City from Wikipedia, the Free Encyclopedia for Other Uses, See City

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

City from Wikipedia, the Free Encyclopedia for Other Uses, See City City From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia For other uses, see City (disambiguation). 1908 Map of Piraeus, the port of Athens, showing the grid plan of the city "The Ideal City" of the Renaissance by Fra Carnevale. Oil and tempera painting (c1480). Panel in the Walters Art Museum A city is a relatively large and permanent settlement.[1][2] Although there is no agreement on how a city is distinguished from a town within general English language meanings, many cities have a particular administrative, legal, or historical status based on local law. For example, in the American state of Massachusetts an article of incorporation approved by the local state legislature distinguishes a city government from a town. In the United Kingdomand parts of the Commonwealth of Nations, a city is usually a settlement with a royal charter.[1]The belief in this distinction is also common in England, where the presence of a cathedral is thought by many to distinguish a 'city' (sometimes called a 'cathedral city') from a 'town' (which has a parish church[citation needed]); the belief is incorrect (Chelmsford, for example, became a city only in 2012, but had a cathedral for most of the 20th century). Cities generally have complex systems for sanitation, utilities, land usage, housing, andtransportation. The concentration of development greatly facilitates interaction between people and businesses, benefiting both parties in the process. A big city or metropolis usually has associated suburbs and exurbs. Such cities are usually associated with metropolitan areas andurban areas, creating numerous business commuters traveling to urban centers for employment. Once a city expands far enough to reach another city, this region can be deemed a conurbationor megalopolis. Contents [hide] 1 Origins 2 Geography 3 History o 3.1 Ancient times o 3.2 Middle Ages o 3.3 Early modern o 3.4 Industrial age 4 External effects 5 Distinction between cities and towns o 5.1 Argentina o 5.2 Armenia o 5.3 Australia o 5.4 Azerbaijan o 5.5 Belarus o 5.6 Bangladesh o 5.7 Belgium o 5.8 Brazil o 5.9 Bulgaria o 5.10 Canada o 5.11 China (People's Republic of China) o 5.12 Chile o 5.13 Colombia o 5.14 Denmark o 5.15 Egypt o 5.16 France o 5.17 Finland o 5.18 Germany o 5.19 Greece o 5.20 Hong Kong o 5.21 Iceland o 5.22 India o 5.23 Indonesia o 5.24 Iran o 5.25 Iraq o 5.26 Ireland o 5.27 Israel o 5.28 Italy o 5.29 Kazakhstan o 5.30 Japan o 5.31 Malaysia o 5.32 Mexico o 5.33 Netherlands o 5.34 Nigeria o 5.35 New Zealand o 5.36 Norway o 5.37 Pakistan o 5.38 Philippines o 5.39 Poland o 5.40 Portugal o 5.41 Romania o 5.42 Russia o 5.43 Singapore o 5.44 South Africa o 5.45 South Korea o 5.46 South Sudan o 5.47 Sweden o 5.48 Taiwan (Republic of China) o 5.49 Turkey o 5.50 Ukraine o 5.51 United Kingdom o 5.52 United States o 5.53 Venezuela o 5.54 Vietnam 6 Global cities 7 Inner city 8 21st century 9 See also 10 References 11 External links Origins[edit] There is insufficient evidence to assert what conditions gave rise to the first cities. Some theorists, however, have speculated on what they consider suitable pre-conditions, and basic mechanisms that might have been important driving forces. The conventional view holds that cities first formed after the Neolithic revolution. The Neolithic revolution brought agriculture, which made denser human populations possible, thereby supporting city development.[3] The advent of farming encouraged hunter-gatherers to abandon nomadic lifestyles and to settle near others who lived by agricultural production. The increased population- density encouraged by farming and the increased output of food per unit of land created conditions that seem more suitable for city-like activities. In his book, Cities and Economic Development, Paul Bairoch takes up this position in his argument that agricultural activity appears necessary before true cities can form. According to Vere Gordon Childe, for a settlement to qualify as a city, it must have enough surplus of raw materials to support trade and a relatively large population.[4] Bairoch points out that, due to sparse population densities that would have persisted in pre-Neolithic, hunter-gatherer societies, the amount of land that would be required to produce enough food for subsistence and trade for a large population would make it impossible to control the flow of trade. To illustrate this point, Bairoch offers an example: "Western Europe during the pre-Neolithic, [where] the density must have been less than 0.1 person per square kilometer".[5] Using this population density as a base for calculation, and allotting 10% of food towards surplus for trade and assuming that city dwellers do no farming, he calculates that "...to maintain a city with a population of 1,000, and without taking the cost of transportation into account, an area of 100,000 square kilometers would have been required. When the cost of transportation is taken into account, the figure rises to 200,000 square kilometers ...".[5] Bairoch noted that this is roughly the size of Great Britain. The urban theorist Jane Jacobs suggests that city-formation preceded the birth of agriculture, but this view is not widely accepted.[6] In his book City Economics, Brendan O'Flaherty asserts "Cities could persist—as they have for thousands of years—only if their advantages offset the disadvantages" (O'Flaherty 2005, p. 12). O'Flaherty illustrates two similar attracting advantages known as increasing returns to scale and economies of scale, which are concepts normally associated with firms. Their applications are seen in more basic economic systems as well. Increasing returns to scale occurs when "doubling all inputs more than doubles the output [and] an activity has economies of scale if doubling output less than doubles cost" (O'Flaherty 2005, pp. 572–573). To offer an example of these concepts, O'Flaherty makes use of "one of the oldest reasons why cities were built: military protection" (O'Flaherty 2005, p. 13). In this example, the inputs are anything that would be used for protection (e.g., a wall) and the output is the area protected and everything of value contained in it. O'Flaherty then asks that we suppose the protected area is square, and each hectare inside it has the same value of protection. The advantage is expressed as: (O'Flaherty 2005, p. 13) (1) , where O is the output (area protected) and s stands for the length of a side. This equation shows that output is proportional to the square of the length of a side. The inputs depend on the length of the perimeter: (2) , where I stands for the quantity of inputs. This equation shows that the perimeter is proportional to the length of a side. So there are increasing returns to scale: (3) . This equation (solving for in (1) and substituting in (2)) shows that with twice the inputs, you produce quadruple the output. Also, economies of scale: (4) . This equation (solving for in equation (3)) shows that the same output requires less input. "Cities, then, economize on protection, and so protection against marauding barbarian armies is one reason why people have come together to live in cities ..." (O'Flaherty 2005, p. 13). Similarly, "Are Cities Dying?", a paper by Harvard economist Edward L. Glaeser, delves into similar reasons for city formation: reduced transport costs for goods, people, and ideas. Discussing the benefits of proximity, Glaeser claims that if you double a city size, workers have a ten-percent increase in earnings. Glaeser furthers his argument by stating that bigger cities do not pay more for equal productivity than in a smaller city, so it is reasonable to assume that workers become more productive if they move to a city twice the size as they initially worked in. However, the workers do not benefit much from the ten-percent wage increase, because it is recycled back into the higher cost of living in a bigger city. They do gain other benefits from living in cities, though. A map dating 1669 showing the location of Multan, Pakistan Geography[edit] Map of Haarlem, the Netherlands, of around 1550 showing the city completely surrounded by a city wall and defensive canal, with its square shape inspired by Jerusalem City planning has seen many different schemes for how a city should look. The most commonly seen pattern is the grid, used for thousands of years in China, independently invented byAlexander the Great's city planner Dinocrates of Rhodes and favoured by the Romans, while almost a rule in parts of pre-Columbian America. Derry, begun in 1613, was the first planned city in Ireland, with the walls being completed five years later. The central diamond within a walled city with four gates was considered a good design for defence. The grid pattern was widely copied in the colonies of British North America. The Ancient Greeks often gave their colonies around the Mediterranean a grid plan. One of the best examples is the city ofPriene. This city had different specialized districts, much as is seen in modern city planning today. Fifteen centuries earlier, the Indus Valley Civilization was using grids in such cities as Mohenjo-Daro. In medieval times there was evidence of a preference for linear planning. Good examples are the cities established by various rulers in the south of France and city expansions in old Dutch and Flemish cities.
Recommended publications
  • World Intellectual Property Report 2019
    Chapter 2 Global networks of innovation hotspots For much of the 20th century, multinational Starting in the 1980s and 1990s, the situation changed. companies (MNCs) from high-income countries The creation of new scientific and technological knowl­ restricted their foreign-based research and edge increasingly required interaction between insti­ development (R&D) operations to other rich tutions and organizations, whether public or private, economies, notably the U.S., Western European national or multinational, irrespective of their location. countries and, later, Japan. This was in marked Gradually, China, India, Eastern Europe and other contrast to the trend in manufacturing activities, middle­income economies gained in importance both which saw increasing outsourcing from richer to as targets for R&D­oriented foreign direct invest­ middle-income and developing economies.1 ment (FDI) by multinational firms and as sources of new knowledge. The rising need for complex and specialized knowledge and technological interaction at both national and international level has resulted – paradoxically – in both geographical concentration and dispersion of innova­ tion creation, as highlighted in Chapter 1. On the one hand, organizations have sought to locate innovation activities and interactions wherever high quality and lower costs are available. On the other, market forces, economies of scale and the need for more face­to­ face communication and multidisciplinary interaction, because of the complexity of the interactions, have pulled in the direction of geographical proximity. Global innovation networks have been a key centrifugal force in the geographical distribution of knowledge­ creation activities. Knowledge­seeking FDI does not target whole countries, but specific locations within them.
    [Show full text]
  • ART and ARCHAEOLOGY Vocabulary ART and ARCHAEOLOGY Vocabulary Version 1.1 (Last Updated: 2018-01-22)
    - Institute for Scientific and Technical Information - ART and ARCHAEOLOGY Vocabulary ART and ARCHAEOLOGY Vocabulary Version 1.1 (Last updated: 2018-01-22) Controlled vocabulary used for indexing bibliographical records for the "Art and Archaeology" FRANCIS database (1972-2015, http://pascal-francis.inist.fr/ ). This resource contains 1960 entries grouped into 133 collections. A French version of this resource is also available. The resource is browsable online on the terminological portal Loterre: https://www.loterre.fr Legend • Syn: Synonym. • → : Corresponding Preferred Term. • FR: French Preferred Term. • ES: Spanish Preferred Term. • DE: German Preferred Term. • BT: Broader Term. • SC: Semantic Category. • DO: Subject Field. • URI: Concept's URI (link to the online view). This resource is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International license: TABLE OF CONTENTS Alphabetical Index 4 Terminological Entries 5 List Of Entries 140 Collections 183 Alphabetical Index from 'Abd al-Samad to 'Abd al-Samad p. 6 -6 from 10th century AD to 1st millenium BC p. 9 -9 from 20th century AD to 2nd millenium BC p. 11 -11 from 30th century BC to 3rd millenium BC p. 12 -12 from 4th century AD to 4th millenium BC p. 13 -13 from 5th century AD to 5th millenium BC p. 14 -14 from 6th century AD to 6th dynasty p. 15 -15 from 7th century AD to 7th dynasty p. 16 -16 from 8th century AD to 8th dynasty p. 17 -17 from 9th century AD to 9th dynasty p. 18 -18 from Abassid dynasty to Aztec Civilization p. 19 -27 from baboon to Byzantium p.
    [Show full text]
  • Tracking the Neolithic House in Europe Sedentism, Architecture, and Practice One World Archaeology
    One World Archaeology Daniela Hofmann Jessica Smyth Editors Tracking the Neolithic House in Europe Sedentism, Architecture, and Practice One World Archaeology Series Editors: Heather Burke, Flinders University of South Australia, Australia Gustavo Politis, Universidad Nacionaldel Centro, Buenos Aires, Argentina Gabriel Cooney, University College, Dublin, Ireland For further volumes: http://www.springer.com/series/8606 Daniela Hofmann · Jessica Smyth Editors Tracking the Neolithic House in Europe Sedentism, Architecture and Practice 1 3 Editors Daniela Hofmann Jessica Smyth School of History, Archaeology and Religion School of Chemistry Cardiff University University of Bristol Cardiff Bristol United Kingdom United Kingdom ISBN 978-1-4614-5288-1 ISBN 978-1-4614-5289-8 (eBook) DOI 10.1007/978-1-4614-5289-8 Springer New York Dordrecht Heidelberg London Library of Congress Control Number: 2012954540 © Springer Science+Business Media New York 2013 This work is subject to copyright. All rights are reserved by the Publisher, whether the whole or part of the material is concerned, specifically the rights of translation, reprinting, reuse of illustrations, recita- tion, broadcasting, reproduction on microfilms or in any other physical way, and transmission or infor- mation storage and retrieval, electronic adaptation, computer software, or by similar or dissimilar meth- odology now known or hereafter developed. Exempted from this legal reservation are brief excerpts in connection with reviews or scholarly analysis or material supplied specifically for the purpose of being entered and executed on a computer system, for exclusive use by the purchaser of the work. Duplica- tion of this publication or parts thereof is permitted only under the provisions of the Copyright Law of the Publisher’s location, in its current version, and permission for use must always be obtained from Springer.
    [Show full text]
  • Why Did the Netherlands Develop So Early? the Legacy of the Brethren of the Common Life
    CPB Discussion Paper | 228 Why Did the Netherlands Develop so Early? The Legacy of the Brethren of the Common Life İ. Semih Akçomak Dinand Webbink Bas ter Weel Why Did the Netherlands Develop so Early? The Legacy of the Brethren of the Common Life* İ. Semih Akçomak Middle East Technical University [email protected] Dinand Webbink Erasmus University Rotterdam and CPB [email protected] Bas ter Weel CPB and Maastricht University [email protected] Abstract This research provides an explanation for high literacy, economic growth and societal developments in the Netherlands in the period before the Dutch Republic. We establish a link between the Brethren of the Common Life (BCL), a religious community founded by Geert Groote in the city of Deventer in the late fourteenth century, and the early development of the Netherlands. The BCL stimulated human capital accumulation by educating Dutch citizens without inducing animosity from the dominant Roman Catholic Church or other political rulers. Human capital had an impact on the structure of economic development in the period immediately after 1400. The educated workforce put pressure on the Habsburg monarchy leading to economic and religious resentment and eventually to the Revolt in 1572. The analyses show that the BCL contributed to the high rates of literacy in the Netherlands. In addition, there are positive effects of the BCL on book production and on city growth in the fifteenth and sixteenth century. Finally, we find that cities with BCL-roots were more likely to join the Dutch Revolt. These findings are supported by regressions that use distance to Deventer as an instrument for the presence of BCL.
    [Show full text]
  • Trade and Political Fragmentation on the Silk Roads: the Economic Effects of Historical Exchange Between China and the Muslim East
    Trade and Political Fragmentation on the Silk Roads: The Economic Effects of Historical Exchange between China and the Muslim East Lisa Blaydes, Christopher Paik Working Paper # 0033 December 2019 Division of Social Science Working Paper Series New York University Abu Dhabi, Saadiyat Island P.O Box 129188, Abu Dhabi, UAE http://nyuad.nyu.edu/en/academics/academic-divisions/social-science.html Trade and Political Fragmentation on the Silk Roads: The Economic Effects of Historical Exchange between China and the Muslim East Lisa Blaydes∗ Christopher Paiky Word Count: 9,831 Abstract The Silk Roads stretched across Eurasia, connecting East and West for centuries. At its height, the network of trade routes enabled merchants to travel from China to the Mediterranean Sea, carrying with them high-value commercial goods, the exchange of which encouraged urban growth and prosperity. We examine the extent to which urban centers thrived or withered as a function of shocks to trade routes, particularly political fragmentation along natural travel paths. We find that political fragmenta- tion along the roads to Aleppo and historic Chang'an | major terminus locations for cross-regional trade | damaged city growth. These conclusions contribute to our understanding of how a pre-modern international system operated through an exami- nation of exchange between the two most developed world regions of the medieval and early modern periods, China and the Muslim East. ∗Department of Political Science, Stanford University yDivision of Social Science, New York University Abu Dhabi The Silk Roads were among the world's most important historical commercial routes, connecting economic interests in prosperous areas like China and the Middle East for cen- turies.
    [Show full text]
  • A Strategic Analysis of a Company in the Wedding Industry
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Simon Fraser University Institutional Repository A STRATEGIC ANALYSIS OF A COMPANY IN THE WEDDING INDUSTRY by Martin Salim Bachelor of Applied Science, University of British Columbia, 2008 PROJECT SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF MASTER OF BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION In the Faculty of Business Administration MANAGEMENT OF TECHNOLOGY PROGRAM © Martin Salim 2013 SIMON FRASER UNIVERSITY Summer 2013 All rights reserved. However, in accordance with the Copyright Act of Canada, this work may be reproduced, without authorization, under the conditions for Fair Dealing. Therefore, limited reproduction of this work for the purposes of private study, research, criticism, review and news reporting is likely to be in accordance with the law, particularly if cited appropriately. Approval Name: Martin Salim Degree: Master of Business Administration Title of Project: A Strategic Analysis of a Company in the Wedding Industry Supervisory Committee: _______________________________________ Dr. Aidan R. Vining Senior Supervisor CNABS Professor of Business and Government Relations & Area Coordinator Faculty of Business Administration _______________________________________ Dr. Elicia Maine Second Reader Associate Professor Faculty of Business Administration Date Approved: _______________________________________ ii Abstract PrincessWedding4U is a new ecommerce company that targets the wedding industry within the Indonesian market. The purpose of this strategic analysis is to provide PrincessWedding4U with some analytical information and to present the company with a strategic option so that the company can maintain its sustainable growth. PrincessWedding4U is competing in a fragmented market that has a low level of industry attractiveness. PrincessWedding4U needs to utilize its competitive advantage in brand building to position itself in this crowded market.
    [Show full text]
  • Informal Document No
    Informal document No. 5 Distr.: General 22 February 2013 English only Economic Commission for Europe Inland Transport Committee Seventy-fifth session Geneva, 26 February–28 February 2013 Item 5 (a) of the provisional agenda UNECE Transport review for the year 2012 “Urban transport and mobility” UNECE Transport review for the year 2012 “Urban transport and mobility” Note by the secretariat Summary The note provides the Inland Transport Committee with a review of the publication “Transport review for the year 2012: Urban transport and mobility”. It also highlights the importance to further strengthen and study urban transport and mobility since urban transport systems are integral parts of national transport systems. Moreover, it provides information regarding the main objectives and the structure of the publication as well as a preliminary analysis of some indicators based on data received so far. The Inland Transport Committee is invited to consider how this topic should be followed up regularly, and which Working Party should take the lead. The Committee is invited to encourage governments and municipalities of their capitals to support the secretariat’s survey on urban transport and mobility. GE. Informal document No. 5 I. The Mandate 1. At its seventy-fourth session in February 2012 the Inland Transport Committee of the United Nations Economic Commission for Europe (UNECE) took note of the draft publication ”Review of the transport situation in 2011 and emerging trends in ECE region”. The Committee also endorsed the decision by the Working Party 5 to transform the review into an annual publication on transport trends and economics in the ECE region (ECE/TRANS/224, paras.
    [Show full text]
  • Container Sea Ports and Dry Ports: Future CO2 Emission Reduction Potential in China
    sustainability Article Container Sea Ports and Dry Ports: Future CO2 Emission Reduction Potential in China Weidong Li 1 , Olli-Pekka Hilmola 1,2,* and Yulia Panova 3 1 School of Economics & Management, Beijing Jiaotong University, Beijing 100044, China; [email protected] 2 LUT Kouvola, LUT University, Kouvola 45100, Finland 3 Department of E-Commerce, Luoyang Normal University, Luoyang 471934, China; [email protected] * Correspondence: olli-pekka.hilmola@lut.fi Received: 28 January 2019; Accepted: 6 March 2019; Published: 13 March 2019 Abstract: Nowadays, China dominates logistics volumes, and its container logistics is associated with the largest sea ports, such as Shanghai, Shenzhen, and Ningbo. However, China’s coastal line is long and contains numerous million-container-handling sea ports. Current leading sea ports are located mostly in the south or at the middle point of the coastal line. Volumes are rather concentrated in these few areas. Despite the fact that China’s vast population is well-spread throughout the coastal line, major cities are also located in the hinterlands. Apart from some regions (e.g., the Pearl and the Yangtze River Delta) where there are many cities that are very close to each other, distances between cities are rather long in general. Therefore, this research examines the CO2 emission reduction potential of using a larger number of sea ports (such as distribution hubs), as well as the interaction of these with analytically chosen dry ports. Results of the hypothetical country level container transportation model, using linear integer programming concerning 51 cities (largest hinterland and container sea port cities), showed that better and more equal use of sea ports serving the major cities will result in considerable emission reductions.
    [Show full text]
  • ART and ARCHAEOLOGY Vocabulary ART and ARCHAEOLOGY Vocabulary Version 1.1 (Last Updated : Jan
    - Institute for scientific and technical information - ART and ARCHAEOLOGY Vocabulary ART and ARCHAEOLOGY Vocabulary Version 1.1 (Last updated : Jan. 22, 2018) This resource contains 1960 entries. Controlled vocabulary used for indexing bibliographical records for the "Art and Archaeology" FRANCIS database (1972-2015, http://pascal-francis.inist.fr/ ). This vocabulary is browsable online at: https://www.loterre.fr Legend • Syn: Synonym. • →: Corresponding Preferred Term. • FR: French Preferred Term. • ES: Spanish Preferred Term. • DE: German Preferred Term. • URI: Concept's URI (link to the online view). This resource is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International license: LIST OF ENTRIES List of entries English French Page • 10th century AD Xe siècle apr. J.-C. 46 • 10th dynasty Xe dynastie 46 • 11th century AD XIe siècle apr. J.-C. 46 • 11th century BC XIe siècle av. J.-C. 46 • 11th dynasty XIe dynastie 46 • 12th century AD XIIe siècle apr. J.-C 46 • 12th century BC XIIe siècle av. J.-C 46 • 12th dynasty XIIe dynastie 46 • 13th century AD XIIIe siècle apr. J.-C 46 • 13th century BC XIIIe siècle av. J.-C 46 • 13th dynasty XIIIe dynastie 46 • 14th century AD XIVe siècle apr. J.-C 46 • 14th century BC XIVe siècle av. J.-C 46 • 14th dynasty XIVe dynastie 46 • 15th century AD XVe siècle apr. J.-C 46 • 15th century BC XVe siècle av. J.-C 46 • 15th dynasty XVe dynastie 46 • 16th century AD XVIe siècle apr. J.-C 46 • 16th century BC XVIe siècle av. J.-C 46 • 16th dynasty XVIe dynastie 46 • 17th century AD XVIIe siècle apr.
    [Show full text]
  • The Urban Mortality Transition and the Rise of Poor Mega-Cities
    The Urban Mortality Transition and the Rise of Poor Mega-Cities Remi Jedwab and Dietrich Vollrath∗ November 3, 2016 Abstract Today the world’s largest cities lie in poor countries, unlike the historical norm. Also unlike the “killer cities” of history, today’s poor mega-cities grow not just through in-migration but also through their own natural increase. First, we use novel historical data to document that these poor mega-cities arose at the same time as the post-war urban mortality transition. Second, we develop a general equilibrium model of location choice with heterogeneity in congestion costs and demographics across locations to account for this. In the model, the aggregate rate of population growth and the locational choice of individuals interact. Third, we calibrate the model to data from a sample of poor countries, and find that informal urban areas (e.g. slums) grew in large part because relative to other locations they were able to absorb additional population easily. We show that between 1950 and 2005 the urban mortality transition by itself would have doubled the urbanization rate as well as the size of informal urban areas in this sample. Of these effects, one-third can be attributed to the direct amenity effect of lower urban mortality rates, while the remainder is due to higher population growth disproportionately pushing people into informal ur- ban areas. Fourth, policy analysis suggests that family planning programs may be as effective as higher productivity or urban infrastructure and institutions, and more effective than migration restrictions and slum clearance, at trans- forming mega-cities of the developing world into “engines of growth”.
    [Show full text]
  • ARCH202 History of Architecture Spring 2013-2014
    University of Nizwa College of Engineering & Architecture Dept. of Architecture & Interior Design ARCH202 History of Architecture Spring 2013-2014 Dr. Janon Kadhim Associate Professor of Architecture ARCH 202 History of Architecture Lecture #2 Mesopotamian ARCHITECTURE Dr. Janon A. W. Kadhim Associate Professor of Architecture University of Nizwa Spring 2013-2014 Mesopotamia: The Cradle of civilization • The caves in Northern • On the land of Mesopotamia contain Mesopotamia we can remains of the ancient trace the growth and Cavemen. development of human • The first Agrarian existence and settlements in the civilization from the world formed in the earliest times in a north of Mesopotamia continuous sequence. some of which go back to 10000 BC. Dr. Janon Kadhim 3 The fertile Crescent Arab Gulf Mesopotamia, the land between the rivers, is situated in the region called the fertile crescent Dr. Janon Kadhim 4 Mesopotamia: Attributes of the Natural Environment • Mesopotamia is part of what is known as the “Fertile Crescent”; • It contains some of the most fertile and rich land in the world; • Diverse topography and climate: which provided a variety of building materials, and led to the creation of a variety of art forms and architectural types; • Mesopotamia does not have any natural means of fortification other than the mountains that create the North and North-Eastern boundaries of the region. This has created a continuous problem for Mesopotamia over history causing it to be invaded many times over history by surrounding entities. Dr. Janon Kadhim 5 Other Natural attributes: • Characterized by the two large rivers, The Tigris and the Euphrates, and their many tributaries; • The rivers are known for their annual floods.
    [Show full text]
  • The Mortality Transition, Malthusian Dynamics, and the Rise of Poor Mega-Cities∗
    The Mortality Transition, Malthusian Dynamics, and the Rise of Poor Mega-Cities∗ Remi Jedwab† and Dietrich Vollrath‡ January 2015 Abstract: The largest cities in the world today lie mainly in relatively poor countries, which is a departure from historical experience, when the largest cities were typically found in the richest places. Using new data on the demographic history of the 100 largest mega- cities of today, we establish several new stylized facts distinguishing poor mega-cities from historically rich mega-cities. To account for these facts we develop a model that combines Malthusian models of endogenous population growth with urban models of agglomeration and congestion, and it shows that the absolute growth of the urban population determines whether a city becomes a poor or rich mega-city. We posit that poor mega-cities arose in part because the post-war mortality transition raised their absolute growth above a crucial threshold. Poor mega-cities continue to grow in size but not in living standards because their poverty keeps population growth high. By expanding prior to the mortality transition, historical mega-cities experienced smaller absolute growth that allowed them to sustain wage growth and kept population growth relatively low. Keywords: Urban Malthusianism; Demographic Regime; Megacities; Congestion; Growth JEL classification: O11; O14; O18; L16; N10; N90; R10 ∗We would like to thank Quamrul Ashraf, Alain Bertaud, Edward Glaeser, Stelios Michalopoulos, Paul Romer, Nico Voigtlaender, David Weil and seminar audiences at George Mason-George Washington Economic History Workshop, George Washington (IIEP and SAGE), George Washington University Urban Day, Harvard Kennedy School (NEUDC), Michigan, Minnesota (MIEDC), NYU Urbanization Project, Oxford (CSAE), Paris School of Economics (seminar and RSUE Workshop), University of California-Los Angeles (PACDEV), University Paris 1, U.S.
    [Show full text]