The Politics of Housing in South Africa by Zachary B. Levenson A
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
1 Representation and Recognition: The Politics of Housing in South Africa By Zachary B. Levenson A dissertation submitted in partial satisfaction of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Sociology in the Graduate Division of the University of California, Berkeley Committee in charge: Professor Michael Burawoy, Chair Professor Dylan Riley Professor Gillian Hart Professor Michael Watts Summer 2018 2 Representation and Recognition: The Politics of Housing in South Africa © 2018 by Zachary B. Levenson 1 Abstract Representation and Recognition: The Politics of Housing in South Africa by Zachary B. Levenson Doctor of Philosophy in Sociology University of California, Berkeley Professor Michael Burawoy, Chair How do postcolonies manage the sudden urbanization of surplus populations in the years following democratization? In post-apartheid South Africa, the government has delivered more free, single-family homes than any other democracy in modern history; yet over the same quarter century, the number of informal settlements has grown more than nine-fold. During the apartheid period, the South African state could simply shift populations at will. But the post-apartheid state does not have this option, as it must simultaneously resolve its housing crisis and reproduce its own legitimacy as a democracy in the eyes of its newly integrated, racialized subjects. As new informal settlements emerge – what I call land occupations – city governments must manage the rapid urbanization of surplus populations without appearing authoritarian. My dissertation explores municipal strategies for managing land occupations in post-apartheid Cape Town. I conducted 17 months of fieldwork combining participant observation, interviews, and archival research in two such occupations in Mitchell’s Plain, Cape Town’s second largest township. Through a careful study of eviction targeting, I demonstrate empirically how squatters’ informal politics affect the outcome of municipal urban policies. One of these occupations, Rivenland, began with a thousand Colored squatters erecting shacks on a publicly owned field far from any major thoroughfare. They did so in a Colored area, and many of them were supporters of the majority political party in Mitchell’s Plain. No nearby neighbors demanded their removal. By contrast, a second occupation, Holfield, began just a couple of kilometers down the road on two contiguous plots of private property. After a few dozen squatters built shacks, hundreds more arrived every day until there were soon 6000 residents. Most of them were Black in a Colored area, and many of them were presumed to be hostile to the ruling party. Holfield sits along the road connecting one of Mitchell’s Plain’s middle class neighborhoods to the city center, and this neighborhood’s residents mobilized continually to demand Holfield’s eradication. After a year, Rivenland was evicted, but Holfield was allowed by the High Court to stay put. Today it contains more than 8000 people by the City’s count. How should we understand this counterintuitive outcome? This is where I turn to residents’ own politics as a means of explanation. In Holfield, residents were able to organize a coherent settlement committee prior to their eviction hearing. This largely had to do with the way that their leaders framed the occupation as a social 2 movement, with unified action articulated as the most strategic approach to obtaining official toleration. By contrast, the Rivenland occupation was mired in factionalism, with residents aligning with outside organizations – charities, NGOs, political parties – and competing with one another for access to their lawyers and the court. They did this because their occupation was framed as the distribution of plots of land to potential homeowners; this is what I call the politics of petty proprietorship. The extent of this infighting prompted judges to view the Rivenland occupation as opportunistic. The same court ruled the Holfield occupation legitimate, describing the occupiers as “homeless people in need.” In order to explain this contrast, I develop the concepts of struggles over representation and struggles over recognition. Without the resolution of struggles over representation and the formation of a unified settlement committee, factionalism will persist, and this, I argue, means that eviction is the most likely outcome. But these factions do not merely reflect preexisting divisions along lines of race, religion, or neighborhood; it is precisely through the formation of representative committees – through the process of representation – that divisions emerge and are concretized. Struggles over representation directly impact how occupations are viewed by the municipal government and High Court judges. When struggles over representation are resolved, judges are likely to recognize occupiers as part of a legible and legitimate population. But when struggles over representation are left unresolved as in Rivenland, judges will fail to recognize occupiers as having any legitimate moral claim to the land. Instead, they will likely view them not as a coherent population, but as individual opportunists attempting to bypass the government’s housing distribution program. In short, the moralizing distinction between homeless people in need on the one hand, and opportunistic queue jumpers on the other, emerges from struggles over representation. In bringing the insights of political sociology to bear upon urban studies, I break with the prevailing explanation that evictions are most likely in sites planned for development and are driven solely by profit motive. Instead, I conceive of the state not as a coherent institutional entity that simply enacts policies upon populations, but instead as a social relation. The government did not simply design eviction policies and then implement them upon populations; it was through complex relations with residents that eviction outcomes were determined. Only in this way – that is, by seeing the state as a relation, as the condensation of a relationship of forces – can we begin to understand how it was that squatters were evicted from Rivenland and not from Holfield. i Table of Contents Preface: Two Land Occupations, One Eviction iii Acknowledgements xiii Chapter 1: Introduction 1 Chapter 2: Civil Society and the Politics of City-States 28 Chapter 3: Rivenland: The Politics of Petty Proprietorship 50 Chapter 4: Holfield: Exit Civil Society 78 Chapter 5: Conclusion 108 References 125 Appendix: Notes on Data and Methods 147 ii “In actual reality civil society and State are one and the same.” – Antonio Gramsci, Prison Notebooks (1971 [1933]:160) “Daily life masks the state level while referring the reflective consciousness to it. Likewise, security measures, which are simultaneously fictitious and real, refer to menaces that are no less fictitious and no less real. Daily life conceals and contains the state, but the two taken together mask the tragic element they contain.” – Henri Lefebvre, Critique of Everyday Life, Vol. 3 (2014 [1981]:833) “The State is neither the instrumental depository (object) of a power- essence held by the dominant class, nor a subject possessing a quantity of power equal to the quantity it takes from the classes which face it: the State is rather the strategic site of organization of the dominant class in relation to the dominated classes. It is a site and a centre of the exercise of power, but it possesses no power of its own.” – Nicos Poulantzas, State, Power, Socialism (1978:148) iii Preface: Two Land Occupations, One Eviction Rivenland1 is a municipally owned field located on the periphery of Cape Town’s second largest township, Mitchell’s Plain (See Figure 1). When South Africa was formally segregated under apartheid, townships were urban areas reserved for any populations defined as “non-white.” While democratization entailed de jure desegregation, South African cities remain highly segregated, with peripherally located townships still nearly entirely non-white. Today they contain tens of thousands, if not hundreds of thousands, of residents, and each contains a number of distinct neighborhoods. In the particular neighborhood in which Rivenland is located, the unemployment rate has been climbing at a faster pace than elsewhere, though the official rate for the entire township is higher than South Africa’s average of nearly 27 percent. Local politicians in this ward have been promising new affordable housing developments for nearly two decades now, but they remain just that: promises. In the immediate vicinity of Rivenland, there isn’t much in the way of middle class housing. There are some working class homes constructed by the late apartheid state a few minutes walk from the field and quite a few more another couple hundred meters away, but it would be a stretch to claim that Rivenland abuts a sizable residential area. Plus, the homes that are nearby are located in the poorest section of the poorest ward in the entire township. Rivenland is also fairly out of sight. In order to get there, I would drive a kilometer or so down a long road flanked by trash-strewn fields on both sides. These fields stood as buffers between a nature reserve on the township’s southern coast and the residential area above the road, but it could hardly be construed as a major thoroughfare. Indeed, it abruptly ended in a cul-de- sac at Rivenland. The only reason there was a road at all is because the field is adjacent to the final stop on Cape Town’s commuter rail line connecting this township to the city center. While there are plenty of other public transportation options in the city, Metrorail is the cheapest (albeit least reliable) option. Lines are frequently down, cars are overcrowded and dangerous, and this line in particular is a last resort for many commuters. Most of my contacts in the neighborhood would rather suffer the indignity of asking for a few rands for a shared taxi to town than risk the ride on Metrorail, which may or may not actually get them to work. A recent Sunday Times headline put it quite aptly: “Metrorail’s Own Stats Show How Bad Its Service Is” (Payne and Washinyira 2017).