Against Partisan Gerrymandering

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Against Partisan Gerrymandering The Third Criterion: Compactness as a Procedural Safeguard Against Partisan Gerrymandering Daniel D. Polsbyt and Robert D. Poppertt The health of democracies, of whatever type and range, depends on a wretched technical detail-electoral procedure. All the rest is secondary.' In the aftermath of the decennial census, reapportionment and its wayward stepchild gerrymandering have again become topics of the hour. In 1991 or 1992, based on the new census, state legislatures will establish new boundaries for congressional and state legislative districts. 2 In order to conform to the constitutional mandate that districts have equal populations 3-"one person, one vote" 4-states will have to redraw district lines to account for population shifts that have accumulated over the past ten years. Yet reapportionment, made necessary by fidelity to democratic principles, also will bring with it gerryman- dering. Gerrymandering, broadly speaking, is any manipulation of district lines for partisan purposes. 5 There are different varieties of gerrymandering, includ- ing racial gerrymandering, 6 remedial racial gerrymandering, 7 and collusive bipartisan gerrymandering. 8 Partisan gerrymandering, the most common kind t Daniel D. Polsby is the Kirkland & Ellis Professor of Law at Northwestern University. tt Robert D. Popper is an associate at Orrick, Herrington & Sutcliffe in New York. Many people helped and challenged us as we prepared this article, but particular, grateful acknowledgement must be made to at least the following: Lynn Baker, Pamela Karlan, Bill Stuntz, and the participants in the University of Virginia Legal Studies workshop; Michael Fitts, Michael Moore, Stephen Morse, Jerry Newman, Menachim Speigel, and the participants in the University of Pennsylvania Law School workshop; Robert Bennett, Robert Burns, Mayer Freed, Mark Grady, David Haddock, Gary Lawson, and Victor Rosenblum of the Northwestern law faculty; John F. Beukema of the Minnesota Bar; Bruce Cain of the University of California political science faculty; and Brendan Duffy of Raymond Marketing, Inc. As always, the conventional absolutions apply. 1. JOSE ORTEGA Y GASSET, THE REVOLT OF THE MASSES 158 (1932). 2. Under Article I, Section 4 of the Constitution, state legislatures exercise the districting power subject to supervening congressional regulation. 3. The constitutional basis for this requirement is the Equal Protection Clause of the Fourteenth Amendment for state elections, or, in the case of federal elections, Article I, Section 2 of the Constitution, which provides that representatives shall be elected by "the people." See Reynolds v. Sims, 377 U.S. 533 (1964) (state legislatures); Wesberry v. Sanders, 376 U.S. 1 (1964) (federal districts). 4. Gray v. Sanders, 372 U.S. 368, 381 (1963); see also Reynolds, 377 U.S. at 558. 5. See, e.g., Richard L. Engstrom, The Supreme Court and Equipopulous Gerrymandering: A Remaining Obstacle in the QuestforFair and Effective Representation, 1976 ARIZ. ST. L. J. 277, 278-280. 6. Gomillion v. Lightfoot, 364 U.S. 339 (1960). 7. Race-conscious line-drawing is one of the remedies available under the Voting Rights Act of 1965, 42 U.S.C. § 1973 (1988); see United Jewish Org. of Williamsburg v. Carey, 430 U.S. 144 (1977). 8. See e.g., Gaffney v. Cummings, 412 U.S. 735 (1973) (upholding bipartisan gerrymandering accord between Democratic and Republican members of Connecticut's legislature). Other kinds of districts, including school, hospital, tax or judicial districts, also can be gerrymandered. Yale Law & Policy Review Vol. 9:301, 1991 and the subject of this paper, is undertaken by the political party in control of a state legislature to help itself and injure its competitor. It should not be surprising that redistricting is the occasion for so much gamey partisan brawling, for in the districting game legislators are fighting for their own political lives and that of their party, just as surely as in an election campaign, but with more durable results. Depending on how district lines are drawn, a party with only a minority of the popular vote can assert control over a majority of seats in the state assembly and over its state's delegation to the national House of Representatives. More typically, a party that enjoys only a small majority in popular support over its principal competi- tor will, through its control of the districting process, translate this popular edge into preemptive institutional dominance. Potential remedies for gerrymandering, as Bernard Grofman has pointed out, come in two varieties: political and formal.9 A political remedy, for example, might require that a redistricting plan satisfy a panel of bipartisan commissioners, or that it be adopted by a supermajority of the legislature. The remedy we propose is formal. In addition to adhering to criteria which mandate that representational districts be composed of contiguous territories and have equal populations, we suggest that those who define district boundaries must also be required to respect a third criterion, the constraint of compactness. Without the ability to distend district lines so as to include or exclude blocks of voters whose political loyalties are known, it is not practically possible to gerrymander. The diagnostic mark of the gerrymander is the noncompact district. Anyone who eyeballs a few legislative district maps quickly will learn to recognize gerrymanders, although admittedly with imper- fect accuracy. But one need not rely on seat-of-the-pants reckoning to find the sort of noncompactness that implies gerrymandering. A number of mathemati- cal measures of compactness exist, some of which are no more difficult to apply than the "one person, one vote" standard of Reynolds v. Sims.1 o These measurements are useful because they correspond closely to a mapmaker's practical ability to gerrymander districts. One of these compactness measures, as we show in part III.D, is the best way to measure the kind of non-com- pactness that is required for a workable gerrymander. 9. Bernard Grofman, Criteriafor Districting:A Social Science Perspective, 33 UCLA L. REv. 77, 79, 98-99 (1985). 10. 377 U.S. 533, 579 (1964). The Third Criterion I. GERRYMANDERING AND POLITICS At the time of Elbridge Gerry, the eponymous gerrymanderer," and for almost 200 years until Baker v. Carr," abusive partisan districting was a relatively simple matter because there was no constitutional requirement that districts be equinumerous. 13 Malapportionment was so powerful a tool for diluting the opposition's votes that partisans needed no other.' 4 With the advent of "one person, one vote" and periodic reapportionment, the focus of partisan districting changed. Creative gerrymandering now has replaced the older strategy of malapportionment through legislative inaction. Although districts must be equal in population, they need not have any particu- lar shape or character, and they still may be manipulated to suit partisan needs. Happily for partisans, the apportionment revolution coincided with technical innovations in computers and in market research that made modern gerry- mandering both easy and effective.' 5 Professional advice on effective gerry- mandering is now a staple of the political consulting business. 6 The techniques for gerrymandering are simple and widely understood. In single-member districts, only one legislator can win an election. Any support beyond fifty-percent-plus-one is therefore superfluous, or, from the party's point of view, "wasted." The partisan mapmaker seeks to draw lines which concentrate the opposition's electoral support in just a few districts (called "packing" or "stacking"), while at the same time creating many more districts 11. ELMER GRFFrrH, THE RISE AND DEVELOPMENT OF THE GERRYMANDER 19 (1907). 12. 369 U.S. 186 (1962). Baker established the justiciability of constitutional challenges to malappor- tioned districts. 13. Until 2 U.S.C. § 2a was amended in 1929, there was a statutory requirement that districts be equal in population and be compact, but both requirements were routinely ignored. See RicHARD CORTNER, THE APPORTIONMENT CASES 15 n.32 (1970); see also, Colegrove v. Green, 328 U.S. 549, 551, 555 (1946). Since 1929, no equivalent statutory provision has been on the books. 14. See infra part III.A. 15. Gerrymandering software for desktop computers increases in power and sophistication almost by the month, with correlative augmentations in the capabilities of those with the political authority to draw district boundaries. See Anderson & Dahlstrom, Technological Gerrymandering, 22 URBAN LAWYER 59, 73-76 (1990); William E. Schmidt, New Age of Gerrymandering:Political Magic by Computer?, N.Y. TIMEs, January 10, 1989 at Al; Mitch Betts, Gerrymandering Made Easy in 1990, COMPUTERWORLD, Aug. 28, 1989, at 1. The generation of computers which drew the gerrymanders of the 1980s are almost certainly obsolete. Now, for example, there is the Topographical Integration Geographic Encoding and Referencing (TIGER), the U.S. Census Bureau's "new, high-tech map of America ... [that] means that anyone can quite cheaply buy a detailed computerized map of any state-accurate down to street lev- el-loaded with demographic data. Combined with other new technology this means that almost anyone will be able to draw their own political maps." See Drawing Salamanders, ECONOMIST, Jan. 6, 1990, at 26, 30. 16. See, e.g., David Anderson, Note, When Restraint Requires Activism: Partisan Gerrymandering and the Status Quo Ante, 42 STANFORD L. REV. 1549, 1557 (1990) ("[In
Recommended publications
  • MAURICE DUVERGER, UN JURISTE SOUS VICHY EN 1940-1941 Fantin FABRE1
    MAURICE DUVERGER, UN JURISTE SOUS VICHY EN 1940-1941 Fantin FABRE1 Para citar este artículo puede utilizarse el siguiente formato: Fantin Fabre (2015): «Maurice Duverger, un juriste sous Vichy en 1940-1941», en Revista europea de historia de las ideas políticas y de las instituciones públicas, nº 9 (diciembre 2015). Puede leerse este artículo en línea en: http://www.eumed.net/rev/rehipip/09/duverger-vichy.html. RESUME : Âgé de vingt-trois ans, Maurice Duverger débute dans la doctrine avec une présentation des textes du régime de Vichy modifiant le statut des fonctionnaires. Ces derniers prévoyaient d'exclure les juifs de la fonction publique. L'article de M. Duverger lui a posé problème à plusieurs reprises. Il est étudié la façon dont l'auteur, par l'utilisation de l'exégèse en fonction de la posture qu'il prétend avoir eu, s'est retrouvé dans une impasse méthodologique. Des raisons paradoxales aux implications concrètes, M. Duverger n'est pas sans ambiguïté dans sa démarche. Il est important de savoir l'erreur qui a été faite afin d'éviter de la reproduire. MOTS-CLEFS : Doctrine, Exégèse, Positivisme, Vichy, Fonction publique, Neutralité, Méthodologie, Science du droit, Responsabilité. ABSTRACT : Twenty three years old, Maurice Duverger begins in the doctrine with a presentation of the texts of the Vichy's Regim modifying the status of the state employees. This texts planned to exclude the Jews of the public service. The M. Duverger's article raised him problem repeatedly. It is studied that the way the author, by the use of the exegesis according to the posture whom he claims to have had, found himself in a methodological dead end.
    [Show full text]
  • Reclaiming Their Shadow: Ethnopolitical Mobilization in Consolidated Democracies
    Reclaiming their Shadow: Ethnopolitical Mobilization in Consolidated Democracies Ph. D. Dissertation by Britt Cartrite Department of Political Science University of Colorado at Boulder May 1, 2003 Dissertation Committee: Professor William Safran, Chair; Professor James Scarritt; Professor Sven Steinmo; Associate Professor David Leblang; Professor Luis Moreno. Abstract: In recent decades Western Europe has seen a dramatic increase in the political activity of ethnic groups demanding special institutional provisions to preserve their distinct identity. This mobilization represents the relative failure of centuries of assimilationist policies among some of the oldest nation-states and an unexpected outcome for scholars of modernization and nation-building. In its wake, the phenomenon generated a significant scholarship attempting to account for this activity, much of which focused on differences in economic growth as the root cause of ethnic activism. However, some scholars find these models to be based on too short a timeframe for a rich understanding of the phenomenon or too narrowly focused on material interests at the expense of considering institutions, culture, and psychology. In response to this broader debate, this study explores fifteen ethnic groups in three countries (France, Spain, and the United Kingdom) over the last two centuries as well as factoring in changes in Western European thought and institutions more broadly, all in an attempt to build a richer understanding of ethnic mobilization. Furthermore, by including all “national
    [Show full text]
  • How an Outdated Electoral Structure Has Led to Political Polarization in the United States
    The United States Election System: How an Outdated Electoral Structure has led to Political Polarization in the United States by Jake Fitzharris A THESIS submitted to Oregon State University Honors College in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Honors Baccalaureate of Science in Political Science and Psychology (Honors Associate) Presented January 24, 2019 Commencement June 2019 AN ABSTRACT OF THE THESIS OF Jake Fitzharris for the degree of Honors Baccalaureate of Science in Political Science and Psychology presented on January 24, 2019. Title: The United States Election System: How an Outdated Electoral Structure has led to Political Polarization in the United States. Abstract approved:_____________________________________________________ Christopher Nichols Political Polarization in the United States is at a level higher today than at any point in the past few decades. Possible causes of this rise in polarization have been provided from various sources, including explanations such as mass media and income inequality. Through historical analysis and a wide literature review, this thesis explores a major factor in political polarization, the United States election system. The thesis argues that the election system in the United States exacerbates the intensely polarized political climate of the modern day United States in three main ways: the electoral college, which produces the persisting two party system, primary elections, which reinforce extreme candidate views, and districting, which tends to increase politically uniform districts and lead candidates to position themselves at the poles rather than in the center. The thesis concludes that the only way to eliminate political polarization stemming from all of these sources would be to implement a unique proportional representation system for the United States.
    [Show full text]
  • Duverger Chapter Maestri Elgie
    MAURICE DUVERGER: A LAW, A HYPOTHESIS AND A PARADOX Robert Elgiei In Donatella Campus, Gianfranco Pasquino and Martin Bull eds., Maestri of Political Science, volume 2, Colchester: ECPR Press, pp. 75-92, ISBN 9781907301193 INTRODUCTION Maurice Duverger was born in Angoulême, France, in 1917. He is undoubtedly the most influential French political scientist to date. Indeed, it would scarcely be an exaggeration to suggest that he is also perhaps the most well-known political scientist anywhere, given that all students of politics are bound to come across Duverger’s Law at some point or another in their professional studies. As we shall see, Duverger’s work profoundly shaped the international political science research agenda and it did so in three distinct areas – the study of party organisations, the consequences of electoral systems, and the concept of semi- presidentialism. The paradox, though, and we may wish to call it Duverger’s Paradox, is that the ideas for which Duverger was internationally famous had very little impact on the research agenda within France. With the notable exception of Jean Blondel, who spent almost all of his working life outside France, there are very few other French political scientists who have studied political parties comparatively. The same is true for the study of electoral systems. Perhaps most tellingly of all, there are very few scholars within France who are willing even to entertain the concept of semi-presidentialism, particularly those whose training lies in constitutional and public law. In both his academic work and his popular writings Duverger was often a controversial and contested figure.
    [Show full text]
  • Rehabilitating Duverger's Theory: Testing the Mechanical
    Comparative Political Studies Volume 39 Number 6 10.1177/0010414005278420ComparativeClark, Golder Political / Rehabilitating Studies Duverger ’s Theory August 2006 679-708 © 2006 Sage Publications 10.1177/0010414005278420 Rehabilitating http://cps.sagepub.com hosted at Duverger’s Theory http://online.sagepub.com Testing the Mechanical and Strategic Modifying Effects of Electoral Laws William Roberts Clark University of Michigan, Ann Arbor Matt Golder Florida State University, Tallahassee Although Duverger is traditionally seen as synonymous with the institution- alist approach to party systems, this article shows that he believed social pres- sures were the driving force behind the multiplication of parties. Electoral institutions are important, but only because they determine the extent to which social forces are translated into political parties. Although the literature has finally come to realize that social and institutional forces interact to shape party systems, scholars still do not seem to fully understood the implications of Duverger’s theory. This article shows that existing research employs flawed statistical specifications, makes inferential errors, and does not calculate de- sired quantities of interest. Using a new data set that includes elections since 1946, the authors reexamine Duverger’s theory and find that modern tests largely bear out his expectations when properly specified and interpreted. This analysis also extends current research by specifically estimating the mechani- cal and strategic modifying effects of electoral institutions. Keywords: Duverger; social heterogeneity; party systems; electoral institutions he literature addressing the number of political parties in a polity is one T of the richest in comparative politics (Cox, 1997; Duverger, 1954/1963; Lijphart, 1994; Lipset & Rokkan, 1967; Riker, 1982).
    [Show full text]
  • Why Do Political Parties Exist? Who Is the Party?
    Why Parties? What/who is a political party? What do political parties do? Why do political parties exist? Who is the Party? • Members • Identifiers • Elected Officials • Organizations Classic “Tripartite” Distinction • Parties as Organizations • Parties in the Electorate • Parties in Government Activities/Functions • Field candidates for public office • Organize caucuses, primaries, and conventions to conduct party business • Organize legislative activity to coordinate work of their elected members • Develop public policies • Articulate a platform and/or ideology for governing • Inform and mobilize members of the electorate Normative View: Why We Need Parties? • Diverse Coalitions that override particular interests. • Provide Collective Responsibility. • Ease Task of Voters. • Responsible Party Government: – Complex system requires cohesive parties. – Drawbacks? Positive Views: Why We Have Parties… ….Or Why Politicians Create Parties: – Overcome ambitious office-seekers problem – Overcome social choice problems in decision- making bodies – Overcome collective action problems in elections Electoral Rules & Party Fortunes Defining Party Systems Explaining Party Systems What is a Party System? • “Party System” as a Pattern of Party Competition – Describes a country by the number and character of its parties – May be irrespective of identities of parties • “Party System” as a Particular Time Period – Describes a political era by the nature of its party competition – Primarily concerned with identity of parties & balance of power – Examples
    [Show full text]
  • L'esprit Des Lois ? L'étude Des Modes De Scrutin Un Demi-Siècle Après Les
    G3/400-D63162-LC-CR-521à 538 Page 524 Mercredi, 20. juillet 2005 12:49 12 Document téléchargé depuis www.cairn.info - Institut d'Etudes Politiques de Paris 193.54.67.93 31/10/2014 15h23. © Presses Sciences Po L’esprit des lois ? L’étude des modes de scrutin un demi-siècle après Les partis politiques de Maurice Duverger Peu d’œuvres peuvent aujourd’hui prétendre à une postérité aussi marquante que l’analyse faite par Maurice Duverger de l’effet des modes de scrutin 1. Cette analyse aura non seulement marqué son temps en structurant les débats 2, mais peu d’auteurs, et notamment d’auteurs fran- çais, voient encore aujourd’hui leur nom aussi souvent cité. Cette postérité est assurément liée à la formulation des conclusions sous forme de loi, les fameuses trois lois suivant lesquelles les systèmes partisans tendent (le déterminisme reproché à M. Duverger doit de ce point de vue être relativisé) à être bipartisan, multipartite ou multipartite, mais avec coalitions électorales stables, suivant que le mode de scrutin est majoritaire à un tour, proportionnel ou bien majoritaire à deux tours. Mais ces lois sont également soutenues par une théorie explicative du rôle structurant des modes de scrutin par la distinction d’effets mécaniques (ceux liés à la transformation des voix en sièges par l’arithmétique de la loi électorale) d’effets psychologiques, résultant de la sophistica- tion des choix d’électeurs anticipant les effets mécaniques du mode de scrutin. Ces différentes pistes ouvertes par M. Duverger ont directement incité de nombreux auteurs à proposer des analyses plus poussées des mécanismes en jeu.
    [Show full text]
  • Constitutional Frameworks and Democratic Consolidation: Parliamentarianism Versus Presidentialism Author(S): Alfred Stepan and Cindy Skach Source: World Politics, Vol
    Constitutional Frameworks and Democratic Consolidation: Parliamentarianism versus Presidentialism Author(s): Alfred Stepan and Cindy Skach Source: World Politics, Vol. 46, No. 1 (Oct., 1993), pp. 1-22 Published by: Cambridge University Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2950664 Accessed: 12/08/2010 11:50 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=cup. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Cambridge University Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to World Politics. http://www.jstor.org CONSTITUTIONAL FRAMEWORKS AND DEMOCRATIC CONSOLIDATION Parliamentarianismversus Presidentialism By ALFRED STEPAN and CINDY SKACH* INTRODUCTION T HE struggle to consolidate the new democracies-especially those in Eastern Europe, Latin America, and Asia-has given rise to a wide-ranging debate about the hard choices concerning economic re- structuring, economic institutions, and economic markets.' A similar de- bate has focused on democratic political institutions and political markets.
    [Show full text]
  • Contemporary Democracy in a Parliamentary System*
    CONTEMPORARY DEMOCRACY IN A PARLIAMENTARY SYSTEM* KAZUYUKI TAKAHASHI* * I INTRODUCTION Since recovering its independence in 1952, Japan has never experienced a change of government in a proper sense. Power has been held without interruption, first by the Liberal Party and then by the Liberal Democratic Party ("LDP"), which was formed in 1955 when the Liberal and Democratic Parties merged. It is often said that there is no democracy without a change of government. Does this mean that Japan has not yet established a democracy? I would not say so. No doubt the Japanese have succeeded in running their government in a democratic manner, at least compared to the prewar era. But democracy has different styles and qualities, and Japan has achieved a democracy that has never been tested by a transfer of power. A change of government has two implications for the quality of democracy. First, a change of government confirms the existence of democracy. There is no better proof that democracy exists than the fact that a change of government takes place following a free popular election. Second, popular belief in the possibility of a change of government, supported and strengthened by actual experience, enables the people to make a real choice. Where there is no significant chance of altering government, elections lose their meaning. The people are forced either to accept the existing government or embrace uncertainty by rejecting it. But rejecting the government in power while not being able to conceive of an alternative is a hard venture. Hard as it may be, however, rejection is possible.
    [Show full text]
  • Semi-Presidential Systems: Dual Executive and Mixed Authority
    French Politics, 2005, 3, (323–351) r 2005 Palgrave Macmillan Ltd 1476-3419/05 $30.00 www.palgrave-journals.com/fp Semi-Presidential Systems: Dual Executive And Mixed Authority Patterns Matthew Søberg Shugart Graduate School of International Relations and Pacific Studies, University of California, San Diego, USA. E-mail: [email protected] Maurice Duverger in 1980 advanced the concept of a ‘semi-presidential’ regime: a mix of a popularly elected and powerful presidency with a prime minister heading a cabinet subject to assembly confidence.We can understand the performance of these regimes through a neo-Madisonian perspective that stresses agency relations between institutional actors.Executive and legislature as separate agents of the electorate — as in presidentialism — necessitates transactional interbranch relations.Fusion of powers — as in parliamentarism — means an executive that is hierarchically subordinated to the legislature.The dual executive of a semi- presidential system mixes a transactional executive-legislative relationship with a hierarchical one.The advantages of this perspective include allowing delinea- tion of semi-presidentialism from other hybrids, highlighting subtypes (premier- presidential and president-parliamentary) according to variations in the locus of transactional and hierarchical institutional relationships, and predicting which observed relationships between actors derive from relatively immutable constitutional features and which from more transitory features such as partisan alignments. French Politics
    [Show full text]
  • The May Events: from Practice to Theory
    1 The May Events: From Practice to Theory Andrew Feenberg 2 Preface These translations of documents collected on the streets of Paris in May 1968 were intended for inclusion in a book later published as When Poetry Ruled the Streets. In the end, they were not published in that book but have been posted to the May Events Archive at http://edocs.lib.sfu.ca/projects/mai68/ where the originals can also be found. The texts were selected for their theoretical interest. While the May Events lives on in memory primarily through scenes of violence in the streets of Paris, a great deal of serious debate was also going on. The debates inspired the production of significant documents. It is unfortunate that Marxist have not yet learned the lessons of May. This was the last great anti-capitalist uprising in the West but it is treated as a symbol rather than analyzed as a historical experience. These documents offer hints of what those lessons are. Perhaps the most unexpected revelation of the May Events was the potential for collaboration between professional and technical personnel and a socialist mass movement. The documents offer analyses of this phenomenon based on traditional Marxist notions and innovative approaches that break with that tradition to focus on the emergence of new class relations. The picture that emerges provides perspective on many later struggles in which radical professionals, scientists and technologists have collaborated with left movements. It also suggests the possibility of a new mode of socialist governance based on permanent dialogue between technical experts and those they nominally serve.
    [Show full text]
  • The Mechanical and Psychological Effects of Electoral Systems
    Sorting Out Mechanical and Psychological Effects in Candidate Elections: An Appraisal with Experimental Datai Karine VAN DER STRAETEN (Toulouse School of Economics, France) Nicolas SAUGER (Sciences‐Po Paris, France) Jean‐François LASLIER (Ecole Polytechnique, France) André BLAIS (Université de Montréal, Canada) i We thank the French Agence Nationale de la Recherche (Project “2 Tours”, coordinator: Annie Laurent), the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada (Project “Making Electoral Democracy Work”, coordinator: André Blais), the Center for the Study of Democratic Citizenship, and the Centre pour la Recherche Economique et ses Applications (CEPREMAP) for their financial support. Abstract The paper proposes a way to measure mechanical and psychological effects of majority runoff versus plurality electoral systems in candidate elections. Building on a series of laboratory experiments, we evaluate these effects with respect to the probability of electing a Condorcet winner candidate. In our experiment, the runoff system very slightly favours the Condorcet winner candidate, but this total effect is small. We show that this is the case because the mechanical and psychological effects tend to cancel each other out. Compared to plurality, the mechanical effect of runoffs is to systematically advantage the Condorcet winner candidate, as usually assumed; but our study detects an opposite psychological effect, to the disadvantage of this candidate. 1 Most of the literature about electoral systems is based on Maurice Duverger’s intuitions.ii Duverger claims that electoral systems have systematic effects (hence the well‐known “laws”) on the structure of electoral competition. In particular, the plurality rule entails a two‐party system whereas majority runoff leads to multiparty competition.
    [Show full text]