NAFTA and Mexico's Economic Performance

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

NAFTA and Mexico's Economic Performance A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Tornell, Aaron; Westermann, Frank; Martínez, Lorenza Working Paper NAFTA and Mexico's Economic Performance CESifo Working Paper, No. 1155 Provided in Cooperation with: Ifo Institute – Leibniz Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich Suggested Citation: Tornell, Aaron; Westermann, Frank; Martínez, Lorenza (2004) : NAFTA and Mexico's Economic Performance, CESifo Working Paper, No. 1155, Center for Economic Studies and ifo Institute (CESifo), Munich This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/76631 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu NAFTA AND MEXICO’S ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE AARON TORNELL FRANK WESTERMANN LORENZA MARTÍNEZ CESIFO WORKING PAPER NO. 1155 CATEGORY 5: FISCAL POLICY, MACROECONOMICS AND GROWTH MARCH 2004 An electronic version of the paper may be downloaded • from the SSRN website: www.SSRN.com • from the CESifo website: www.CESifo.de CESifo Working Paper No. 1155 NAFTA AND MEXICO’S ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE Abstract Mexico, a prominent liberalizer, failed to attain stellar gross domestic product (GDP) growth in the 1990s, and since 2001 its GDP and exports have stagnated. In this paper we argue that the lack of spectacular growth in Mexico cannot be blamed on either the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) or the other reforms that were implemented, but on the lack of further judicial and structural reform after 1995. In fact, the benefits of liberalization can be seen in the extraordinary growth of exports and foreign domestic investment (FDI). The key to the Mexican puzzle lies in Mexico’s response to crisis: a deterioration in contract enforceability and an increase in nonperforming loans. As a result, the credit crunch in Mexico has been far deeper and far more protracted than in the typical developing country. The credit crunch has hit the nontradables sector especially hard and has generated bottlenecks, which have blocked growth in the tradables sector and have contributed to the recent fall in exports. JEL classification: E20, E44, F30, F43, G15, O40, O50. Keywords: boom-bust cycles, currency mismatch, lending booms, real exchange rate, FDI, credit market imperfections and volatility. Aaron Tornell Frank Westermann Department of Economics CESifo (University of Munich & Ifo Institute) University of California, Los Angeles Poschingerstrasse 5 8283 Bunche Hall 81679 Munich 405 Hilgard Avenue Germany Los Angeles, CA 90024 [email protected] U.S.A [email protected] Lorenza Martínez Banco de Mexico Av. 5 de Mayo No. 1, segundo piso, Colonia Centro, C.P. 06059, Deleg. Cuauhtémoc, México D.F [email protected] This paper is part of “Liberalization, Growth and Financial Crises: Lessons from Mexico and the Developing World” that was prepared for the Brookings Panel on Economic Activity. We want to thank Sasha Becker, Bill Brainard, Pierre O. Gourinchas, Gordon Hanson, Graciela Kaminski, Tim Kehoe, Aart Kraay, Anne Krueger, Norman Loayza, George Perry, Romain Ranciere, Luis Serven, Sergio Schmuckler, Carolyn Sissoko and Alejandro Werner for helpful discussions. For providing data we thank Josúe Campos, Jaime de la Llata, Gerardo Leyva, Arturo López at INEGI, and Alfonso Guerra and Jessica Serrano at Banco de México. Miguel Díaz, Pedro J. Martínez, Paulina Oliva and Roberto Romero provided excellent research assistance. 1. Introduction The Mexican experience is often considered a prime example of what can go wrong with liberalization. Mexico liberalized its trade and finance and entered the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), yet despite these reforms and the advantage of proximity to the United States, Mexico’s growth performance has been unremarkable in comparison with that of its peers. Moreover, during the last two years exports and GDP have stopped growing. Why has Mexico’s aggregate growth performance failed to meet expectations? Why has there been an export slowdown? Where can we see the effects of liberalization and entry into NAFTA? Some have argued that countries like Mexico could have grown faster had they not liberalized trade and finance so fast, and had they received more FDI and less capital in the form of risky bank flows; in this way, Mexico could have avoided the lending boom and the Tequila crisis. We do not agree. That liberalization is bad for growth because it leads to crises is the wrong lesson to draw from the Mexican experience. We have shown in a recent paper that in countries with severe credit market imperfections, liberalization leads to more rapid growth, but also to financial fragility and occasional crises.1 Mexico is thus no exception in experiencing a boom and a bust. Something else must be at work. To find out what that is, we compare Mexico’s experience to an international empirical norm. We argue that Mexico’s less-than-stellar growth is not due to liberalization or to the lending boom and crisis it engendered, and that, in all likelihood, GDP growth would have been slower without liberalization and NAFTA. In fact, in the wake of the crisis, exports experienced extraordinary growth and GDP growth recovered quite quickly. Instead, we argue that a lack of structural reform and Mexico’s credit crunch, which was deeper and more protracted than that of the typical MIC, are important factors behind Mexico’s unremarkable growth performance and the recent slowdown in exports. The data indicate that a key ingredient in any successful explanation of the Mexican experience should account for the sharp ups and downs of the nontradables (N) sector relative to the tradables (T) sector. Furthermore, to account for the effects of trade and financial liberalization, models are needed that focus on the sources of financing at the firm level. As we noted previously, the fastest growing countries of the developing world tend to experience booms and busts. Although Mexico’s growth, relative to its initial GDP, has been decent, when we control for bumpiness Mexico is an underperformer. Even in the period since 1 Tornell, Westerman, and Martinez (2004). liberalization, the Mexican economy has grown 2 percentage points less per year than the average for other countries with comparably risky paths. When we compare Mexico’s boom-bust cycle with that of the typical MIC, we find that Mexico’s boom phase and subsequent crisis are typical; it is Mexico’s response to the crisis that is the outlier. Relative to the typical MIC, Mexico’s credit crunch was both more severe and more protracted. The credit-to-GDP ratio in Mexico fell from 49 percent in 1994 to 17 percent in 2002. This severe credit crunch is in contrast to the fast recovery of GDP growth in the wake of the Tequila crisis of 1994-95. The fast recovery of GDP growth masks a sharp sectoral asymmetry between an impressive increase in exports and a lagging N-sector. The N-to-T output ratio fell about five times as much in Mexico as in the average country in the aftermath of crisis. Micro-level data reveal that the prolonged postcrisis credit crunch mainly affected the N-sector, whereas the T-sector received a large share of foreign direct investment (FDI) and was insulated from the credit crunch because it could access international financial markets and shift away from domestic bank credit. Over the past eight years, tight domestic credit has limited investment and growth in the financially constrained N-sector, with the result that it is the T-sector, in large part, that has enjoyed the beneficial effects of liberalization and NAFTA. Mexico’s persistent credit crunch is puzzling. It cannot be explained by a fall in loanable funds: deposits have grown in parallel with GDP, and a large share of the banking system (88 percent by 2001) has been sold to foreigners. What accounts, then, for the credit crunch? Evidence suggests that the fall in credit has been associated both with a sharp deterioration in contract enforceability and with the policy response to the problem of nonperforming bank loans. Since 2001 Mexican exports and GDP have stopped growing. The empirical evidence indicates that the U.S. recession can account for part of this slowdown, but not all of it. We show that some internal factors--fire sales and the bottleneck effect--can help account for this residual. Access to international financial markets combined with a real depreciation allowed the T-sector to buy N-sector inputs at fire-sale prices and thus to grow rapidly in the wake of the crisis. However, this rosy scenario could not go on forever. Lack of credit and of structural reform depressed N- sector investment, and the resulting decline in N-sector output generated bottlenecks that eventually blocked T-sector growth. In fact, sectoral evidence shows that the subsectors where exports have declined the most are those that use N-sector inputs most intensively. Given the lackluster performance of the N-sector, this suggests that bottlenecks are contributing to the slowdown.
Recommended publications
  • Mexico: a Decade of Falling Inequality: Market Forces Or State Action? Gerardo Esquivel, Nora Lustig, and John Scott
    07-0410-2 CH 7:Cohen-Easterly 3/17/10 8:47 PM Page 175 7 Mexico: A Decade of Falling Inequality: Market Forces or State Action? gerardo esquivel, nora lustig, and john scott exico is among the most unequal countries in the world.1 However, it is Mmaking progress in becoming less unequal: from 1996 to 2006, Mexico’s Gini coefficient fell from 0.543 to 0.498 (or by 0.8 percent a year),2 and from 2000 to 2006 it fell by 1 percent a year.3 The decline in inequality coincided with 1. The authors are grateful to participants in the UNDP project “Markets, the State, and the Dynam- ics of Inequality in Latin America,” coordinated by Nora Lustig and Luis Felipe López Calva, as well as to participants in seminars at the United Nations offices in New York and Mexico City, the Latin American and Caribbean Economic Association meeting in Rio de Janeiro, and the Latin American Studies Associa- tion meeting in Rio de Janeiro. We also are very grateful to Mary Kwak and anonymous reviewers for their very useful comments and suggestions and to Fedora Carbajal as well as Edith Cortés, Francisco Islas, and Mariellen Malloy Jewers for their outstanding research assistance. 2. The Gini reported in this paragraph is calculated by using total income (which includes monetary income and nonmonetary income, such as the imputed value of owner-occupied housing and auto- consumption, but does not include capital gains). The decomposition of income inequality by source pre- sented in this chapter uses current monetary income (which excludes capital gains and nonmonetary income).
    [Show full text]
  • Did NAFTA Help Mexico? an Update After 23 Years
    CEPR CENTER FOR ECONOMIC AND POLICY RESEARCH Did NAFTA Help Mexico? An Update After 23 Years By Mark Weisbrot, Lara Merling, Vitor Mello, Stephan Lefebvre, and Joseph Sammut* Updated March 2017 Center for Economic and Policy Research 1611 Connecticut Ave. NW tel: 202-293-5380 Suite 400 fax: 202-588-1356 Washington, DC 20009 http://cepr.net Mark Weisbrot is Co-Director at the Center for Economic and Policy Research (CEPR) in Washington, DC. Lara Merling is a Research Assistant, Vitor Mello is an International Program Intern, Stephan Lefebvre is a former Research Assistant, and Joseph Sammut is a former International Program Intern at CEPR. Contents Executive Summary ........................................................................................................................................... 2 Income and Growth .......................................................................................................................................... 5 Agriculture and Employment ......................................................................................................................... 14 Economic Policy and Mexican Integration with the United States Economy ....................................... 16 Conclusion ........................................................................................................................................................ 21 References ........................................................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • The Giant Sucking Sound: Did NAFTA Devour the Mexican Peso?
    J ULY /AUGUST 1996 Christopher J. Neely is a research economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Kent A. Koch provided research assistance. This article examines the relationship The Giant between NAFTA and the peso crisis of December 1994. First, the provisions of Sucking Sound: NAFTA are reviewed, and then the links between NAFTA and the peso crisis are Did NAFTA examined. Despite a blizzard of innuendo and intimation that there was an obvious Devour the link between the passage of NAFTA and Mexican Peso? the peso devaluation, NAFTA’s critics have not been clear as to what the link actually was. Examination of their argu- Christopher J. Neely ments and economic theory suggests two possibilities: that NAFTA caused the Mex- t the end of 1993 Mexico was touted ican authorities to manipulate and prop as a model for developing countries. up the value of the peso for political rea- A Five years of prudent fiscal and mone- sons or that NAFTA’s implementation tary policy had dramatically lowered its caused capital flows that brought the budget deficit and inflation rate and the peso down. Each hypothesis is investi- government had privatized many enter- gated in turn. prises that were formerly state-owned. To culminate this progress, Mexico was preparing to enter into the North American NAFTA Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) with NAFTA grew out of the U.S.–Canadian Canada and the United States. But less than Free Trade Agreement of 1988.1 It was a year later, in December 1994, investors signed by Mexico, Canada, and the United sold their peso assets, the value of the Mex- States on December 17, 1992.
    [Show full text]
  • Introduction
    1 Introduction Peter Hakim and Robert E. Litan When it came into force on January 1, 1994, the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) joined the eco- nomic futures of Canada, Mexico, and the United States. Clearly both Canada and Mexico—given their geography and markets—had been integrating with the United States well before NAFTA took effect. Indeed, the United States and Canada had signed a bilateral free trade accord six years earlier. But, with NAFTA in place, the pace of inte- gration accelerated, and systematic rules governing trade and investment along with dispute resolution mechanisms were established, and the governments assumed an active role in guiding, promoting, and managing economic rela- tions among the three countries. Moreover, the three coun- tries are increasingly viewed as a single economic entity, one with a gross domestic product (GDP) of some $10 tril- 1 2 Introduction lion, or 15 percent larger than the fifteen-country European Union (EU). What then lies ahead for North America? As it stands, NAFTA takes a narrow view of integration, focusing almost exclusively on trade and investment matters, steering clear of any new institutional, social, or development arrange- ments. NAFTA barely addresses such vital issues as immi- gration policy and labor markets, the energy sector, envi- ronmental protection, and law enforcement. Moreover, despite their trilateral relationship, the three governments of North America largely conduct business within the frame- work of two bilateral relationships, that is, between Canada and the United States and between Mexico and the United States. The governments of Canada, Mexico, and the United States now must confront the question of whether NAFTA is enough.
    [Show full text]
  • The Effects of Foreign Direct Investment in Mexico Since NAFTA
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive The Effects of Foreign Direct Investment in Mexico since NAFTA Waldkirch, Andreas Colby College 28 March 2008 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/7975/ MPRA Paper No. 7975, posted 29 Mar 2008 06:58 UTC The Effects of Foreign Direct Investment in Mexico since NAFTA∗ Andreas Waldkirch† March 2008 Abstract Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) into Mexico has increased dramatically since the inception of the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), raising questions about its effect on the Mexican economy. This paper studies the impact of FDI on industry productivity and wages over the first ten years of NAFTA, paying particular attention to the source country and destination industry of investments. It also offers a detailed description of the evolution of FDI, its components, sectoral composition, and sources from 1994-2005. There is evidence of a positive effect of FDI on productivity, particularly total factor productivity (TFP). The effect on wages is negative or zero at best, suggesting a divergence from productivity over this time period. The positive productivity effect stems largely from U.S. FDI into non-maquiladora industries, which receive over two thirds of manufacturing FDI. There is no evidence that more distant source countries have a differential effect. Consistent with theoretical expectations, FDI into maquiladoras benefits unskilled workers at the expense of skilled workers. This effect may be strong enough to dampen income inequality. Keywords: Foreign Direct Investment, Mexico, NAFTA, Productivity, Wages, Income Inequality. JEL Classification: F15, F21, F23, O15. ∗I thank seminar participants at the 4th Minnesota International Economic Development Conference, the Western Economic Association Conference in Seattle, the European Trade Study Group Conference in Athens/Greece and the North American Economics and Finance Association Winter Meetings in New Orleans and especially Sven Arndt and Galina Hale for useful comments on an earlier version of the paper.
    [Show full text]
  • Mexico-U.S-Canada Relations in the New World Order
    UCLA Chicana/o Latina/o Law Review Title Mexico-U.S-Canada Relations in the New World Order Permalink https://escholarship.org/uc/item/28q7861b Journal Chicana/o Latina/o Law Review, 12(1) ISSN 1061-8899 Author Brooks, David Publication Date 1992 DOI 10.5070/C7121021003 Peer reviewed eScholarship.org Powered by the California Digital Library University of California MEXICO-U.S.-CANADA RELATIONS IN THE NEW WORLD ORDER DAVID BROOKS t We are faced today with the most pivotal moment in this coun- try's relations with Mexico and Canada. Over the last year, we have witnessed the ongoing dialogue intended to forge a North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA). This free-trade agree- ment would be the largest and wealthiest in the world. The United States would be entering into a free trade agreement with its first and third largest trading partners, Canada and Mexico, respec- tively. This, prospectively, could have a direct impact on 350 mil- lion people in these three countries. We have heard a lot of reports on the benefits of such an arrangement from the three governments involved as well as from others who support the negotiations. We also know, despite repeated assertions by the administrations, that this deal is not only about trade, but also about lowering tariffs and other barriers. NAFTA involves something far more extensive than simply a commercial agreement. It will have a powerful impact on how the three nations of the North American continent will relate to one another, and to the world beyond, outside of the pure eco- nomic context.
    [Show full text]
  • "Mexican Meltdown: States, Markets, and Post-NAFTA Financial Turmoil" (With Maxwell Cameron)
    A revised version appears as: "Mexican Meltdown: States, Markets, and post-NAFTA Financial Turmoil" (with Maxwell Cameron). Third World Quarterly, Vol. 17, No. 5, 1996 MEXICAN MELTDOWN: STATES, MARKETS AND POST-NAFTA FINANCIAL TURMOIL Maxwell A. Cameron Associate Professor Norman Paterson School of International Affairs Carleton University, Ottawa, Ontario K1S 5B6 CANADA Tel: (613) 520-6655 Fax: (613) 520-2889 and Visiting Fellow Helen Kellogg Institute for International Studies 216 Hesburgh Center University of Notre Dame, Indiana 46556 USA Tel: (219) 631-6982 Fax: (219) 631-6717 E-Mail: [email protected] Vinod K. Aggarwal Professor University of California, Berkeley Berkeley, California, 94720 USA Tel: (510) 642-2817 Fax: (510) 642-9515 E-Mail: [email protected] September 1996 ABSTRACT The devaluation of the Mexican peso in December 1994 triggered a financial panic that required massive intervention by the United States government and the International Monetary Fund in an effort to prevent a full-scale financial collapse. This article examines the impact, causes, and policy implications of the peso crisis, as well as the reasons for the U.S.-led bailout package. It then considers the crisis in the light of three classical schools of international political economy: liberalism, mercantilism, and structuralism. The conclusions call attention to the potentially destabilising effects of deregulated financial markets, especially for countries that are heavily reliant on foreign savings, and suggests that existing institutions at the international level are inadequate for managing the problem. ABOUT THE AUTHORS Maxwell A. Cameron is Associate Professor at the Norman Paterson School of International Affairs at Carleton University and a Visiting Fellow at the Helen Kellogg Institute for International Studies at the University of Notre Dame.
    [Show full text]
  • Poverty and Inequality in Mexico
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Research Papers in Economics Serie documentos de trabajo THE DYNAMICS OF INCOME INEQUALITY IN MEXICO SINCE NAFTA Gerardo Esquivel El Colegio de México DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO Núm. IX - 2010 . The Dynamics of Income Inequality in Mexico since NAFTA Gerardo Esquivel 1 El Colegio de México This version: November 2010 Abstract: This paper reviews the pattern of income inequality in Mexico since 1994. It shows that in the past few years there has been an important reduction of income inequality in Mexico, which has almost reverted the sharp increase in inequality observed between 1984 and 1994. Using a Gini decomposition exercise we conclude that labor income, transfers and remittances have all played an important role in this process. We also argue that the equalizing effect of labor income and the reduction of wage inequality in Mexico can be explained by a structural change in Mexico‟s workforce composition in terms of education and experience. In general, we conclude that the recent reduction of inequality in Mexico is due to the interaction of both, the market and the State. 1 This paper was originally written as part of the UNDP project “Markets, the State and the Dynamics of Inequality,” coordinated by Nora Lustig and Luis Felipe López Calva. I thank participants in previous seminars at United Nations offices in New York and Mexico City, as well as participants at the Latin American and Caribbean Economic Association (LACEA) Congresses in Rio de Janeiro, Brazil and Buenos Aires, Argentina for their useful comments and suggestions.
    [Show full text]
  • Old Foods and New Consumers in Mexico Under Economic Reforms
    African Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics Volume 9 Number 1 pages 33-53 Old foods and new consumers in Mexico under economic reforms Antonio Yúnez-Naude PRECESAM, El Colegio du Mexico. E-mail: [email protected] Paper prepared for the Plenary Session: “The changing agrarian structure in Africa: lessons from South America” at the 4th International Conference of the African Association of Agricultural Economists, Hammamet, Tunisia. 1. Introduction In the 1980s, the Mexican government instituted wide-ranging market-oriented policies. With respect to the food, agriculture and rural sectors, the reforms ranged from constitutional changes to enhance private property rights in rural “communal” lands, to the elimination of price supports granted to farmers producing staple crops. Policy changes included agricultural trade liberalisation: in 1985, Mexico joined the General Agreement on Trade and Tariffs (GATT), and January 1994 saw the start of the implementation of the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA). At the same time, transitional agricultural policies were being implemented and a comprehensive social programme was initiated to alleviate rural poverty. The main objective of this paper is to evaluate the performance of agricultural and food production in Mexico during the reforms and NAFTA, as well as the consequences of this performance and of food trade liberalisation on food security, consumption patterns and food poverty. The paper is divided into six parts. Part 2 assesses major agricultural reforms and trade liberalisation under NAFTA, and their expected impacts, as well as new policies that accompanied the reforms. In Part 3, major trends in agricultural production and trade, farm size and yields during the last decades are discussed.
    [Show full text]
  • Mexican Manufacturing and Its Integration Into Global Value Chains
    Inclusive and Sustainable Industrial Development Working Paper Series WP 3 | 2016 MEXICAN MANUFACTURING AND ITS INTEGRATION INTO GLOBAL VALUE CHAINS DEPARTMENT OF POLICY RESEARCH AND STATISTICS WORKING PAPER 03/2016 Mexican manufacturing and its integration into global value chains Juan Carlos Castillo UNU-MERIT Adam Szirmai UNU-MERIT UNITED NATIONS INDUSTRIAL DEVELOPMENT ORGANIZATION Vienna, 2016 Acknowledgements We gratefully acknowledge financial support from UNIDO for the PhD project of the first author (UNIDO Specialization on Structural Change and Industrialization). We thank Bart Verspagen for advice, comments and criticisms. The designations employed, descriptions and classifications of countries, and the presentation of the material in this report do not imply the expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of the Secretariat of the United Nations Industrial Development Organization (UNIDO) concerning the legal status of any country, territory, city or area or of its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of its frontiers or boundaries, or its economic system or degree of development. The views expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect the views of the Secretariat of the UNIDO. The responsibility for opinions expressed rests solely with the authors, and publication does not constitute an endorsement by UNIDO. Although great care has been taken to maintain the accuracy of information herein, neither UNIDO nor its member States assume any responsibility for consequences which may arise from the use of the material. Terms such as “developed”, “industrialized” and “developing” are intended for statistical convenience and do not necessarily express a judgment. Any indication of, or reference to, a country, institution or other legal entity does not constitute an endorsement.
    [Show full text]
  • Primax International Journal of Commerce and Management Research (PIJCMR)
    Primax International Journal of Commerce And Management Research (PIJCMR) Your GATEWAY to World class Research • Research Papers • Articles • Case studies Primax International Journal of Commerce and Management Research No.25/A, Nagadevanahalli, Boothappa Temple Road, 80 Feet Ring Road, Jnanabharathi Post, Bangalore -56, Karnataka, India. Ph: 08971725451 Email: [email protected], [email protected] www.primaxijcmr.com Primax International Journal of Commerce and Management Research Online ISSN: 2321-3612 Managing Editor: Prof. T. Rajeswari., M.Sc.,M.A(Eng).,M.B.A.,M.A.(Soc)., Chief Editor: Dr.K.V. Ramanathan., M.Com.,M.Phil.,M.B.A.,P.D.B.S.,Ph.D., Professor- Primax Research Center Bangalore. Coordinator: Dr. V. Selvaraj Former, Head & Associate Professor, Nehru Memorial College (Autonomous),Tiruchirappalli Dr. M. Muthu Gopalakrishnan Associate Professor, Acharya Bangalore B School, Bangalore. Dr. N. Giri Babu, Associate Professor, Sri Venkateswara College of Engineering & Technology, Chittoor. Publisher: Primax Commerce and Management Research Academy, Bangalore-56 (Karnataka Reg.: 48/159/CE/0103/2013) Issue: Special Issue, November 2015 COPYRIGHT: 1. All rights reserved. And Copyright © 2013, Primax Commerce and Management Research Academy. 2. Reproduction of any part of this Journal in the whole or in part without written permission from the publisher is prohibited . 3. All rights reserved ISSN: 2321-3604 Contact: Prof. T. Rajeswari., M.Sc.,M.A(Eng.).,M.B.A.,M.A(Soc) Founder and Managing Editor, Primax Commerce and Management Research
    [Show full text]
  • English Industrialists Supported Universal Education at the End of the 19Th Century As a Way to Increase Their Ability to Compete with French and German Companies
    NO GROWTH WITHOUT EQUITY? Inequality, Interests, and Competition in Mexico Santiago Levy and Michael Walton Editors NO GROWTH WITHOUT EQUITY? INEQUALITY, INTERESTS, AND COMPETITION IN MEXICO NO GROWTH WITHOUT EQUITY? INEQUALITY, INTERESTS, AND COMPETITION IN MEXICO Santiago Levy and Michael Walton Editors A copublication of Palgrave Macmillan and the World Bank ©2009 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank 1818 H Street NW Washington DC 20433 Telephone: 202-473-1000 Internet: www.worldbank.org E-mail: [email protected] All rights reserved 01 02 03 04 12 11 10 09 A copublication of The World Bank and Palgrave Macmillan. Palgrave Macmillan Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire RG21 6XS and 175 Fifth Avenue, New York, N. Y. 10010 Companies and representatives throughout the world Palgrave Macmillan is the global academic imprint of the Palgrave Macmillan division of St. Martin’s Press, LLC and of Palgrave Macmillan Ltd. Macmillan® is a registered trademark in the United States, United Kingdom and other countries. Palgrave® is a registered trademark in the European Union and other countries. This volume is a product of the staff of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank. The fi ndings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this volume do not necessarily refl ect the views of the Executive Directors of The World Bank or the governments they represent. The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply any judgement on the part of The World Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries.
    [Show full text]