Econ 337901 Financial Economics

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Econ 337901 Financial Economics ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Peter Ireland Boston College Spring 2021 These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike 4.0 International (CC BY-NC-SA 4.0) License. http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-sa/4.0/. 1 Mathematical and Economic Foundations A Mathematical Preliminaries 1 Unconstrained Optimization 2 Constrained Optimization B Consumer Optimization 1 Graphical Analysis 2 Algebraic Analysis 3 The Time Dimension 4 The Risk Dimension C General Equilibrium 1 Optimal Allocations 2 Equilibrium Allocations Mathematical Preliminaries Unconstrained Optimization max F (x) x Constrained Optimization max F (x) subject to c ≥ G(x) x Unconstrained Optimization To find the value of x that solves max F (x) x you can: 1. Try out every possible value of x. 2. Use calculus. Since search could take forever, let's use calculus instead. Unconstrained Optimization Theorem If x ∗ solves max F (x); x then x ∗ is a critical point of F , that is, F 0(x ∗) = 0: Unconstrained Optimization F (x) maximized at x ∗ = 5 Unconstrained Optimization F 0(x) > 0 when x < 5. F (x) can be increased by increasing x. Unconstrained Optimization F 0(x) < 0 when x > 5. F (x) can be increased by decreasing x. Unconstrained Optimization F 0(x) = 0 when x = 5. F (x) is maximized. Unconstrained Optimization Theorem If x ∗ solves max F (x); x then x ∗ is a critical point of F , that is, F 0(x ∗) = 0: Note that the same first-order necessary condition F 0(x ∗) = 0 also characterizes a value of x ∗ that minimizes F (x). Unconstrained Optimization F 0(x) = 0 when x = 5. F (x) is minimized. Unconstrained Optimization F 0(x) = 0 and F 00(x) < 0 when x = 5. F (x) is maximized. Unconstrained Optimization F 0(x) = 0 and F 00(x) > 0 when x = 5. F (x) is minimized. Unconstrained Optimization Theorem If x ∗ solves max F (x); x then x ∗ is a critical point of F , that is, F 0(x ∗) = 0: Unconstrained Optimization Theorem If F 0(x ∗) = 0 and F 00(x ∗) < 0; then x ∗ solves max F (x) x (at least locally). The first-order condition F 0(x ∗) = 0 and the second-order condition F 00(x ∗) < 0 are sufficient conditions for the value of x that (locally) maximizes F (x). Unconstrained Optimization F 0(x ∗∗) = 0 and F 00(x ∗∗) < 0 at the local maximizer x ∗∗ and F 0(x ∗) = 0 and F 00(x ∗) < 0 at the global maximizer x ∗. Unconstrained Optimization F 0(x ∗∗) = 0 and F 00(x ∗∗) < 0 at the local maximizer x ∗∗ and F 0(x ∗) = 0 and F 00(x ∗) < 0 at the global maximizer x ∗, but F 00(x) > 0 in between x ∗ and x ∗∗. Unconstrained Optimization Theorem If F 0(x ∗) = 0 and 00 F (x) < 0 for all x 2 R; then x ∗ solves max F (x): x Unconstrained Optimization F 00(x) < 0 for all x 2 R and F 0(5) = 0. F (x) is maximized when x = 5. Unconstrained Optimization If F 00(x) < 0 for all x 2 R, then the function F is concave. When F is concave, the first-order condition F 0(x ∗) = 0 is both necessary and sufficient for the value of x that maximizes F (x). And, as we are about to see, concave functions arise frequently and naturally in economics and finance. Unconstrained Optimization: Example 1 Consider the problem 1 max − (x − τ)2; x 2 where τ is a number (τ 2 R) that we might call the \target." The first-order condition −(x ∗ − τ) = 0 leads us immediately to the solution: x ∗ = τ. Unconstrained Optimization: Example 2 Consider maximizing a function of three variables: max F (x1; x2; x3) x1;x2;x3 Even if each variable can take on only 1,000 values, there are one billion possible combinations of (x1; x2; x3) to search over! This is an example of what Richard Bellman (US, 1920-1984) called the \curse of dimensionality." Unconstrained Optimization: Example 2 Consider the problem: 1 2 1 2 1 2 max − (x1 − τ) + − (x2 − x1) + − (x3 − x2) : x1;x2;x3 2 2 2 Now the three first-order conditions ∗ ∗ ∗ −(x1 − τ) + (x2 − x1 ) = 0 ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ −(x2 − x1 ) + (x3 − x2 ) = 0 ∗ ∗ −(x3 − x2 ) = 0 ∗ ∗ ∗ lead us to the solution: x1 = x2 = x3 = τ. Constrained Optimization To find the value of x that solves max F (x) subject to c ≥ G(x) x you can: 1. Try out every possible value of x. 2. Use calculus. Since search could take forever, let's use calculus instead. Constrained Optimization A method for solving constrained optimization problems like max F (x) subject to c ≥ G(x) x was developed by Joseph-Louis Lagrange (France/Italy, 1736-1813) and extended by Harold Kuhn (US, 1925-2014) and Albert Tucker (US, 1905-1995). Constrained Optimization Associated with the problem: max F (x) subject to c ≥ G(x) x Define the Lagrangian L(x; λ) = F (x) + λ[c − G(x)]; where λ is the Lagrange multiplier. Constrained Optimization Then, look for a critical point of the full Lagrangian L(x; λ) = F (x) + λ[c − G(x)]; instead of just the objective function F by itself. That is, use the FOC F 0(x ∗) − λ∗G 0(x ∗) = 0: Constrained Optimization L(x; λ) = F (x) + λ[c − G(x)]; Theorem (Kuhn-Tucker) If x ∗ maximizes F (x) subject to c ≥ G(x), then there exists a value λ∗ ≥ 0 such that, together, x ∗ and λ∗ satisfy the first-order condition F 0(x ∗) − λ∗G 0(x ∗) = 0 and the complementary slackness condition λ∗[c − G(x ∗)] = 0: Constrained Optimization In the case where c > G(x ∗), the constraint is non-binding. The complementary slackness condition λ∗[c − G(x ∗)] = 0 requires that λ∗ = 0. And the first-order condition F 0(x ∗) − λ∗G 0(x ∗) = 0 requires that F 0(x ∗) = 0. Constrained Optimization In the case where c = G(x ∗), the constraint is binding. The complementary slackness condition λ∗[c − G(x ∗)] = 0 puts no further restriction on λ∗ ≥ 0. Now the first-order condition F 0(x ∗) − λ∗G 0(x ∗) = 0 requires that F 0(x ∗) = λ∗G 0(x ∗). Constrained Optimization: Example 1 For the problem 1 max − (x − 5)2 subject to 7 ≥ x; x 2 F (x) = (−1=2)(x − 5)2, c = 7, and G(x) = x. The Lagrangian is 1 L(x; λ) = − (x − 5)2 + λ(7 − x): 2 Constrained Optimization: Example 1 With 1 L(x; λ) = − (x − 5)2 + λ(7 − x); 2 the first-order condition −(x ∗ − 5) − λ∗ = 0 and the complementary slackness condition λ∗(7 − x ∗) = 0 are satisfied with x ∗ = 5, F 0(x ∗) = 0, λ∗ = 0, and 7 > x ∗. Constrained Optimization: Example 1 Here, the solution has F 0(x ∗) = 0 since the constraint is nonbinding. Constrained Optimization: Example 2 For the problem 1 max − (x − 5)2 subject to 4 ≥ x; x 2 F (x) = (−1=2)(x − 5)2, c = 4, and G(x) = x. The Lagrangian is 1 L(x; λ) = − (x − 5)2 + λ(4 − x): 2 Constrained Optimization: Example 2 With 1 L(x; λ) = − (x − 5)2 + λ(4 − x); 2 the first-order condition −(x ∗ − 5) − λ∗ = 0 and the complementary slackness condition λ∗(4 − x ∗) = 0 are satisfied with x ∗ = 4 and F 0(x ∗) = λ∗ = 1 > 0. Constrained Optimization: Example 2 Here, the solution has F 0(x ∗) = λ∗G 0(x ∗) > 0 since the constraint is binding. F 0(x ∗) > 0 indicates that we'd like to increase the value of x, but the constraint won't let us. Constrained Optimization: Example 2 With a binding constraint, F 0(x ∗) 6= 0 but F 0(x ∗) − λ∗G 0(x ∗) = 0. The value x ∗ that solves the problem is a critical point, not of the objective function F (x), but instead of the entire Lagrangian F (x) + λ[c − G(x)]. Consumer Optimization 1. Graphical Analysis 2. Algebraic Analysis 3. Time Dimension 4. Risk Dimension Consumer Optimization Alfred Marshall, Principles of Economics, 1890. { supply and demand Francis Edgeworth, Mathematical Psychics, 1881. Vilfredo Pareto, Manual of Political Economy, 1906. { indifference curves Consumer Optimization John Hicks, Value and Capital, 1939. { wealth and substitution effects Paul Samuelson, Foundations of Economic Analysis, 1947. { mathematical reformulation Irving Fisher, The Theory of Interest, 1930. { intertemporal extension. Consumer Optimization Gerard Debreu, Theory of Value, 1959. Kenneth Arrow, \The Role of Securities in the Optimal Allocation of Risk Bearing," Review of Economic Studies, 1964. Extensions to include risk and uncertainty. Consumer Optimization: Graphical Analysis Consider a consumer who likes two goods: apples and bananas. Y = income ca = consumption of apples cb = consumption of bananas pa = price of an apple pb = price of a banana The consumer's budget constraint is Y ≥ paca + pbcb Consumer Optimization: Graphical Analysis So long as the consumer always prefers more to less, the budget constraint will always bind: Y = paca + pbcb or Y pa cb = − ca pb pb Which shows that the graph of the budget constraint will be a straight line with slope −(pa=pb) and intercept Y =pb. Consumer Optimization: Graphical Analysis The budget constraint is a straight line with slope −(pa=pb) and intercept Y =pb. Consumer Optimization: Graphical Analysis The budget constraint describes the consumer's market opportunities. Francis Edgeworth (Ireland, 1845-1926) and Vilfredo Pareto (Italy, 1848-1923) were the first to use indifference curves to describe the consumer's preferences. Each indifference curve traces out a set of combinations of apples and bananas that give the consumer a given level of utility or satisfaction.
Recommended publications
  • The Soft Budget Constraint
    Acta Oeconomica, Vol. 64 (S1) pp. 25–79 (2014) DOI: 10.1556/AOecon.64.2014.S1.2 THE SOFT BUDGET CONSTRAINT An Introductory Study to Volume IV of the Life’s Work Series* János KORNAI** The author’s ideas on the soft budget constraint (SBC) were first expressed in 1976. Much progress has been made in understanding the problem over the ensuing four decades. The study takes issue with those who confine the concept to the process of bailing out loss-making socialist firms. It shows how the syndrome can appear in various organizations and forms in many spheres of the economy and points to the various means available for financial rescue. Single bailouts do not as such gener- ate the SBC syndrome. It develops where the SBC becomes built into expectations. Special heed is paid to features generated by the syndrome in rescuer and rescuee organizations. The study reports on the spread of the syndrome in various periods of the socialist and the capitalist system, in various sectors. The author expresses his views on normative questions and on therapies against the harmful effects. He deals first with actual practice, then places the theory of the SBC in the sphere of ideas and models, showing how it relates to other theoretical trends, including institutional and behav- ioural economics and theories of moral hazard and inconsistency in time. He shows how far the in- tellectual apparatus of the SBC has spread in theoretical literature and where it has reached in the process of “canonization” by the economics profession. Finally, he reviews the main research tasks ahead.
    [Show full text]
  • Preview Guide
    ContentsNOT FOR SALE Preface xiii CHAPTER 3 The Behavior of Consumers 45 3.1 Tastes 45 CHAPTER 1 Indifference Curves 45 Supply, Demand, Marginal Values 48 and Equilibrium 1 More on Indifference Curves 53 1.1 Demand 1 3.2 The Budget Line and the Demand versus Quantity Consumer’s Choice 53 Demanded 1 The Budget Line 54 Demand Curves 2 The Consumer’s Choice 56 Changes in Demand 3 Market Demand 7 3.3 Applications of Indifference The Shape of the Demand Curve 7 Curves 59 The Wide Scope of Economics 10 Standards of Living 59 The Least Bad Tax 64 1.2 Supply 10 Summary 69 Supply versus Quantity Supplied 10 Author Commentary 69 1.3 Equilibrium 13 Review Questions 70 The Equilibrium Point 13 Numerical Exercises 70 Changes in the Equilibrium Point 15 Problem Set 71 Summary 23 Appendix to Chapter 3 77 Author Commentary 24 Cardinal Utility 77 Review Questions 25 The Consumer’s Optimum 79 Numerical Exercises 25 Problem Set 26 CHAPTER 4 Consumers in the Marketplace 81 CHAPTER 2 4.1 Changes in Income 81 Prices, Costs, and the Gains Changes in Income and Changes in the from Trade 31 Budget Line 81 Changes in Income and Changes in the 2.1 Prices 31 Optimum Point 82 Absolute versus Relative Prices 32 The Engel Curve 84 Some Applications 34 4.2 Changes in Price 85 2.2 Costs, Efficiency, and Gains from Changes in Price and Changes in the Trade 35 Budget Line 85 Costs and Efficiency 35 Changes in Price and Changes in the Optimum Point 86 Specialization and the Gains from Trade 37 The Demand Curve 88 Why People Trade 39 4.3 Income and Substitution Summary 41
    [Show full text]
  • Coasean Fictions: Law and Economics Revisited
    Seattle Journal for Social Justice Volume 5 Issue 2 Article 28 May 2007 Coasean Fictions: Law and Economics Revisited Alejandro Nadal Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.law.seattleu.edu/sjsj Recommended Citation Nadal, Alejandro (2007) "Coasean Fictions: Law and Economics Revisited," Seattle Journal for Social Justice: Vol. 5 : Iss. 2 , Article 28. Available at: https://digitalcommons.law.seattleu.edu/sjsj/vol5/iss2/28 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Student Publications and Programs at Seattle University School of Law Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Seattle Journal for Social Justice by an authorized editor of Seattle University School of Law Digital Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. 569 Coasean Fictions: Law and Economics Revisited Alejandro Nadal1 After the 1960s, a strong academic movement developed in the United States around the idea that the study of the law, as well as legal practice, could be strengthened through economic analysis.2 This trend was started through the works of R.H. Coase and Guido Calabresi, and grew with later developments introduced by Richard Posner and Robert D. Cooter, as well as Gary Becker.3 Law and Economics (L&E) is the name given to the application of modern economics to legal analysis and practice. Proponents of L&E have portrayed the movement as improving clarity and logic in legal analysis, and even as a tool to modify the conceptual categories used by lawyers and courts to think about
    [Show full text]
  • Francis Ysidro Edgeworth
    Francis Ysidro Edgeworth Previous (Francis Xavier) (/entry/Francis_Xavier) Next (Francis of Assisi) (/entry/Francis_of_Assisi) Francis Ysidro Edgeworth (February 8, 1845 – February 13, 1926) was an Irish (/entry/Ireland) polymath, a highly influential figure in the development of neo­ classical economics, and contributor to the development of statistical theory. He was the first to apply certain formal mathematical techniques to individual decision making in economics. Edgeworth developed utility theory, introducing the indifference curve and the famous "Edgeworth box," which have become standards in economic theory. He is also known for the "Edgeworth conjecture" which states that the core of an economy shrinks to the set of competitive equilibria as the number of agents in the economy gets large. The high degree of originality demonstrated in his most important book on economics, Mathematical Psychics, was matched only by the difficulty in reading it. A deep thinker, his contributions were far ahead of his time and continue to inform the fields of (/entry/File:Edgeworth.jpeg) microeconomics (/entry/Microeconomics) and areas such as welfare economics. Francis Y. Edgeworth Thus, Edgeworth's work has advanced our understanding of economic relationships among traders, and thus contributes to the establishment of a better society for all. Life Contents Ysidro Francis Edgeworth (the order of his given names was later reversed) 1 Life was born on February 8, 1845 in Edgeworthstown, Ireland (/entry/Ireland), into 2 Work a large and wealthy landowning family. His aunt was the famous novelist Maria 2.1 Edgeworth conjecture Edgeworth, who wrote the Castle Rackrent. He was educated by private tutors 2.2 Edgeworth Box until 1862, when he went on to study classics and languages at Trinity College, 2.3 Edgeworth limit theorem Dublin.
    [Show full text]
  • A Macroeconomic Model with Financially Constrained Producers and Intermediaries ∗
    A Macroeconomic Model with Financially Constrained Producers and Intermediaries ∗ Vadim Elenev Tim Landvoigt Stijn Van Nieuwerburgh NYU Stern UT Austin NYU Stern, NBER, and CEPR October 24, 2016 Abstract We propose a model that can simultaneously capture the sharp and persistent drop in macro-economic aggregates and the sharp change in credit spreads observed in the U.S. during the Great Recession. We use the model to evaluate the quantitative effects of macro-prudential policy. The model features borrower-entrepreneurs who produce output financed with long-term debt issued by financial intermediaries and their own equity. Intermediaries fund these loans combining deposits and their own equity. Savers provide funding to banks and to the government. Both entrepreneurs and intermediaries make optimal default decisions. The government issues debt to finance budget deficits and to pay for bank bailouts. Intermediaries are subject to a regulatory capital constraint. Financial recessions, triggered by low aggregate and dispersed idiosyncratic productivity shocks result in financial crises with elevated loan defaults and occasional intermediary insolvencies. Output, balance sheet, and price reactions are substantially more severe and persistent than in non-financial recession. Policies that limit intermediary leverage redistribute wealth from producers to intermediaries and savers. The benefits of lower intermediary leverage for financial and macro-economic stability are offset by the costs from more constrained firms who produce less output. JEL: G12,
    [Show full text]
  • Soft Budget Constraint Theories from Centralization to the Market1
    Economics of Transition Volume 9 (1) 2001, 1–27 Soft budget constraint theories From centralization to the market1 Eric Maskin* and Chenggang Xu** *Institute for Advanced Study, Princeton and Department of Economics, Princeton University. Institute for Advanced Study, Einstein Drive, Princeton, NJ 08540, USA. Tel: + 1 609-734- 8309; E-mail: [email protected] **Department of Economics and CEP, London School of Economics, London WC2A 2AE, UK. Tel: +44 (0)207 955 7526; E-mail: [email protected] Abstract This paper surveys the theoretical literature on the effect of soft budget constraints on economies in transition from centralization to capitalism; it also reviews our understanding of soft budget constraints in general. It focuses on the conception of the soft budget constraint syndrome as a commitment problem. We show that the two features of soft budget constraints in centralized economies – ex post renegotiation of firms’ financial plans and a close administrative relationship between firms and the centre – are intrinsically related. We examine a series of theories (based on the commitment-problem approach) that explain shortage, lack of innovation in centralized economies, devolution, and banking reform in transition economies. Moreover, we argue that soft budget constraints also have an influence on major issues in economics, such as the determination of the boundaries and capital structure of a firm. Finally, we show that soft budget constraints theory sheds light on financial crises and economic growth. JEL classification: D2, D8, G2, G3, H7, L2, O3, P2, P3. Keywords: soft budget constraint, renegotiation, theory of the firm, banking and finance, transition, centralized economy.
    [Show full text]
  • A Sparsity-Based Model of Bounded Rationality
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A SPARSITY-BASED MODEL OF BOUNDED RATIONALITY Xavier Gabaix Working Paper 16911 http://www.nber.org/papers/w16911 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 March 2011 I thank David Laibson for a great many enlightening conversations about behavioral economics over the years. For very helpful comments, I thank the editor and the referees, and Andrew Abel, Nick Barberis, Daniel Benjamin, Douglas Bernheim, Andrew Caplin, Pierre-André Chiappori, Vincent Crawford, Stefano DellaVigna, Alex Edmans, Ed Glaeser, Oliver Hart, David Hirshleifer, Harrison Hong, Daniel Kahneman, Paul Klemperer, Botond Kőszegi, Sendhil Mullainathan, Matthew Rabin, Antonio Rangel, Larry Samuelson, Yuliy Sannikov, Thomas Sargent, Josh Schwartzstein, and participants at various seminars and conferences. I am grateful to Jonathan Libgober, Elliot Lipnowski, Farzad Saidi, and Jerome Williams for very good research assistance, and to the NYU CGEB, INET, the NSF (grant SES-1325181) for financial support. The views expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer- reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2011 by Xavier Gabaix. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. A Sparsity-Based Model of Bounded Rationality Xavier Gabaix NBER Working Paper No. 16911 March 2011, Revised May 2014 JEL No. D03,D42,D8,D83,E31,G1 ABSTRACT This paper defines and analyzes a “sparse max” operator, which is a less than fully attentive and rational version of the traditional max operator.
    [Show full text]
  • Lecture 4 - Utility Maximization
    Lecture 4 - Utility Maximization David Autor, MIT and NBER 1 1 Roadmap: Theory of consumer choice This figure shows you each of the building blocks of consumer theory that we’ll explore in the next few lectures. This entire apparatus stands entirely on the five axioms of consumer theory that we laid out in Lecture Note 3. It is an amazing edifice, when you think about it. 2 Utility maximization subject to budget constraint Ingredients • Utility function (preferences) • Budget constraint • Price vector Consumer’s problem • Maximize utility subject to budget constraint. 2 • Characteristics of solution: – Budget exhaustion (non-satiation) – For most solutions: psychic trade-off = market trade-off – Psychic trade-off is MRS – Market trade-off is the price ratio • From a visual point of view utility maximization corresponds to point A in the diagram below – The slope of the budget set is equal to − px py – The slope of each indifference curve is given by the MRS at that point • We can see that A P B, A I D, C P A. Why might we expect someone to choose A? 3 2.1 Interior and corner solutions There are two types of solution to this problem, interior solutions and corner solutions • The figure below depicts an interior solution • The next figure depicts a corner solution. In this specific example the shape of the indifference curves means that the consumer is indifferent to the consumption of good y. Utility increases only with consumption of x. Thus, the consumer purchases x exclusively. 4 • In the following figure, the consumer’s preference for y is sufficiently strong relative to x that the the psychic trade-off is always lower than the monetary trade-off.
    [Show full text]
  • Theoretical Tools of Public Finance
    Theoretical Tools of Public Finance 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley 1 THEORETICAL AND EMPIRICAL TOOLS Theoretical tools: The set of tools designed to understand the mechanics behind economic decision making. Empirical tools: The set of tools designed to analyze data and answer questions raised by theoretical analysis. 2 CONSTRAINED UTILITY MAXIMIZATION Economists model individuals' choices using the concepts of utility function maximization subject to budget constraint. Utility function: A mathematical function representing an individual's set of preferences, which translates her well-being from different consumption bundles into units that can be compared in order to determine choice. Constrained utility maximization: The process of maximiz- ing the well-being (utility) of an individual, subject to her re- sources (budget constraint). 3 UTILITY MAPPING OF PREFERENCES Indifference function: A utility function is some mathemat- ical representation: U = u(X1;X2;X3; :::) where X1;X2;X3; and so on are the goods consumed by the individual and u(:; :; :::) is some mathematical function that describes how the consumption of those goods translates to utility p Example with two goods: u(X1;X2) = X1 · X2 with X1 num- ber of movies, X2 number of music songs Individual utility increases with the level of consumption of each good 4 PREFERENCES AND INDIFFERENCE CURVES Indifference curve: A graphical representation of all bundles of goods that make an individual equally well off. Because these bundles have equal utility, an individual is indifferent as to which bundle he consumes Mathematically, indifference curve giving utility level U¯ is given by the set of bundles (X1;X2) such that u(X1;X2) = U¯ Indifference curves have two essential properties, both of which follow naturally from the more-is-better assumption: 1.
    [Show full text]
  • Exchange Economy in Two-User Multiple-Input Single-Output
    1 Exchange Economy in Two-User Multiple-Input Single-Output Interference Channels Rami Mochaourab, Student Member, IEEE, and Eduard Jorswieck, Senior Member, IEEE Abstract—We study the conflict between two links in a Pareto optimal point is an achievable utility tuple from which it multiple-input single-output interference channel. This setting is is impossible to increase the performance of one link without strictly competitive and can be related to perfectly competitive degrading the performance of another. Consequently, Pareto market models. In such models, general equilibrium theory is used to determine equilibrium measures that are Pareto optimal. optimality ensures efficient exploitation of the wireless channel First, we consider the links to be consumers that can trade resources. For this purpose, there has been several work on goods within themselves. The goods in our setting correspond to characterizing the set of beamforming vectors that are relevant beamforming vectors. We utilize the conflict representation of the for Pareto optimal operation in the MISO IFC [4]–[8]. Next, consumers in the Edgeworth box, a graphical tool that depicts we will discuss these approaches. the allocation of the goods for the two consumers, to provide closed-form solution to all Pareto optimal outcomes. Afterwards, we model the situation between the links as a competitive market A. Characterization of Pareto Optimal Points which additionally defines prices for the goods. The equilibrium in this economy is called Walrasian and corresponds to the prices Designing a Pareto optimal mechanism requires finding the that equate the demand to the supply of goods. We calculate joint beamforming vectors used at the transmitters that lead the unique Walrasian equilibrium and propose a coordination process that is realized by an arbitrator which distributes the to the Pareto optimal point.
    [Show full text]
  • Mathematical Economics
    Mathematical Economics Dr Wioletta Nowak, room 205 C [email protected] http://prawo.uni.wroc.pl/user/12141/students-resources Syllabus Mathematical Theory of Demand Utility Maximization Problem Expenditure Minimization Problem Mathematical Theory of Production Profit Maximization Problem Cost Minimization Problem General Equilibrium Theory Neoclassical Growth Models Models of Endogenous Growth Theory Dynamic Optimization Syllabus Mathematical Theory of Demand • Budget Constraint • Consumer Preferences • Utility Function • Utility Maximization Problem • Optimal Choice • Properties of Demand Function • Indirect Utility Function and its Properties • Roy’s Identity Syllabus Mathematical Theory of Demand • Expenditure Minimization Problem • Expenditure Function and its Properties • Shephard's Lemma • Properties of Hicksian Demand Function • The Compensated Law of Demand • Relationship between Utility Maximization and Expenditure Minimization Problem Syllabus Mathematical Theory of Production • Production Functions and Their Properties • Perfectly Competitive Firms • Profit Function and Profit Maximization Problem • Properties of Input Demand and Output Supply Syllabus Mathematical Theory of Production • Cost Minimization Problem • Definition and Properties of Conditional Factor Demand and Cost Function • Profit Maximization with Cost Function • Long and Short Run Equilibrium • Total Costs, Average Costs, Marginal Costs, Long-run Costs, Short-run Costs, Cost Curves, Long-run and Short-run Cost Curves Syllabus Mathematical Theory of Production Monopoly Oligopoly • Cournot Equilibrium • Quantity Leadership – Slackelberg Model Syllabus General Equilibrium Theory • Exchange • Market Equilibrium Syllabus Neoclassical Growth Model • The Solow Growth Model • Introduction to Dynamic Optimization • The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Growth Model Models of Endogenous Growth Theory Convergence to the Balance Growth Path Recommended Reading • Chiang A.C., Wainwright K., Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics, McGraw-Hill/Irwin, Boston, Mass., (4th edition) 2005.
    [Show full text]
  • 3 Scarcity, Work and Choice
    Beta September 2015 version 3 SCARCITY, WORK AND CHOICE Shutterstock HOW INDIVIDUALS DO THE BEST THEY CAN, GIVEN THE CONSTRAINTS THEY FACE, AND HOW THEY RESOLVE THE TRADE-OFF BETWEEN EARNINGS AND FREE TIME • Decision-making under scarcity is a common problem because we usually have limited means available to meet our objectives • Economists model these situations: first by defining all of the possible actions • ... then evaluating which of these actions is best, given the objectives • Opportunity cost describes an unavoidable trade-off in the presence of scarcity: satisfying one objective more means satisfying other objectives less • This model can be applied to the question of how much time to spend working, when facing a trade-off between more free time and more income • This model also helps to explain differences in the hours that people work in different countries and also the changes in our hours of work through history See www.core-econ.org for the full interactive version of The Economy by The CORE Project. Guide yourself through key concepts with clickable figures, test your understanding with multiple choice questions, look up key terms in the glossary, read full mathematical derivations in the Leibniz supplements, watch economists explain their work in Economists in Action – and much more. 2 coreecon | Curriculum Open-access Resources in Economics Imagine that you are working in New York, in a job that is paying you $15 an hour for a 40-hour working week: so your earnings are $600 per week. There are 24 hours in a day and 168 hours in a week so, after 40 hours of work, you are left with 128 hours of free time for all your non-work activities, including leisure and sleep.
    [Show full text]