUAL TRADING VOLUME U.S. Money Market Futures Millions 60

50

m Treasury Bills 40 B Eurodollar

@!$ 30-Day Interest Rate 30

0 l-Month LIBOR

?O

10

0 I976 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 92 has contributed to the growth of trading in Eurodollar PRICERELATIONSHIPSBETWEEN futures.6 Most interest rate contracts specify FUTURE~ANDS~~TPVIARKETS payments contingent on three- or six-month LIBOR. Price relationships between futures and spot Swap market dealers sometimes use Eurodollar markets can be explained using arbitrage pricing futures to their positions in interest rate swaps. theory, which is based on the premise that two Evidence of the widespread use of Eurodollar futures different assets, or combinations of assets, that yield to hedge swap exposures can be found in the fact the same return should sell for the same price. that the IMM currently lists Eurodollar futures with Buying a futures contract on the final day of trading delivery dates stretching as far as 60 months into the is equivalent to buying the underlying item in the future. In contrast, virtually all other futures contracts cash market, since delivery is no longer deferred once list delivery dates only 24 months into the future a futures contract matures. Thus, arbitrage pricing (Burghardt et al., 1991). Third, it has become com- theory predicts that the futures price of an item mon practice for commercial banksto index interest should just equal its spot market price on the futures rates on loans to their corporate customers to contract maturity date: this is just the phenomenon LIBOR. Such borrowers sometimes use Eurodollar of convergence noted earlier. Buying a futures con- futures to hedge their borrowing costs. (In recent tract before the contract maturity date fixes the,cost years, however, it has become more common for of future availability of the underlying item. But the such borrowers to arrange interest rate swaps.) cost of future availability of an item can also be fixed in advance by buying and holding that item. The one-month LIBOR contract enables traders Holding actual physical stocks of a commodity or to use futures contracts to synthesize maturities security entails opportunity costs in the form of corresponding to a wider range of standard maturities interest foregone on the funds used to purchase the in the Eurodollar market. Other than overnight and item and, in some instances, explicit storage costs. one-week deposits, standard maturities in the Euro- The cost associated‘ with financing the purchase of dollar market range from one to six months in one- an asset, along with related storage costs, is known month increments, nine months, one year, eighteen as the cost of carry. Since physical storage can months, and two to five years in one-year increments. substitute for buying a futures contract, arbitrage pricing theory predicts that the cost of carry should The one-month LIBOR contract allows a trader to determine the relationship between futures and spot synthetically duplicate the interest rate exposure market prices. associated with a four-month Eurodollar deposit, as an example, using a combination of a three-month Basis and the Cost of Carry Eurodollar contract and a one-month LIBOR con- tract. Although trading in the contract has been The cost of carry for agricultural and other com- active since it was introduced in 1990, Charts 1 modities includes financing costs, warehousing fees, and. 2 show that trading activity in the one-month transportation costs, and any transactions costs incurred in obtaining the commodity. Storage costs LIBOR contract has yet to approach that of the more are negligible for financial’ assets such as Treasury popular three-month Eurodollar futures contract. bills and Eurodollar deposits. Moreover, financial The CBT first listed its 30-day interest rate futures assets often yield an explicit payout, such as interest contract in 1988. Although there are differences in or payments, that offsets at least a fraction of any financing costs. The convention in financial the way the one-month LIBOR and 30-day interest markets, therefore, is to apply the term net carrying contracts are priced, both are based on indexes of cost to the difference between the interest cost one-month interbank lending rates. At present, associated with financing the purchase of a financial trading volume in the CBT contract is roughly one- asset and any explicit interest or dividend payments third the volume of trading in the one-month LIBOR earned on that asset. contract. Past experience has shown that whenever two different exchanges list futures contracts for Let S(0) denote the purchase price of an asset at similar underlying instruments, only one contract time 0 and r(O,7’) denote the market rate of interest survives. Thus, the current outlook for these latter at which market participants can borrow or lend over two contracts remains uncertain as of this writing. a period starting at date 0 and ending at some future date T.’ Assuming, for the sake of convenience,

6 An is a formal agreement between two parties to exchange cash flows based on the difference between ’ This discussion assumes perfect capital markets in which two different interest rates. market participants can borrow and lend at the same rate.

28 ECONOMIC REVIEW, NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1992 that transactions and storage costs are negligible, the futures delivery date. Ultimately, the market forces cost of purchasing an item and storing it until date created by arbitrageurs selling the overpriced futures T is just the financing cost r(O,T)S(O). Let y(O,T) contract and buying the underlying item should force denote any explicit yield earned on the asset over the spread between futures and spot prices down to the same holding period. Then, the net carrying cost a level just equal to the cost of carry, where arbitrage for the asset is is no longer profitable. In practice, arbitrageurs rarely find it necessary to hold their positions to contract 40,T) = b-(O,T)-y(O, TKW). maturity; instead, they undertake offsetting transac- Since physical storage of an item can substitute tions when market forces bring the spot-futures price for buying a futures contract for that item, arbitrage relationship back into alignment. pricing theory would predict that the futures price should just equal the price of the underlying item plus Example 1: Pricing a Commodity Futures Con- net carrying costs. This result is known as the cost tract Suppose the current spot price of a com- of carry pricing relation. Let F(O,T) denote the modity is $100 and the market rate of interest is 10 futures price of an item at date 0 for delivery at some percent. Assuming that transactions and storage costs future date T. Then, the cost of carry pricing rela- are negligible, the cost of carry for this commodity tion can be stated formally as: for a period of one year is

F(O,T) = S(0) + c(O,T). c(O,T) = (O.lO)($lOO) The difference between the spot price of an item = $10. and its futures price is known as basis.* Notice that the cost of carry pricing relationship equates basis Thus, the fair futures price for delivery in one year with the negative of the cost of carry. This relation- is $110. ship is easily demonstrated by rearranging terms in Now consider the opportunity for arbitrage if the the cost of carry relation to yield futures contract in this example is overpriced. If the S(O)-F(O,T) = -c(O,T). futures price for delivery in one year’s time is $115, an arbitrageur could earn a certain profit by selling Positive carrying costs imply a negative basis-that futures contracts at $115, borrowing $100 at 10 is, a futures price above the spot market price. In percent to buy the underlying commodity, and de- such instances the buyer of a futures contract pays livering the commodity in fulfillment of contract a premium for deferred delivery, known as . requirements atthe futures delivery date. The total cost of purchasing and storing the underlying com- Cash-and-Carry Arbitrage modity for one year is $1.10, while the short posi-’ To see why futures prices should conform to the tion in a futures contract fixes the sale price of the cost of carry model, consider the arbitrage oppor- commodity at $115. Thus, at the end of one year tunities that would exist if they did not. Suppose the the arbitrageur could close out his position by sell- futures price exceeds the cost of the underlying item ing the underlying commodity in fulfillment of con- plus carrying costs; that is, tract requirements, thereby earning a $5 profit net of carrying costs. F(O,T) > S(0) + c(O,T).

In this case, an arbitrageur could earn a positive profit Example 2: Pricing an Interest Rate Futures of F(0, T) -S(O) -c(O,T) dollars by selling the over- Contract Suppose a long-lived asset that pays a 15 priced futures contract while buying the underlying percent annual yield can be purchased for $100, and item, storing it until the futures delivery date, and assume that the cost of borrowing to finance the pur- using it to satisfy delivery requirements. chase of this asset for one year is 10 percent. In this case, the $10 annual financing cost is more than off- This type of transaction is known as cash-and-carry set by the annual $15 yield earned on the asset. The arbitrage because it involves buying the underlying net cost of carry for a one-year holding period is item in the cash market and carrying it until the (O.lO-0.15)$100 = -965.

8 Some authors define basis as the difference between the futures price and the spot price. The definition adopted above is the Thus, the fair futures price for delivery in one year more common. is $95.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND 29 The net cost of carry is negative in this last ex- Reverse cash-and-carry arbitrage operations require ample, resulting in a futures price below the spot that market participants be able to effect short sales market price. This type of price relationship is known of the item underlying the futures contract so as as backwardation. It is common for interest rate to take advantage of an underpriced futures con- futures prices to exhibit a pattern of backwardation, tract. Various impediments to short sales exist in although this pattern can be reversed when short- some markets, however. In the , for term interest rates are higher than long-term rates. example, government regulations, as well as trading rules, limit the ability of market Reverse Cash-and-Carry Arbitrage participants to effect short sales. If the futures price of an item fails to reflect full The importance of such impediments is mitigated carrying costs, arbitrageurs have an incentive to by the fact that it is not always necessary to engage engage in an operation known as reverse cash-and- in a short sale to effect a reverse cash-and-carry carry arbitrage. Reverse cash-and-carry arbitrage arbitrage operation. Many firms are ideally situated involves selling the underlying commodity short while to take advantage of the opportunities presented by buying the corresponding futures contract. A short underpriced futures contracts simply by selling any sale involves borrowing a commodity or asset for a inventories they hold while buying futures contracts fixed time period and selling that item in the cash to fix the cost of buying back the underlying item. market with the intent of repurchasing it when the Yet market participants often do not sell their asset commodity is due to be returned to the lender. holdings to take advantage of “underpriced” futures contracts because ready access to actual physical In the case of a short sale of an interest-bearing stores of an item can yield certain implicit benefits. security, a lender typically requires the borrower to For example, a miller might value having a ready return the security plus any interest or dividend supply of grain on hand to ensure the uninterrupted payments accruing to the security over the period operation of his milling operations. A futures con- of the loan. Thus, the net profit resulting from a tract can substitute for physical holdings of the reverse cash-and-carry operation is determined by the underlying commodity in the sense that it fixes the proceeds from the short sale, S(O), plus the interest cost of future availability, but the miller cannot use earned on those proceeds over the holding period, futures contracts to keep his mill operating in the r(O,T)S(O), less the cost of repurchasing the secur- event that he runs out of grain. Supplies of agricultural ity at date T, F(O,T), and less the interest or divi- commodities can be scarce in periods just preceding dend that would have been earned by holding the harvests, making market participants such as com- security, which is y(O,T)S(O). The total net profit modity processors willing to pay an implicit conve- in this case is just nience yield in return for assured access to physical stores of a commodity at such times. A measure of [I +r(O,T)-y(O,T)]S(O)-F(O,T). the implicit convenience yield, call it yC(O,T), can be obtained by calculating the difference between the Banks active in the Eurodollar market can effect cost of storage and the futures price: short sales of deposits simply by accepting such deposits from other market participants and investing yc(O,T) = W) + 40,T) -F(O,T), the proceeds until the deposits mature. Dealers in the Treasury bill market can effect short sales through where the term c(O,T) in the above expression arrangements known as repurchase agreements. represents the explicit carrying cost.9 These operations are described in more detail below. Pricing Treasury Bill Futures: The Implied Repo Rate The Phenomenon of “Underpriced” Futures Contracts A , more commonly termed a “repo” or “RP,” is a transaction involving the sale Futures prices sometimes fail to reflect full carry- of a security with a commitment on the part of the ing costs, a phenomenon that is most pronounced seller to repurchase that security at a higher price in commodity markets. At least two different expla- nations have been offered for this phenomenon: the first deals with impediments to short sales; the 9 Siegel and Siegel (1990, Chap. 2) contains a good intro- ductory discussion of these topics. See Williams (1986) for a second with the implicit convenience yield that comprehensive analysis of the price behavior of agricultural accrues to physical ownership of certain assets. futures.

30 ECONOMIC REVIEW, NOVEMBERlDECEMBER 1992 on some future date-usually the next day, although delivery requirements for the nearby futures contract. such agreements sometimes cover periods as long If the current discount yield on bills with 15 1 days as six months. A repurchase agreement can be viewed to maturity is 3.8 percent, the cash price of the as a short-term loan collateralized by the underlying bill is security, with the difference between the repurchase S(0) = $1,000,000 price and the initial sale price implicitly determining - $1,000,000(0.038)(151/360) an interest rate, known as the “rep0 rate.” Repur- chase agreements constitute a primary source = $984,061.11. for dealers in the market for U.S. Treasury securities. Now suppose that the price of the nearby Treasury Cash-and-carry arbitrage using Treasury bill futures bill futures contract is 96.25. An index price of 96.25 involves the purchase of a bill that will have 13 weeks implies a futures discount yield for the nearby to maturity on the contract delivery date. A cash- Treasury bill contract of 100 - 96.25 = 3.75 per- and-carry arbitrage operation can be viewed as an cent. Since the deliverable bill will have 91 days to implicit reverse repurchase agreement, which is just maturity, the future delivery price implied by this a repurchase agreement from the viewpoint of the yield is lender. A reverse repo entails the purchase of a J-(0,60)= $1 ,OOO,OOO security with a commitment to sell the security back - $1,000,000(0.0375)(91/360) at some future date. A party entering into a reverse repo effectively lends money while taking the = $990,520.83. underlying security as collateral. Like a party to a The implied repo rate in this case is reverse repo, a trader who buys a Treasury bill while selling a futures contract obtains temporary posses- irr = [($990,520.83 sion of the bill while committing himself to sell it - $984,061.11)/$984,061.11](360/60) back to the market at some future date. Just as the = 0.0394, difference between the purchase price of a bill and the agreed-upon sale price determines the interest or 3.94 percent. rate earned by a party to a reverse repo, the differ- ence between the futures and spot price determines The cost of carry pricing relation can be used to the return to a cash-and-carry arbitrage operation. show that the no-arbitrage price should equate the In effect, the trader “lends” money to the market, implied repo rate with the actual repo rate. To see earning the difference between the future delivery this, note that the cost of carry pricing relation im- price and the price paid for the security as implicit plies that the no-arbitrage price must satisfy interest. The rate of return earned on such an opera- F(O,T)-S(0) = c(O,T). tion is known as the “implied repo rate.” Although Treasury bills are interest-bearing securi- By market convention, the implied repo rate is ties, the interest earned on a bill is implicit in the expressed as the annualized rate of return that could difference between the purchase and redemption be earned by buying a Treasury bill at a price S(O) price. This means that y(O,T) =O, so that total net at date 0 and simultaneously selling a futures con- carrying costs for a Treasury bill must just equal tract for delivery at date T for a price F(O,T). The formula is c(O,T) = r(O,OW), where r(O,T) represents the cost of financing the in- = ([F(O,T)-S(O)]/S(O))(360/T), purchase of the bill, expressed as an unannualized where irk denotes the implied repo rate. Note that interest rate. Substituting these last two expressions this formula follows the convention in money markets into the definition of the implied repo rate gives of expressing annual interest rates in terms of a irr = r(O,T)(360/T). 360-day year. Because repurchase agreements constitute a primary The following example illustrates the calculation funding source for dealers in the Treasury bill market, of the implied repo rate. Suppose that it is exactly ~(0, T) should reflect the cash repo rate. lo Thus, the 60 days to the next delivery date on three-month Treasury bill futures. A bill with 15 1 days left to 10Gendreau (1985) found empirical support for the assertion that maturity will have 9 1 days left to maturity on the next the repo rate provides the correct measure of carrying costs for futures delivery date and can be used to satisfy Treasury bill futures.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND 31 cost of carry pricing relation implies that the implied be placed in three months fixed by buying a repo rate should just equal the cash repo rate. Eurodollar futures contract. The condition that a six- month deposit should earn as much as a succession Comparing implied repo rates with actual rates of two three-month deposits requires that amounts to comparing theoretical futures prices, as determined by the cost of carry model, with actual 1 + r(O,6) = 11 +r(0,3)][1 +r,(3,6)]. futures prices. An implied repo rate above the actual three-month repo rate would indicate that The no-arbitrage futures interest rate can thus be futures contracts are relatively overpriced. In this case calculated from the other two spot rates by rearrang- arbitrage profits could be earned by borrowing money ing terms to yield in the cash repo market and implicitly lending the money back out through a cash-and-carry arbitrage r-(3,6) = [ 1 +r(0,6)]/[ 1 +r(O,3)] - 1. to earn the higher implied repo rate. As an example, suppose the prevailing three-month Conversely, an implied repo rate below the actual LIBOR is quoted at 4.0 percent and the six-month rate would indicate that futures contracts are under- LIBOR at 4.25 percent (in terms of annualized in- priced. In this second case, arbitrageurs would have terest rates). Suppose further that the six-month rate an incentive to “borrow” money by means of a reverse applies to a period of exactly 180 days and the three- cash-and-carry futures hedging operation while lend- month rate applies to a period of 90 days. Finally, ing into the cash market through a reverse repo. Such assume that the nearby Eurodollar contract con- an operation would entail buying an underpriced veniently happens to mature in exactly 90 days. futures contract and simultaneously entering into a Then, the no-arbitrage interest rate on a three-month reverse repurchase agreement to lend money into the Eurodollar deposit to be made three months in the cash repo market. future is r,(3,6) = [ 1 + (0.0425)( 180/360)]/ The concept of an implied repo rate can also be [I+ (0.04)(90/360)] - 1 applied to other types of financial futures. Merrick (1990) and Siegel and Siegel (1990) discuss other = 0.0111. applications. To express this result as an annualized interest rate Pricing Eurodollar Futures just multiply the number obtained above by (360/90). The result is Now consider the problem of determining the theoretically correct price of a three-month Eurodollar r,(3,6)(360/90) = 0.0444, futures contract maturing in exactly 90 days. Note that a six-month deposit can be viewed as a succes- which means that the no-arbitrage futures interest sion of two three-month deposits. Thus, a bank can rate in this example is 4.44 percent and the theo- synthesize an implicit six-month deposit by placing retically correct index price is 95.56. The same a three-month deposit and buying a futures contract methodology can be used to price one-month LIBOR to fix the rate of return earned when the proceeds futures.” of the first deposit are reinvested into another deposit. Arbitrage opportunities Will exist unless the return If the futures rate is below the no-arbitrage rate, to this synthetic six-month deposit equals the return the interest rate on a synthetic six-month deposit will to the actual six-month deposit. be less than on an actual six-month deposit. A bank can effect a cash-and-carry arbitrage operation by Let r(O,3) and r(O,6) denote the current (un- “buying” a six-month deposit now (that is, by annualized) three- and six-month LIBOR, respec- placing a deposit with another bank) while accepting tively. Eurodollar deposits pay a fixed rate of interest a three-month deposit and selling a Eurodollar futures over the term of the deposit. For maturities under contract. In this case, arbitrage amounts to lending one year, interest is paid at maturity. Thus, an in- at the higher spot market rate (by placing a six-month vestor placing $1 in a 180-day deposit in an account deposit with another bank) while borrowing at the paying an interest rate of r(0,6) receives $[ 1 +r(0,6)] at maturity. Similarly, a 90-day deposit will return I1 Readers interested in a more detailed exposition of forward (1 +r(O,3)] per dollar at maturity. Now let r,(3,6) interest rate calculations and the pricing of Eurodollar futures denote the interest rate on a three-month deposit to should see Burghardt et al. (1991).

32 ECONOMIC REVIEW, NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1992 lower synthetic six-month rate (obtained by accept- Speculators have been active participants in futures ing a three-month deposit and selling a futures markets since the earliest days of futures trading. On contract). several occasions, the perception that futures market exerted a destabilizing influence on com- Conversely, a futures interest rate above the modity markets led to attempts to restrict or ban theoretically correct rate is a signal for banks to enter futures trading. I3 But despite the association of into a reverse cash-and-carry arbitrage. In this case, speculative activity with futures trading, it is widely a bank would wish to accept a six-month deposit to accepted that futures markets evolved primarily in borrow at the lower spot market rate while placing response to the needs of commodity handlers, such a three-month deposit and buying the nearby futures as dealers in agricultural commodities and process- contract to lend at the higher synthetic six-month ing firms, who used futures contracts in conjunction rate. with their routine business transactions. The same types of market forces appear to’underlie the recent Daily Settlement and the Cost of Carry growth of trading in financial futures, the heaviest users of which are financial intermediaries such as As a concluding comment, it should be noted that commercial banks, securities dealers, and investment the pricing formulas developed in this section do not funds that routinely use futures contracts to hedge take account of the effect of variation margin flows. cash transactions in financial markets. When interest rates fluctuate randomly, the fact that a futures contract is marked to market on a daily basis While it is widely accepted that futures markets means that some of the payoff to a futures position evolved to facilitate hedging, the motivation behind will need to be reinvested at different interest rates. observed hedging behavior in futures markets has Thus, the cost of carry formulas derived above hold been the topic of considerable debate among exactly only if interest rates are constant or if there economists. Risk transfer traditionally has been are no variation margin payments, as typically is viewed as the primary economic function of futures the case with forward agreements (Cox, Ingersoll, markets. According to this view, the economic pur- and Ross, 1981). In all other cases, the formulas pose of futures markets is to provide a means for derived above yield theoretical futures prices that transferring the price risk associated with owning an only approximate true theoretical futures prices. As item to someone else. A number of economists have an empirical matter, however, the approximation come to question this traditional view in recent years, appears to be a close one, so that the cost of carry however, arguing that the desire to transfer price risk model is commonly used to price futures contracts cannot fully explain why market participants use as well as forward contracts.lz futures contracts.

THEECONOMICFLJNCTIONOF The discussion that follows examines the hedging FUTURESMARKETS uses of money market futures and reviews three Hedging, Speculation, and Futures Markets different views of the economic function of futures markets in an effort to provide some insight into the It is common to categorize futures market trading reasons firms use futures markets. All three theories activity either as hedging or speculation. In the most are based on the premise that futures markets evolved general terms, a futures hedging operation is a futures to facilitate hedging on the part of firms active in market transaction undertaken in conjunction with underlying spot markets, but the different theories an actual or planned spot market transaction. Futures each emphasize different characteristics of futures market speculation refers to the act of buying or contracts and futures markets to explain why hedgers selling futures contracts solely in an attempt to use futures contracts. This review is of more than profit from price changes, and not in conjunction with academic interest. Futures hedging operations are an ordinary commercial pursuit. According to these complex and multifaceted transactions, and each definitions, then, a dentist who buys wheat futures in anticipation of a rise in wheat prices would be classified as a speculator, while a grain dealer under- 13One of the most drastic efforts to curb futures trading in- volved the arrest of nine prominent members of the Chicago taking a similar transaction would be regarded as a Board of Trade following ;he enactment of the Illinois Elevator hedger. Bill of 1867. The act classified the sale of contracts for future delivery as gambling except in cases where the seller actually owned physical stocks of the commodity being sold. Those pro- 12Chance (1989) reviews the results of studies dealing with the visions were soon repealed, however, and the exchange members effect of variation margin payments on futures prices. never came to trial (Hieronymus, 1971, Chap. 4).

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND 33 theory provides important insights into different motivated by the desire to transfer price risk. For aspects of hedging behavior. example, commercial banks, savings and loans, and insurance companies use interest rate futures to pro- Future Markets as Markets for tect their balance sheets and future earnings from Risk Transfer potentially adverse effects of changes in market interest rates.14 In addition, nonfinancial firms some- In conventional usage, the term “hedging” refers times use interest rate futures to fix interest rates to an attempt to avoid or lessen the risk of loss by on anticipated future investments and borrowing rates matching a risk exposure with a counterbalancing on future loans. risk, as in hedging a bet. A futures hedge can be viewed as the use of futures contracts to offset the The Liquidity Theory of Futures Markets risk of loss resulting from price changes. A short (cash-and-carry) hedging operation, for example, Working (1962) and Telser (198 1, 1986) contend combines a short futures position with a long posi- that the hedging behavior of firms cannot be tion in the underlying item to fix the future sale price understood by looking at risk avoidance alone as the of that item, thereby protecting the hedger from the primary motivation for hedging. Instead, they argue risk of loss resulting from a fall in the value of his that the hedging behavior of optimizing firms is best holdings. Reverse cash-and-carry arbitrage, which understood when hedging is viewed as a temporary, combines a short position in an item with a long low-cost alternative to planned spot market trans- futures position, represents an example of a long actions. According to this line of reasoning, futures hedge. The long futures position offsets the risk that markets exist primarily because they provide market the price of the underlying item might rise before participants with a means of economizing on trans- the hedger can buy the item back to return to the actions costs, and not solely because futures contracts owner. More generally, a long hedge combines a long can be used to transfer price risk. Williams (1986) futures position with a planned future purchase of has termed this view the liquidity theory of futures an item to produce an offsetting risk that protects markets. the hedger from the risk of an increase in the future purchase price of the item. Working’s and Telser’s arguments rest on the observation that market participants need not use Most textbook hedging examples rely on this tradi- futures contracts to insure themselves against price tional definition of hedging to motivate descriptions risk. As noted in the earlier discussion on arbitrage of hedging operations. Thus, a dealer in Treasury pricing, spot purchases (or short sales) of an item can securities might sell Treasury bill futures to offset substitute for buying (selling) a futures contract to the risk that an unanticipated change in market fix the cost of future availability (future sale price) interest rates will adversely affect the value of his of an item. Moreover, forward contracts can also be securities holdings. Note that the short hedge in this used to transfer price risk. Because they can be example effectively shortens the maturity of the custom-tailored to the needs of a hedger, forward con- interest-bearing asset being hedged. In contrast, a tracts would appear to offer a better means of insur- long hedge fixes the return on a future investment, ing against price risk than futures contracts. Contract thereby lengthening the effective maturity of an standardization, while contributing to the liquidity existing interest-earning asset. of futures markets, practically insures that futures con- tracts will not be perfectly suited to the needs of This traditional definition of hedging accords with any one hedger. is It would seem, then, that a the view that the primary function of futures markets hedger interested solely in minimizing price risk is to facilitate the transfer of price risk. The party would have little incentive to use futures contracts, buying the futures contracts in the above example might be an investor planning to buy Treasury bills at some future date or a speculator hoping to profit I4 Brewer (1985) and Kaufman (1984) discuss the problem such firms face in managing interest rate risk. from a decline in market interest rates. In the first case the risk exposure is transferred from one hedger 1s Since planned transaction dates rarely coincide with stan- dardized futures delivery dates, most hedgers must unwind to another who faces an opposite risk. In the second, their futures positions before the contracts mature. As a result, the risk is willingly assumed by the speculator in the hedging operations must rely upon the predictability of the spot- hope of earning windfall gains. futures price relationship, or basis. Although theory predicts that behavior of basis should be determined by the cost of carry, changes in the spot-futures price relationship are not always Other common hedging operations involving predictable in practice. Thus, a futures hedge involves “basis money market futures can also be viewed as being risk,” which is much easier to avoid with forward contracts.

34 ECONOMIC REVIEW. NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1992 a conclusion which suggests that the view of futures the spot market and hedge by selling the appropriate markets as markets for transferring price risk is futures contract. In either case, the firm will have incomplete. temporary use of the item and will be required to return (deliver) that item at some set future date. Although it makes futures contracts less suited to Depending on one’s view, therefore, a short hedger insuring against price risk, contract standardization, is either extending a loan of money collateralized along with the clearinghouse guarantee, facilitates by the item underlying the futures contract or trading in futures contracts and reduces transactions borrowing the underlying commodity using cash as costs. By focusing attention on these characteristics collateral. of futures contracts, Working (1962) and Telser (198 1, 1986) are able to explain why dealers and A natural question to ask at this juncture is why other intermediaries who perform the function of a firm would choose to engage in a cash-and-carry marketmakers in spot markets tend to be the primary hedging operation to synthesize an implicit loan of users of futures contracts. Market-making activity an item rather than borrowing the item outright. The requires dealers to constantly undertake transactions answer lies with the advantages that futures contracts that change the composition of their holdings. have in the event of or . Consider Securities dealers, for example, must stand ready to the consequences of a default on the part of a firm buy and sell securities in response to customer orders. that loans out securities while borrowing cash. Sup- As they do, their cash positions change continually, pose firm A enters into a repurchase agreement with along with their exposure to price risk. Similarly, the firm B. If firm A defaults on its obligations, firm B assets and liabilities of commercial banks change con- cannot always be assured that the courts will permit tinually as they accept deposits and offer loans to their it to keep the security collateralizing the loan because customers. Thus, financial intermediaries such as the “automatic stay” provisions of the U.S. Bank- commercial and investment banks hedge using ruptcy Code may prevent creditors from enforcing futures contracts because the greater liquidity and liens against a firm that enters into bankruptcy pro- lower transactions costs in futures markets mean that ceedings. Thus, when Lombard-Wall, Inc. entered a futures hedge can be readjusted frequently with bankruptcy proceedings in 1982, its repurchase relatively little difficulty and at minimal cost. agreement counterparties could neither use funds obtained through a repurchase agreement or sell To illustrate these concepts, consider the situ- underlying repo securities without first obtaining the ation faced by an investor who holds a three-month court’s permission (Lumpkin, 1993). In such cases, Treasury bill but wishes to lengthen the effective creditors may be forced to settle for a fraction of the maturity of his holding to six months. The investor amounts owed them. could sell the three-month bill and buy a six-month bill, or he could buy a futures contract for a three- Subsequent amendments to the U.S. Bankruptcy month Treasury bill deliverable in three months. A Code have clarified the steps needed to perfect a col- long hedging operation of this type effectively con- lateral interest in securities lending arrangements, verts the three-month bill into a synthetic six-month making it possible for investors to avoid many of the bill. The preferred strategy will depend on the relative difficulties Lombard-Wall’s counterparties encoun- costs of the two alternatives. Since transactions costs tered with the Bankruptcy Court. Nevertheless, col- in futures markets tend to be lower than those in lateralized lending agreements are never riskless. A underlying spot markets, the futures hedge is often party to a reverse RP, for example, faces the risk the more cost-effective alternative. that the market value of the underlying security might fall below the agreed-upon repurchase price. More- Futures Markets as Implicit Loan Markets over, parties to mutual lending arrangements some- times fraudulently pledge collateral to several different Williams (1986) argues that futures markets are creditors. In either case, a lender is exposed to the best viewed as implicit loan markets, which exist risk of loss in the event of a default on the part of because they provide an efficient means of inter- a borrower. Finally, the Bankruptcy Code amend- mediating . Recall that a firm that needs ments do not apply to all types of lending. For to hold physical inventories of some item for a fixed example, Eurodollar deposits cannot be collateral- period has two choices. First, it can make arrange- ized under existing banking laws. ments to borrow the item directly, often by pledg- ing some form of collateral such as cash or securities The consequence of a default is quite different to secure the loan. Second, it can buy the item in when a firm uses futures contracts to synthesize an

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND 35 implicit loan. Because synthesizing a loan through These observations led Williams to conclude that the use of futures contracts involves no exchange of futures markets are best viewed as markets for principal, the risk exposure associated with a futures intermediating short-term loans, which resemble contract in the event of a default is much smaller money markets. Although Williams’ rationale for the than the exposure associated with an outright loan. existence of futures markets differs in emphasis from Thus, a futures hedging operation amounts to a col- that of Working and Telser, the two theories are not lateralized lending arrangement in which the collateral inconsistent. While Williams acknowledges that is never at risk in the event of a default. A position futures markets have certain advantages over other in a futures contract does create credit-risk exposure markets stemming from greater liquidity and lower when changes in market prices change the value of transactions costs, he argues that Working and Telser the contract; however, the resulting exposure is a place too much importance on contract standard- small fraction of the notional principal amount of ization and transactions costs as primary reasons for the contract, and the exchange clearinghouse risks the existence of futures markets. In the end, however, losing only the change in value in the futures con- both theories question the traditional view that the tract resulting from price changes in the most recent primary function of futures markets is to accommo- trading session. Here, daily settlement, or marking date the transfer of price risk. to market, of futures contracts provides an efficient means of enforcing contract performance. In the Since Williams published his work, the Bank- event that a firm fails to meet a margin call, the ruptcy Code has been amended to exempt certain clearinghouse can order its futures position to be repurchase agreements and forward agreements from liquidated and claim the firm’s margin deposit to offset the automatic stay provisions applicable to most other any losses accruing to the futures position. If the liabilities of bankrupt firms. As a result, such con- defaulting firm subsequently enters formal bankruptcy tracts now have a legal status similar to that of futures proceedings, the futures margin is exempt from the contracts in the event of bankruptcy. Williams’ theory automatic stay imposed by the Bankruptcy Code.i6 would thus predict that repurchase agreements and Thus, a futures clearinghouse is entitled to seize a forward contracts should become more widely used, trader’s margin deposit to offset any trading losses which is what has happened in recent years. Rather without being required to first appeal to the Bank- than replacing futures contracts, however, the growth ruptcy Court. of over-the-counter derivatives such as interest rate swaps and Forward Rate Agreements appears to be Although forward contracts can also be used to driving an accompanying increase in trading in futures synthesize implicit loans in much the same way as contracts, especially Eurodollar futures, which futures contracts, Williams (1986) argues that a derivatives dealers use to hedge their swap and for- crucial difference between futures contracts and ward contract exposures. Thus, even when forward forward agreements lies with their legal status in the agreements and collateralized lending arrangements event of default and bankruptcy proceedings. While carry the same legal status as futures contracts in the forward agreements sometimes specify margin de- event of a default, each type of contract appears to posits, such deposits have not, until very recently, offer certain advantages to different types of users. been exempt from the automatic stay provisions of Still, Williams’ research highlights an important aspect the Bankruptcy Code.17 of futures contracts and futures markets not addressed by earlier work in this area. r6 Williams (1986) cites a precedent-setting legal decision that exempted margin deposits from the automatic stay provisions of the Bankruptcy Code. I7 Recent amendments to the Bankruptcy Code exempt margin deposits on certain types of forward contracts from the automatic stay. See Gooch and Pergam (1990) for a detailed description of these amendments.

36 ECONOMIC REVIEW. NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1992 REFERENCES

Brewer, Elijah. “Bank Gap Management and the Use of Finan- Lumpkin, Stephen A. “Repurchase and Reverse Repurchase cial Futures,” Federal Reserve Bank of. Chicago Economic Agreements,” in Timothy Cook and Robert LaRoche, eds., Perspectiwes, vol. 9 (March/April 1985), pp. 12-21. Instmments of the Money Market, 7th ed. Richmond, Va.: Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, forthcoming 1993. Burghardt, Belton, Lane, Lute, and McVey. &rvdo&rr Futures and Options. Chicago: Probus Publishing Company, Merrick, John J., Jr. Financial Futures Markets: &mctum, &icing, 1991. and Practice. New York: Harper and Row, 1990.

Chance, Don M. An Intnduction to OptionsandFutures. Chicago: Siegel, Daniel R. and Diane F. Siegel. The Futures Markets. The Dryden Press, 1989. Chicago: Probus Publishing Company, 1990. Commodity Futures Trading Commission. AnnuulRepm.1991. Silber, William L. “Marketmaker Behavior in an Auction Cox, J. C., J. E. Ingersoll, and S. A. Ross. “The Relation Market: An Analysis of Scalpers in Futures Markets,” Between Forward Prices and Futures Prices,” Journal of Jouma/of Finance, vol. 39 (September 1984) pp. 937-53. , vol. 9 (Winter. 1983), pp. 321-46. Telser, Lester G. “Why There Are Organized Futures Gendreau, Brian C. “Carrying Costs and Treasury Bill Futures,” Markets,” Journal of Law and Economics, vol. 24 (April Journal of PortfoLio Management, Fall 1985, pp. 58-64. 1981), pp. l-22.

Gooch, Anthony C. and Albert S. Pergam. “United States . “Futures and Actual Markets: How-They Are and New York Law,” in Robert J. Schwartz and Clifford Related,” The Journal of Business, vol. 59 (April 1986), Smith, Jr., eds., The Handbook of Currency and Intenst Rate pp. s-20. Risk Manugement. New York: New York Institute of Finance, 1990. Williams,’ Jeffrey. Th Economic Function of Futures Markets. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1986. Hieronymus, Thomas A. Economics of Futures Trading. New York: Commodity Research Bureau, Inc., 1971. Working, Holbrook. “New Concepts Concerning Futures Kaufman, George G. “Measuring and Managing Interest Rate Markets and Prices,” Ametican Economic Rewieq vol. 52 Risk: A Primer,” Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Eco- (June 1962), pp. 432-59. nomic Perspectives, vol. 8 (January/February 1984) pp. 16-29.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND 37