The Use of Econometric Models in Developing Countries

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Use of Econometric Models in Developing Countries This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Short-Term Macroeconomic Policy in Latin America Volume Author/Editor: Jere R. Behrman and James Hanson, eds. Volume Publisher: NBER Volume ISBN: 0-88410-489-3 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/behr79-1 Publication Date: 1979 Chapter Title: The Use of Econometric Models in Developing Countries Chapter Author: Jere Behrman, James A. Hanson Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c3882 Chapter pages in book: (p. 1 - 38) 1 F JEREBEHRMAN TheUse of and Econometric JAMES A. HANSON Modelsin Developing Countries* 1. INTRODUCTION National-income-determinationmodels and stabilization have not been the major concern of either empirical or theoretical macro- economic analysis in the developing economies. For example, a recentsurveyofthestateof theartregardingthe use of economywide models for less developed countries (LDCs), Blitzer, et a!. (1975), does not even include a chapter on macroeconomic income-determination models. Instead, the dominant frameworks for macroeconomic policy analysis and policy recommendations have been provided by Harrod- Domaraggregate-growth models,staticanddynamiclinear- programming models, and Chenery-Strout two-gap models.' These *This paper draws on Behrman, "Econometric Modeling of National Income Determination in Latin America, with Special Reference to the Chilean Ex- perience," presented at the Seminar on Use of Econometric Models in Latin America, sponsored by The Center of Economic and Demographic Studies of El Colegio de Mexico and the National Bureau of Economic Research, held in Mexico City on November 27-29, 1974. 1 2 Short Term Macroeconomic Policy in Latin America modelsgenerally include assumptions that: (i) the degree of capacity utilization, the rate of inflation, and the level of aggregate demand are unimportant considerations; (ii) that the financial constraints on government and central bank behavior (and, thus, the entire fiscal-monetary-income-internationalpolicy-inflationnexus)can be ignored; (iii) short-run flexibility is limited by low elasticities of substitution and short-run unresponsiveness to price; (iv) (at least for the programming models on which the greatest resources have been expended) the most interesting question is "what could happen if socially optimal readjustment of the economy occurred in response to policy changes," rather than "what would happen if the independent economic units which make up the economy followed their traditional behavioral patterns in response to such changes."2 The resulting models usually include only real phenomena and are characterized by supply bottlenecks resulting from foreign exchange or capital constraints. Such an emphasis reflects two widely held views: (1) Growth is a relatively more important economic objective (and stabilization less important) in the developing countries than in the developed coun- tries. (2) Income-determination models involving demand as well as supply are of limited value for developing economies.3 Some exceptions to the predominant view have long existed. The participants in the "structuralist-monetarist" controversy in Latin America, for example, accorded significant importance to inflation and stabilization policies in the development process.4 These exceptions have been increasing in number. The recognition by such authors as Schydlowsky (Chapter 9, this volume) and Behrmari (1973b) of considerable underutilized capacity, particularly in cyclical downturns, has increased interest in using national-income- determination models for stabilization purposes. Numerous partial equilibrium econometric estimates have been made that imply sig. nificantly nonzero elasticities of substitution and significant responses to prices in both capacity utilization and capacity creation decisions.5 Even the strongest advocates of supply-oriented capital and foreign- exchange-constrained analysis seem to be having second thoughts about the importance of short-run factors and stabilization problems. For example, throughout the above-cited survey by Blitzer, et al. (1975), there are frequent references to the need to consider short-run features (e.g., prices responses, capacity utilization determination, aggregate.demand.related policies). d Recently, because of this growing interest in stabilization and othershort-runproblems,alarge number of Keynesian-based national-income-determination models have been constructed and utilized for the developing economies.6 •4'l r TheUse of Econometric Models in Developing Countries 3 Abasic problem with the construction and use of these models for policymaking purposes in developing economies is the general lack of I accurate,up-to-date information (e.g., quarterly information on out- ts put and its components and sectoral or cyclical indicators that are • re available with a short time lag). This is a gap that at present forces policymakers to act on incorrect or dated information.7It also means that income-determination models of developing countries are a annual rather than quarterly. However, in the developed countries econometric models have been "most successful" in predicting out- put in the next quarter or six months; over a nine or twelve-month • period simple trends are often as good.8 Thus improvement in modeling may require an investment in improving the data base, an :2 investmentthat has the additional payoff of providing more accurate and up-to-date information to policymakers.9 e There remains the more philosophical question of our present abil- ity to forecast and affect in predictable ways the very short run with corresponding effects on the long run. However, political pressures a force governments to accept some advice and take some action in the -s very short run, often to the detriment of the long run. Therefore, it is probably best for economists to offer advice on the short run and on short-run—long-run tradeoffs while specifying the fragile nature of such advice. e • A second problem results from a simplistic transfer of aggregate demand models of developed economies with little or no adjustment for the special conditions in the developing countries. As a result, there are numerous shortcomings in such models' specifications, shortcomings that, while they may also exist in developed country d applications, are perhaps less important in that context. For ex- ample: (1) National income is determined by aggregate demand in a Keynesian fashion with no testing for the existence of possible con- straints due to the stocks of capital or labor, the supply of foreign exchange, or supply limitations imposed by quantitative restric- tions.'° (2) Underemployed or surplus labor and dualism in the labor market I are not explicitly incorporated. (3) Aggregation is so great that there is no possibility of capturing the impact of policies on relative prices, even though economists like Hansen (1973b) have maintained that policies in developing nations are primarily reflected in altered relative prices and Wachter (Chapter 8, this volume) has demonstrated, econometrically, the structuralist proposition that differing speeds of adjustment of relative prices (plus passive money) may result in inflation. The possible importance of intersectoral d flows, moreover, is lost by the high level of aggregation. On the other d hand, data problems are often cited as preventing disaggregation to any significant level, and there remains the question of whether dis- I 4 Short Term Macroeconomic Policy in Latin America aggregatedmodels provide more accurate projections of the aggregate variables, and to what extent such models divert attention from more global problems, such as the financial-monetary-international policy- income nexus. (4) Potential policy variables are often overlooked. For example, it is often assumed that an overvalued exchange rate willbe maintained through a continuance of exchange control ai although this is obviously a policy that is subject to change. (5) The significance of the foreign sector as a source of noncompetitive, intermediate imports, of capital goods, of government finance, and of household money and nonmonetary asset holdings is not well presented. (6) The importance—owing to fragmented and poorly functioning capital markets—of direct flows and retained earnings in the real investment process is not explored. (7) The degree of endog- eneity of fiscal, monetary, and international variables and their inter- relation in poorly functioning capital markets is ignored with the result that policy options are overstated. (8) There is little attempt to integrate the short-run income-determination model with long-run c developmentmodels. In particular, although plant and equipment decisions are well treated, no attempt is made to study human capital formation, despite the growing evidence for its significance in devel- opment. The role of social overhead capital, long emphasized by such leading development economists as Rosenstein-Rodan (1961), also ir is not explored.''(9) There is a tendency to ignore economywide disequilibrium.'2 ai At the same time as interest in and use of income-determination— stabilization, models for the LDCs has been growing, controversies d have emerged over the specification of such models in the developed economies. In the past decade, critics have claimed that deficiencies U in the theoretical structure, deficiencies that may be related to points sI 1 to 9 above, make any analysis of stabilization policies based on p1 such
Recommended publications
  • Long Term Consequences of Early Childhood Malnutrition
    Long Term Consequences Of Early Childhood Malnutrition Harold Alderman, World Bank John Hoddinott, Dalhousie University and IFPRI Bill Kinsey, University of Zimbabwe and Free University, Amsterdam June 2002 Acknowledgements The authors thank Jere Behrman and Hanan Jacoby, as well as seminar participants at Dalhousie, IFPRI, McMaster, Oxford, Toronto and the World Bank for insightful comments on earlier drafts. We gratefully acknowledge funding for survey work from the British Developme nt Division in Central Africa, UNICEF, the former Ministry of Lands, Resettlement and Rural Development, Zimbabwe, FAO, the Nuffield Foundation, ODI, DfID, IFPRI, CSAE Oxford, the Free University, Amsterdam, the Research Board of the University of Zimbabwe and the World Bank. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent. JEL classification: I12; I20; O15 Key words: health; education; shocks; Zimbabwe Address for correspondence: John Hoddinott, International Food Policy Research Institute, 2033 K Street NW, Washington DC, 20006, USA. em: [email protected] Long Term Consequences Of Early Childhood Malnutrition Abstract This paper explores the long-term consequences of shocks on children’s health and education using longitudinal data from rural Zimbabwe. We link exposure to the war preceding Zimbabwe’s independence and the 1982-84 drought to the health status of the children in our sample (as measured by their height-for-age in 1983, 1984 and 1987) and to their health and educational attainments as adolescents measured in 2000. Instrumental variables- maternal fixed effects estimates show a statistically significant relationship between height-for -age in children under 5 and height attained as a young adult, the number of grades of schooling completed and the age at which the child starts school.
    [Show full text]
  • Behrman 2011
    Do Conditional Cash Transfers for Schooling Generate Lasting Benefits? A Five-Year Followup of PROGRESA/Oportunidades Jere R. Behrman Susan W. Parker Petra E. Todd ABSTRACT Conditional cash transfer (CCT) programs link public transfers to human capital investment in hopes of alleviating current poverty and reducing its intergenerational transmission. However, little is known about their long- term impacts. This paper evaluates longer-run impacts on schooling and work of the best-known CCT program, Mexico’s PROGRESA/Oportunida- des, using experimental and nonexperimental estimators based on groups with different program exposure. The results show positive impacts on schooling, reductions in work for younger youth (consistent with postpon- ing labor force entry), increases in work for older girls, and shifts from agricultural to nonagricultural employment. The evidence suggests school- ing effects are robust with time. Jere R. Behrman is the W. R. Kenan Jr. Professor of Economics and Sociology and PSC research associ- ate at the University of Pennsylvania. Susan W. Parker is a professor/researcher in the Division of Eco- nomics at the Center for Research and Teaching in Economics (CIDE) in Mexico City. Petra E. Todd is professor of economics and a research associate of PSC at the University of Pennsylvania, the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) and the Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA). This work received support from the Instituto Nacional de Salud Publica (INSP) and the Mellon Foundation/Population Studies Center (PSC)/University of Pennsylvania grant to Todd (P.I.) on “Long-term Impact Evaluation of the Oportunidades Program in Rural Mexico.” The authors thank three anonymous referees, Bernardo Herna´ndez, Iliana Yaschine and seminar participants at the University of Pennsylvania, the World Bank, and the University of Goettingen for helpful comments on early versions of this paper.
    [Show full text]
  • The 4 Economic Systems What Is an Economic System?
    The 4 Economic Systems What is an Economic System? Economics is the study of how people make decisions given the resources that are provided to them Economics is all about CHOICES, both individual and group choices. We must make choices to provide for our needs and wants. The choices each society or nation selects leads to the creation of their type of economy. 3 Basic Questions Each economic system tries to answer the three basic questions: What should be produced? How it should be produced? For whom should it be produced? How they answer these questions determines the kind of system they have. Four Types of Systems There are four main types of economic systems. The Traditional Economic System The Command Economic System The Market Economic System The Mixed Economic System Each system has its strengths and weaknesses. Traditional Economy In a traditional economy, the customs and habits of the past are used to decide what and how goods will be produced, distributed, and consumed. Each member of society knows from early on what their role in the larger group will be. Jobs are passed down from generation to generation so there is little change in jobs over the generations. In a traditional economy, people are depended upon to fulfill their jobs. If someone fails to do their part, the system can break down. Farming, hunting, and herding are part of a traditional economy. Traditional economies can be found in different indigenous groups. In addition, traditional economies bartering is used for trade. Bartering is trading without money. For example, if an individual has a good and he trades it with another individual for a different good.
    [Show full text]
  • Ancient Economic Thought, Volume 1
    ANCIENT ECONOMIC THOUGHT This collection explores the interrelationship between economic practice and intellectual constructs in a number of ancient cultures. Each chapter presents a new, richer understanding of the preoccupation of the ancients with specific economic problems including distribution, civic pride, management and uncertainty and how they were trying to resolve them. The research is based around the different artifacts and texts of the ancient East Indian, Hebraic, Greek, Hellenistic, Roman and emerging European cultures which remain for our consideration today: religious works, instruction manuals, literary and historical writings, epigrapha and legal documents. In looking at such items it becomes clear what a different exercise it is to look forward, from the earliest texts and artifacts of any culture, to measure the achievements of thinking in the areas of economics, than it is to take the more frequent route and look backward, beginning with the modern conception of economic systems and theory creation. Presenting fascinating insights into the economic thinking of ancient cultures, this volume will enhance the reawakening of interest in ancient economic history and thought. It will be of great interest to scholars of economic thought and the history of ideas. B.B.Price is Professor of Ancient and Medieval History at York University, Toronto, and is currently doing research and teaching as visiting professor at Massachusetts Institute of Technology. ROUTLEDGE STUDIES IN THE HISTORY OF ECONOMICS 1 Economics as Literature
    [Show full text]
  • Mothers' Social Networks and Socioeconomic Gradients of Isolation
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MOTHERS’ SOCIAL NETWORKS AND SOCIOECONOMIC GRADIENTS OF ISOLATION Alison Andrew Orazio Attanasio Britta Augsburg Jere Behrman Monimalika Day Pamela Jervis Costas Meghir Angus Phimister Working Paper 28049 http://www.nber.org/papers/w28049 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 November 2020 This study was funded by the NICHD (grant R01 HD072120), the Cowles Foundation and ISPS at Yale, the Population Studies Center at the University of Pennsylvania and the SIEF program at the World Bank. This project has also received funding from the European Research Council (ERC) under the European Union’s Horizon 2020 research and innovation program (grant agreement No 695300-HKADeC-ERC-2015-AdG). In addition, we gratefully acknowledge the support of the Economic and Social Research Council’s Centre for the Microeconomic Analysis of Public Policy at IFS (grant reference ES/M010147/1). We bear sole responsibility for all errors and opinions expressed. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2020 by Alison Andrew, Orazio Attanasio, Britta Augsburg, Jere Behrman, Monimalika Day, Pamela Jervis, Costas Meghir, and Angus Phimister. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Mothers’ Social Networks and Socioeconomic Gradients of Isolation Alison Andrew, Orazio Attanasio, Britta Augsburg, Jere Behrman, Monimalika Day, Pamela Jervis, Costas Meghir, and Angus Phimister NBER Working Paper No.
    [Show full text]
  • The-Great-Depression-Glossary.Pdf
    The Great Depression | Glossary of Terms Glossary of Terms Balanced budget – Government revenues equal expenditures on an annual basis. (Lesson 5) Bank failure – When a bank’s liabilities (mainly deposits) exceed the value of its assets. (Lesson 3) Bank panic – When a bank run begins at one bank and spreads to others, causing people to lose confidence in banks. (Lesson 3) Bank reserves – The sum of cash that banks hold in their vaults and the deposits they maintain with Federal Reserve banks. (Lesson 3) Bank run – When many depositors rush to the bank to withdraw their money at the same time. (Lesson 3) Bank suspensions – Comprises all banks closed to the public, either temporarily or permanently, by supervisory authorities or by the banks’ boards of directors because of financial difficulties. Banks that close under a special holiday declaration and remained closed only during the designated holiday are not counted as suspensions. (Lesson 4) Banks – Businesses that accept deposits and make loans. (Lesson 2) Budget deficit – When government expenditures exceed revenues. (Lesson 4) Budget surplus – When government revenues exceed expenditures. (Lesson 4) Consumer confidence – The relationship between how consumers feel about the economy and their spending and saving decisions. (Lesson 5) Consumer Price Index (CPI) – A measure of the prices paid by urban consumers for a market basket of consumer goods and services. (Lesson 1) Deflation – A general downward movement of prices for goods and services in an economy. (Lessons 1, 3 and 6) Depression – A very severe recession; a period of severely declining economic activity spread across the economy (not limited to particular sectors or regions) normally visible in a decline in real GDP, real income, employment, industrial production, wholesale-retail credit and the loss of overall confidence in the economy.
    [Show full text]
  • Evaluating the Early Childhood Development Program in the Philippines*
    Evaluating the Early Childhood Development Program in the Philippines* by Jere Behrman (University of Pennsylvania, [email protected]) Paulita Duazo (University of San Carlos, [email protected]) Sharon Ghuman (University of Michigan, [email protected]) Socorro Gultiano (University of San Carlos, [email protected]) Elizabeth M. King (The World Bank, [email protected]) Nanette Lee (University of San Carlos, [email protected]) The Office of Population Studies, University of San Carlos ECD Team 15 March 2005 * This project was supported by NIH Research Grant # R01 TW05604 on “Filipino Early Childhood Development: Longitudinal Analysis” funded by the Fogarty International Center, National Institute of Child Health and Human Development (NICHD), the Office of Behavioral and Social Science Research (OBSSR), and the Global Development Network (GDN); the Department of Social Welfare and Development (DSWD) of the Government of the Philippines; and the World Bank Research Advisory Committee (RAD). The authors thank all these organizations for support for this project, the Early Childhood Development (ECD) Team at the Office of Population Studies (OPS) of the University of San Carlos for excellent support in all stages of the data collection and initial preparation process; and the ECD Project Management Office for making administrative data on implementation available to us. This paper is being presented at the Population Association of American Annual Meetings in Philadelphia on 1 April 2005 at Session 108 on “Long Term Effects of Early Childhood Interventions” by Sharon Ghuman. Abstract Increasing attention and resources have been devoted in recent years to early childhood development (ECD) in low to middle income countries.
    [Show full text]
  • Different Economic Systems Assessment
    Social Studies Assessment Activity #14 DDIIFFFFEERREENNTT EECCOONNOOMMIICC SSYYSSTTEEMMSS Introduction The new cars and trucks have arrived! Should you buy a medium-sized car? As you may know, they are efficient and more economical to operate than a truck. But the new pickups are so flashy, and they offer all the conveniences of a car! Decisions! Decisions! Decisions! Speaking of decisions, can you even afford a new vehicle? If you don’t have enough cash, you’ll have to finance. Financing or borrowing means another monthly payment -- one that could put a damper on your future recreational spending. Perhaps you better think about this further. Making a decision to buy a new vehicle can be difficult and there are several options available. Our “market driven” economy allows privately owned corporations to produce many styles of vehicles to meet the needs and interests of the American consumer. Purchasing a new vehicle means selecting a specific make and model that comes equipped with the latest in “gadgetry.” Additionally, one must select from a wide range of colors. Obviously, purchasing a new vehicle involves more than one decision, but at least we have the freedom to make those choices. Do people living in other countries go through the same process when they consider buying a new vehicle? In some countries they do, in others they don’t. Economic systems differ. As such, making economic decisions in some countries is quite different from economic decisions that are made by Americans. In this activity, you will: Use the resources you have accumulated to write an essay that analyzes the similarities and differences between two economic systems.
    [Show full text]
  • Nancy Birdsall Curricula Vitae
    Curriculum Vitae NANCY BIRDSALL EMPLOYMENT Center for Global Development Oct. 2001- present President Carnegie Endowment for International Peace 1998- 2001 Senior Associate and Director, Economic Reform Project Inter-American Development Bank August 1993-1998 Executive Vice President. Chief operating officer of the bank. Responsible for operations, finance, legal and policy and all other management, and deputy to the President. The Bank has a portfolio of $30 billion in 26 borrowing countries and makes new commitments of about $6 billion a year in new operations. World Bank August 1979-93 Economic policy, research and operational work on developing countries, including on human resource development (population, education and health); environment; and adjustment, trade and privatization issues. Management and technical positions in lending operations covering Latin America and in the policy research complex covering Latin America, Asia, Africa, Eastern Europe and former Soviet Union. Member, World Bank Research Committee, 1987 to 1992. Member, Economists' Review Panel, 1988 to 1993 (reviews managers' proposals for staff promotions to senior economist positions). Member, Young Professionals Admission Committee, 1991 to 1993. Advisor, Finance and Development (World Bank and IMF magazine). 1991-1993 Director, Policy Research Department. Department of about 85 professional staff, primarily economists, responsible for the Bank's economic research and policy analysis in such areas as trade, adjustment and growth issues, including in transitional socialist economies, poverty and human resources, tax and expenditures, financial sector, environment, public sector management, and private sector development. 1990-1991 Chief, Environment Division, Latin America Region. Division of 15 full-time staff responsible for lending operations in environment, including Global Environmental Facility and Montreal Protocol operations, for policy studies, and for coordination of environmental assessment of investments in Latin America financed by the World Bank.
    [Show full text]
  • JA Economics® Course Overview and Outline
    JA Economics® | Course Overview and Outline Initial JA Economics® Course Release Overview and Outline Spring 2019 Market for Goods JA Economics is a one-semester course that connects high and Services school students to the economic principles that influence their daily lives as well as their futures. It addresses each BANK of the economics standards identified by the Council for Production of Goods and Household Economic Education as being essential to complete a high Services + + Consumer school economics course. Course components equip students to: Market for Labor • Learn the necessary concepts applicable to state and national educational standards • Apply economic reasoning and skills in the world around them • Synthesize elective concepts through a cumulative, tangible deliverable (optional case studies and/or projects) • Demonstrate the skills necessary for future financial literacy pathway success • Integrate College and Career Readiness anchor standards in Reading, Informational Text, Speaking and Listening, and Vocabulary Volunteers engage with students through a variety of activities that includes subject matter guest speaking and coaching or advising for case study and project course work. Volunteer activities help students better understand the relationship between what they learn in school, their future career, and their successful participation in today’s global economy. Through a variety of experiential activities presented by the teacher and volunteer, students better understand the relationship between what they learn
    [Show full text]
  • History of Economic Thought
    History of economic thought The term economics was coined around 1870 and popularized by Alfred Marshall, as a substitute for the earlier term political economy which has been used through the 18-19th centuries, with Adam Smith, David Ricardo and Karl Marx as its main thinkers and which today is frequently referred to as the "classical" economic theory. Both economy and economics are derived from the Greek oikos- for "house" or "settlement", and nomos for "laws" or "norms". Economic thought may be roughly divided into three phases: Premodern (Greek, Roman, Arab), Early modern (mercantilist, physiocrats) and Modern (since Adam Smith in the late 18th century). Systematic economic theory has been developed mainly since the birth of the modern era. Premodern economic thought Several ancient philosophers made various economic observations. Among them Aristotle is probably the most important. Mediaeval Arabs also made contributions to the understanding of economics. In particular, Ibn Khaldun of Tunis (1332-1406) wrote on economic and political theory in his Prolegomena, showing for example, how population density is related to the division of labour which leads to economic growth and so in turn to greater population in a virtuous circle. Early Western precursors of economics engaged in the scholastics theological debates during the middle ages. An important topic of discussion was the determination of the just price of a good. In the religious wars following the Reformation in the 16th century, ideas about free trade appeared, later formulated in legal terms by Hugo de Groot or Grotius (Mare liberum). Economic policy in Europe during the late middle ages and early renaissance treated economic activity as a good which was to be taxed to raise revenues for the nobility and the church.
    [Show full text]
  • Intensive Industries and Distributed Knowledge Bases.1
    What is the ‘knowledge economy’? Knowledge- intensive industries and distributed knowledge bases.1 Keith Smith STEP Group Oslo Norway May 2000 Prepared as part of the project “Innovation Policy in a Knowledge-Based Economy” commissioned by the European Commission 1 I would like to thank Daniele Archibugi, Robin Cowan, Paul David, Dominique Foray, Gert van de Paal, Luc Soete and members of the European Commission for comments on an earlier draft of this paper. Introduction: technology and competence Public policies for science, technology and innovation have always been aimed primarily at creating and diffusing knowledge. In recent years such policies have attracted increasing attention as a result of claims that knowledge-intensive industries are now at the core of growth, and that we are now entering a new type of knowledge-driven economy or even a completely new form of ‘knowledge society’. What does it mean to speak of a ‘knowledge-intensive’ industry or a ‘knowledge- based’ economy, however? These terms are often used in a superficial and uncritical way, and there is a real need to consider whether they are anything more than slogans. The objectives of this paper are firstly to assess some of the issues involved in the concept of a knowledge economy or learning economy, and to criticise the idea that the knowledge economy should be identified with high-technology industries (as conventionally defined). Against this background I describe some empirical dimensions of knowledge creation in Europe, and then turn to concepts and a methodology for mapping the knowledge base of an economic activity. The paper proposes the concept of a ‘distributed knowledge base’ for industries, and argues that the term ‘knowledge economy’ is only meaningful if we see it in terms of widely- spread knowledge intensity across economic activities, including so-called ‘low technology’ sectors.
    [Show full text]