The Neoliberal and the Powerlessness of Ideas
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Load more
Recommended publications
-
Liam Brunt – Teaching Material – Keynesian Revolution 1 Week 4
Liam Brunt – Teaching Material – Keynesian Revolution Week 4. The Keynesian Revolution. What were the major theoretical and practical obstacles to the adoption of Keynesian demand management to cure unemployment in the inter-war years? Would it have been effective? Was there a ‘Keynesian Revolution’ in economic thought and policy in the 1940s and 1950s? Readings. Peden, G. C., ‘The “Treasury View” on Public Works and Employment in the Inter-war Period,’ Economic History Review (1984). Outlines the theoretical orthodoxy against which Keynes rebelled. Middleton, R. C., ‘The Treasury in the 1930s: Political and Administrative Constraints to the Acceptance of the “New” Economics,’ Oxford Economic Papers (1982). McKibbin, R. I., ‘The Economic Policy of the Second Labour Government, 1929-31,’ Past and Present (1975). [Number 68, p96-102]. A useful look at the international reception of Keynesian policies. Floud, R., and D. N. McCloskey, The Economic History of Britain since 1700, vol. 2 (1860-1939). (Second edition, 1994). [Chapter 14 (Thomas)]. Quantitative analysis of the impact of plausible Keynesian policies. Booth, A. R., ‘The “Keynesian Revolution” in Economic Policy-making,’ Economic History Review (1983). See also the comment by Tomlinson, Economic History Review (1984). Discusses the definition and timing of the Keynesian revolution. Rollings, N., ‘British Budgetary Policy, 1945-54: a “Keynesian Revolution”?’ Economic History Review (1988). A strong rebuttal of Booth. Note: if you are unsure about the Keynesian model of the labour market then refer to Levacic and Rebmann, p70-5, 86-93. 1 Liam Brunt – Teaching Material – Keynesian Revolution KEYNESIANISM. The Central Features Of Keynesianism. 1. The economy was not self-adjusting and the government should use active policy to bring the economy back to full employment in a recession. -
Nine Lives of Neoliberalism
A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Plehwe, Dieter (Ed.); Slobodian, Quinn (Ed.); Mirowski, Philip (Ed.) Book — Published Version Nine Lives of Neoliberalism Provided in Cooperation with: WZB Berlin Social Science Center Suggested Citation: Plehwe, Dieter (Ed.); Slobodian, Quinn (Ed.); Mirowski, Philip (Ed.) (2020) : Nine Lives of Neoliberalism, ISBN 978-1-78873-255-0, Verso, London, New York, NY, https://www.versobooks.com/books/3075-nine-lives-of-neoliberalism This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/215796 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative -
Was There a Methodological Keynesian Revolution
Was There a (Methodological) Keynesian Revolution? Published in B Dimand, R Mundell and A Vercelli (eds), Keynes’s General Theory After Seventy Years. London: Palgrave Macmillan for the International Economic Association, 2010, 268-86. Sheila C Dow Department of Economics University of Stirling Stirling FK9 4LA Scotland, UK Tel: +44-1786-467474 Fax: +44-1786-467469 e-mail: [email protected] February 2008 I believe myself to be writing a book on economic theory which will largely revolutionise - not, I suppose, at once but in the course of the next ten years – the way the world thinks about economic problems (Keynes, 1935). 1. Introduction The purpose of this paper is to examine whether, how far, and in what sense we might say that there has been a Keynesian revolution at the level of methodology. This involves an interpretation of Keynes’s expression ‘the way the world thinks about economic problems’ as referring, not just to the content of economics, but also to the mode of thought and specific methodology employed in addressing that content. It is hard to separate content from methodology; at least here we put the accent on methodology. The notion of a revolution in economic thought was given focus in the 1960s by the work of Thomas Kuhn (1962), who characterized the history of scientific thought more generally in terms of revolutionary transitions from one paradigm to the next. The notion of a paradigm is helpful in that it applies to scientific thought at a variety of levels. Kuhn’s thesis was that scientific thought develops within scientific communities, which have shared foundations in terms of understanding of reality and principles for building knowledge, and thus methodology. -
Keynesian, New Keynesian and New Classical Economics Author(S): B
View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Columbia University Academic Commons Keynesian, New Keynesian and New Classical Economics Author(s): B. Greenwald and J. E. Stiglitz Source: Oxford Economic Papers, New Series, Vol. 39, No. 1 (Mar., 1987), pp. 119-133 Published by: Oxford University Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2663132 . Accessed: 29/04/2013 13:45 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Oxford University Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Oxford Economic Papers. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 128.59.62.83 on Mon, 29 Apr 2013 13:45:43 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions OxfordEconomic Papers 39 (1987), 119-132 KEYNESIAN, NEW KEYNESIAN AND NEW CLASSICAL ECONOMICS By B. GREENWALD and J. E. STIGLITZ' 1. Introduction FOR more than two centuries, there have been two opposing views of the capitalist economy. One stresses its virtues, and the efficiency with which prices carry information between consumers and producers, and allocate resources. The other spotlights the shortcomingsof the market system, and particularlyits episodes of massive unemployment of capital and labour. -
Reflections on the History and Enduring Relevance of Keynes’ Economics Investigación Económica, Vol
Investigación Económica ISSN: 0185-1667 [email protected] Facultad de Economía México Palleya, Thomas The General Theory at 80: Reflections on the history and enduring relevance of Keynes’ economics Investigación Económica, vol. LXXVI, núm. 301, julio-septiembre, 2017, pp. 87-101 Facultad de Economía Distrito Federal, México Available in: http://www.redalyc.org/articulo.oa?id=60155349003 How to cite Complete issue Scientific Information System More information about this article Network of Scientific Journals from Latin America, the Caribbean, Spain and Portugal Journal's homepage in redalyc.org Non-profit academic project, developed under the open access initiative Investigación Económica, vol. LXXVI, núm. 301, julio-septiembre de 2017, pp. 87-101. The General Theory at 80: Reflections on the history and enduring relevance of Keynes’ economics* Thomas Palleya Abstract This paper reflects on the history and enduring relevance of Keynes’ economics. Keynes unleashed a devastating critique of classical macroeconomics and introduced a new replacement schema that defines macroeconomics. The success of the Keynesian revolution triggered a counter-revolution that restored the classical tradition and now enforces a renewed classical monopoly. That monopoly has provided the intellectual foundations for neoliberalism which has produced economic and political conditions echoing the 1930s. Openness to Keynesian ideas seems to fluctuate with conditions, and current conditions are conducive to revival of the Keynesian revolution. However, a revival will have to overcome the renewed classical monopoly. Key words: Keynes, General Theory, Keynesian revolution, Classical economics, classical counter-revolution. JEL Classification: B1, B2, E0, E12. Resumen Este artículo reflexiona en torno a la historia y permanencia de la economía de Key- nes. -
Employment in the Keynesian and Neoliberal Universe: Theoretical Transformations and Political Correlations
Munich Personal RePEc Archive Employment in the Keynesian and neoliberal universe: theoretical transformations and political correlations Ioannidis, Yiorgos University of Crete May 2011 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/45062/ MPRA Paper No. 45062, posted 15 Mar 2013 08:10 UTC Employment in the Keynesian and neoliberal universe: theoretical transformations and political correlations Ioannidis Yiorgos Paper prepared for CUA’s (Commission on Urban Anthropology) Annual Conference, “Market Vs Society? Human principles and economic rationale in changing times”, Corinth 27-29 May 2011 Abstract The question this paper poses relates to the role of economic theories in gaining wider support around political agendas. That is their ability to describe a problem in such a way, so that the “answer” would appear not as a political demand in favor of one class, but as a prerequisite for the general well being. The main argument is that in the context of Keynesian economics, labour cost has been set in the periphery of the theory, allowing labour relations to become a subject of social-political regulation. By contrast, neoclassical economic theory and its successors place the cost of labour at the core of the theory, which in turn means that any attempt to regulate labour relations by non- economic criteria undermines the common wellbeing. Neither the first nor the second theoretical setting predetermines or abolishes class and political conflicts. But they both produce general attitudes with political consequences. Keywords: employment theory, unemployment theory, political agendas In 1944 Karl Polanyi (2001 [1944]: 159) wrote that “class interests offer only a limited explanation of long-run movements in society. -
After Keynesian Macroeconomics (P
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly R6ViCW , Spring 1979 # * S 3 ^ £c After Keynesian Macroeconomics (P. n \ Cc;.%. ^SERsJt ^ ^ A Cloudy Future for Minnesota's Businesses (P. nf District Conditions (p. 24) Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review vol. 3, no. 2 This publication primarily presents economic research aimed at improving policymaking by the Federal Reserve System and other governmental authorities. Produced in the Research Department. Edited by Arthur J. Rolnick, Kathleen S. Rolfe, and Alan Struthers, Jr. Graphic design by Phil Swenson and charts drawn by Mary K. Steffenhagen, Graphic Services Department. Address requests for additional copies to the Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank, Minneapolis, Minnesota 55480. The views expressed herein are those of the authors Articles may be reprinted if the source is credited and the Research and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Department is provided with copies of reprints. Bank of Minneapolis or the Federal Reserve System. After Keynesian Macroeconomics* Robert E. Lucas, Jr. Thomas J. Sargent Professor of Economics Adviser, Research Department University of Chicago Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and Professor of Economics University of Minnesota For the applied economist, the confident and appar- ments involved) to other advanced countries and in ently successful application of Keynesian principles many cases have been amplified. These events did to economic policy which occurred in the United not arise from a reactionary reversion to -
LAWRENCE R. KLEIN Is the Founder of Wharton Econometric Forecasting Associates, and Former Chairman of the Scientific Advisory Board
Upjohn Institute Press [The State of Economic Science] Lawrence Robert Klein University of Pennsylvania Chapter 3 (pp. 41-58) in: The State of Economic Science: Views of Six Nobel Laureates Werner Sichel, ed. Kalamazoo, MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research, 1989 10.17848/9780880995962.ch3 Copyright ©1989. W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research. All rights reserved. LAWRENCE R. KLEIN is the founder of Wharton Econometric Forecasting Associates, and former Chairman of the Scientific Advisory Board. He is also a principal investigator for Project LINK, an interna tional research group for the statistical study of world trade and payments. Professor Klein earned a B. A. degree from the University of Califor nia, Berkeley, and a Ph.D. degree from MIT. He has been awarded about twenty honorary degrees from universities in the United States and several foreign nations. He has taught at the University of Pennsylvania for the past thirty years. Before joining the Pennsylvania faculty he was associated with the University of Chicago, the National Bureau of Economic Research, the University of Michigan, and Oxford Universi ty. While at the University of Pennsylvania he has served as visiting professor at several U.S. universities including the University of Califor nia at Berkeley, Princeton, Stanford, and City University of New York and at foreign centers of learning in Japan, Austria, and Denmark. Dr. Klein is a past president of the American Economic Association, the Eastern Economic Association, and the Econometric Society. In 1959, he was awarded the John Bates Clark Medal by the American Economic Association. He is a member of the American Academy of Arts and Sciences, the American Philosophical Society, and the National Academy of Sciences. -
The Origins and Evolution of Progressive Economics Part Seven of the Progressive Tradition Series
AP PHOTO/FILE AP This January 1935 photo shows a mural depicting phases of the New Deal The Origins and Evolution of Progressive Economics Part Seven of the Progressive Tradition Series Ruy Teixeira and John Halpin March 2011 WWW.AMERICANPROGRESS.ORG The Origins and Evolution of Progressive Economics Part Seven of the Progressive Tradition Series Ruy Teixeira and John Halpin March 2011 With the rise of the contemporary progressive movement and the election of President Barack Obama in 2008, there is extensive public interest in better understanding the ori- gins, values, and intellectual strands of progressivism. Who were the original progressive thinkers and activists? Where did their ideas come from and what motivated their beliefs and actions? What were their main goals for society and government? How did their ideas influence or diverge from alternative social doctrines? How do their ideas and beliefs relate to contemporary progressivism? The Progressive Tradition Series from the Center for American Progress traces the devel- opment of progressivism as a social and political tradition stretching from the late 19th century reform efforts to the current day. The series is designed primarily for educational and leadership development purposes to help students and activists better understand the foundations of progressive thought and its relationship to politics and social movements. Although the Progressive Studies Program has its own views about the relative merit of the various values, ideas, and actors discussed within the progressive tradition, the essays included in the series are descriptive and analytical rather than opinion based. We envision the essays serving as primers for exploring progressivism and liberalism in more depth through core texts—and in contrast to the conservative intellectual tradition and canon. -
Who Is Afraid of Neoliberalism? a Comment on Mirowski
Who is afraid of Neoliberalism? A comment on Mirowski While the Neoliberal movement’s concerns extend into a broad political reorganization of society, it remains intimately connected with neoclassical economic thought Matías Vernengo The idea of a Neoliberal Thought Collective (NTC) being a “completely different school of thought” from neoclassical economics is not quite correct. It is true that Neoliberalism transcends the more limited scope of neoclassical economics with a much broader preoccupation with the political reorganization of society. On the other hand, it is hard to think of any Neoliberal author cited by Mirowski that does not fall within the neoclassical school. Neoliberalism is a term that has suffered the semantic saturation effect. It has been used so often in so many different contexts that it has almost lost its meaning. Philip Mirowski has provided an important reappraisal of the term Neoliberalism and its concealed and unacknowledged relevance intellectual relevance in economics. Mirowski (2014) correctly noted that the widespread confusion about the term Neoliberal has been, to some extent, fabricated and propagated by Neoliberals themselves. The notion that Neoliberalism does not exist has been facilitated by the use of the term by many left of center intellectuals to refer to basically anything that they dislike, “a catch-all short hand for the horrors associated with globalization and recurring financial crises” as argued by Stedman-Jones (2012: p. 2). In particular, Mirowski (2014: p. 8) points out that one should not equate Neoliberalism with neoclassical economics. Mirowski definition of Neoliberalism is based on the sociology of science. He analyzes a community with a shared set of core ideas in close intellectual interaction, to which he refers as the Neoliberal Thought Collective (NTC). -
A Brief Introduction to Post Keynesian Macroeconomics
39. Jahrgang (2013), Heft 4 Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft A Brief Introduction to Post Keynesian Macroeconomics J. E. King 1. Introduction I begin by setting out the core of Post Keynesian macroeconomics, using six propositions asserted by Tony Thirlwall and drawing some important conclusions from them. I then distinguish three schools within Post Keynesian theory: the fundamentalist Keynesian approach taken by Paul Davidson, the Kaleckian variant represented by Eckhard Hein, and Hyman Minsky’s financial instability hypothesis. I take note of both their differ- ences and their very significant points of agreement. I continue by identify- ing what Post Keynesian macroeconomics is not, and outlining some very substantial criticisms of both “Old Keynesian” and “New Keynesian” the- ory. There follows an historical interlude, in which I sketch the develop- ment of Post Keynesian theory in Cambridge (UK) and the United States in the 1950s and 1960s and summarise the contributions of two eminent Austrian theorists, Josef Steindl and Kurt Rothschild. I continue by discussing the distinctive Post Keynesian position on ques- tions of macroeconomic policy, focussing on monetary and fiscal policy, the regulation of prices and incomes, and the reform of the international monetary system. I then apply these principles to explaining the Global Fi- nancial Crisis that began in 2007 and suggesting some Post Keynesian policy proposals that might make similar crises less likely in the future. I conclude by discussing the relationship between Post Keynesianism and three other schools of heterodox economic theory: Marxism, institutiona- lism and behavioural economics. Space constraints prevent me from discussing the relationship between Post Keynesianism and six other heterodox schools: feminism, ecological economics, evolutionary economics, Sraffian theory, social economics, and Austrian theory (of the Hayek-von Mises variety). -
How Germany's Anti-Keynesianism Has Brought Europe to Its Knees
Working Paper No. 886 How Germany’s Anti-Keynesianism Has Brought Europe to Its Knees by Jörg Bibow Levy Economics Institute of Bard College* March 2017 * Comments on an earlier draft by Hélène de Largentaye and James Trevithick are gratefully acknowledged. The Levy Economics Institute Working Paper Collection presents research in progress by Levy Institute scholars and conference participants. The purpose of the series is to disseminate ideas to and elicit comments from academics and professionals. Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, founded in 1986, is a nonprofit, nonpartisan, independently funded research organization devoted to public service. Through scholarship and economic research it generates viable, effective public policy responses to important economic problems that profoundly affect the quality of life in the United States and abroad. Levy Economics Institute P.O. Box 5000 Annandale-on-Hudson, NY 12504-5000 http://www.levyinstitute.org Copyright © Levy Economics Institute 2017 All rights reserved ISSN 1547-366X ABSTRACT This paper investigates the (lack of any lasting) impact of John Maynard Keynes’s General Theory on economic policymaking in Germany. The analysis highlights the interplay between economic history and the history of ideas in shaping policymaking in postwar (West) Germany. The paper argues that Germany learned the wrong lessons from its own history and misread the true sources of its postwar success. Monetary mythology and the Bundesbank, with its distinctive anti-inflationary bias, feature prominently in this collective odyssey. The analysis shows that the crisis of the euro today is largely the consequence of Germany’s peculiar anti-Keynesianism. Keywords: John Maynard Keynes; Mercantilism; Economic and Monetary Union; Euro Crisis JEL Classifications: B31, E30, E58, E65, N14 1 1.