<<

This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic

Volume Title: Short-Term Macroeconomic Policy in

Volume Author/Editor: Jere R. Behrman and James Hanson, eds.

Volume Publisher: NBER

Volume ISBN: 0-88410-489-3

Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/behr79-1

Publication Date: 1979

Chapter Title: The Use of Econometric Models in Developing Countries

Chapter Author: Jere Behrman, James A. Hanson

Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c3882

Chapter pages in book: (p. 1 - 38) 1 F JEREBEHRMAN TheUse of and Econometric JAMES A. HANSON Modelsin Developing Countries*

1. INTRODUCTION

National-income-determinationmodels and stabilization have not been the major concern of either empirical or theoretical macro- economic analysis in the developing economies. For example, a recentsurveyofthestateof theartregardingthe use of economywide models for less developed countries (LDCs), Blitzer, et a!. (1975), does not even include a chapter on macroeconomic income-determination models. Instead, the dominant frameworks for macroeconomic policy analysis and policy recommendations have been provided by Harrod- Domaraggregate-growth models,staticanddynamiclinear- programming models, and Chenery-Strout two-gap models.' These

*This paper draws on Behrman, "Econometric Modeling of National Income Determination in Latin America, with Special Reference to the Chilean Ex- perience," presented at the Seminar on Use of Econometric Models in Latin America, sponsored by The Center of Economic and Demographic Studies of El Colegio de and the National Bureau of Economic Research, held in Mexico City on November 27-29, 1974.

1 2 Short Term Macroeconomic Policy in Latin America

modelsgenerally include assumptions that: (i) the degree of capacity utilization, the rate of , and the level of aggregate are unimportant considerations; (ii) that the financial constraints on government and central behavior (and, thus, the entire fiscal-monetary-income-internationalpolicy-inflationnexus)can be ignored; (iii) short-run flexibility is limited by low elasticities of substitution and short-run unresponsiveness to ; (iv) (at least for the programming models on which the greatest resources have been expended) the most interesting question is "what could happen if socially optimal readjustment of the economy occurred in response to policy changes," rather than "what would happen if the independent economic units which make up the economy followed their traditional behavioral patterns in response to such changes."2 The resulting models usually include only real phenomena and are characterized by bottlenecks resulting from foreign exchange or constraints. Such an emphasis reflects two widely held views: (1) Growth is a relatively more important economic objective (and stabilization less important) in the developing countries than in the developed coun- tries. (2) Income-determination models involving demand as well as supply are of limited for developing economies.3 Some exceptions to the predominant view have long existed. The participants in the "structuralist-monetarist" controversy in Latin America, for example, accorded significant importance to inflation and stabilization policies in the development process.4 These exceptions have been increasing in number. The recognition by such authors as Schydlowsky (Chapter 9, this volume) and Behrmari (1973b) of considerable underutilized capacity, particularly in cyclical downturns, has increased interest in using national-income- determination models for stabilization purposes. Numerous econometric estimates have been made that imply sig. nificantly nonzero elasticities of substitution and significant responses to in both capacity utilization and capacity creation decisions.5 Even the strongest advocates of supply-oriented capital and foreign- exchange-constrained analysis seem to be having second thoughts about the importance of short-run factors and stabilization problems. For example, throughout the above-cited survey by Blitzer, et al. (1975), there are frequent references to the need to consider short-run features (e.g., prices responses, capacity utilization determination, aggregate.demand.related policies). d Recently, because of this growing interest in stabilization and othershort-runproblems,alarge number of Keynesian-based national-income-determination models have been constructed and utilized for the developing economies.6

•4'l r

TheUse of Econometric Models in Developing Countries 3

Abasic problem with the construction and use of these models for policymaking purposes in developing economies is the general lack of I accurate,up-to-date information (e.g., quarterly information on out- ts put and its components and sectoral or cyclical indicators that are • re available with a short time lag). This is a gap that at present forces policymakers to act on incorrect or dated information.7It also means that income-determination models of developing countries are a annual rather than quarterly. However, in the developed countries econometric models have been "most successful" in predicting out- put in the next quarter or six months; over a nine or twelve-month • period simple trends are often as good.8 Thus improvement in modeling may require an in improving the data base, an

:2 investmentthat has the additional payoff of providing more accurate and up-to-date information to policymakers.9 e There remains the more philosophical question of our present abil- ity to forecast and affect in predictable ways the very short run with corresponding effects on the long run. However, political pressures a force governments to accept some advice and take some action in the -s very short run, often to the detriment of the long run. Therefore, it is probably best for to offer advice on the short run and on short-run—long-run tradeoffs while specifying the fragile nature of such advice. e • A second problem results from a simplistic transfer of aggregate demand models of developed economies with little or no adjustment for the special conditions in the developing countries. As a result, there are numerous shortcomings in such models' specifications, shortcomings that, while they may also exist in developed country d applications, are perhaps less important in that context. For ex- ample: (1) National income is determined by aggregate demand in a Keynesian with no testing for the existence of possible con- straints due to the stocks of capital or labor, the supply of foreign exchange, or supply limitations imposed by quantitative restric- tions.'° (2) Underemployed or surplus labor and dualism in the labor I are not explicitly incorporated. (3) Aggregation is so great that there is no possibility of capturing the impact of policies on relative prices, even though economists like Hansen (1973b) have maintained that policies in developing nations are primarily reflected in altered relative prices and Wachter (Chapter 8, this volume) has demonstrated, econometrically, the structuralist proposition that differing speeds of adjustment of relative prices (plus passive money) may result in inflation. The possible importance of intersectoral d flows, moreover, is lost by the high level of aggregation. On the other d hand, data problems are often cited as preventing disaggregation to any significant level, and there remains the question of whether dis- I 4 Short Term Macroeconomic Policy in Latin America

aggregatedmodels provide more accurate projections of the aggregate variables, and to what extent such models divert attention from more global problems, such as the financial-monetary-international policy- income nexus. (4) Potential policy variables are often overlooked. For example, it is often assumed that an overvalued willbe maintained through a continuance of exchange control ai although this is obviously a policy that is subject to change. (5) The significance of the foreign sector as a source of noncompetitive, intermediate imports, of capital , of government , and of household money and nonmonetary asset holdings is not well presented. (6) The importance—owing to fragmented and poorly functioning capital markets—of direct flows and retained earnings in the real investment process is not explored. (7) The degree of endog- eneity of fiscal, monetary, and international variables and their inter- relation in poorly functioning capital markets is ignored with the result that policy options are overstated. (8) There is little attempt to integrate the short-run income-determination model with long-run c developmentmodels. In particular, although plant and equipment decisions are well treated, no attempt is made to study capital formation, despite the growing evidence for its significance in devel- opment. The role of social overhead capital, long emphasized by such leading development economists as Rosenstein-Rodan (1961), also ir is not explored.''(9) There is a tendency to ignore economywide disequilibrium.'2 ai At the same time as interest in and use of income-determination— stabilization, models for the LDCs has been growing, controversies d have emerged over the specification of such models in the developed economies. In the past decade, critics have claimed that deficiencies U in the theoretical structure, deficiencies that may be related to points sI 1 to 9 above, make any analysis of stabilization policies based on p1 such models suspect. Recently, however, some convergence seems to have occurred, at least regarding the nature of the issues. Ando el (1974), Blinder and Solow (1973), and Hansen (1973a) and others have attempted to adjust the IS-LM model to explore these contro- versies. However, less agreement has been obtained on the signifi- cj canceof Lucas's (1976) point that systematic attempts to use an estimated model for policymaking purposes alters the parameters of ft the system and thus the responses to policy. b Given some convergence on the nature of stabilization issues in the developed countries and given the increasing preoccupation with stabilization problems in the developing countries, the time seems ripe to reexamine the applicability of modern stabilization analysis a4 to the special situations of the developing countries. s'

•11 The Use of Econometric Mode/s in Developing Countries 5

Thestrategy pursued in this chapter is to examine briefly each of the components of recent econometric models used in developed economies. Then the chapter considers how these models need to be altered for analysis of stabilization in developing economies. Models of Chile and Panama are considered as examples incorporating these alterations. The prototype model for the developed economies uses as a start- ing point the combination of the features of the closed economy model of Ando (1974) and the analysis of international capital move- ments of Branson (1974). These models are somewhat complex in order to incorporate a number of features discussed in recent contro- versies. Solution by differentiation does not lead to simple elegant

• - expressions.For an understanding of such models beyond the ex- • - planationprovided below, the reader is referred to the papers by

• Ando and Branson.

• Regarding ) the two models, Behrman's (1976b) p

1 Chileanstudy is an annual macroeconomic model for the period t 1945—1965. It is a nine-sector model with capacity creation, capacity utilization, export, import, and price and wage determination rela- - tionsfor each sector involving 17.2 endogenous variables. Consump- tion- decisions are estimated for households and nonprofit ) institutions,business, and the government. Many aspects of govern- e ment fiscal and monetary policies are endogenous. Its specification attempts to oyercome the nine shortcomings listed above, which are - frequently encountered in Keynesian-basednational-income- s determination models for developing economies. Less explicit refer- ence is made to Behrman and Vargas's (Chapter 2, this volume) s trimestral model of Panama. Though less complex than the Chilean s study this model still includes 97 endogenous variables describing , prices, and wages in three broad sectors—exports, other ) tradedand nontraded goods—which in turn are subdivided into ) eightproducing sectors. Final demand components are also estimated s separately. Finally, before considering the appropriate modifications of the developed country model, two caveats are in order. First, the devel- oping countries are far from homogeneous. For almost any relevant f feature the range across countries is enormous. In what follows below, therefore, the suggested modifications reflect characteristics a not necessarily common to all developing countries but at least to a h significant number of them. Second, a separate paper, if not a book. is 'couldbe written on data problems. In this chapter some allusions is are made to these problems, but they are not treated systematically so that the chapter can be kept to a manageable length. 6 Short Term Macroeconomic Policy in Latin America

2. COMPONENTS OF NATIONAL- INCOME-DETERMINATION MODELS ( Table1-1 presents the prototype model for the developed economies that is used as a starting point for the discussion of this section. Each of the major components of that model will be examined in turn with a focus on altering them for analysis of stabilization issues in developing countries.

2.1Labor Market, Labor Supply, and Determination of Prices and Wages

2.LAThe Developed Country Model:Equations (1)through(4) describe the labor market and the determination of prices and wages in a representative econometric model of developed economies. Equation (1) depicts the short-run relationship between output and the required man-hours to satisfy demand. It is assumed that at any point in time the economy has a collection of machines whose labor-output ratios were determined by the and the ex- pected relative prices at the time of each machine's manufacture. Given the current relative prices, machines (and the labor associated with them) are used in descending order of efficiency until the de- manded (desired)output is produced. New machines may contain different technology based on expected relative prices. Thus pro- ducers' durable equipment takes the form of putty-clay. Equation (2) gives the rate as a function of man- hours and population characteristics. It incorporates into one expres- sion the determination of hours worked per person and the response of labor force size to employment conditions and to demographic features of the population. Equation (3) is a Phillips curve relation for the determination of the rate of change of wages as a function of the unemployment rate and price expectations. It may be considered a reduced form equa- tion of underlying relations in the labor market. Lucas (1973) argues that this relation may depend upon government policy and provides some evidence to that effect. Equation(4) determines the price level of output under the hy- S pothesis of a (possibly lagged) markup on minimized average cost. The price level should vary proportionally with the money wage level and reciprocally with long-run productivity. The markup factor is p. Sirfce the markup may vary in the short run with the utilization of capacity, the unemployment rate is also included in the function. The Use of Econometric Models in Developing Countries 7

Table 1-1.Prototype Macroeconomic Model for Developed Economies

I.Labor Market, Supply Price, and Wages Demand for Labor E=E(Z) (1) Supply of Labor and the Definition of Unemployment Rate u=u(E,N) (2) Determination of Money Wage Level I —=w(u,LI(--—J Ii (3) \

s Determinationof Real Wage Rate and Price Level

t (4)

e II. Market and Aggregate Demand Definition of National Product Z=C÷I÷G+X-IM (5) Function C=C(Y,A) (6) Investment Function I=I(Z,rk,r) (7) GovernmentExpenditure G=Ge+Gd(Y,N,rk) (8) Import Function

;e IM=IM(ER,P Y) (9) Export Function it X = X(ER,F) (10) III. Financial Markets and Assets Demand for Real Assets

fV(rhrr Y) (11) • ci Demandfor Bonds B/PA IB(rh Y) (12) I 8 Short Term Macroeconomic Policy in Latin America

Table 1-1.continued

Demandfor Foreign Securities SER =A•,S(rh rr Y) (13) P S Demandfor Money

h M/P=AfMh(ru,re,, r, Y) (14) Definition of Net Worth M+B+SER A=V+ (15) P Relation between Holding Rate and Capitalization Rate rS_r k k rhrk (16) rk

Relationbetween Real and Nominal Short-Term Interest Rates p2..p — (17) b

Relationbetween Holding and International Rate for Foreign Securities ER5-ER rhr+ (18) $ S ER Generation of Expected Rate of Change of rk

(19) V.j Generation of Expected Rate of Change of Prices

(20) P P Generation of Expected Rate of Change of Exchange Rate I rER1\ 1 (21) ER \LERJ/ ' ExpectedIncome from Capital

(22) The Use of Econometric Models in Developing Countries 9

Table 1-1.continued

MarketValue of Capital

?Te (23) 3 PV—

IV. Identities and Miscellaneous Relations 4) Definition of Disposable Income (24) Definition of Savings Y_P.C±d*(P. V) (25) Definition of Income from Capital (26) 6) C CapitalGains on Existing Capital d*(P.V)=d(P.V)_P.I (27) Balance of Payments Surplus 7) (28) Tax Function SER,ir,r) (29) 8) P TT(PZ+rb Government Budget Constraint

B (30)

V.Variable Definitions A: Net Worth of B: Government Held by :0) C: Consumption in Constant d*(PV): Real Capital Gain on Existing Real Assets in Current Currency E: Employment in Man-Hours

• . ER: Exchange Rate in Domestic Currency per Unit of Foreign Currency ERa: Expected Exchange Rate in Domestic Currency per Unit of For- 2) eign Currency G: Total Government Expenditures in Constant Currency 10 Short Term Macroeconomic Policy in Latin America

Table1-1.continued T(

Gex: Exogenous Government Expenditures in Constant Currency Gd Endogenous Government Expenditures in Constant Currency H: Surplus on Balance of Payments in Current Currency I: Net Investment in Constant Currency IM: Imports in Constant Currency kets: L: Lag Operator M: in Current Currency (Currency Plus Reserves) chari shori N: Vector Expressing Total Population and its Structure cluch ji: Standard Mark-up Factor (i.e., the Ratio of Price of Output to its In Minimized Cost of Production Expected to Prevail under Normal that Employment Conditions) to ti P: Price Level for Output recer Pe: PriceLevel Expected to Prevail secto ii: Income from Real Assets in Current Currency tries 7T*: Expected Income from Existing Real Assets in Current (not future) For I Currency

r : Nominal Rate of Interest on- sis lit largei RealRate of Interest on Government Debt

rk. CapitalizationRate (in real terms) Applicable to Real Assets Levelof Expectedto Prevail HoldingRate (in real terms) Applicable to Real Assets averal

rs: RealRate of Interest on Foreign Securities HoldingRate (in real terms) Applicable to Foreign Securities age s r':$ S: Net Foreign Securities Held by Private Sector age Taxes in Constant Currency apprc labor 7: Tax Rates (Subscript "C" refers to Corporations) suppi; Unemployment Rate (2), w, W: Market Value of Existing Real Assets in Constant Currency includ W: Nominal Wage Rate per Man-Hour tor

'Ti. I

TheUse of Econometric Models in Developing Countries 11

Table 1-1. continued

X: Exports in Constant Currency Y: Disposable Income in Constant Currency Z: Net National Product in Constant Currency

2.1.B.1 Wage and Price Determination in Dualistic Labor Mar- kets:Most developing economies are characterized by dualism in labor and product markets. To capture the effects of long-run changes in the sectoral of the labor force, as well as the short-run problems of income determination, it is necessary to in- clude explicitly this dualism. In a dualistic labor market there is thought to be a modern sector

In that is market oriented andpays wages approximately proportional tothe value of the marginal product of labor. Its technology is of recent vintage and permits only limited substitution between pri- mary factors.'3 In some countries unions are quite powerful in this sector. The traditional sector is much less market oriented. In most coun- tries a major component of this sector is noncommercial . uture) For this subsector the marketed surplus often is a small part of total production and may be an inverse function of price. However, analy- sis in Behrman (1968) suggests that this response is positive and quite large. While factor substitution usually is possible, the relatively high labor-to-capital ratio often results in disguised unemployment with marginal products substantially below those in the modern sector. Because of family and communal arrangements, the income of indi- vidual laborers may be determined by tradition and related to the average rather than the marginal product. The dominant view of the impact of this dualism on the labor market is based on the well-known model of Lewis (1954). The aver- age share of labor in the traditional sector, plus a differential for moving costs, provides a floor for modern sector wages.'4 The aver- age share of labor in the traditional sector is assumed to remain approximately constant over a wide range of sizes of the traditional labor force.'5 It is therefore argued that over a substantial range the supply of labor for the modern sector is quite elastic. One way of incorporating this approach into equations (1) and (2), would be to apply them only to the modern sector (with all the included variables referring only to that sector). The traditional sec- tor would act as one residual claimant on labor, and urban unemploy- 12 Short Term Macroeconomic Policy in Latin America

ment,open or disguised, as the other)6In practice it might be necessary to aggregate these two residuals, given the problems of defining urban unemployment and due to continual shifts in demand for "modern" goods, which affect both open unemployment and rural-urban migration in a complicated fashion. Prima facie this approach might seem to lead to an approximation of a Keynesian case in the modern sector, with an "unlimited supply of labor" at a fixed wage and employment in the modern sector determined by the demand for modern sector goods. But this wage is fixed in real terms, and thus the situation is also classical in an impor- tant sense, which suggests an alternative approach. If modern and traditional goods were good substitutes, so that we could treat them as one good, equations (1) and (2) could be said to apply to the economy and equation (3) could be replaced by an equality between (expected) real wages in the modern sector and the exogenously given, traditional labor income. Equilibrium employ- ment and output would be unresponsive to changes in aggregate demand. Rather than wages determining the price level, as shown in equation (4), prices (as determined by equation [14], the demand for money) would tend to determine nominal wages in classical fash- ion.'7 These results hold in their essentials if the goods are not per- fect substitutes, although in this case a shift in demand patterns could alter the distribution of employment and, if directed toward modern goods, yield some aggregate efficiencies. The problem with this approach is that it does not cover the case of urban Keynesian unemployment, resulting from a lack of aggre- gate demand. For a given, fully employed labor force there is a unique allocation of labor that equates (expected) urban wages with a given, traditional labor income.'8 To consider both dualistic labor markets and Keynesian unemployment the strict equality between labor incomes in the traditional and modern sectors must be re- placed by a gradual adjustment process toward equality. In that case a drop in aggregate demand, assuming also a slow adjustment of prices, would lower modern sector output, cause urban unemploy- ment, and slow rural-urban migration out of the growing population. The average rural income might differ from the (expected) wage for a time. Over a longer period migration and would alter urban labor supply substantially, and capital-labor ratios would vary. Moreover, changes in minimum (as opposed to average) wages may de9end (inversely) upon (lagged?) urban unemployment. These fac- tors would tend to narrow the relation between measured (expec- The Use of Econometric Mode/s in Deve/oping Countries 13

ted?)urban wages and the average share of labor in the traditional of sector over the longer run. The basic problem highlighted in this discussion is that equation (3) remains a reduced form of the operation of the labor market in which the underlying supply and demand relations are not well )fl stated or perhaps even understood. The explicit statement of these ly relations becomes very important in explaining wages in one sector or of a jointly determined two- (or more) sector model. In an explicitly is two-sector model wages in the urban sector are determined by the demand for labor, which depends on nominal wages and prices of ur- ban sector goods and the supply of labor, which in turn is dependent upon nominal wages and on prices in the twosectors.Far from being constant, rural supply, relative prices of rural goods, and rural in- Lfl comes may all vary with employment in the urban sector.'9 The same problem of incomplete specification exists in the equa- tion of price determination via markup, expressed in equation (4), te aside from the obvious point that short-run variations in markups in (and therefore, their explanation) are much more important in coun- tries where the industrial noriwage share reaches 40 to 50 percent of h- value added (see Michalopolous [1969]) and some important items in the price index are produced by government factories or closely (iS controlled by governments. At best equation (4) could explain rela- tive prices in a two-good model but not their absolute level. One solution might be to treat the traditional sector rather than its se labor force as a residual. The urban wage level could be related to the e- unemployment rate and some trend in rural incomes. The price index a could be determined through a markup equation with a nonunitary (ii elasticity of the price index with respect to urban wages. The diffi- culty with this approach is that it neglects the determinants of the ff1 intersectoral movements it is trying to model. e- Perhaps the best solution would be toretainthe demand- se determined modern sector employment figure of equation (1) and jointly determine the unemployment rate, the wage in the modern sector, and the (residual) labor force, output, and average product in fl. thetraditional sector through a set of equations that require relative prices to adjust to equate and supplies for both traditional and modern products and long-run equality between real labor earn- er ings in the two sectors. This approach obviously a division of aggregate demands between the two sectors and an additional equation to determine the general price level. C Inthe Chilean model (Behrman [1976b]) of income determina- c- tion in an inflationary economy, the major determinant of the gen-

.1

I. .. 0 'l 14 Short Term Macroeconomic Policy in Latin America eral pricelevel was the rate of change of the money supply, with its impact distributed over a number of years. As described below, this money supply was determined by other factors in the system, Such as the government budget deficit. Because of the distributed lags in the price-determination process, moreover, stemming inflation is quite difficult unless expectations about future price movements can be lowered drastically. Nonmonetary factors also affect the general price level. Cost-push factors operating through intermediate input and unit labor costs are more important in transmitting overall inflationary pressures (includ- rf ing those that arise from the role of expectations in the wage- bargaining process) than previous studies, such as Harberger (1963), r have maintained. Real changes in per capita a (and other indices of current activity), in labor productivities, in de- mands (final and intermediate) relative to sectoral capacity, and in t thedistribution of factoral income and of sectoral product have sig- nificant effects, as do foreign sector policies. Government minimum wages, although widely discussed in Chilean circles, do not appear to have a very significant impact on wage changes once other prices are incorporated into the wage change relations. On the other hand, in the Panamanian case, which is probably a prototype of open economies, prices seemed to be largely deter- mined by the economy, plus taxes and tariffs. However, Borts and Hanson (Chapter 9, this volume) suggest the relation is not pro- portional, perhaps because of home goods and variations in the ef- fective exchangerate or government price setting. Thus there is more 4 scopefor monetary policy than Johnson's (1973) simple, monetary model of the balance of payments allows, as discussed below. Re- garding wages, the (expected) price levels are one of the most impor- tant determinants, unemployment rates and sectoral productivity seem less important, and minimum wages have almost no effect. Brodersohn (1977), Behrman (1971a), and other studies cited in Fernandez and Hanson (1977) confirm the fact that price expecta- tions are important in Latin American wage determination, generally entering proportionately. However, Brodersohn (Chapter 7, this vol- ume) in the Phillips curve context, and Barro (Chapter 6, this vol- ume), Fernandez (Chapter 5, this volume), and Lucas (1973) in an alternative form provide little support for a stable relation either between wage growth and unemployment or between cyclical vari- ations in real output and monetary fluctuations. 2.1.B.2 The Importance of the Foreign Sector: The foreign sec- tor plays a much more important direct role in labor, production, The Use of Econometric Models in Developing Countries15

its and price relations in most developing economies (and probably in his most small open developed countries) than is indicated in the model LCI1 of Table 1-1. Four modifications of the counterparts of equations in (1) to (4) for the modern sector need to be made to reflect the impact of the foreign sector. (i) Some imported intermediate inputs and raw materials are crit- ical in the production process. The elasticity of substitutions be- ish tween such imports and domestic factors may be low or zero. are Especially in the disequilibrium exchange rate system common for many developing economies, the constraint on production and em- ge- ployment may not be the putty-clay stock of machinery and equip- 3), ment, but the availability of these imported inputs. Equation (1) ict may require modification to reflect this possibility.

• ie- (ii) Equation (1) also needs to be modified to reflect the fact that

• in used in the modern sector are largely imported from

• ;ig- developed countries with much different factor endowments. Very little choice may be available (or may be thought to be available) even ex ante for the capital-labor ratio of the developing countries. Therefore, the putty-clay response to expected relative prices is con- strained to a choice among relatively capital-intensive technologies. a What Eckaus (1955) calls the "factor proportions problem" limits er- the absorption of labor by the modern sector. rts (iii) The discussion in section 2.1.B.1 suggests that for many devel- ro- oping economies equation (3) should be modified or the structural ef- formmore explicitly specified. One further modification needs to be )re made. In many developing economies an important and easily avail- 4 ableindex of inflationary expectations is the rate of change of the

• • exchangerate. In addition to the of past inflation, therefore, this variable (or some function of past values of it) should be in- •ty cluded for such countries. If wages respond to such factors, they may "overshoot" the in devaluation-induced price rises in some industries. In that case it is

• ta- possible that equation (1) does not hold because wage costs on the ly "last" machine needed to produce demanded output exceed the Dl- firm's income. Output is then determined by desired supply, not de- )l- mand as indicated in (1), and unemployment is related to high real an wages, not a lack of demand. Such an interpretation may explain the er negative output effects associated with devaluation in Chile in the ri. late 1950s (Harberger [1963]), Argentina in 1959, and Colombia in 1962. (iv) In light of the widespread importance of consumption and intermediate and raw material imports if a variant of equation (4) is included, then it should be modified to reflect markups on imports 16 Short Term Macroeconomic Policy in Latin America

aswell as on labor costs. Changes in the international prices or in import policies, therefore, have direct effects on the domestic price level and on output, particularly in open economies such as those of the Caribbean and .

2.2 Product Market and Aggregate Demand

2.2.A DevelopedCountries:Equation (5) is the definition of net national product. Equations (6) through (10) describe the demand for real output. Equation (6) is the consumption function. Real consumption de- pends upon expected real disposable income (approximated by a dis- ni tributed lag of actual real disposable income) and net worth in a variant of the life cycle hypothesis. Equation (7) is the investment function. For the developed coun- tries in which capital markets are well functioning so that the cost of capital is well identified, investment decisions are based on a compar- ison of the present value of the expected stream of income generated by the investment and the cost of investment. Simultaneous variables that enter into the investment decision, therefore, include the capi- talization rate applicable to real assets and net national product in a, real terms. The appropriate tax rates also have a role. Equation (8) defines total government expenditure as the sum of exogenous central government expenditures and endogenous local government expenditures. The latter respond fairly strongly to cycli- cal conditions of the economy. Equation (9) is the import function and equation (10) is the ex- port function for developed economies. Imports respond positively to the level of income and the domestic price level and inversely to lii the exchange rate (defined as the number of units of domestic cur- rency per unit of foreign currency). Exports are assumed to respond directly to the exchange rate and inversely to the domestic price hI level. a 2.2.B.1 Consumption in Developing Countries:For the develop- ing economies, several hypotheses about private consumption behav- ior have been suggested.(i) Because of the existence of a large number of individuals at or near a subsistence income level, con- ol sumption may not be proportional to income even in the long run. If tc true, the high marginal propensity to consume at low income levels, fa ceteris paribus, may imply a relatively high multiplier. (ii) Retained business earnings (although not necessarily from corporations) are a relatively important source of savings. Therefore, a division between

J r

• The Use of Econometric Models in Developing Countries17

unretainedand retained income of businesses might be desirable. Modigliani and Tarantelli (1975) provide some evidence that a fur- ther division between property and labor income may be less fruitful. (iii) The marginal propensity to consume out of the income gener- ated in some sectors—especially sectors related to exports—may be higher than elsewhere in the economy. The inclusion of a separate argument in the function for income from exports might be desir- able. This modification would further increase the impact of the foreign sector on stabilization. (iv) If interest rates are controlled, then a policy-oriented model would consider the direct effect of their decontrol on the rate of consumption. Controlled interest rates may also increase the substitution between foreign and domestic . Finally, data problems may make it difficult to include nonmone- tary assets in the measure of net worth.2° This distortion is not as great as it would be for the developed countries because the stock of money balances represents a large percentage of privately held assets, perhaps as great as 40 percent in nominal terms.2' 2.2.B.2 Investment in Developing Countries:For some of the more advanced developing countries, evidence exists that supports the use of the same basic formulation (e.g., Behrman [1972b] con- siders investment by sectors). More generally, however, substantial modifications are needed to reflect special aspects of capital markets, social overhead capital, and international considerations.

• (i) Domestic capital markets in developing economies often are

• not well functioning. Markets are very fragmented, especially be- tween the traditional and modern sectors. In the modern sector legal limits on nominal interest rates frequently are effective so that rationing occurs in bank markets. Government planning organiza- tions also often attempt to control the allocation of physical capital •

• bynonmarket means. The net result is that much of the domestically financed invest- ment does not pass through a capital market (or, at least not through "the" capital market). Instead it originates in retained earnings or in

• direct flows from the government. Government policy is often di- rected toward increasing the former source by changes in the terms of , by price ceilings, and foreign trade policies in favor of sec- tors in which investment is desired. Quite commonly is so favored over primary production, and import substitution or nontra- ditional exports are favored relative to traditional exports. To capture these features, direct financial flows from the govern- ment and the results of quantitative allocations mechanisms need to

I 18 Short Term Macroeconomic Policy in Latin America

beincluded in the investment function. Some success was obtained with these real credit variables in the Panamanian model. To repre- sent the impact of policies that through altering terms of trade, a multisector model is required. (ii) The development literature emphasizes repeatedly the role of social overhead capital in the development process. Because of ex- ternalities and increasing returns to scale over the relevant range, Rosenstein-Rodan (1961) and others maintain that the government must increase such social overhead capital in order to induce private investment. Birnberg and Resnick (1973) show that social overhead capital was an historically important element. in export growth. The role of social overhead capital in determining the stream of expected net income from investment, therefore, should be made explicit. (iii) International considerations may enter into investment de- cisions in two important ways. First, a considerable portion of the capital stock originates from direct foreign investment in the modern sectors of many developing economies. One implication of this foreign ownership is that for such investment the relevant cost of capital reflects the opportunity cost in the international capital market (modified by local tax, repatri- ation and earnings regulations, and expected exchange rate move- ments) and not in the domestic market. Another implication is that net factor payments abroad may have a stabilizing influence if they are determined as a residual. (See Reynolds [1968].) Second, for many of the developing economies much of the machinery and equipment for investment in the modern sector is im- ported.22This point is related to the factor proportions problem referred to above because of the concentration on developing rela- tively capital-intensive technology in the mature economies and to the disaggregation of imports referred to below. It also means that exchange rate policy and other import policies have important roles in determining the cost of capital. Finally, it is possible that the quantity of imported capital goods may constrain real investment if the elasticity of substitution between domestic and foreign invest- ment goods is, in fact, very low and quantitative restrictions are an important component of trade policy as in many developing coun- tries. Behrman (1975a) provides evidence that the availability of imported machinery and equipment constrained investment in Chile.23

2.2.B.3 Government Expenditure in Developing Countries:For developing economies current government expenditures often (but

1

- The Use of Econometric Models in Developing Countries19 ied not are more centralized than in developed economies such re- as the . Nevertheless, there remains a large, effec- de, tively endogenous component. The government is a relatively large employer in comparison to total modern sector employment, its of wage bill makes up a substantial portion of its expenditures, and ex- cuts in these expenditures as part of stabilization policy would be ge, extremely risky politically in most cases. ?nt Government expenditures also generally are affected directly by foreign sector conditions through the budget constraint. Taxes re- lated to the foreign sector are a major source of variance in govern- he ment revenues (see below). A further effect is through official capital inflows. The evidence presented by Papanek (1972, 1973) suggests (although not conclusively, see Mikesell and Zinzer [1973]) that such flows are diverted partly to current government expenditures. These inflows may also lead to local inflationary problems if they re- suit in monetary creation instead of increased imports. ng ch 2.2.B.4 The Import Equation in Developing Countries:For most )St developing economies, as is noted above, imports play a critical role in the provision of noncompetitive raw materials, intermediate in- puts, and machinery and equipment capital goods for the modern La sector. Moreover, because many of these imports are noncompetitive ey and because import substitution policies often have reduced corn- petitive imports to a low level, the price and exchange rate elasticities he usually are thought to be low while measured income elasticities are high. However, for Chile estimated elasticities suggest that the 63 m percent drop in the price level deflated exchange rate (between 1946 and 1973) implied ceteris paribus increases in imports of 57 percent for secondary consumption goods, 88 percent for transportation- a related investment goods, 18 percent for intermediate goods, and 50 es percent for services (Behrman [1975a] and [1976a]). To capture the differential impact of the various types of imports on growth and stabilization as well as the differential responses to - differentcomponents of income and price indices, some disaggrega- tion is necessary. Policies to regulate imports are widely thought to be among the most potent available to the governments of developing countries in their quest toward growth, distribution, and stabilization objectives. Among the policies often utilized are multiple exchange rate systems, tariffs, direct government imports, prior import deposits, and quanti- tative restrictions.24 Clearly in a policy-oriented model these policies should be included explicitly in the import function. It should also '1 20 Short Term Macroeconomic Policy in Latin America benoted that import demand may depend on "excessive" monetary expansion in a fixed-rate regime as discussed in the Panamanian model and Borts and Hanson (Chapter 9, this volume). Quantitative restrictions frequently are used to maintain a disequi- sli librium system with overvalued exchange rate(s) and excess demand lad for foreign exchange. Disequilibrium is allowed to persist because of the perceived negative distribution, inflationary and political effects of devaluation, and widespread convictions about inadequacies of al- ca' location by prices. The existence of strong vested interests in the dis- equilibrium system (e.g., owners of factors in import substitution subsectors, the recipients of import licenses, or the government bu- de reaucracy) also helps to perpetuate the continuance of these systems. re* To satisfy what appears to be substantial excess demand, perpetuated aci in part by the restrictions themselves,25 controls generally are re- ab laxed when foreign exchange becomes available from export booms th' or increased capital inflows. The import functions need to be modi- th' fied, therefore, not only to include the above-mentioned policy tools wi and foreign prices, but also the availability of foreign exchange in a system of disequilibrium exchange control. sea. 2.2.B.5 The Export Equation in Developing Countries:The cor- rect specification of the export function, or functions, is a critical component of a stabilization model for most developing economies. Fluctuations in the value of exports from developing economies, re according to the structuralists and a large number of others (e.g., Heller [1954] and Higgins [1968]), are a major source of instability for these countries. Not only do such variations directly affect total aggregate demand, but, through the government deficit they also change aggregate demand because of the dependence of government revenues on international trade revenues. Furthermore, they may a alter production in the modern sector because of the low elasticity of substitution for critical, imported inputs and a short.run foreign ex- ni change constraint. The holders of this view conclude that general fis- ri cal and monetary policy will not be very effective in stabilization ti attempts. Instead emphasis must be placed on exchange rate and tax policies directly related to exports. Some observers further conclude 1 that movement toward less dependence on the foreign sector is desir- able in order to lessen its destabilizing influence. MacBean (1966) summarizes a variety of previous work on export- based instability and suggests that the above-hypothesized strong tz relationship between export instability and overall instabilityis exaggerated. Diaz Alejanciro reports substantially more varia-

ii. The Use of Econometric Models in Developing Countries 21

ry tion in Colombian imports than in exports and in exports than in an GDP. Màthieson and McKinnon (1974) even conclude that there is a slight indication that "outward-looking" trade policies may decrease Ui instability. MacBean (1966) posits that two factors lie behind the rid lack of a strong relationship between domestic variables and export of fluctuations: (i) the low value of the foreign trade multiplier in part because of repatriation of factor returns to foreign owners and be- al- cause of leakages into taxes on exports and (ii) thedistributed lag iS nature of reactions to change in exports. Ofl Such studies challenge the once-conventional wisdom about the destabilizing influence of international markets. The issue is far from iS. resolved, however, because of the failure of such studies to specify ed adequately the structure (including the lags in responses mentioned re- above) of the developing economies. Even the strongest doubters of T1S the importance of international market fluctuations, moreover, grant that export variations probably are destabilizing in those cases in its which exports are very concentrated in a few products. i a To effectively capture the important, short-run role of exports, it seems best to divide them into two (or more) categories that differ substantially in exchange rate and tax subsidy treatment: traditional (largelyprimaryproducts) and nontraditional (oftenindustrial ml products). es. The traditional exports are often major sources of government eS, revenues. In addition to their "world" price, as modified by taxes, g., some element of market power (perhaps within the framework of ty international commodity agreements) may need to be represented. tal Far from being taxed, many nontraditional exports may receive SO substantial subsidies in hopes of diversifying sources of foreign ex- nt change and gaining entry into faster growing markets without causing ay a decline in "world" price. Many studies have shown a substantial of positive response to changes in these subsidies and a corresponding negative response to an increasingly overvalued exchange rate. Refer- • is- ring once again to Chile, Behrman (1975a) and (1976a) show that the 63 percent drop in the price level deflated nominal exchange rate ax between 1946 and 1972 caused, ceteris paribus, drops in exports of de 100 percent from industry, 50 percent from small- and medium-scale ir- , 32 percent from agriculture, 19 percent from large-scale

• mining, arid 13 percent for exports from services. These results also rt- suggest that these foreign sector regimes increase dependence on rig traditional exports (i.e., those from large-scale mining) despite stated is intentions to encourage diversification. The response to uncertainty • a- in relative prices was widespread although not generally large in mag- '1 22 Short Term Macroeconomic Policy in Latin America

nitude,implying that there was a significant, but not substantial, tici. payoff to the sliding-peg exchange rate policy of 1965—1970 in terms op( of reducing balance of payments difficulties. For Colombia various studies show that "minor" exports, that is, noncoffee, nonpetroleum exports, were extremely responsive to ma. changes in the effective exchange rate (elasticities of two to four are fui reportedin Diaz Alejandro [1977], Musalem (1970], and Sheahan yes and Clark [1972]). The system of effective devaluations initiated ory in 1967 is generally considered ,responsible for the enormous jump in the proportion of minor exports in a much higher total export gel figure.26 Ce 2.3Financial Markets and Assets op BE 2.3.AA Simple Model of Financial Markets in Developed Coun- fai tries:The financial market for the developed economies in Table 1-1 is patterned on the extensions of Tobin's (1969) portfolio equi- ju librium model by Ando (1974) and Branson (1974). Equations (11) ch to (14) are demand functions of private sector asset holders for four in imperfectly substitutable assets: equities, government bonds, foreign securities, and money. Equation (15) is the definition of the rates of iii return (with a fixed zero rate of interest for money) and income in. (with a transactions demand for money). The nominal supplies of ti; money and bonds and the on foreign securities of a re

. d! given risk are assumed to be exogenous. . All assets are gross substitutes. Domestic asset holders must hold given quantities of equities and government bonds, since these assets ti are not traded internationally. Domestic asset holders face an elastic supply of foreign securities at an interest rate fixed internationally. ° Theyare free to trade in money and foreign securities. Any purchase of the latter implicitly reduces domestic foreign exchange by an identical amount, and its effects on domestic money supply are corn- pletely sterilized. . Equations (16) to (18) are relations between holding and capitali- C zation, real and nominal, and holding and international rates for the three respective nonzero return assets. Equations (19) to (22) are C simple hypotheses about the formation of expectations. Equation (23) determines the market value of real assets by capitalizing the expected stream of income from existing assets. Branson (1974) analyzes a similar model for developed countries. T His main results are as follows. (1) The inclusion of noninternation- d ally traded assets restores the effectiveness of monetary policy as measured by the possibility of altering rates of return on such domes- I

j The Use of Econometric Models in Developing Countries 23

al tic assets relative to foreign securities. (2) The relative impact of open market operations on domestic asset rates depends on which asset is the instrument of open market operations. is For the developing economies a number of changes need to be made. As discussed above, asset markets are generally fragmented,

Lre function poorly, and are relatively unimportant in channeling in- vestible funds. Dualism is a common feature, with changes in the organized market having only limited impact on the unorganized sector. Government bond markets and private security markets both ';rt generally are quite small. Monetary policy usually is limited in scope, especially internally. Central are hesitant to undertake substantial open market operations in the very narrow bond market. In some cases the Central Bank acts as a development bank, making lines of credit available to favored sectors. The nominal money supply is not only dependent le upon such credit or rediscount operations but also on de facto or de jure obligations to finance the government deficit and on foreign ex- 1) change movements. Among the monetary instruments that might be ur included in a complete model of the financial sector are marginal and average reserve requirements, rediscount rates, prior deposits on of imports, and exchange rate(s). Also important are interest rate ceil- ae ings and quantitative restrictions on internal credit and on interna- tional capital flows. The use of this latter group of policies may a require that relations in the model be modified to reflect rationing due to quantitative variables. Uncertainty about future quantitative Id policies also may complicate the formation of expectations in equa- ts tions (19) to (22). ic The foreign sector impinges on the financial markets ma number y. of important ways. As is indicated in the previous paragraph, foreign se exchange movements have substantial impact on the domestic money in supply, and the major discretionary monetary operations are in the foreign sector. This discretion is probably limited to the short run, especially if the government attempts to maintain overvalued ex- li- change rates. In particular, with fixed, effective exchange rates it may be difficult to pursue an independent monetary policy because re domestic credit expansion will largely "leak out" via excessive im- )fl portsand capital outflows that lead to drops in international reserves and money.27 Rather than affecting inventories and ultimately out-

• put, imports and local holdings of foreign assets may simply increase. 5. Tobe effective monetary policy may have to be linked with effective devaluation. Foreign direct ownership or domestic capital in the modern sector often is important, and therefore equation (22) or (23) must be mod-

I I 24 Short Term Macroeconomic Policy in Latin America ifiedso that only the value of the domestically owned portion of the capital stock enters into domestic portfolio decisions. Ina few developing countries, such as Mexico, the interest rate in ( the international market may effectively create a liquidity trap for the organized monetary market. In general, however, the interna- tional interest rate does not peg the domestic rate for at least one of three reasons:(i)Quantitative restrictions on capital movements break the link between domestic and international capital markets. (ii) The existence of Bransonian internationally nontraded assets that are not perfect substitutes for internationally traded assets permits some independence in interest rate movements. (iii) Risk premiums may be dependent upon the debt-income ratio (Hanson [1974]). While some of these features have been incorporated in various models of less developed countries, particularly the interrelation be- tween money supply, the foreign sector, and the government deficit, this area remains one of the weak points of such models. Too little is known about the functioning of domestic capital markets to permit an adequate specification though the information accumulated through results of the OAS Capital Markets program may improve future models.

2.4.Identities and Miscellaneous Relations Equations(24) to (28) define disposable income, private savings, income from capital, and the balance of payments surplus. For the developed countries these definitions are basically self-explanatory. Note that capital gains on existing assets arise because of changes in the capitalization rate or changes in the expected stream of income from these existing assets due to varying economic conditions. They do not, of course, include additions to real assets from current net investment. For the developing countries the major special problem is the evaluation of capital gains because of the narrow markets for internal equities. Equation (29) is the tax function (net of transfers). For developed economies the major complication behind this simple representation often is the treatment of the corporation . Therefore, income from capital is included as an argument in this function in addition to total . In developing economies the tax equation is more complex. (i) The traditional sector is not monetized. (ii) Within the modern sector wages represent a smaller function of output than in developed coun- tries, making withholding difficult. (iii) Literacy is relatively low. (iv) Systematic accounting systems are not widely used. (v) The legiti- macy of government revenue collection is less widely accepted and I.

The Use of Econometric Mode/s in Developing Countries 25

thetradition of voluntary compliance is less strong. (vi) Lack of re- sources, low civil pay, and traditional social relations often in make efficient and honest tax collection very difficult. or As a result, the relative importance of alternative sources of tax a- revenues differs from patterns in developed countries. General per- of sonal and corporation income taxes are much less important. Instead ts dependence is greater on import and export taxes, indirect taxes, and taxes on income generated by foreign-owned corporations. Taxes at related t9 the foreign sector are much more significant because gen- erally they are relatively simple to administer and more difficult to evade. This greater dependence on the foreign sector adds to the difficulties of stabilizing these economies because balance of pay- us ment considerations may conflict with the use of taxes for stabiliza- tion purposes. The more regressive nature of the tax structures with it, itsgreater dependence on indirect taxes, moreover, implies less is "automatic stabilization" from the tax system than in more devel- oped countries. Thus it might be appropriate to disaggregate the tax ed system (see Behrman [1976b] for example). ve Equation (30) is the government budget constraint that Christ (1968) and others emphasize repeatedly. In a closed economy or in an economy with balance of payments equilibrium, this relation need not appear explicitly. The model already contains the private sector gs, accountsand a full recording of transactions between the private and ;he government sectors. If the private sector accounting identities are ry. satisfied, so also must be those for the government sector, and the in model is a closed system. However, as alluded to above, and as dis- rue cussed in the Panamanian model, the question of the appropriate tey way of closing the model is important when output and demand functions are estimated separately. Models based on developed coun- em try experience seem to use inventories as the slack variable while • for those dealing with more open economies and fixed exchange rates

• tend to use the balance of payments deficit.

• )ed The model of Table 1-1 for the developed economies is presented ion on a very aggregative level. Actual empirical utilizations of such ,re, models often are on a more disaggregate level. The frequently en- in countered hypothesis that a major source of inflation in the United States and in some of the other more developed economies is the • (i) combination of sectoral shortages with short-run rigidities points to tor the need for at least some disaggregation. Un- For the developing countries, we have already discussed the need (iv) to separate the labor market. In addition, Hansen (1973b) argues pti- that disaggregation is much more important than in developed coun- and tries since much of the direct policy impact is on relative prices. The 26 Short Term Macroeconomic Policy in Latin America

estimationof Chilean sectoral relations (Behrman [1976b]) provides support for this claim. There is a great deal of heterogeneity across sectors in technological substitutabilities and in: both the degree and the time path of behavioral responses to economic variables. Relative prices play major roles in both short-run and long-run resource allo- cation decisions. Both capacity utilization and capacity creation decisions respond significantly to these prices. Possibilities for sub- stantial increases in capacity utilization and for factor substitution do exist.28 To ignore the role of the and these other characteris. tics when conducting analysis and giving policy presumptions, there- fore, may be costly in terms of foregoing the use of some policy tools, overemphasizing the role of "key factors," and creating incen- tivesfor misallocations. And yet the dominant macroeconomic frameworks utilized for analysis of development problems for the tI most part assume that these factors can be ignored. For example, in IL the Chilean case, ODEPLAN (Oficina de Planificaciàn Nacional, Na- ci tional Economics Planning Office) has utilized relative rigid fixed- capital-coefficient and/or foreign-exchange-saving gap models as the basis for planning and prediction.29 On the other hand, policy tools a: have included price ceilings, quantitative restrictions on international trade and on credit, and multiple exchange rates at overvalued levels. ir 2.6The Effects of Macroeconomic Policy in Models of Income Determination ti Toexplain how the developed and developing country models ai work, as well as to obtain a qualitative simulation of the impact of cI policy variables, itis useful to consider two hypothetical experi- ments, an unexpected increase in the money supply and an increase iii in government spending, and trace out their effects on the major variables in the system. In the developed country model, an increase in the stock of in money, realized through the open market purchase of government w bonds (equation [30]), tends to change interest rates (equation [14] d and equation [16]). To the extent the cost of capital falls, it stimu- lates demand for investment goods (equation [7]). (We neglect the p foreign sector, changes in taxes, and any possible wealth effects from a change in the ratio of money to bonds.) Demand for labor and out- hr put rise, stimulating second round demands of households, govern- ment, and investors (taxes also rise, which may have second-order sé effects on government bonds and private wealth). Unemployment in falls (equation [1] and equation [2]) and prices rise because of the direct effect of unemployment (positive in equation [4]) and the di

:7 r

The Use of Econometric Mode/s in Deve/oping Countries 27

ies indirect effect on wages (equation [3]) and prices (equation [4]). )ss The extent of the price rise, relative to the rise in output, depends on the ratio (lagged?) of aggregate demand to the labor force. we An expansion of government demand, financed through bond sales, lo- raises demand directly (equation [8]) and indirectly (equations [30] on and [6]) through the second-round output-income effects. (We again neglect the foreign sector, changes in taxes, and changes in wealth.) on The rise in bond sales raises interest rates and reduces investment, partially offsetting the increase in government spending. The fall in

I unemployment (equations [1]and[2]) has positive, direct, and re- indirect effects on prices (equations [3] and [4]). icy In the developing country model it is difficult to separate mone-

• tarypolicy from government spending because there are no orga-

• Qic nized financial markets in which to buy or sell bonds.3° Aside from

• ;he the use of government spending, about the only practical way to

• in increase the money supply is through changes in bank reserves or central bank . In all three cases the effects of changes in money tend to be concentrated in certain sectors and affect their the second-round spending directly, owing to previous credit rationing, ols as compared to the more general effects of interest rate changes in nal developing countries. The more general effects of monetary policy in developing countries occur through such second-round spending of income recipients on local as opposed to imported goods and on local intermediate purchases by the favored industries. To the extent that the favored industries and their suppliers are close to "capacity" •els and fixed exchange rates are maintained, relative prices tend to of change and/or imports and capital flows tend to vary, weakening the ?ri- general impact of monetary policy on domestic output. In particular, ase in the Panamanian case, the effect of increases in nonagricultural .jor credit or money was quite small although positive.3' While coordi-

• nated variation in effective, exchange rates would permit greater of independence in monetary pplicy, the necessity of their coordination ?nt with monetary policy reduces the number of completely indepen- 4] dent instruments. riu- Fiscal policy in developing countries is closely related to monetary the policy, again because of the narrow financial markets. Variations in government spending, financed locally through variations in bank ut- holdings of government debt, tend to cause inverse variations in

• rn- credit that "crowd out" other local credit demand and produce off- ler setting effects in investment. On the other hand, variations in govern- ent ment spending, financed through foreign borrowing that does not bid the up local interest rates, have a two-pronged effect through their in- the direct effect on reserves and money as well as their direct effect on I 28 Short Term Macroeconomic Policy in Latin America

spending.The Panamanian model seems to indicate the "crowding out" effect or capacity constraints are quite important. In developing economies both monetary and fiscal policy have their greatest effect on the modern sector. Their effect on the tra- ditional sector occurs through variations in relative prices and in rural-urban migration rates. The greater the gap between (expected) wages in the city and the average labor income in the country, the smaller is the variation in relative prices and the greater is the varia- tion in migration rates. Thus, in a special sense, the rural sector also acts as a capacity constraint that affects the division of changes in aggregate demand between price and output effects. IT 2.7 Conclusions: Some General Points in Income-Determination Models and Short-Term Policymaking in Developing Countries gi Whileconditions vary substantially across countries and modeling of certain aspects of the developing countries remains rudimentary, e: several important general points or questions about income determi- nation processes and countercyclical policy have appeared in our discussions. (1) Supply variations in the traditional sector may cause cyclical U variations while countercyclical policies mainly affect the modern sector. More general policy tools must be developed to affect both si sectors. (2) If the traditional sector determines the real wage for the mod- em sector and there is no money illusion, then the modern sector labor market is very classical. Increased aggregate demand will not raise equilibrium employment and production although they will af- vI fect these variables when urban unemployment is abnormally high. Decreases in aggregate demand will lower urban employment and slow migration. However, much research remains to be done on the determination of labor's income in the traditional sector and its rela- t! tion to urban wages through migration. (3) Changing international conditions and/or variations in govern- e ment policy seem to be responsible for most of the cyclical fluctua- C tionsin developing countries, as opposed to the traditional view U expressed in developed country models that investment is the key.32

• In addition to the oft.described direct and multiplier effects of changes in world prices of exports or imports, variations in world al prices tend to have indirect effects through variations in international reserves and, correspondingly, the money supply. Government policy may respond to reserve losses and variations in conditions in the ex-

.1 The Use of Econometric Models in Developing Countries 29

portand import competing industries; in addition, variations in external financing may force variations in emission. Varia- tionS in prices of noncompetitive raw materials and intermediate a- import may cause short-run fluctuations through either supply in limitations or reduction of demand in other sectors. Finally, attempts to maintain disequilibrium exchange rates may lengthen the period of adjustment to external disturbances. a- Given the importance of the foreign sector in generating cyclical fluctuations, some effort should be devoted to ensuring its correct in specification in the income-determination model. The various poli- cies to reduce its impact should be closely studied and some effort made to. direct stabilization policies toward it. Some attempts have been made in this direction, both on the level of individual countries and in cooperation with other countries. However, stabilization pro b- lems often are viewed as less important than objectives such as growth and distribution. If a temporary foreign exchange surplus is available because of an export boom or increased capital inflows, for example, pressures are enormous to utilize it to alleviate other prob- lems. Only rarely do governments find it feasible to conserve such an excess for use when the next foreign exchange deficit occurs. Only when such governments are convinced that the costs to these fluctua- al tions are large or that there are gains in other policy dimensions of increased stabilization are more resources likely to be utilized for stabilization purposes. (4) The international capital market does not limit stabilization

options in developing countries by fixing domestic interest rates.33 4 Thisis so because of the existence of Bransonian noninternationally traded assets, because of quantitative restrictions and exchange rate variations that break the link between international and domestic h. markets, and because of variations in risk premiums as international vary relative to national product. (5) Stabilization policies are limited by international creditors, by a- the lack of integrated and well-functioning financial markets, and by the offsetting response of international reserves to domestic credit expansion. The last limitation is, of course, true only under fixed ex- a- change rates, and monetary policy would be "more independent" under flexible rates. However, exchange rate and aggregate demand policies are too often treated as independent policy .

• (6) The partial equilibrium evidence of substantial technological and behavioral flexibilities suggests that models that assume too great. rigidities (see the introduction) may distort the perceived choice set and overemphasize the importance of "key" factors. The partial equilibrium evidence of significant substitution possibilities and price

.1 30 Short Term Macroeconomic Policy in Latin America

responsessuggest that macropolicies might have significant impact on aggregate variables. However, general equilibrium simulations of the Chilean model and particularly the Panamanian model indicate that these policies may have much less aggregate impact than partial equi- librium analysis might suggest, owing to overall resource constraints and indirect effects (such as those transmitted through the money supply-foreign exchange-price nexus). A great deal of the effect of macropolicies also depends on the size of and behavior within the traditional sector as well as relations be- th1 tween conditional and modem sectors and the ratio between aggre- gate demand and existing capacity, factors that are not well described ve in existing models. (7) Both the partial equilibrium and the general equilibrium anal-

yses lend support to Hansen's (1973b) emphasis on the need for WE disaggregation to capture relative price effects. The estimated partial equilibrium relations are quite heterogeneous across sectors in regard pa to technological possibilities, behavioral responses, and patterns of adjustment. The general equilibrium simulations suggest that policies may have much greater impact on the composition of aggregates than on their size, especially when the economy is near its capacity as de- fined by existing institutions and behavior. To what extent institu- tions and behavior of individuals and policymakers should be taken as given remains a special dilemma for those who would venture into the tangle of income-determination models of developing countries. NOTES fii 1. Examples include Adelman and Thorbecke (1966), Blitzer, Clark, and (11 Taylor (1975), Cabezon (1969), Chenery and Strout (1966), Clark and Foxley (1970, 1973), Eckaus and Parikh (1968), Manne (1974), UNECAFE (1960), and UNCTAD (1968). 2. "Socially optimal" is used here not to imply the incorporation of exter- nalities, but to mean the maximization of an objective function, given con- td straints imposed by the model, starting and terminal conditions, and exogenous n: variables. Some aspects of behavioral responses are incorporated in these studies, such as the sectoral pattern of income elasticities for private consumption. ui 3. Rao (1952) presents an early statement of this view. Ranis (1974) gives a w recent summary. in 4. For good summaries of the "structuralist-monetarist" debate, see Campos bil

• (1964) and Wachter (1974). tic

• 5. Behrman (1968) summarizes many of the estimates that relate to agricul- un tural supplies. Morawetz (1974) gives references for a number of studies of elasticities of substitution. Behrman (1971a, 1972a, 1972b, 1972c, 1973a, 1973c, and 1976b) and Behrman and Garcia (1973) present sectoral estimates for the Chilean experience. di The Use of Econometric Mode/s in Developing Countries 31

)O 6.Beltrán (1974) summarizes the features of many of the Latin American models. Larry Lau (1975) has compiled a bibliography of 200 such models of at which 50 relate to Latin America. 7. For example, R. French-Davis (1973) shows that the Chilean Klein-Saks ts stabilization program was originally thought to have failed when inflation doubled in 1958 but reestimates show the rate was approximately constant over eY the 1957-1958 period. While the social costs of this stability also may have been judged too high, the facts of the case were substantially different from those ze that went into the original evaluation. 8. See Zamowitz (1967), for example. re- 9. See Behrman and Vargas (Chapter 2, this volume) for an attempt to de- ed velop and use such data bases in constructing quarterly models of developing countries - aI- 10. See Barro and Grossman (1976) for a theoretical framework of supply as 'or well as demand restraints that determine income for an economy that is not in ial general equilibrium. Howard (1976) finds support for the Barro-Grossman hy. pothesis regarding supply constraints in a controlled economy. 11. Many of the studies previously mentioned attempt to correct one or two of these shortcomings. Nevertheless, the list of shortcomings in any specific 1es studygenerally is quite large. For example, Corbo's (1971) well-known study of an Chile considers the problem of an endogenous money supply and includes sup- ply constraints, but it does not avoid most of the other shortcomings listed in tU the text. Moreover in the simulations of that study, because of convergence :en problems, excess demand is exogenized so that there is no link between mone- ito tary and real variables or the money supply and prices. es- 12. See Barro and Grossman (1976) and Behrman (197Gb). 13. The movement toward putty-clay considerations in the macroeconomic literature for developed economies lags substantially the emphasis on ex post fixed proportions for the modern sector of the less developed economies. Eckaus irid (1955) provides an early statement regarding less developed countries. ley 14. The discrepancy between the marginal products in the two sectors obvi- 0), ously leads to static inefficiencies.

• 15. The average share per laborer sometimes is assumed to be fixed by tradi- ter- tion until withdrawal of surplus labor raises the marginal product in this sector on- to that prevailing in the modern sector, when market behavior begins to domi-

- ous nate the economy (Fei and Ranis [19641). ies, 16. Harris and Todaro (1970) attribute a certain minimum level of urban unemployment to the existence of government or unions, which establish fixed a wages. They claim that rural-urban migration occurs as long as the expected income (taking into account both the higher modern sector wage and the proba- pos bility of obtaining employment) exceeds the average labor share in the tradi- tional sector. The result is an equilibrium level of open employment or disguised cul- unemployment in the cities, which persists as long as government or unions • of maintain a differential between the traditional sector's average labor share and '3a, the modern sector wage. )ral 17. Interest rates might also enter so the model need not be completely dichotomized.

:1 32 Short Term Macroeconomic Policy in Latin America

18.Suppose that production functions in both sectors are subject to constant return to scale and for simplicity that individual returns in the traditional sector are equal to the average product of labor. For given capital stocks in the two sectors there is only one labor allocation that equates the marginal product in the modern sector and the average in the traditional and "employs" all of the labor force. If unemployment in the urban sector is permitted, then a single "equilibrium" level of unemployment will be determined unless the elasticities of labor "demand" schedules in the two sectors have a very particular con- figuration. 19. Fei and Ranis (1964) claim that it may be difficult to use the rural sur- plus for development if rural labor incomes do not remain at the traditional level and prices of rural goods tend to rise. See also Hymer and Resnick (1971). 20. The theoretical question also remains as to whether privately held govern. ment bonds should be counted as private wealth. See Barro (1974). 21. See Gomez and Schlesinger (1971) for an attempt to estimate family net worth in Colombia. 22. Diaz Alejandro (1977) reports 75 percent of investment of Colombian machinery and was imported in 1975. 23. If the availability of foreign capital inflows (both official and private) directlyor indirectly affects investment (e.g., see Areskong [1974]) they should be included in the model as part of a reduced form of the investment equation and through spillovers of frustrated demands in the consumption-saving function. The theoretical framework for modeling such spillovers might follow Barro and Grossman (1976). 24. In some developing economies considerable smuggling exists in attempts to avoid these policies. 25. See Bruton (11369) and Musalem (1971). 26. Noncoffee exports grew from $177 million or approximately 25 percent of exports in 1966 to $671 million or 55 percent of exports in 1974 or over 28 percent per year. While Calvo and Escandón (1973) and Cabarrouy and Spillane (197 4) attribute much of the growth up to 1969 or 1971 as simple maintenance of market share, one must point out that market share would not be maintained without appropriate incentives to export, that is, conversion of the world price into an appropriate local currency value. 27. Borts and (Chapter 9, this volume) discuss the extent to which this view is correct with some empirical results for the Panamanian case.

• 28. Estimated sectoral elasticities of substitution between capital and labor range from 0.0 to 0.9. The adjustment periods for substitution between primary factors are fairly long in several cases in which the long-run elasticities are high. For most sectors in the short and medium runs, therefore, the results provide some support for the assumption of limited flexibility that underlies Eckaus's (1955) technological explanation of the existence of under. or unemployed labor, the structuralist analysis of inflation, and the use of fixed coefficients in input-output-based models. Limited flexibility, however, is not the same as no flexibility. Some primary factor substitution apparently is always possible in response to real relative price changes. 29. For example, see Harberger and Selowsky (1966) or ODEPLAN (1970). .t

V The Use of Econometric Models in Developing Countries 33

30.The lack of markets may reflect government attempts to sell bonds at low, fixed rates of return to banks as well as the stage of development. 31. See Behrman and Vargas (Chapter 2, this volume) and Borts and Hanson (Chapter 9, this volume). 32. But see Friedman (1965) and Okun (1970). 33. Macrotheory suggests that fiscal policy would retain its potency under fixed rates; itis only the effectiveness of monetary policy that is questioned. See Mundell (1968).

REFERENCES

Adelman,Irma, and Erik Thorbecke, eds. The Theory and Design of Econom- ic Development. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins, 1966. Ando, Albert. "Some Aspects of Stabilization Policies, the Monetarist Con- troversy, and the MPS Model." International Economic Review 15:3 (October 1974), 541—576. Areskoug, Kaj. "Private Investment and Capital Formation in Developing Countries." (Mimeo., New York University, 1974). Barro, Robert. "Are Government Bonds Net Wealth?" Journal of 82:6 (November/December 1974), 1095-1117. —."Money and Output in Mexico, Colombia, and ." This volume. Barro, Robert, and Herschel Grossman. Money, Employment and Inflation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1976. Behrman, Jere R. Supply Response in Underdeveloped Agriculture: A Case Study of Four Major Annual Crops in , 1937-1963. Amsterdam: North Holland Publishing Co., 1968. —."TheDeterminants of the Annual Rates of Change of Sectoral Money 4 Wagesin a Developing Economy." International Economic Review 12:3 (Octo- ber 1971a), 431-447. —."ReviewArticle: Trade Prospects and Capital Needs of Developing Countries." International Economic Review 12:3 (October 1971b), 519-525. -"SectoralElasticities of Substitution between Capital and Labor in a Developing Economy: Time Series Analysis in the Case of Postwar Chile." Econometrica 40:2 (March 1972), 311-327. - "SectoralInvestment Determination ina Developing Economy." American Economic Review 62:5 (December 1972b), 825-841. —."Short-RunFlexibility in a Developing Economy: The Postwar Chilean Experience." Journal of Political Economy 80:2 (March-April 1972c), 292-313. —."AggregativeMarket Response in Developing Agriculture: The Postwar Chilean Experience." in R. Eckaus and P.N. Rosenstein-Rodan, eds. Analysis of Development Problems: Studies of the Chilean Economy. Amsterdam: North- Holland Publishing Co., 1973a, 229-250. —."CyclicalSectoral Capacity Utilization in a Developing Economy," in R. Eckaus and P.N. Rosenstein-Rodan, eds -Analysisof Development Problems: Studies of the Chilean Economy. Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Co., 1973b, 251-268. 34 Short Term Macroeconomic Policy in Latin America

—. "PriceDetermination in an Inflationary Economy: The Dynamics of Chilean Inflation Revisited," in R. Eckaus and P.N. Rosenstein-Rodan, eds. A1 Analysis of Development Problems: Studies of the Chilean Economy. Amster- dam: North Holland Publishing Co., 1973c, 369-398. —."ModelingStabilization Policy for the LDC's in an International Set- ting," in A. Ando, ed. International Aspects of Stabilization Policy. Proceedings of ISPE—Boston Federal Reserve Bank Conference, 1974. —."Foreign.SectorRegimes and in Chile." Paper presented at the ECLA-NBER Conference, 1975c. "Econometric Modeling of National Income Determination in Develop. F! ing Countries, with Special Reference to the Chilean Experience." Annals of Economic and Social Measurement 4:4 (Fall 1975b), 461-488. [a —.ForeignTrade and Economic Development: The Chilean Experience. New York: NBER and Columbia University Press, 1976a. SI —.MacroeconomicPolicy in a Developing Country: An Econometric In- gr vestigation of the Postwar Chilean Experience. Amsterdam: North-Holland Pub- lishing Co., 1976b. Behrman, JR., and M. Jorge Garcia. "A Study of Quarterly Nominal Wage Change Determinants in an Inflationary Developing Economy," in R. Eckaus and R.N. Rosenstein-Rodan, eds. Analysis of Development Problems: Studies of the Chilean Economy. Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Co., 1973, Sc 399-416. °i Behrman, J.R., and L.R. Klein. " Models for the Devel- oping Economy," in W.A. Eltis, M. Fg. Scott and N.N. Wolfe, eds. Induction, Growth and Trade. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1970. di Behrman, JR., and JR. Vargas. "A Quarterly Econometric Model of Pan- ama." This volume. 1. Beltrán del Rio, Abel. "Statistical Regularities in Macroeconometric Models of Developing Economies." Paper presented at Seminar on Economic Models of Emerging Nations, Tel Aviv, October 1974. Beltrãn del Rio, Abel, and L.R. Klein. "Macroeconometric Model Building in Ai Latin America: The Mexican Case," in N. Ruggles, ed. The Role of the Compul. T er in Economic and Social Research in Latin America. New York: NBER and 2( Columbia University Press, 1974. Birnberg, Thomas, and Stephen Resnick. "A Model of Trade and Government In Sectors in Colonial Economies." American Economic Review 63:3 (September 1973), 572-587. H Blinder, Alan, and Robert Solow. "Does Fiscal Policy Matter?" Journal of 2:2 (June 1973), 319-337. ai Blitzer, Charles R., Peter B. Clark, and Lance Taylor, eds. Economy-Wide Models and Development Planning. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1975. Sorts, George, and James Hanson. "A Monetary Model of the Balance of Payments with Empirical application to Panama." This volume, a Branson, William H. "Portfolio Equilibrium and Monetary Policy with For. eign and Non-Traded Assets." (Mimeo., draft for Third Paris-Dauphine Ed ference, 1974). I.

The Use of Econometric Models in Developing Countries 35

Bruton,Henry. "The Two Gap Approach to Development: Comment." American Economic Review 59:3 (June 1969), 439-446. Brodersohn, Marco. "The Phillips Curve and the Conflict Between Full Em- ployment and Price Stability in the Argentine Economy, 1964-1974." This volume. Cabezón, Pedro. "An Evaluation of Commercial Policy in the Chilean Eco- nomy." Madison: University of Wisconsin, unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, 1969. Caburrouy, Evaldo, and James Spillane. "La Experiencia de Colombia en r Materia de Exportaciones de Manufacturas en el Periodo 1960—69." Revista de Planeación 6:1 (enero.marzo 1974), 5 1-86. Calvo, Harold, and Jose Escandón. Las Exportaciones Columbianas de Manu- 1" facturas: 1963-1971. Bogota: FEDESARROLLO, 1973. Campos, Roberto de Oliveira. "Economic Development and Inflation with Special Reference to Latin America," in OECD, Development Plans and Pro- grammes. Paris: OECD Development Centre, 1964, 129-37. Chenery, Hollis B., and A. Strout. "Foreign Assistance and Economic Devel- opment." American Economic Review 56:3 (September 1966), 679-7 33. Christ, Carl. "A Simple Macroeconomic Model with a Government Budget Restraint." Journal of Political Economy 76:1 (January-February 1968), 5 3-67. IS Clark, Peter Bentley, and R. Alejandro Foxley. "Sub-Optimal Growth: The Social Cost of Make-Work Employment Policies." Paper presented at the session on "Numerical Models of Development Planning," Second World Congress of the Econometric , Cambridge, England, September 8-14, 1970, mimeo. Corbo Lioi, Vittorio. "An Econometric Study of Chilean Inflation." Ph.D. dissertation, MIT, 1971. Published as Inflation in Developing Countries: An Eco- riometric Study of Chilean Inflation. Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Co., 1974. Diaz Alejandro, Carlos. Foreign Trade Regimes and Economic is Colombia. New York: NBER and Columbia University Press, 1977. Is Eckaus, R.S. "The Factor.Proportions Problem in Underdeveloped Areas." American Economic Review, 1955. Reprinted in A. Agarwala and S. Singh, eds. The Economics of Underdevelopment. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1958, 205-218. Eckaus, Richard S., and Kirit S. Parikh. Planning for Growth: Multisector Intertemporal Models Applied to . Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1968. Fei, John, and Gustav Ranis. Development of the Labor Surplus Economy. Homewood, Ill.: Irwin Publishing Co., 1964. Fernandez, Roque. "The Short.Run Output Inflation Tradeoff in Argentina and Brazil." This volume.

• Fernandez, Roque, and James Hanson. "Los Interrelaciones del Carto Plazo entre Inflacidn, Producción y Empleo en America Latina." In ILPES, Planifica- of cidn del Corto Plazo: La Dindmica de los Precios, el Empleo y el Productb, Santiago: 1977. French-Davis, Ricardo. Poli'ticas Económicas en Chile, 1952-1970. Santiago: Ediciones Nueva Universidad, Universidad Católica de Chile, 1973. Friedman, Milton. "Monetary Policy in Developing Countries," in Paul A. 36 Short Term Macroeconomic Policy in LatinAmerica

Davidand Melvin W. Reder, eds. Nations and Households in Economic Growth: Essaysin Honor of Moses Abramovitz. New York: Academic Press, 1974, 265-27 8. - TheGreat Contraction. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1965. Gomez, Armando, and Daniel Schlesinger. Ancilisis Preliminar de las Cuentas de Flujode FondosFinancieros dela EconomIa Colombiana 1962-1964. Bogota: Banco de Ia Repüblica, 1971. Hansen, Bent. "On the Effects of Fiscal and Monetary Policy: A Taxonomic Discussion." American Economic Review 63:3 (September 1973a), 546-7 1. —."Simulationof Fiscal, Monetary and Exchange Policy in a Primitive Economy: Afghanistan." In Economic Structure and Development. Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Co., 1973, 215-237. F Hanson, James. "Optimal International Borrowing and Lending." American Economic Review 64:3 (September 1974), 616-630. Harberger, Arnold. "The Dynamics of Inflation in Chile," in Carl Christ, ed. Measurements in Economics. Palo Alto, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1963. Harberger, Arnold C., and Marcelo Selowsky. "Key Factors in the Economic Growth of Chile: An Analysis of the Sources of Past Growth and of Prospects for 1965—70." Paper presented at Conference on "The Next Decade of Latin 5 American Economic Development," April 20—22, 1966, Cornell University, mimeo. Harris, John R., and Michael P. Todaro. "Migration, Unemployment and Development: A Two-Sector Analysis." American Economic Review 60:1 (March 1970), 126-142. Heller, Walter W. "Fiscal Policies for Underdevelopment Economies," in Has- kell P. Wald, ed. Conference on Agricultural Taxation and Economic Develop- a ment.Cambridge, Mass: International Program in Taxation, Harvard Law School, 1954. Higgins, Benjamin. Economic Development: Principles, Problems and Policies; rev. ed., New York: W.W. Norton and Co., 1968. Howard, David. "The Disequilibrium Model in the Controlled Economy: An Empirical Test of the Barro-Grossman Model." American Economic Review 66:5 (December 1976), 871-879. Hymer, Stephen, and Stephen Resnick. "A Model of an Agrarian Economy." American Economic Review 59:4 (March 1969), 493-506. Johnson, Harry. "The Monetary Approach to the Balance of Payments," in M. Connally and A. Swoboda, eds. International Trade and Money. Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1973, pp. 206-224. Lau, Lawrence. "A Bibliography of Macroeconomic Model of Developing Economies." Palo Alto, Calif.: Stanford University (Mimeo., 1975). S Lewis, W. Arthur. "Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labor." The Manchester School 22:1 (May 1954), 139-191. Lucas, Robert. "Some International Evidence on Output-Inflation Trade- offs." American Economic Review 63:3 (June 1973), 326-34. —."EconometricPolicy Evaluation: A Critique," in Karl Brunner and Allan Meltzer, eds. The Phillips Curve and Labor Markets. Amsterdam: North- Holland Publishing Co., 1976. 9 r

The Use of Econometric Models in Developing Countries 37

MacBean,Alasdair I. ExportInstability andEconomicDevelopment.Cam-

4 bridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1966. Manne, Alan. "Multi-Sector Models for Development Planning: A Survey." 5. Journal of 1:1 (June 1974), 4 3-70. Mathieson, Donald J., and Ronald I. McKinnon. "Instability in veloped Countries: The Impact of the International Economy," in Paul A. David and Melvin W. Reder, eds. Nations and Households in Economic Growth: Essays in Honor of Moses Abramovitz. New York: Academic Press, 1974, 315-332. Michalopolous, Constantine. "Productivity Growth in Latin America: Corn- ment." American Economic Review 59:3 (June 1969), 435-439. Mikesell, Raymond F., and James E. Zinser. "The Nature of the Savings Function in Developing Countries: A Survey of the Theoretical and Empirical Literature." Journal of Economic Literature 11:1 (March 1973), 1-26. Modigliani, Franco, and F. Tarantelli. "The Consumption Function in a De- veloping Economy and the Italian Experience." American Economic Review 3. 65:5 (December 1975), 825—842. Morawetz, David. "Employment Implications of Industrialization in Develop. ts ing Countries: A Survey." Economic Journal 84:335 (September 1974), 491- in 542. Mundell, R. . New York: Macmillan, 1968. Musalem, Alberto. Las Exportaciones Colombianas, 1959-1969. Bogota: 1970, unpublished. :1 —.Demandapor Dinero y Balanza de Pagos en Colombia. Bogota: Banco de Ia Repüblica, 1971. s. ODEPLAN. "Marco de referencia cuantitativo preliminar para La elaboración del programa 1970-80." Santiago: January 1970. Okun, Arthur. The Political Economy of Prosperity. New York: W.W. Norton and Co., 1970. Papanek, Gustav. "The Effect of Aid and Other Resource Transfers on Sav- ings and Growth in Less Developed Countries." Economic Journal 327 (Septem- her 1972), 934-950. w —."Aid,Foreign Private Investment, Savings and Growth in Less Devel- oped Countries." Journal of Political Economy 81:1 (January/February 1973), ." 120—131. Ranis, Gustav. "Short.Run Policy in Semi-Industrialized Economies:

• in ment." Economic Development and Cultural Change 22:3 (January 1974), 345-346. Rao, V.K.R.V. "Investment, Income and the Multiplier in an Underdeveloped ig Economy." The Indian Econo,nic Review, 1952. Reprinted in A. Agarwala arid S. Singh, eds. The Economics of Undet-development. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1958, 205-218.

• Rosenstein-Rodan, Paul N. "Notes on the Theory of the 'Big Push'." in H. Ellis, ed. Economic Development for Latin America. New York: St. Martin's Press, 1961, 57-81. Reynolds, Clark. "Development Problems of an Export Economy," in C. Reynolds and M. Mamalakis, eds. Essays on the Chilean Economy. Homewood, Ill.: Irwin Publishing Co., 1968, 203-398.

.4' I 38 Short Term Macroeconomic Policy in Latin America

Schydlowsky,Daniel M. "Short-Run PolicyinSemi-Industrialized Eco- nomies." EconomicDevelopment and Cultural Change 19:3(April 1971), 391— 413. "Capital Utilization, Growth, Employment and Balance of Payments and Price Stabilization." This volume. Sheahan, John, and Sara Clark. LasRespuestas de las Exportaciones Colom- bianas a Variaciones en Ia Tasa Efectiva de Cambio. Bogota:FEDESARROLLO, 1972. Taylor, Lance. "Short-Term Policy in Open Developing Economies: The Nar- row Limits of the Possible." Journalof Development Economics 1:2(September 1974), 85-104. Tobin, James. "A General Equilibrium Approach to Monetary Theory." Journalof Money, Credit and Banking 1:1,(1969), 15-30. United Nations Economic Commission for Asia and the Far East (UNE- CAFE). ProgrammingTechniques [or Economic Development, Bangkok:United Nations, 1960. United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD). Trade Prospects and Capital Needs of Developing Countries. NewYork: United Na- tions, 1968. Wachter,Susan. LatinAmerican Structuralist and Monetarist Inflation Theories: An Application to Chile. Ph.D.Thesis, Boston College, September 1974. 1. Wachter, Susan "Structuralism vs. Monetarism: Inflation in Chile." This volume. Ti Zarnowitz, Victor. AnAppraisal of Short-Term Forecasts. NewYork: NBER Co and Columbia University, 1967. 1.

2.,

3-

4-

E Po ar. imi Dei la Pol Sta