Entrepreneurial risk-taking beyond bounded rationality : risk factors, cognitive biases and strategies of new technology ventures

Citation for published version (APA): Podoynitsyna, K. S. (2008). Entrepreneurial risk-taking beyond bounded rationality : risk factors, cognitive biases and strategies of new technology ventures. Technische Universiteit Eindhoven. https://doi.org/10.6100/IR635533

DOI: 10.6100/IR635533

Document status and date: Published: 01/01/2008

Document Version: Publisher’s PDF, also known as Version of Record (includes final page, issue and volume numbers)

Please check the document version of this publication:

• A submitted manuscript is the version of the article upon submission and before peer-review. There can be important differences between the submitted version and the official published version of record. People interested in the research are advised to contact the author for the final version of the publication, or visit the DOI to the publisher's website. • The final author version and the galley proof are versions of the publication after peer review. • The final published version features the final layout of the paper including the volume, issue and page numbers. Link to publication

General rights Copyright and moral rights for the publications made accessible in the public portal are retained by the authors and/or other copyright owners and it is a condition of accessing publications that users recognise and abide by the legal requirements associated with these rights.

• Users may download and print one copy of any publication from the public portal for the purpose of private study or research. • You may not further distribute the material or use it for any profit-making activity or commercial gain • You may freely distribute the URL identifying the publication in the public portal.

If the publication is distributed under the terms of Article 25fa of the Dutch Copyright Act, indicated by the “Taverne” license above, please follow below link for the End User Agreement: www.tue.nl/taverne

Take down policy If you believe that this document breaches copyright please contact us at: [email protected] providing details and we will investigate your claim.

Download date: 29. Sep. 2021

Entrepreneurial risk-taking beyond bounded rationality:

Risk factors, cognitive biases and strategies of new technology ventures

Ksenia Podoynitsyna

CIP-DATA LIBRARY TECHNISCHE UNIVERSITEIT EINDHOVEN

Podoynitsyna, Ksenia Sergeyevna

Entrepreneurial risk-taking beyond bounded rationality: risk factors, cognitive biases and strategies of new technology ventures / by Ksenia Sergeyevna Podoynitsyna. - Eindhoven : Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 2008. – Proefschrift. - ISBN 978-90-386-1280-5 NUR 801 Keywords: Entrepreneurship / New technology ventures / Success factors / Cognitive biases / Risk and uncertainty management strategies / Performance

Entrepreneurial risk-taking beyond bounded rationality:

Risk factors, cognitive biases and strategies of new technology ventures

PROEFSCHRIFT

ter verkrijging van de graad van doctor aan de Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, op gezag van de Rector Magnificus, prof.dr.ir. C.J. van Duijn, voor een commissie aangewezen door het College voor Promoties in het openbaar te verdedigen op woensdag 11 juni 2008 om 16.00 uur

door

Ksenia Sergeyevna Podoynitsyna geboren te Moskou, Rusland

Dit proefschrift is goedgekeurd door de promotoren: prof.dr.ir. M.C.D.P. Weggeman en prof.dr. X.M. Song

Copromotor: dr. J.D. van der Bij

i

Table of contents

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS V

CHAPTER 1 GENERAL INTRODUCTION 11

1.1 META -ANALYSIS OF SUCCESS FACTORS 12

1.2 THE MECHANISM OF ENTREPRENEURIAL RISK -TAKING 14

1.3 RISK AND UNCERTAINTY MANAGEMENT STRATEGIES 16

CHAPTER 2 META-ANALYSIS OF SUCCESS FACTORS 19

2.1 INTRODUCTION 20

2.2 DATA COLLECTION AND METHODOLOGY 21 2.2.1 Selection of studies as input for the analysis 22 2.2.2 Protocol for meta-analysis 23

2.3 ANALYSIS AND RESULTS 26 2.3.1 Success factors of technology ventures 26 2.3.2 Moderators 31

2.4 IDENTIFICATION OF HIGH -QUALITY MEASUREMENT SCALES 33

2.5 DISCUSSION AND FUTURE RESEARCH DIRECTIONS 34 2.5.1 Market and opportunity 36 2.5.2 Entrepreneurial team 37 2.5.3 Resources 38

2.6 LIMITATIONS 39 ii CHAPTER 3 THE MECHANISM OF ENTREPRENEURIAL RISK-TAKING 41

3.1 INTRODUCTION 42

3.2 THEORETICAL BACKGROUND 44 3.2.1 Dual process theory: Definitions and theoretical foundation 44 3.2.2 Heuristics and biases stream of research 45

3.3 CONCEPTUAL MODEL AND HYPOTHESES 46 3.3.1 Relationship between biases and risk-taking propensity 47 3.3.2 Relationship between the two systems and risk-taking propensity 52 3.3.3 Relationship between the two systems and biases 54

3.4 METHODOLOGY 55 3.4.1 Sample and data collection 55 3.4.2 Measurements 56 3.4.3 Analysis 60

3.5. RESULTS 63

3.6. DISCUSSION 66 3.6.1 Major research findings and theoretical implications 66 3.6.2 Managerial implications 69 3.6.3 Limitations 70

CHAPTER 4 RISK AND UNCERTAINTY MANAGEMENT STRATEGIES 73

4.1 INTRODUCTION 74

4.2 THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK 77 4.2.1 Traditional risk management strategies 77 4.2.2 Real options strategy 80 4.2.3 Performance consequences of risk management strategies 82 4.2.4 Moderator: Technology standards 85 4.2.5 Moderator: Network externalities 88

4.3 METHODOLOGY 90 4.3.1 Sample and data collection 90 4.3.2 Measurements 91 4.3.3 Analysis 92

iii

4.4 RESULTS 95

4.5 DISCUSSION 97

4.6 CONCLUSION 103

CHAPTER 5 GENERAL DISCUSSION 106

5.1 DISCUSSION OF CHAPTER 2: THE META -ANALYSIS OF SUCCESS FACTORS 107 5.1.1 Conclusions 107 5.1.2 Future directions of research 108

5.2 DISCUSSION OF CHAPTER 3: THE MECHANISM OF ENTREPRENEURIAL RISK -TAKING 111 5.2.1 Conclusions 111 5.2.2 Future directions of research 112

5.3 DISCUSSION OF CHAPTER 4: RISK AND UNCERTAINTY MANAGEMENT STRATEGIES 114 5.3.1 Conclusions 114 5.3.2 Future directions of research 114

5.4 FINAL REMARKS 116

REFERENCES 117

APPENDIX A: MEASURES 129

A2.1. SCALES OF THE MOST IMPORTANT META -FACTORS FROM CHAPTER 2 129

A3.1. CONSTRUCTS , MEASUREMENT ITEMS , AND CONSTRUCT RELIABILITIES FOR

CHAPTER 3 131

A4.1. CONSTRUCTS , MEASUREMENT ITEMS , AND CONSTRUCT RELIABILITIES FOR

CHAPTER 4 136

APPENDIX B: ADDITIONAL TABLES 138

B2.1. METHODOLOGICAL CHARACTERISTICS OF THE ARTICLES INCLUDED IN THE META -

ANALYSIS 138

B2.2. PUBLICATION SOURCES OF THE STUDIES INCLUDED IN THIS META -ANALYSIS 141

B3.1. LISREL RESULTS FOR THE SYSTEMS -BIASES -RISK -TAKING MEDIATION

(STANDARDIZED SOLUTION) 142 iv APPENDIX C: FORMULAS 143

C2.1. FORMULAS FOR VARIANCES CALCULATIONS 143

SHORT SUMMARY 145

ABOUT THE AUTHOR 149

ECIS DISSERTATION SERIES 151

v

Acknowledgments

The author would like to thank the alphabet for the letters it kindly provided.

This year is very special for me since I happen to experience a double birth: that of my daughter and that of this thesis. Both of them can be seen as long-term projects characterized by high risk and uncertainty. Despite some similarities, one of the most important lessons I learned during the PhD is to never treat your work as your own child – otherwise you can never improve on it. I owe this and many other lessons to my supervisors. There have been a total of four of them in different phases of my PhD and it has been an honor of working with them all. My first first promoter, Joop Halman; I am looking back with great pleasure at the beginning of my PhD. You sparked my interest in science and I am grateful for your enthusiasm and insightful comments. My second first promoter, Mathieu Weggeman; thank you for reminding me of the importance of the practitioners view on scientific research. Your feedback allowed me to take an "outside view" on my work. My second promoter, Michael Song; thank you for giving me the freedom to choose the research paths I was interested in and for making sure that they were scientifically sound. Each discussion of our papers is a challenge I immensely enjoy – they are always unpredictable and stimulating. My daily supervisor, Hans van der Bij; I am truly thankful for your tremendous support and for sharing your knowledge with me. You helped me dare to make my own decisions, not the decisions that ought to be mine. Thank you for being always open for the crazy ideas I could come with and even accepting them so now and then. vi I am grateful to Aard Groen, Joop Halman, Rob Verbakel, Leo Verhoef en Mathieu Weggeman for helping me find "de proefkonijnen" for my case-studies and pre-tests of the two surveys. I am similarly indebted to the nearly 30 entrepreneurs who agreed to share their inspiring stories and answered my numerous questions. My gratitude to the PhD commission for this dissertation; Anthony Di Benedetto, Geert Duijsters and Mark Parry, thank you for evaluating this thesis and for your understanding when I had to move its defense date due to the problems in my pregnancy. I owe a lot of warm memories to the company of our PhD students: Ad, Bonnie, Deborah, Elise, Jeroen, Maurice, Michael, Michiel, Mirjam, Rebekka, Stephan and Vareska. I am thankful to the rest of our OSM colleagues who both helped me improve my Dutch during the lunch hours and helped me out scientifically whenever I needed their advice. The secretary room has been a social center of our group all the time, and it could not be possible without Bianca, Marion and Marjan. Julius Caesar, famous for his multitasking, would be jealous of your abilities to combine things! I am endlessly grateful to my parents for raising me who I am, for tinkling my curiosity and for being there whenever I needed their advice. Your warm words and (sometimes not so polite) questions helped me through the most difficult times in my PhD. Dearest Vladimir, the more I know you, the more I treasure our relationship. Thank you for your patience and your support back home! Even more, thank you for not throwing away my laptop in the busiest times of my PhD!

Introduction  11

Chapter 1

General introduction

Despite all the controversy about what entrepreneurship is about and who an entrepreneur precisely is (Shane and Venkataraman, 2000), one aspect that consistently comes back in the debates is risk-taking. Taking risk is one of the core functions of an entrepreneur (e.g. Knight, 1921). In our exploratory in-depth interviews with entrepreneurs we came across different risks ranging from "not having focus", "not having a proper image" to " in the laboratory" and "an essential staff member leaves the firm". No matter how the various risk factors are framed, it all tends to come back to the survival and prosperity of the firm: i.e. to finances. Although entrepreneurship is the driving force behind new job creation (Shane, 2003), not all the new entrepreneurial firms become new Microsoft's or Dell's. The majority will bleed to death: depending on the industry, only 37-54% of new firms survive the first year (Timmons and Spinelli, 2004). The risks seem to be huge – so how can entrepreneurs improve their risk-taking? Despite its importance, the risk theme has been under-researched in the entrepreneurship literature. One of the reasons may be the influential study of Brockhaus (1980) that found no differences in risk-taking of entrepreneurs as opposed to managers in traditional organizations. However, the recent meta-analyses of Stewart and Roth (2001, 2004) found that there is still a significant difference, no matter what measures are being used, although these measures do influence the magnitude of the effect.

12  Introduction Probably the most serious problem in studying risk is still of theoretical nature. Risk is a concept that can be applied to almost any field and any theory. It is so broad that it can easily become too limited. Each theory may have its own risks (e.g. Johnson and Van de Ven, 2002). Therefore, bringing all the possible risks under the same umbrella would mean creating a "theory soup". A clear theoretical lens should be used for risk studies. The empirical part of the research on risk also has a number of pitfalls. The term "risk" has a strong negative connotation, a consequence of which is that data about risks are hard to get from the entrepreneurs. As we have observed in our exploratory case studies, entrepreneurs are reluctant to reveal information on risks, which may also explain why there are so few studies explicitly studying risks. A particular risk can be framed both in positive and negative terms. Therefore, in the studies of risk diagnostics researchers are advised to frame the risk statements positively in order not to evoke defensive behavior from the respondents (Keizer, Halman and Song, 2002). We tried to avoid these pitfalls and intend to contribute to the entrepreneurship field by answering the following three-fold main research question: (1) What kinds of risks do entrepreneurs take? (2) How do they take the risks? (3) What kinds of strategies do they use to manage the risks? We answer these research questions in three core chapters of this dissertation: chapter two, three and four respectively. We answer the two "what" questions at the firm level and the "how" question at the individual level.

1.1 Meta-analysis of success factors

"Luck is one of the key factors in entrepreneurial success." Fern Mandelbaum (Monitor Venture Partners)

"My idea of risk and reward is for me to get the reward and others to take the risks." An unknown entrepreneur

We started this research by asking ourselves: what kinds of risks do entrepreneurs take? However, due to the lack of studies researching entrepreneurial risks directly, we decided to focus on the positive side and consider risks as the opposite of success factors: i.e. if a given factor is truly a success factor, then not possessing it would mean a risk for an entrepreneurial firm. The higher the effect of a given factor on performance, the more severe it becomes for a new technology venture not to possess this factor.

Introduction  13 In order to answer this question, we conducted a meta-analysis. A meta-analysis is a method to review and integrate existing research on a given topic (Hunter and Schmidt, 1990). One aspect that clearly differentiates it from narrative reviews is its quantitative character. Unlike primary research, in a meta-analysis the data analyzed consist of the findings from previous empirical studies (Camisón-Zornoza et al., 2004). Just as empirical research requires the use of statistical techniques to analyze its data, meta-analysis applies statistical procedures that are specifically designed to integrate the results of a set of primary empirical studies. This allows meta-analysis to pool all the existing literature on a given topic, not only the most influential and best-known studies (Stewart and Roth, 2001, 2004). At the same time, meta-analysis compensates for quality differences by correcting for different artifacts and sample sizes (Hunter and Schmidt, 1990, 2004). In this meta-analysis we subdivide the main research question into a set of these lower-level research questions:

• What are the success factors for new technology ventures? • Is the literature consistent on their estimates of these factors? • In cases when the literature is not consistent, what are the potential methodological moderators for these factors?

For our meta-analysis, we used the methodology developed by Hunter and Schmidt (1990, 2004). We searched for studies on new technology ventures performance in ABI- INFORM and on the internet using the following keywords: “new,” “adolescent,” “young,” and “emergent“ to define the “new” axis; "technology", "high-tech", “technology-intensive,” and “technology-based” to describe the technology domain; and “firm,” “venture,” and “start- up” to define the entity. We examined past research studies where the majority of the sample represented such “new” “technology” ventures. In general, the primary studies set the maximum age for new technology ventures at 15 years, yet most primary studies selected cut- off values of 6 and 8 years. The last selection criterion was publication of a correlation matrix with a performance measure, because correlation matrices serve as the main input for the meta-analysis. One of our conclusions from the meta-analysis is that there is a lack of entrepreneurship studies bridging the strategic management and the deeper cognitive mechanisms of entrepreneurial decision making. As Busenitz and Barney (1997) argued, if certain individuals are cognitively biased in different ways, they may make strategic decisions

14  Introduction in different ways. Past research shows that besides susceptibility to cognitive biases, entrepreneurs differ cognitively from managers in more traditional firms on a number of dimensions, including risk-taking propensity and reliance on intuition (Busenitz and Barney, 1997; Stewart and Roth, 2004). Thus, such cognitive mechanisms may represent sources of competitive advantage or disadvantage of the firms (Barney, 1991). We intend to explore the aforementioned gap on two levels: we look at the individual level how entrepreneurial risk- taking propensity is formed and then we explore at the firm level the performance consequences of various risk and uncertainty management strategies new technology ventures pursue.

1.2 The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking

''There is a fine line between confidence and arrogance. […] You have to have confidence in order to take risks, because too many people are knocking you down and if you do not have confidence, you are not going to keep going. But then at some point, you have success and that confidence changes to arrogance. That's where it really gets dangerous. Arrogance indicates that you are not listening to customers, employees and the market. So it is a fine line and you have to stay on the good side!" Judy Estrin (Packet Design)

"The younger the company, the more opportunity to take risks you have. Big companies do not take risks. This is the advantage you have when you start a new company. Propensity to take risks is what really differentiates an entrepreneur from a manager in a big company." Randy Adams, serial entrepreneur (AuctionDrop)

In venture-related decisions, entrepreneurs have to cope on a daily basis with ill- structured, uncertain sets of possibilities, while having the ultimate responsibility for each decision (Knight, 1921; Stewart and Roth, 2001). There are a number of risks associated with this kind of decisions and the question is: How do entrepreneurs take these risks? What is the more precise mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking? Entrepreneurship literature provides two alternative answers about how entrepreneurs take these risks. One explanation is that entrepreneurs objectively tolerate more risks, that they are risk-seeking and that they consciously take the risks (Stewart and Roth, 2001; 2004). A competing, cognitive explanation is that in their intuitive decision-making, entrepreneurs are unconscious (or at least not fully conscious) of the actual risks associated with their decisions; they simply do not see them all due to the cognitive biases (Simon, Houghton and

Introduction  15 Aquino, 2000). These biases are in fact errors in decision-making arising from the use of heuristics. How can these two be brought closer to each other? Dual process theory provides an answer. By now the entrepreneurship literature (e.g. Covin, Slevin, and Heeley, 2001; Simon, Houghton, and Savelli, 2003) focused on intuition as the opposite side of being rational. Entrepreneurs are seen as predominantly intuitive decision-makers. However, according to the dual process theory, people can be intuitive and rational at the same time (Epstein, Pacini, Denes-Raj, and Heier, 1996; Pacini and Epstein, 1999). This theory postulates that all judgments and behavior of people are a joint output of both intuitive and rational thinking (Epstein et al., 1996). The rational thinking monitors and eventually corrects outputs of intuitive thinking (including the heuristics and biases). It provides an answer itself if no intuitive judgment is available (Epstein et al., 1996; Stanovich and West, 2000). Recent theoretical developments suggest that at least some of the cognitive biases studied until now can be actually conceptualized as biases of human intuition (Kahneman, 2003). Thus, while risk-seeking perspective can be related to the rational dimension in the dual process theory, the cognitive perspective can be related to the intuitive dimension in the dual process theory. In this individual-level study, we subdivide the main research question into a set of lower-level research questions: we concentrate on how intuitive thinking, rational thinking, heuristics and biases form entrepreneurial risk-taking:

• To what extent can the cognitive biases studied until now be called "intuitive", i.e. deriving from the intuition? • To what extent can rational thinking (i.e. without any special training) correct the entrepreneurial cognitive biases and improve entrepreneurial decision-making? • Do the intuitive and rational thinking also directly influence the entrepreneurial risk-taking? • To what extent do cognitive biases influence entrepreneurial risk-taking propensity?

We integrate these two perspectives in a model where heuristics and biases mediate the relationship between the intuitive and rational thinking and entrepreneurial risk-taking propensity. We answer our research questions by testing the conceptual model using SEM with Maximum Likelihood (ML) estimator on a sample of 289 entrepreneurs from the US.

16  Introduction 1.3 Risk and uncertainty management strategies

"There are many kinds of risk that you have when starting a company: there's technical risk, market risk, financing risk and many other kinds of risks you can learn in a business school. The trick is to take the risk out as early as possible. And take as few risks as possible." Jerry Kaplan, entrepreneur (Winster)

"There are risks and costs to a program of action, but they are far less than the long- range risks and costs of comfortable inaction." John F. Kennedy, president of USA

This chapter is dedicated to the risk and uncertainty management strategies new technology ventures may pursue. We distinguish two major types of risk and uncertainty management strategies: the traditional risk management (Miller, 1992) and the recently emerged real options reasoning (McGrath, 1999; McGrath, Ferrier and Mendelow, 2004). Both types of strategies concern the mitigation of risk and management of uncertainty. An example of the differences between them is that traditional risk management strategies typically target immediate risk reduction, whereas real options strategy delays the full commitment decision and provides flexibility for future decisions. In Chapter 4, we further elaborate on the differences between traditional risk management strategies and real options strategy using the dimensions identified by Bowman and Hurry (1993), namely risk, uncertainty, size and timing of investments. Despite the integrative review (Miller, 1992), the traditional risk management strategies were hardly ever compared empirically. Recent developments in the real options theory refined the concept of real options strategy, providing the basis for thorough empirical tests (McGrath et al., 2004). However, real options has also received certain critique raising doubts about the value and distinctiveness of this strategy (Adner and Levinthal, 2004a,b; Miller and Arikan, 2004). In this study, we aim to tackle these issues by developing a scale to measure the real options strategy directly and comparing its performance consequences with those of the traditional risk management strategies. We also examine how market and opportunity characteristics influence the preference of entrepreneurial ventures for each type of strategic risk management strategy. We consider the effects of established versus emerging technology standards as well as effects of markets with high versus low network externalities.

Introduction  17 In this firm-level study, we subdivide the main research question into two lower-level research questions:

• What are the performance consequences of the risk and uncertainty management strategies? • How is the effect of these strategies influenced by market and technology characteristics?

We test our conceptual model by OLS regressions for three different performance measures: return on investment, customer retention rate and sales growth rate. For this test, we use the data from 420 new technology ventures from USA.

Meta-analysis of success factors  19

Chapter 2

Meta-analysis of success factors

New technology ventures have the lowest survival rate among all the new ventures (Timmons and Spinelli, 2004). To get a more integrated picture of what factors lead to the success or failure of new technology ventures, we conducted a meta-analysis to examine the success factors in new technology ventures. We culled the academic literature to collect data from existing empirical studies and conducted a meta-analysis. We identified 24 most-widely researched success factors for new technology ventures. Among these 24 factors, 8 are consistently estimated as significant success factors for new technology ventures (i.e., they are homogeneous positive significant meta-factors that are correlated to venture performance). They are supply chain integration, market scope, firm age, size of founding team, financial resources, founders’ marketing experience, founders’ industry experience, and existence of patent protection. Of the original 24 success factors, 5 were not significant: the success of technology ventures are not correlated with founders’ R&D experience, founders’ experience with start-ups, environmental dynamism, environmental heterogeneity, and competition intensity. The remaining 11 success factors are heterogeneous. For those heterogeneous success factors, we conducted a moderator analysis. Of this set, 3 appeared to be success factors and 2 were failure factors for subgroups within the new technology ventures’ population. To facilitate the development of a body of knowledge in technology entrepreneurship, this study also identifies high-quality measurement scales for future research. We conclude the article with future research directions.

20  The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking 2.1 Introduction

Technology entrepreneurship is key to economic development. New technology ventures can have positive effects on employment, and can rejuvenate industries with disruptive technologies (Christensen and Bower, 1996). Unfortunately, the survival rate of new technology ventures is the lowest among new ventures in general. In our most recent empirical study of 11,259 new technology ventures established between 1991 and 2000 in the United States, we found that after four years only 36 percent, or 4,062 companies with more than five full-time employees, had survived. After five years, the survival rate fell to 21.9 percent, leaving only 2,471 firms with more than five full-time employees still in operation. Given this high rate of failure, it is important to identify what factors lead to the success and failure of new technology ventures. Current academic literature, however, does not offer much insight. Numerous studies focus on success factors for new technology ventures, but the empirical results are often controversial and fragmented. For example, the data on R&D investments alone yield ambivalent conclusions. While Zahra and Bogner (2000) found no significant relationship between R&D expenses and new technology venture performance, Bloodgood, Sapienza, and Almeida (1996) found a negative relationship and Dowling and McGee (1994) found a positive relationship between R&D investments and new technology venture performance. Similarly, although new technology ventures often develop knowledge-intensive products and services (OECD, 1997), the research results on product innovativeness have been ambiguous. More than two-thirds of the empirical studies have found a positive relationship between product innovation and firm performance, while the remaining studies have found a negative relationship or none at all (Capon, Farley, and Hoenig, 1990; Li and Atuahene-Gima, 2001). Li and Atuahene-Gima (2001) addressed this problem by introducing contingencies into their regression models and indeed found three moderators. The inconsistent and often contradictory results can stem from methodological problems, different study design, different measurements, omitted variables in the regression models, and noncomparable samples. More than on any one methodology, entrepreneurship theory hinges on its setting (new firms) as its common denominator. Because of that, numerous theoretical streams run through the scholarship (Shane and Venkataraman, 2000). To help resolve this problem, we looked for a method that would operate independently of model composition. Meta-analysis provides a solution (Hunter and Schmidt, 1990, 2004) and

Meta-analysis of success factors  21 a lens through which we can evaluate the success factors that contribute to new technology ventures’ performance. We based our meta-analysis on studies that explicitly focus on antecedents of new technology venture performance. This chapter attempts to make several contributions to technology entrepreneurship literature: (1) our integrated quantitative evaluation of the success factors of new technology ventures provides one step toward developing a theoretical foundation for technology entrepreneurship, (2) it identifies universal success factors, (3) it identifies success factors that are controversial and, by moderator analysis, offers some tentative reasons for those controversies, (4) it reports existing high-quality scales that are important for new technology venture performance, and (5) it proposes and provides a new theoretical framework for studying success factors of technology ventures and a road map for future research in technology entrepreneurship. This chapter is organized in the following manner. First, we explain our methodology. We then present the results of our research, including the results of the meta-analysis, examples of high-quality scales, and the discussion of future research directions. We conclude the chapter with a description of its limitations and some final remarks.

2.2 Data collection and methodology

Meta-analysis is a statistical research integration technique (Hunter and Schmidt, 1990). One aspect that clearly differentiates it from narrative reviews is its quantitative character. Unlike primary research, in a meta-analysis the data analyzed consist of the findings from previous empirical studies (Camisón-Zornoza et al., 2004). Just as empirical research requires the use of statistical techniques to analyze its data, meta-analysis applies statistical procedures that are specifically designed to integrate the results of a set of primary empirical studies. This allows meta-analysis to pool all the existing literature on a given topic, not only the most influential and best-known studies (Stewart and Roth, 2001, 2004). At the same time, meta-analysis compensates for quality differences by correcting for different artifacts and sample sizes (Hunter and Schmidt, 1990, 2004). There are two main types of meta-analytic studies in the literature. The first focuses on a relationship between two variables or a change in one variable across different groups of respondents. In general, this type of meta-analysis is strongly guided by one or two theories

22  The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking (e.g., Palich, Cardinal, and Miller, 2000; Stewart and Roth, 2001, 2004). The second type of meta-analytic studies examines a large number of meta-factors related to one particular focal construct, such as performance. Such meta-analyses aim to integrate all the existing research on that focal construct and are largely atheoretical because the research they combine rests on heterogeneous theoretical grounds (e.g., Gerwin and Barrowman, 2002; Montoya-Weiss and Calantone, 1994). Because the current literature teems with numerous theoretical streams where only the setting (new firms) is the common denominator (Shane and Venkataraman, 2000), we chose the second type of meta-analysis to study the potential success meta-factors of new technology venture performance. We selected independent ventures and collected studies that explicitly focused on antecedents of new technology ventures’ performance. In our study, we explore—rather than define ourselves—what “new technology venture” means in the literature. Primary studies use such terms as “new,” “adolescent,” “young,” or “emergent“ to define the “new” axis; and “high technology,” “technology- intensive,” and “technology-based” to describe the technology domain. We examined past research studies where the majority of the sample represented such “new” “technology” ventures. In general, the primary studies set the maximum age for new technology ventures at 15 years, yet most primary studies selected cut-off values of 6 and 8 years. Another important selection criterion was the publication of the correlation matrix in the paper, because the correlation matrices serve as the main input for the meta-analysis. All the collected studies investigated surviving new technology ventures; consequently, we do not consider failures in our meta-analysis. Meta-analysis allows the comparison of different empirical studies with similar characteristics, and thus lets researchers integrate the results. To conduct a meta-analysis it is important to select studies as input for the analysis and follow a meta-analytical protocol to arrive at those results.

2.2.1 Selection of studies as input for the analysis First, we combed the literature for research that discussed the success factors of new technology ventures, using the ABI-INFORM system and the Internet. We used keywords— “new,” “adolescent,” “young,” “emerging” and “high-tech,” “technology,” “technology- intensive,” “technology-based”—to limit our sample’s age and domain. Finally, to assess the type of firm, we applied the keywords “firm,” “venture,” and “start-up.” We intentionally did

Meta-analysis of success factors  23 not limit the studies to those recognized as the best in the field, as usually done in a narrative review: this would have betrayed the spirit of meta-analysis (Hunter and Schmidt, 1990). Instead, we collected as much research as possible, corrected later for any quality differences and controlled for missing studies. After we gathered papers from ABI-INFORM and the Internet, we added cross- referenced studies from them. In total, we collected 106 studies that met our search criteria. Next, we ensured that the articles on our list (1) represented the correct level of analysis, (2) significantly reflected new technology ventures, and (3) reported a correlation matrix with at least one antecedent of performance and one performance measure. This procedure reduced the number of appropriate research studies to 31 due to the absence of correlation matrices. Appendix B2.1 details our study sample by countries of origin, industries, performance measures, the minimum and maximum ages of the ventures, and their sample sizes. In addition, we provide two other features. First, “sample type” indicates the particular characteristics of the sample. This may be new technology ventures that went through initial public offering (IPO), ventures funded by venture capitalists (VC), ventures from a general database, ventures involved in a governmental support program, ventures that have activity abroad, or combinations of these types. Second, “venture origin” indicates whether the venture was actually independent. Although our meta-analysis focused primarily on independent ventures, it also included mixed samples of independent and corporate ventures, where most were independent, and samples where the type of venture was not specified. Appendix B2.2 lists the journals from which the 31 papers originate. When coding the studies, we took care to refer to the scales reported in the primary studies, so that dissimilar elements would not be combined inappropriately, and conceptually similar variables would not be coded separately, to compensate for the slightly different labels that authors use to refer to similar constructs (Henard and Szymanski, 2001).

2.2.2 Protocol for meta-analysis We used Hunter and Schmidt’s protocol (1990) for our meta-analysis. Our most important consideration was to the ability to make comparisons across research studies. To do this, we could draw on Pearson correlations between a meta-factor and the dependent variable or the regression coefficient between the meta-factor and the dependent variable. Because regression coefficients depend on the particular variables included into the model and because

24  The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking the models vary across studies, we followed the suggestions of Hunter and Schmidt (1990). Hunter and Schmidt strongly encourage using Pearson correlations as the input, because correlations between two variables are independent of the other variables in the model (Hunter and Schmidt 1990). Other meta-analytic studies have made this choice, including Gerwin and Barrowman (2002) and Montoya-Weiss and Calantone (1994). Another advantage of Hunter and Schmidt’s method (1990) is their use of random effects models instead of fixed effects models (Hunter and Schmidt, 2004; p.201). The distinction is as follows: fixed effects models assume that exactly the same “true” correlation value between meta-factor and dependent variable underlies all studies in the meta-analysis, while random effects models allow for the possibility that population parameters vary from study to study. Given the differences in how new technology ventures were defined in the selected primary studies, the choice for random effects models was appropriate. Following the procedure of Hunter and Schmidt (1990), our second step was to correct meta-factors for dichotomization, sample size differences, and measurement errors. 1) To correct dichotomized meta-factors: we made a conservative correction by dividing the observed correlation coefficient of the sample by 0.8, because dichotomization reduces the real correlation coefficient by at least 0.8 (Hunter and Schmidt, 1990, 2004). Individual correction of observed correlatio ns for dichotomiz ation :

roo i ro = , i ad where :

ad : correction for dichotomiz ation;

ad = 0.8 if variable is dichotimiz ed and ad = 1 if it is not;

roo i : observed correlatio n of the primary study i.

2) To correct sampling error: we weighted the sample correlation by sample size (Hunter and Schmidt, 1990, 2004).

Weighted average of correlatio ns individual ly corrected for dichotomiz ation : n i o ∑N r i i=1 ro = n , ∑ Ni i=1 where Ni : sample size of the primary study i.

Meta-analysis of success factors  25 3) To remedy measurement errors: we used Cronbach’s alphas. We divided the correlation coefficient by the product of the square root of the reliability of the meta-factor and the square root of the reliability of performance. Since reliabilities were not always reported, we reconstructed them by using the reliability distribution (Hunter and Schmidt, 1990, 2004). Real population correlatio :n r r ρ = o = o , A Rxx * Ryy where : A: compound attentuati on factor;

Rxx : average of the square roots of reliabilit ies of indepedent variables composing a given meta - factor;

Ryy : average of the square roots of reliabilit ies of depedent v ariables composing a given meta - factor.

The third step in the meta-analysis protocol was to determine whether a meta-factor was a success factor. To accomplish this, we assessed three conditions. First, the studies should have, in essence, the same correlation. Other meta-analysis procedures often use a Chi- square test to reveal this homogeneity. However, Hunter and Schmidt (1990, 2004) argue against it and state that this test will have a bias because of uncorrected artifacts. They suggest a variance-based test. The total variance in the correlation coefficient has three sources: variance due to artifacts (dichotomization and measurement errors), variance due to sampling error, and real variance due to heterogeneity of the meta-factor. The meta-factor is assumed to be homogeneous, if the real variance is no more than 25 percent of the total variance. According to Hunter and Schmidt (1990, 2004), in that case unknown and uncorrected artifacts account for these 25 percent, so that the real variance is actually close to zero. We describe the used formulas in Appendix C2.1. For homogeneous meta-factors, we applied two significance tests. First, we determined whether the whole confidence interval (based on the real standard deviation) was above zero. Second, if it was above zero, we calculated the p-value for the real correlation to estimate the degree of significance. Both of these significance tests are necessary, because the p-value is misleading when part of the confidence interval of the real correlation is below zero. Only when all three conditions held did we consider a given meta-factor to be a success meta-factor for new technology ventures.

26  The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking For those heterogeneous meta-factors, we conducted a moderator analysis. We divided the data into subgroups according to various methodological characteristics (see Appendix B2.1). Then, we conducted a separate meta-analysis for each subgroup, hoping to find homogeneous meta-factors in the subgroup in two steps. First, we conducted moderator analysis to deal with different performance measures. Second, we checked whether country, industry, sample type, venture origin, or maximum age of the new technology ventures in the sample were possible moderators. Second, we conducted moderator analysis for different meta-factor measures. Finally, we reviewed the “file drawer” in an attempt to assess any publication bias. Because there is a general tendency to publish only significant results, insignificant results are often abandoned in researchers’ file drawers (Hunter and Schmidt, 1990; Rosenthal, 1991).

This “file drawer” technique provides a number, X S, indicating the number of null-result studies that when added, would make the total significance of a meta-factor exceed the critical level of 0.05. Thus, the higher the value of X S, the more stable and reliable the results are. If

XS, is 0, it indicates that the meta-factors are already insignificant according to the p-value criterion.

2.3 Analysis and results

2.3.1 Success factors of technology ventures Our meta-analysis revealed 24 meta-factors related to the performance of new technology ventures. We present the definitions of these meta-factors in Table 2.1.

Meta-analysis of success factors  27 Table 2.1. Definitions of the 24 meta-factors Meta-factors Definitions Selected references Market and opportunity 1. Competition intensity Strength of inter-firm competition within an industry Chamanski and Waagø, 2001 2. Environmental dynamism High pace of changes in the firm's external environment Zahra and Bogner, 2000 3. Environmental heterogeneity Perceived diversity and complexity of the firm's external environment Zahra and Bogner, 2000 4. Internationalization Extent to which a firm is involved in cross-border activities Bloodgood et al., 1996 5. Low cost strategy Extent to which a firm uses cost advantages as a source of competitive Bloodgood et al., 1996 advantage 6. Market growth rate Extent to which average firm sales in the industry increase Bloodgood et al., 1996; Lee et al., 2001 7. Market scope Variety in customers and customer segments, their geographic range, Li, 2001; Marino and De Noble, 1997 and the number of products 8. Marketing intensity* Extent to which a firm is pursuing a strategy based on unique Li, 2001 marketing efforts 9. Product innovation* Degree to which new ventures develop and introduce new products Li, 2001 and/ or services Entrepreneurial team 10. Industry experience Experience of the firm's management team in related industries and Marino and De Noble, 1997 markets 11. Marketing experience Experience of the firm's management team in marketing McGee et al., 1995; Marino and De Noble, 1997 12. Prior start-up experience Experience of the firm's management team in previous startup Marino and De Noble, 1997 situations 13. R&D experience Experience of the firm's management team in R&D McGee et al., 1995; Marino and De Noble, 1997

28  The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking Table 2.1 (continued). Definitions of the 24 meta-factors

Meta-factors Definitions Selected references Resources

14. Financial resources Level of financial assets of the firm Robinson and McDougall, 2001 15. Firm age Number of years a firm has been in existence Zahra et al., 2001 16. Firm size Number of the firm's employees Zahra et al., 2001 17. Firm type The type of a firm's ownership (corporate ventures or independent ventures) Zahra et al., 2001 18. Non-governmental financial Financial sponsorship from commercial institutes Lee et al., 2001 support 19. Patent protection Availability of firm's patents protecting product or process technology Marino and De Noble, 1997 20. R&D alliances The firm's use of R&D cooperative arrangements. For new technology Zahra and Bogner, 2000; McGee et al., ventures they also correspond to horizontal alliances. 1995 21. R&D investment Intensity of the firm's investment in internal R&D activities Zahra and Bogner, 2000 22. Size of founding team Size of the management team of the firm Chamanski and Waagø, 2001 23. Supply chain integration A firm’s cooperation across different levels of the value-added chain, for George et al., 2001; George et al., example suppliers, distribution channel agents, and/or customers 2002; McDougall et al., 1994 24. University partnerships The firm's use of cooperative arrangement with universities Zahra and Bogner, 2000; Chamanski and Waagø, 2001 * - these two factors are called marketing differentiation and product differentiation in the stream of research stemming from the work of Porter (1980)

Meta-analysis of success factors  29 Table 2.2 reports the meta-analytic results on the antecedents, or the success meta- factors of new technology ventures’ performance. To be concise and limit the sensitivity of the results to studies not included in our meta-analysis, Table 2.2 presents only the meta- factors found in three or more research studies. The table presents ρ, an estimate of the real population correlation; total N, the aggregate sample size; and K, the number of correlations that build a given meta-factor. Both N and K are conservative: we counted each study only once. Ninety-five (95) percent confidence interval is the spread of the real correlation variance. XS is the critical number of null-results studies. To make the analysis of the meta-factors more transparent and interpretable, we generate appropriate categories grounded in the literature’s existing frameworks (Chrisman, Bauerschmidt, and Hofer, 1998; Gartner, 1985; Timmons and Spinelli, 2004). These categories are: (a) Market and Opportunity, (b) the Entrepreneurial Team, and (c) Resources. After three researchers reviewed those categories for completeness and appropriateness, we conducted content analysis, a classification technique that assigns variables to a particular category. Two researchers independently assigned each variable to a category. The two researchers agreed on variables' categorizations in 91.2 percent of the cases across 306 variables. A third researcher resolved any disagreements, making the final categorization. At the same time, variables were combined to form meta-factors. Reflecting the primary studies, the Market and Opportunity category typically described either the market characteristics, such as environmental dynamism, environmental heterogeneity, and competitive strategies based on Porter’s (1980) typology. The Entrepreneurial Team category included characteristics of the new technology venture team, including experience and capabilities, both as individuals and as a team. The Resources category united a broad scope of factors, comprising resources, capabilities, and characteristics of the new technology ventures as firms. Such resources included financial resources, firm size, patents, and university partnerships. The meta-factors were unevenly distributed across the three categories. The majority fell into the Resources category; the smallest number, into the Entrepreneurial Team category. The Resources category consisted of heterogeneous meta-factors for 55 percent and the Market and Opportunity category for 56 Percent. Only the Entrepreneurial Team category was completely homogeneous.

30  The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking

Table 2.2. Results of the meta-analysis 95 % Explained Total Mode- Meta-Factor K ρρρ Confidence Variance Xs N a rators Interval MARKET and OPPORTUNITY 1 Competition intensity 634 7 0.01 100% 0 2 Environmental dynamism 637 5 0.05 100% 0 3 Environmental heterogeneity 287 3 0.10 100% 0 4 Internationalization 523 7 0.08 (*) (-0.21,0.37) 38% Yes 6 5 Low cost strategy 286 4 0.18 (**) (-0.13,0.49) 70% Yes 10 6 Market growth rate 505 4 0.23 (***) (-0.26,0.72) 16% Yes 12 7 Market scope 1046 10 0.21 *** 100% 78 8 Marketing intensity 622 6 0.42 (***) (-0.19,1.00) 23% Yes 64 9 Product innovation 702 8 0.04 (-0.48,0.56) 55% Yes b 0 ENTREPRENEURIAL TEAM 10 Industry experience 423 4 0.11 * 100% 2 11 Marketing experience 381 3 0.11 * 100% 2 12 Prior start-up experience 114 3 0.00 100% 0 13 R&D experience 329 3 0.09 100% 0 RESOURCES 14 Financial resources 638 6 0.12 ** 100% 14 15 Firm age 1890 15 0.16 *** (0.08,0.23) 87% 157 16 Firm size 1360 11 0.26 (***) (-0.31,0.83) 10% Yes 197 17 Firm type 715 4 0.09 (-0.15,0.33) 31% Yes b 0 Non-governmental 18 405 4 0.20 (***) (-0.15,0.55) 31% Yes 16 financial support 19 Patent protection 453 5 0.11 * 100% 1 20 R&D alliances 571 5 0.03 (-0.52,0.58) 31% Yes b 0 21 R&D investments 863 9 0.05 (*) (-0.49,0.60) 19% Yes 3 22 Size of founding team 332 5 0.13 ** 100% 6 23 Supply chain integration 604 6 0.23 *** (0.12,0.35) 89% 41 24 University partnerships 330 3 -0.04 (-0.25,0.17) 50% Yes 0 a – explained variance lower than 75% means that the meta-factor has moderator(s) b – see Table 2.3 for suggested moderators * p < 0.05; ** p < 0.01; *** p < 0.001. 1-tailed test statistic. Direction depends on the sign of ρ p-values indicated by (*), (**) or (***) mean that the meta-factor is heterogeneous

Meta-analysis of success factors  31

Results in Table 2.2 reveal eight universal success factors (i.e., they are homogeneous positive significant meta-factors that are correlated to venture performance):

• supply chain integration ( ρ = 0.23, p<0.001) • market scope ( ρ = 0.21, p<0.001) • firm age ( ρ = 0.16, p<0.001) • size of founding team ( ρ = 0.13, p<0.01) • financial resources ( ρ = 0.12, p<0.01) • marketing experience ( ρ = 0.11, p<0.05) • industry experience ( ρ =0.11, p<0.05) • patent protection ( ρ =0.11, p<0.05)

One success factor represented Market and Opportunity, five success factors represented Resources, and two success factors were part of the Entrepreneurial Team category. Results in Table 2.2 also suggested that the following five factors have no significant effects on technology venture performance: 1) R&D experience, 2) prior start-up experience, 3) environmental dynamism, 4) environmental heterogeneity, and 5) competition intensity. Three of these meta-factors represented Market and Opportunity and two represented the Entrepreneurial Team category.

2.3.2 Moderators As Table 2.2 indicates, 11 of the 24 meta-factors had heterogeneous correlations (i.e., the importance of the factors depend on situations). Therefore, we conducted moderator or subgroup analysis for differences in performance measures, meta-factor measures, venture origin, maximum age of venture in the sample, sample type, country, and industry.

Table 2.3 presents those results from the moderator analysis, including ρ, an estimate of the real population correlation; total N, the aggregate sample size 1; K, the number of correlations that build a given meta-factor; the 95 percent confidence interval of the real variance; and X S, the critical number of null-results studies.

1 Since some studies used multiple measures of performance, sum of performance moderator subgroups sample sizes may be greater than total N of a meta-factor.

32  The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking Table 2.3 also presents the variance explained by dichotomization of meta-factors, measurement, and sampling error. This variance must be more than 75 percent to yield a homogeneous factor. In that case, the real variance is less than 25 percent of the total variance of correlations from the primary studies. The remaining variance is likely due to other unknown and uncorrected artifacts, and therefore it can be neglected (Hunter and Schmidt, 1990, 2004). To keep overview, for the moderator, or subgroup analysis, we only report the meta-factors with at least two subgroups that have no overlapping confidence intervals; each subgroup consists of at least two studies.

Table 2.3. Suggested moderators 95 % Meta- a Total Explained Moderator ρ K Confidence a X factor ρρ N Variance S Interval RESOURCES Firm type 0.09 715 4 (-0.15,0.33) 31% 0 Performance operationalization Profit based -0.01 572 3 (-0.03,0.01) 98% 0 Sales based 0.27 *** 464 2 100% 18 R&D alliances 0.03 * 571 5 (-0.52,0.58) 31% 0 Venture origin Independent ventures -0.36 *** 262 2 100% 10 Mixed origin 0.37 *** 309 3 100% 28 MARKET and OPPORTUNITY Product innovation 0.04 702 8 (-0.71,0.79) 12% 0 Venture origin Independent ventures -0.39 *** 263 3 (-0.52,-0.27) 80% 23 Mixed origin 0.44 *** 300 2 (0.23,0.65) 43% 23 a - explained variance lower than 75% means that the meta-factor has moderator(s) * p < 0.05; ** p < 0.01; *** p < 0.001. 1-tailed test statistic. Direction depends on the sign of ρ

The results reported in Table 2.3 suggest that of the 11 heterogeneous factors, 3 meta- factors (firm type, R&D alliances, and product innovation) had distinct moderator subgroups (i.e., the effect of these factors on venture performance depends on situation). The relationship between firm type and performance depended on the way performance was measured. Firm type was insignificantly related to the profits of new technology ventures, but significantly and positively related to the sales of new technology ventures. No other (methodologically oriented) moderators affected the firm type. R&D alliances were negatively associated with performance for independent ventures. However, for ventures of a mixed origin, R&D alliances were positively associated with performance.

Meta-analysis of success factors  33 Product innovation was moderated by venture origin. For independent new technology ventures, product innovation has a significantly negative association with performance. However, for samples with mixed firm type, product innovation has a significantly positive association with performance. By examining the results in Table 2.2, eight meta-factors proved inconclusive: internationalization, low-cost strategy, market growth rate, marketing intensity, R&D investments, firm size, non-governmental financial support, and university partnerships. Of these eight meta-factors, market growth rate and non-governmental financial support have only one subgroup with two or more studies when differences in meta-factor measurements are considered. We also found only one suitable subgroup for internationalization when looking at sample type, for marketing differentiation when looking at the country, and for university partnerships when either looking at the sample type or the industry. Further research is needed to validate or disprove these potential moderators. Finally, no methodological moderators were found for R&D investments, low cost strategy, and firm size.

2.4 Identification of high-quality measurement scales

Our high-quality scale is either a ratio/interval measure or a Likert-type scale with a Cronbach’s alpha of at least 0.7 (Nunnally 1978) that consists of at least three items. The last condition ensures that Likert-type scales will be reliable and that they will still hold a certain reserve for future studies in case one of the items does not load. Identification of such scales can assist the work of future researchers in the technology entrepreneurship and alert them to poor operationalization practices. Consequently, one of our study goals was to report on scales from meta-factors that were stable and reliable success factors for new technology ventures. We selected only significant homogeneous (unmoderated) meta-factors from Table 2.2 or homogeneous subgroups from Table 2.3. This selection resulted in 11 strongly supported new technology venture success factors. To ensure that individual scales would perform well in further studies, within each meta-factor, we selected only scales with an observed correlation significant at the 0.05 level. Marketing experience did not have a significant high- quality scale in the previous studies. Therefore, we report high-quality scales found for 10 new technology venture success factors in Appendix A2.1. Further research should be

34  The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking conducted on other potentially significant success factors (see moderated meta-factors from Table 2.2) before valid conclusions can be drawn.

2.5 Discussion and future research directions

In this study, we conducted a meta-analysis on antecedents of new technology ventures performance and tried to identify success factors for new technology ventures. To the best of our knowledge, this is the first systematic, quantitative effort to integrate the existing research on this topic. Our study sought to contribute to a more homogeneous theory of technology entrepreneurship. We summarize the results of our meta-analysis in Figure 2.1. In the spirit of meta-analysis, we present the results in four main blocks: significant and insignificant homogeneous factors, heterogeneous factors with moderators and heterogeneous factors without moderators. The latter two blocks are shown by the dotted lines. We also show within each block from which category a given meta-factor originates.

Meta-analysis of success factors  35

Figure 2.1. Summary of success factors in new technology ventures

36  The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking The results are compelling: eight of the 24 meta-factors remain heterogeneous even after we searched for methodological moderators. They are evenly distributed across Market and Opportunity, and Resources categories. Five of the 24 meta-factors were homogeneous, but not significant. Three of them are from Market and Opportunity, and two meta-factors are from Entrepreneurial Team category. Only eight meta-factors are homogeneous and significant, suggesting that they are the only universal success factors for the performance of new technology ventures. The majority of them belong to the Resources group. Two meta- factors are success factors for sub-groups in the population of new technology ventures and one works only for sales and not for profit-based performance. Therefore, more research is necessary on the heterogeneous, moderated meta-factors listed in Table 2.2. While we have identified some moderators in Table 2.3, future research should also explicitly test the effects of these moderators. To help build the body of the knowledge in technology entrepreneurship, we have also identified high-quality scales of the success factors and presented the measurement scales in Appendix A2.1.

2.5.1 Market and opportunity Nine success factors represented the market and opportunity category in our meta- analysis. One was homogeneous and significant, five were heterogeneous, and the other three were insignificant. Therefore, we can conclude that based on extant research only one general factor, market scope, clearly enhances new technology venture performance. Moreover, we found only one success factor within the moderator subgroups. Product innovation improves new technology venture performance of corporate ventures, but it is detrimental for independent new technology ventures. A radical innovation strategy may be too risky for independent ventures, while corporate ventures can share risks with their parent companies. Examining the number of heterogeneous meta-factors, one might conclude that the new technology venture population is generally too heterogeneous to examine the success factors. This idea was supported by the fact that for a number of meta-factors, no methodological moderators were found, suggesting that there may be other moderators that have not been reported in published research studies. As a follow-up of this research, we conducted 16 case studies of new technology ventures. We found a striking difference in the strategies used by these entrepreneurs dependent on their background—technical or business. In the first scenario, the entrepreneurs were usually the inventors of the venture technology

Meta-analysis of success factors  37 and focused on it rather than on its market. In the second scenario, entrepreneurs paid close attention to financials and the product market, while their ventures could do little or even no R&D, and yet these new technology ventures still produced high-technology products by following a sort of “me too“ strategy. Thus, the background of entrepreneurs leading to different involvement in the technological development of the products may be a missing moderator. Another worthy direction for future studies is further contingency research. Until now, scholars in technology entrepreneurship have focused on product differentiation strategy and its interaction with different environmental characteristics, such as competition intensity and environmental dynamism (Li, 2001; Li and Atuahene-Gima, 2001; Zahra and Bogner, 2000). Other competitive strategies have received considerably less attention in studies of environmental contingencies. Existing meta-factors describe opportunity in a rather indirect way. Thus, another possible direction of future research could focus more closely on opportunity, the key concept of entrepreneurship (Shane and Venkataraman, 2000). For example, opportunity sources vary in the amount of uncertainty and thus have different degrees of success predictability (Drucker, 1985; Eckhardt and Shane, 2003). Future researchers may want to consider a greater range of opportunity dimensions. The question of how to measure an opportunity remains open. In general, the technology entrepreneurship research does not address the multiple dimensions of the entrepreneurial opportunity concept and generally overlooks the interaction effects of the strategies followed by new technology ventures, opening these two themes to future researchers.

2.5.2 Entrepreneurial team In our study, four types of experience described the characteristics of the Entrepreneurial Team: marketing, R&D, industry, and prior start-up experience. Only experiences in marketing and industry were significant, suggesting that acquiring more experience in these areas may lead to higher new technology venture performance. However, both prior start-up experience and R&D experience were insignificant at the 0.05 level. The former finding may be further evidence of overestimation of the role of prior start-up experience, ironically one of the most profound venture capitalist evaluation criteria (Baum and Silverman, 2004). It should be noted that the latter finding might have been caused by

38  The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking lack of variance in the samples of new technology ventures, since new technology ventures are often defined by having a certain amount of R&D expenses. Two ways present themselves as means for resolving the weak results of the Entrepreneurial Team factors. First, these findings may be due to the tendency to limit experience to the number of years the founder(s) spent in a certain area, without measuring the quality, variety, and complementarity of both joint and individual experiences (Eisenhardt and Schoonhoven, 1990; Lazear, 2004). Moreover, certain aspects of the Entrepreneurial Team have been overlooked in the literature on new technology ventures. In particular, researchers have identified a variety of cognitive characteristics that make entrepreneurs distinctive, such as psychological traits (Gartner, 1985; Stewart and Roth, 2004), cognitive biases, and thinking styles (Baron, 1998, 2004). An alternative explanation applicable to all these meta-factors is that their influence manifests itself through a more subtle, indirect mechanism. Researchers have concentrated their efforts on direct links between personality characteristics of entrepreneurs and the performance of new technology ventures. However, recent research has found support for their indirect influence on the performance of ventures (Baum, Locke, and Kirkpatrick, 1998); for example, human capital factors influence performance by directing the competitive strategies entrepreneurs choose (Baum, Locke, and Smith, 2001) or channeling the opportunities they recognize (Shane, 2000). Future research should investigate these alternative explanations.

2.5.3 Resources More than half of the identified success factors in our meta-analysis were in the Resource category. Although a significant amount of research has been conducted within this category, results have not been conclusive. We found five success factors within this category: supply chain integration, firm age, size of founding team, financial resources, and patent protection. So investing in supply chain integration seems to yield higher returns. However, except for supply chain integration, most factors may not be fully controllable ones. One may control the size of the founding team and collect more experience in the team (indicating that this factor is close to the Entrepreneurial Team factors), while enlarging communication requirements and facing power problems. In any case, the meta-analysis results indicated that enlarging the team may improve new technology venture performance.

Meta-analysis of success factors  39 The financial resources, however, may be more difficult to control. Even though our study results suggest that more financial resources may improve performance, not all firms can absolutely control their financial resources. Nevertheless, setting up new technology ventures may need to wait until required financial resources have become available. Finally, when a possibility of patent protection exists firms should take the opportunity. Our analysis also found six heterogeneous meta-factors within this category. In our moderator analysis, we showed that firm type has a positive influence on sales performance. Moreover, in ventures of mixed origin, R&D alliances improved performance, while for independent ventures these alliances worsened performance. Perhaps equity conditions could better be negotiated in corporate ventures, having more power than independent ventures. A remarkable finding of our study was that the R&D investments were not a success factor (much like product innovation, mentioned earlier). Generally, when looking at all resource factors, we did not find any particularly technological resource factors. Within the population of new technology ventures, these factors generally have a high level and there was insufficient variation in these factors. However, in line with a resource-based view of the firm, the focus may need to be on the quality of the resources rather than the quantity. Barney (1991) posited that the value, rareness, non-imitability, and non-substitutability of resources—instead of the amount of resources—led to competitive advantage. We advise future research consider that direction.

2.6 Limitations

As with all research, this meta-analysis had several limitations. First, the Pearson correlations we used are primarily intended for measurement of the strength of a linear relationship between two variables. In the case of zero correlation, a chance existed of observing a vivid curvilinear relationship between variables. Second, the primary studies used in the meta-analysis based their samples on surviving new technology ventures because of the difficulties in accessing new technology ventures that failed. Therefore, any meta-analysis in this topical area must be inherently biased toward more successful, surviving firms. This bias has two implications: (1) meta-factors that influence the success and mortality of a new technology venture could conceivably be substantially different (Shane and Stuart, 2002) and (2) strategies (meta-factors) that seem to deliver the best performance can be misleading. The greater the potential a particular strategy has, the greater the risks associated with it. Finally,

40  The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking the last limitation of the study was the sample size of the meta-analysis itself, which included 31 studies reflecting the emerging nature of this research domain as well as the generally poor standards of descriptive statistics publication. However, the 31 studies provided a sufficient sample size for a preliminary meta-analysis (Gerwin and Barrowman, 2002; Montoya-Weiss and Calantone, 1994). Thus, this meta-analysis should not and must not preclude future research, but rather stimulate and direct it.

The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking  41

Chapter 3

The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking

In this study, we use the dual process theory to link two streams of research on entrepreneurial risk-taking: the "conscious" risk-seeking perspective and the "unconscious" cognitive perspective. We model the mechanism of entrepreneurial risky decision-making by looking at how the cognitive biases mediate the relationship between the intuitive and rational thinking of entrepreneurs and their risk-taking propensity. Hereby we reveal the more stable nature of the cognitive biases, as opposed to the context-driven one. In our research, we focus on seven important biases: hindsight bias, illusory correlation, and overconfidence originating from ; and base-rate , illusion of control, sample size fallacy, and regression fallacy deriving from the representativeness heuristic. We show that rational and intuitive thinking have two distinct effects on entrepreneurial risk-taking propensity. While intuition has only indirect, mediating effect on risk-taking, rational thinking has only direct effect on risk-taking. Cognitive biases mainly derive from intuition and the rational system can correct some of them, thereby bringing the subjective experience of risks of the entrepreneur closer to objective reality. While all the biases have a significant effect on risk-taking propensity, some of them have a positive and some have a negative effect. Finally, although entrepreneurs are generally treated by the literature as predominantly intuitive decision makers, our results also highlight the importance of the rational side of entrepreneurs.

42  The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking 3.1 Introduction

This study concentrates on the effects of intuitive and rational thinking on entrepreneurial risk-taking behavior. In venture-related decisions, entrepreneurs have to cope on a daily basis with ill-structured, uncertain sets of possibilities under high time pressures. At the same time, they have the ultimate responsibility for each decision (Knight, 1921; Stewart and Roth, 2001). There are a number of risks associated with this kind of decisions and the question is: How do entrepreneurs take these risks? Entrepreneurship literature holds two alternative perspectives on how entrepreneurs take risks: cognitive perspective assuming intuitive thinking and risk-seeking perspective assuming rational thinking. The former perspective postulates that in their intuitive decision-making, entrepreneurs are unconscious of the actual risks associated with their decisions; they simply do not see them due to cognitive biases (Simon, Houghton and Aquino, 2000). The latter, competing, perspective postulates that entrepreneurs objectively tolerate more risks, that they are risk-seeking and that they consciously take the risks (Stewart and Roth, 2001; 2004). Do these two perspectives really exclude each other or are they complementary? The cognitive perspective postulates that entrepreneurs do not see the risks. The reason for that are heuristics that speed up and simplify their predominantly intuitive decision-making, but also inevitably lead to cognitive biases (Kahneman and Frederick, 2002). Researchers found that entrepreneurs as a group score higher on the biases than other people (Busenitz and Barney, 1997), while entrepreneurs vary in the degree to which they are susceptive to certain biases (Forbes, 2005). The core concept in the risk-seeking perspective is risk-taking propensity. According to Sitkin and Pablo (1992), risk-taking propensity is a general tendency of the decision maker to take or avoid risks. A higher risk-taking propensity is associated with risky behavior. Risk-taking propensity is a predisposition that can change over time and thus is an emergent, although persistent property of the decision maker (Sitkin and Weingart, 1995). After the influential study of Brockhaus (1980), who found no difference in risk-taking propensity between entrepreneurs and other people, risk-taking propensity largely disappeared from the studies of entrepreneurship. However, the meta-analyses of Stewart and Roth (2001; 2004) brought it back. They found that entrepreneurs on the whole have a higher risk-taking propensity than other people, and they also found that entrepreneurs as a group vary in their risk-taking propensity.

The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking  43 The dual process theory provides a way to bridge the risk-seeking and the cognitive perspective. According to the dual process theory, people can be intuitive and rational at the same time (Epstein, Pacini, Denes-Raj, and Heier, 1996; Pacini and Epstein, 1999). This theory postulates that all judgments and behavior of people are a joint output of both intuitive and rational thinking (Epstein et al., 1996). The rational thinking monitors and eventually corrects outputs of intuitive thinking (including the heuristics and biases). It provides an answer itself if no intuitive judgment is available (Epstein et al., 1996; Kahneman, 2003; Stanovich and West, 2000). By now the cognitive and the risk-seeking streams within entrepreneurship research have never been compared. Moreover, the cognitive stream has only focused on three cognitive biases, overconfidence, illusion of control and law of small numbers, and their influence on entrepreneurial decision-making in different situations involving risk (e.g. Simon et al., 2000; Simon and Houghton, 2003). By following this research line studies in the cognitive stream chose for the view that the cognitive biases are evoked by specific contexts rather than emanate from certain personality characteristics. However, both views are valid (Forbes, 2005). Moreover, although the cognitive stream puts emphasis on intuitive decision- making, intuition has been rarely explicitly studied. The risk-seeking stream has mainly focused on entrepreneurs-managers comparisons. Only outcome history, inertia and risk preferences have been identified as antecedents of risk-taking propensity (Sitkin and Pablo, 1992). Despite the more conscious, systematic character of determinants in this stream, rational thinking has never been related to risk-taking propensity. Finally, up till now the primarily conceptual studies in the dual process theory have not focused on risk-taking propensity. In this study, we will try to fill these gaps. We will examine the impact of intuitive and rational thinking on risk-taking propensity. Moreover, we will explore whether seven cognitive biases – hindsight bias, illusory correlation, overconfidence, base-rate fallacy, illusion of control, law of small numbers, and regression fallacy – have a mediating role in this relationship. We empirically test our model using structural equation modeling with maximum likelihood estimation on a sample of 289 entrepreneurs from the US. Our theoretical framework and empirical model allow us to critically assess the different statements and assumptions about entrepreneurial decision-making made by both the cognitive and risk-taking stream of research, such as the highly intuitive nature of

44  The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking entrepreneurs, the origin of cognitive biases and the ways to correct them as well as the effects of these biases on risky decision-making. Moreover, by examining risk-taking propensity as a dependent variable, we consider the more stable part of cognitive biases, thus contributing to the cognitive stream, and to the dual process theory. By explicitly taking into account the intuitive and the rational system, we contribute to the cognitive stream and the risk-seeking stream respectively. By empirically testing the relationship between intuitive and rational thinking and cognitive biases, we contribute to the dual process theory. Finally, we contribute to the entrepreneurial field by applying dual process theory, and by studying the largest set of biases ever examined. Moreover, our study emphasizes the importance of the rational side of entrepreneurs. We build the chapter as follows. In the theoretical background section, we give definitions and review the dual process theory and the concepts of heuristics and biases. Then we develop our conceptual model and research hypotheses. In the following two sections, we describe the methodological grounds of the study, and the results. We finish with the discussion how our results contribute to the entrepreneurship, and dual process theory.

3.2 Theoretical background

3.2.1 Dual process theory: Definitions and theoretical foundation The recent reviews of dual process theory established that despite the different names and focuses the streams in the dual process theory converged towards a unifying view on the functions and properties of the two systems (Epstein, 1994; Kahneman, 2003; Stanovich and West, 2000). Dual process theory postulates that individuals have two fundamentally different systems, intuitive and rational, that are responsible for two modes of information processing (Epstein et al., 1996). All behavior is seen as the product of operation of both intuitive and rational systems. The main assumption of the dual process theory is that the two systems operate simultaneously, independently and interactively (Kahneman, 2003). Probably the most important one is the simultaneous contradictory belief, when people ask themselves a question and get two different answers at the same time. For example, what kind of animal is a whale? The first impression most people get is that a whale is a fish, because it looks like fish. At the same time, technically, a whale is a mammal. In this example the answer "whale is a mammal" comes from the rational system and the answer "whale is a fish" comes from the intuitive system. Because of the simultaneous contradictory belief, judges are often forced

The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking  45 to ignore their intuitive sense of justice in order to mete out punishment according to the law, rationally (Sloman, 2002). Such contradictory beliefs result in "the conflict between the heart and the head" (Epstein, 1994). In this study we will follow the definitions of cognitive-experiential self-theory (CEST) (Epstein, 1994), which is one of the most elaborated dual process theories. According to CEST, the experiential system (also known as intuitive) is a system that operates in an automatic, holistic, associationistic manner (Denes-Raj and Epstein, 1994). It is primarily non-verbal and intimately associated with affect. The rational system is a primarily conscious analytical system that functions by a person's understanding of conventionally established rules of logic and evidence (Denes-Raj and Epstein, 1994). It is intentional, analytic, primarily verbal and relatively affect-free. Below we will elaborate on the role of heuristics and biases in the dual process theory.

3.2.2 Heuristics and biases stream of research Similar to the experiential and the rational system, heuristics and biases influence our decision-making. Research on heuristics and biases started with biases and only recently delivered a formal definition of what drives the biases: namely, heuristics. A judgment is said to be influenced by a heuristic when people do not use the target attribute of the object or subject for their judgment, but substitute it by a related heuristic attribute that comes more readily to mind (Kahneman, 2003). There are two main heuristics described in literature: representativeness and availability. Representativeness is the degree to which the heuristic attribute is similar to or resembles the target attribute. Availability is the ease with which instances or associations related to the target attribute could be brought to mind (Kahneman and Frederick, 2002; Kahneman and Tversky, 1973). For example, a professor has to assess whether her candidate will be suitable for a tenure position in her department. She asks the candidate to give a presentation and makes her judgment on the basis of this presentation. Actually, she uses the representativeness heuristic since she assumes that the quality of the presentation is representative for, or resembles the suitability of a tenure position. Suppose the candidate is married and his wife has a job 600 miles away. The professor may ask herself what is the probability that this distance causes trouble in the new job within one year. In finding an answer, she may look for troublesome instances from her own experience that come readily to mind. In that case, she would use the availability heuristic, since she makes

46  The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking the probability estimates on the basis of available (known) instances of troublesome and less troublesome situations. Biases (or ) are errors in judgment where a heuristic is applied. They appear because the target attribute and the heuristic attribute are not the same (Kahneman and Frederick, 2002). In our research, we focus on seven important biases: hindsight bias, illusory correlations, overconfidence, base-rate fallacy, illusion of control, sample size fallacy, and regression fallacy. Literature suggests that the first three biases primarily originate from the availability heuristic, while the other four primarily originate from the representativeness heuristic (e.g., Tversky and Kahneman, 1974, Kahneman, 2003, Russo and Schoemaker, 1992). We elaborate more on these seven biases while developing hypotheses in the following section.

3.3 Conceptual model and hypotheses

Based on the dual process theory, we present the conceptual framework of the relationship between the two systems of thought, heuristics and biases, and risk-taking propensity. Our model essentially suggests that heuristics and biases (partially) mediate the relationship between the experiential and rational system and risk-taking propensity.

Figure 3.1. The mechanism of risk-taking propensity formation

The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking  47 3.3.1 Relationship between biases and risk-taking propensity In this sub-section we will concentrate on the influence of the heuristics and biases on risk-taking propensity. Below we will first explain this link for the three biases that are primarily deriving from the availability heuristic and then we elaborate on four biases that primarily derive from representativeness heuristic. The first bias is hindsight bias. Hindsight bias appears when, after a certain event occurs, subjects tend to remember their predictions about the event as being more accurate than they actually were. So, there is an inconsistency in the prediction of an outcome before and after knowing the actual outcome of the event (Slovic and Fischhoff, 1977). The Polish proverb "A Pole is wise after damage occurred", is an example of this hindsight bias. In hindsight, people tend to assign higher likelihoods to outcomes that actually had occurred and exaggerate what they could have anticipated in foresight. They tend to view events as having appeared "relatively inevitable" before they happened (Fischhoff, 1982). Let us consider entrepreneurs choosing a certain strategy or developing a business model to promote their product. If the product turns out to be a success, entrepreneurs that score high on hindsight bias may think that this success was inevitable because of their actions. In meanwhile only a limited number of factors could have been truly controlled by the entrepreneurs. Similarly, if the product turns out to be a failure, entrepreneurs that score high on hindsight bias may think that this failure was inevitable and that even those they did their best, they could not have done better for the product. This is also not quite true because to a certain extent they could have interfered in the process. Thus, in both cases such entrepreneurs would have a wrong impression about the factors that lead to success or failure. Therefore the following time when they would try to launch a product, they will probably try to influence wrong factors. Objectively, it would mean that they are taking more risks and have higher risk-taking propensity than entrepreneurs with a low level of hindsight bias. Therefore, we hypothesize: Hypothesis 1a. The level of hindsight bias will be positively associated with the level of entrepreneurial risk-taking propensity

A second bias is illusory correlation. Illusory correlation is the phenomenon of seeing a co-occurrence between two events in a set of data, when no such co-occurrence exists (Tversky and Kahneman, 1974). Tversky and Kahneman (1974) describe an experiment with experienced clinicians and students. They both get information about a number of mental

48  The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking students. From each patient they get a diagnosis statement and a drawing of a person made by that patient. Then the clinicians and students had to recall from memory how often diagnostic statements such as paranoia or suspiciousness were associated with various features of the drawing such as peculiar eyes of the person in the drawing. Both the clinicians and the students markedly overestimated the frequency of co-occurrence of natural associates, for example between suspiciousness and peculiar eyes. Let us consider entrepreneurs who come to the conclusion, when remembering stories from professional journals and newspapers that high technology innovativeness is associated with high venture performance. This association does not exist in reality. Eisenhardt and Schoonhoven (1990) found that technology innovativeness and venture performance are uncorrelated. However, entrepreneurs with high level of illusory correlation would belief in this association and invest in technologies that are highly innovative. As we know, because of high investments before launch and no strong relationship with existing markets, this may lead to high risks and failure rates, so (probably without knowing) these entrepreneurs would be very risk seeking. In general, when entrepreneurs have this type of prejudice they objectively govern their venture on the basis of wrong incentives, and therefore (without knowing) take more risks than entrepreneurs without this prejudice, and thus they have a higher risk-taking propensity. We hypothesize: Hypothesis 1b. The level of illusory correlations will be positively associated with the level of entrepreneurial risk-taking propensity

The third bias is overconfidence. Overconfidence bias is the failure to know the limits of one's knowledge (Russo and Schoemaker, 1992), resulting in unjustified confidence in one's own judgments. To put it simple: it is not what you know, but whether you know what you know and what you do not know. Examples of overconfidence are numerous, and the phenomenon seems to become almost universal when one (over)estimates the likelihood that one's favored outcome will occur (Griffin and Varey, 1996). Even for neutral general knowledge questions people show stable overconfidence (Fischhoff, Slovic and Lichtenstein, 1977). The general procedure is to ask respondents for their answers on the questions and ask them to rate their confidence that these answers are indeed correct. Overconfidence bias occurs therefore when respondents are extremely sure that they are right when they are

The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking  49 actually wrong. In the study of Fischhoff et al. (1977) percent of respondents with extreme overconfidence ranged from 5% to 77% depending on the type of question. Let us consider entrepreneurs busy with a new product introduction. Entrepreneurs with a high level of overconfidence bias will tend to be more certain of the product success than their actual judgment accuracy would allow. When entrepreneurs are overconfident, they feel that the additional risk reduction measures are unnecessary and therefore will be less busy with undertaking actions to mitigate potential risks. This means that objectively, they will be taking more risks than entrepreneurs with a low level of overconfidence and thus have a higher risk-taking propensity. Therefore, we hypothesize: Hypothesis 1c. The level of overconfidence will be positively associated with the level of entrepreneurial risk-taking propensity

The four biases primarily emanating from the representativeness heuristic are base- rate fallacy, illusion of control, sample size fallacy, and regression fallacy (Tversky and Kahneman, 1974). We will also describe these biases below. The fourth bias is the base-rate fallacy. It occurs when irrelevant information is used to make a probability judgment, ignoring available statistical information about prior probabilities (the base-rate frequency) (Tversky and Kahneman, 1974). For example, in an experiment of Tversky and Kahneman (1974) subjects had to make a judgment whether a person named Dick is an engineer or a lawyer based on both statistical and specific information. Dick is part of a population of 70% lawyers and 30% engineers. The specific information about Dick was designed to be worthless for the probability judgment and be equally applicable to both a lawyer and an engineer: Dick is a 30 year old man. He is married with no children. A man of high ability and high motivation, he promises to be quite successful in his field. He is well liked by his colleagues.

The subjects judged the probability of Dick being an engineer to be 50%, just as much as being a lawyer. By doing so they neglected the statistical information about the population and followed the principles of the base-rate fallacy. According to Tversky and Kahneman (1974), people properly utilize prior probabilities when no specific evidence is given; however, they ignore prior probabilities when worthless evidence is given. Let us consider a situation when an entrepreneur gets a chance to take over a machinery facility. The machines are approximately five years old. Statistically 85% of

50  The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking machines of this type need a major repair in the 6 th year. Entrepreneurs may ask an independent engineering firm to check the machines and buy only the ones that have no problems in operation. Entrepreneurs with high level of base-rate fallacy would think that the chance that their new machinery would get a problem within one year is close to zero. In this case they are ignoring statistical information and paying too much attention to the judgment of the engineering firm that is only applicable to the current moment of time and not to the next year. In general, entrepreneurs with high level of base-rate fallacy neglect existing statistical information that is in fact the most accurate indication of the level of risk. It means that objectively they are taking more risks than they perceive and thus have a higher risk- taking propensity than entrepreneurs with the low level of base-rate fallacy. Therefore, we hypothesize: Hypothesis 1d. The level of base-rate fallacy will be positively associated with the level of entrepreneurial risk-taking propensity

The fifth bias primarily emanating from the representativeness heuristic is illusion of control, or unrealistic control. Note that it is different from illusory correlation although it is sometimes confused with it. People have illusion of control when they perceive that objectively chance determined, or uncontrollable events are within their control (Langer and Roth, 1975; Zuckerman, Knee, Kieffer, Rawsthorne and Bruce, 1996). Illusion of control refers to an overestimation of one's skills, and consequently his or her ability to cope with and predict future events (Simon et al., 2000). This phenomenon has to do with the difference between skills and luck. In principle this distinction is clear: in skill situations there is a causal link between behavior and outcome, thus success in skill tasks is controllable; luck, on the other hand, is a fortuitous happening, thus success in luck or chance activities is uncontrollable. When one has a high level of illusion of control, this distinction between skills and luck is not recognized (Langer, 1975). In studies of dice players, researchers found that these players clearly behave as if they were able to control the outcome of a toss. They threw the dice softly when they wanted to have low numbers and threw it hard when large numbers were needed. Moreover, they believed that effort and concentration would pay off (Langer, 1975). In the entrepreneurial setting it means that entrepreneurs with a high level of illusion of control perceive that they can influence factors that only are partially controllable or not controllable at all. For example, they may feel they can accurately foresee and influence their

The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking  51 sales. However, there are always some exogenous factors that they can not control and on which they do not anticipate. Because entrepreneurs with a high level of illusion of control think that they can influence more than they actually can, they are taking actions that are riskier than those of entrepreneurs with a low level of illusion of control. Therefore, we hypothesize: Hypothesis 1e. The level of illusion of control will be positively associated with the level of entrepreneurial risk-taking propensity

The sixth bias, sample size fallacy, is also known as belief in the law of small numbers. Sample size fallacy concerns the phenomenon that people make judgments on the basis of sample proportion, and erroneously do not take into account the size of the sample that crucially influences the reliability of the sample proportion outcome (Tversky and Kahneman, 1974). Suppose an urn is filled with balls, 2/3 of one color and 1/3 of another color, however it is unknown which colors are those. One individual draws 5 balls from the urn, and finds 4 red and 1 white balls. Another individual draws 20 balls, of which 12 are red and 8 white. Which sample provides strongest evidence that 2/3 of the balls are red and 1/3 white (and not the opposite)? Most people feel that the first sample provides more evidence, because the proportion of red balls in the first sample is larger than in the second. However, sampling theory shows that this is not true. People's intuitive judgments are dominated by sample proportion, and not by sample size. This insensitivity to the size of the sample can take many forms. Let us consider nascent entrepreneurs that make their decision to start a venture being inspired by stories of a few successful “college drop-out” entrepreneurs (e.g., Bill Gates and Michael Dell). Success stories of entrepreneurs and their ventures are widely covered in journals and newspapers while publications about failures of similar ventures and risks associated with their business strategies are relatively unknown (Simon and Houghton, 2003). Entrepreneurs with high level of sample size fallacy would generalize from the small samples without being aware of the confidence intervals that information based on these small samples has. Thus they are unaware of the risks surrounding their decisions and objectively are taking more risks than entrepreneurs with low level of sample size fallacy. Therefore, we hypothesize: Hypothesis 1f. The level of sample size fallacy will be positively associated with the level of entrepreneurial risk-taking propensity

52  The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking The last, seventh, bias is regression fallacy. Regression fallacy is an erroneous causal interpretation of regression to the mean (Tversky and Kahneman, 1974). Statistically, regression to the mean is a phenomenon taking place when one looks at two related measurements. The first measurement is either extremely high or extremely low and therefore naturally attracts attention. In this case, the second measurement is likely to move closer to the mean than the first measurement. As such, regression to the mean is a statistical phenomenon, caused by chance. However, when one erroneously tries to explain this phenomenon by a causal mechanism, we speak about regression fallacy. There is a number of regression fallacy examples. For instance, the test of a certain stress-reducing drug, intended to increase reading skills of poor readers. Students get a reading test and 10% of the students with the lowest scores get the drug. After some time, these 10% are tested again with a different, but similar reading test. The general finding is that their reading scores improved significantly. People with a high level of regression fallacy would conclude that the drug has been a great success. However, this is an unwarranted conclusion: even without the drug, the principle of regression to the mean would have predicted the same outcome. Let us consider a situation when a product of the entrepreneurial firm has performed especially well in a given year. Most entrepreneurs would probably try to stimulate and support further success of the product for example by an extensive advertising campaign. However, the next year due to the regression to the mean the product will most likely perform worse or at least deliver a marginal increase in the product performance. The natural conclusion for an entrepreneur with the high level of regression fallacy is that the advertising campaign did not work or was at least not worth it. Thus, the higher the level of regression fallacy by entrepreneurs, the easier they will be making a wrong causal link between their actions and performance of their venture by either abandoning a working strategy or using an actually non-working strategy. Applying a wrong strategy means that the venture has a higher risk of failure. Thus, objectively these entrepreneurs will be taking more risks than entrepreneurs with low regression fallacy. Therefore, we hypothesize: Hypothesis 1g. The level of regression fallacy will be positively associated with the level of entrepreneurial risk-taking propensity

3.3.2 Relationship between the two systems and risk-taking propensity The relationship between experiential system and risk-taking propensity can be substantiated on a number of grounds. While earlier studies tended to use the intuitive and

The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking  53 risk-taking as synonyms (Miller and Toulouse, 1986) or characterize risk-taking as an intuitive activity (McGinnis, 1984), recent theoretical developments allow us to build a more refined relationship between these two concepts. According to the dual process theory, experiential thinking is based on a network of learned associative pathways (Sloman, 2002). So, for a high level of experiential thinking a lot of personal experience is required. Despite the personal experience, there is no guarantee that problems and questions are addressed in their full complexity. In fact, professional judgments are likely to have a very comprehensive view of a restrictively defined problem (Fischhoff, Lichtenstein, Slovic, Derby, and Keeney, 1981: 75). Because of this narrow definition of situation entrepreneurs may perceive that they fully know and have control over the situation. They feel they can safely take risks in such situations, thus demonstrating a high risk-taking propensity. Moreover, even if the decision situation is observed in its full complexity, experienced entrepreneurs feel they are more able to evaluate risks inherent in the situation, and are more inclined to feel safely and accept them, thus objectively showing a higher risk-taking propensity. Therefore, we hypothesize: Hypothesis 2a. The more the experiential system is used the higher the level of entrepreneurial risk-taking propensity will be

Due to the adherence to the formal and abstract rules of logic the rational system is a relatively slow system (Kahneman, 2003). Entrepreneurs relying on this system take time to think the problem thoroughly through. Because of this, potential actions are considered more carefully, which means that there is a higher chance that a potential problem or risk will be discovered. Realizing the additional risks of the potential actions means that concrete actions on these issues become postponed and that eventually some of them will not be preceded. In that case fewer risks are taken, so there is a lower risk-taking propensity. Therefore, we hypothesize:

Hypothesis 2b. The more the rational system is used the lower the level of entrepreneurial risk-taking propensity will be

54  The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking

3.3.3 Relationship between the two systems and biases The mechanism of influence of experiential and rational system on heuristics and biases can be clarified via the dual process theory (Epstein et al., 1996; Kahneman and Frederick, 2002). Epstein et al. (1996) also found a positive association between the experiential system and heuristic thinking, and negative association between the rational system and heuristic thinking. However, they focused on a different vision of heuristics than the heuristics and biases in our study, which are proposed by Kahneman and Tversky. In particular, Epstein et al. (1996) examine emotional (typically angriness or feeling foolish) vs. rational answers to vignettes on various real-life situations. We first explain how the experiential system influences heuristics and biases. As we mentioned previously, experiential system is automatic, holistic and makes associationistic connections (Denes-Raj and Epstein, 1994). Source of knowledge in the experiential system is personal experience (Sloman, 2002). Personal experience makes instances of different events available, which means that they may come automatically and readily to mind. For example, entrepreneurs may find instances of how technical problems were solved in other apparently similar situations, and will try to use these solutions in the new situations. Similarly, entrepreneurs may fall back on former experiences in treating potential clients during sales negotiations. In general, the more experience is built up, the more experienced events come readily to mind, and thus the more likely an entrepreneur will use the availability heuristic, which leads to the aforementioned availability biases. In the same way, with an increased level of experience, more apparent regularities amongst various features within the venture come to mind and can be used. For instance, an entrepreneur that used to work in the aircraft construction and is now developing accessories for cars will have a lot of associations with airplanes in his work. The more associations are built up, the more likely it is that they are used to replace a target attribute by a seemingly similar heuristic attribute, thus the more likely will entrepreneurs use the representativeness heuristic, that leads to the aforementioned representativeness biases. The experiential system is also a holistic system (Denes-Raj and Epstein, 1994), because it delivers answers to the question as a whole, not trying to differentiate between various aspects and features of the question and thus staying on a more aggregate, rough level. On this level there is a greater chance that issues appear to have more similarities, because the

The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking  55 particular details are omitted. Having more similarities creates a fertile ground for the representativeness heuristic. This means that the more individuals use the experiential system, the greater is the likelihood that they will use the representativeness heuristic, and that the representative biases will occur. Recapitulating the former discussion, we can hypothesize: Hypothesis 3a. The more the experiential system is used, the higher the level of heuristics and biases of entrepreneurs will be

The rational system is a primarily conscious analytical system that functions by a person's understanding of conventionally established rules of logic and evidence. (Denes-Raj and Epstein, 1994). It is slow, effortful and rule-governed (Kahneman, 2003). On the other hand, the core characteristic of heuristics is that they provide answers that are automatically computed and come immediately to mind, allowing for quick and efficient decision making. Decision making based on heuristic thinking is characterized as a simplifying strategy (Busenitz and Barney, 1997; Kahneman and Frederick, 2002; Kahneman, 2003). When working according to the thorough, rule-based way of the rational system, it is unlikely that target attributes are substituted by heuristic attributes that simplify matters and quickly come to mind. The logic reasoning within the rule-based system simply does not allow for that type of replacements. Thus, the more a person uses the rational system, the less he or she will be involved in heuristic thinking, and therefore he or she will not be exposed to biases. Therefore, we can hypothesize the following: Hypothesis 3b. The more the rational system is used, the lower the level of heuristics and biases of entrepreneurs will be

3.4 Methodology

3.4.1 Sample and data collection Several sources were utilized to identify entrepreneurs for this study: (1) A list of the one hundred entrepreneurs, compiled by the venture capitalist, David Silver (Silver, 1985); (2) The list of national winners of the Entrepreneurs of the Year awards, compiled by Ernst and Young; and (3) a list of 6,359 founders of venture-backed firms provided by VentureOne, a leading VC research company based in San Francisco. VentureOne began tracking equity investment in 1992. It collects data by surveying VC firms for recent funding activities and

56  The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking portfolio updates, gathering information through direct contacts at venture-backed companies, and investigating various secondary resources such as company press releases and IPO prospectuses from VentureOne 2001. Together, these sources drew their members from a pool that included virtually every enduring company created by an entrepreneur in the US from 1960 till 2001. 1,500 randomly selected entrepreneurs with complete contact information were selected for the survey. In administering the survey, we followed the total design method for survey research (Dillman, 1978). The first mailing packet included a personalized letter, a project fact sheet, the survey, a priority postage-paid envelope with an individually-typed return-address label, and a list of research reports available to participants. The package was sent by priority mail to 1500 selected entrepreneurs. 324 mailing packages were returned due to undeliverable addresses or names. Thus, the adjusted sample was 1,176 entrepreneurs. To increase the response rate, we sent four follow-up mailings to the companies. One week after the mailing, we sent a follow-up letter. Two weeks after the first follow-up, we sent a second package with same content as the first package to all non-responding companies. After two additional follow-up letters, we received completed questionnaires from 289 entrepreneurs, representing a response rate of 24.6% (289/1176).

3.4.2 Measurements In our survey we used existing cases and scales from the literature if possible. We strengthened the measurements by developing additional entrepreneurial cases based on the existing cases. Due to the survey length limitations we had to select the items from the scales. We chose items with the highest factor loadings. Moreover, when there were no scales available we deduced items from the definitions, examples and ideas in the existing literature. Because of these changes we had to pre-test the survey. We conducted a pre-test by extensively interviewing twelve entrepreneurs. In the beginning of each interview entrepreneurs told us about the background of their ventures, how they started, how they discovered the opportunity and how the business idea developed over the time. This allowed us to break the ice and better interpret their answers on the questionnaire. In the last part of the interview we used the protocol method and asked the entrepreneurs to "think aloud" as they filled out the English questionnaire (Hunt, Sparkman, Jr., and Wilcox, 1982). The interviews were recorded and two researchers made careful notes

The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking  57 of the verbalizations and the thinking process of the entrepreneurs. The analysis of interviews led to changes in wording of instructions and wording of some cases and items. Appendix A3.1 provides the construct reliabilities, the response format employed in the questionnaire, and the details of the measurement items used in this study. Dependent variable. We measure risk-taking propensity using the certainty equivalent approach, which aims to plot the individual form of the entrepreneur's utility curve (Kahneman and Tversky, 1979; Mullins, Forlani and Walker, 1999; Schneider and Lopes, 1986). In this approach entrepreneurs receive a number of scenarios with two possible options: one certain and one risky with the same expected value. Risk aversion is thus preference for certain outcomes to gambles of equal expected value, while risk-seeking is the opposite. In the measure taken from Mullins et al. (1999) and Schneider and Lopes (1986) entrepreneurs get five scenarios, each scenario measuring risky actions on a different level of the expected value. Entrepreneurs are completely risk averse if they choose for certain options and are completely risk-seeking if they choose for risky options in all the five scenario's. The scores between 0 and 5 represent varying degrees of risk-taking propensity. We supplemented this measure by another two risk-taking propensity measures based on the certainty equivalent approach. However, in these two measures entrepreneurs have to choose between one certain option and nine risky options. All the 10 options have the same expected value. The risky options are ranked according to their riskiness manipulated by the percent of the total sum that entrepreneurs can win and loose. As a result, we get a very precise estimate of a point on the entrepreneur's utility curve. This point is enough to estimate the form of the utility curve of the entrepreneur using the approximation by the exponential function (e.g., Walls and Dyer, 1996). The Cronbach's α for all three measures of risk-taking propensity is 0.87. Mediating variables. Hindsight bias occurs when entrepreneurs remember their predictions about a former event more accurately than they actually were. In the beginning of our survey we asked entrepreneurs to answer a number of questions and rate with what probability their answers on these questions were correct. The questions were difficult general knowledge questions with two answer options: correct and incorrect. At the end of the survey, we gave respondents the correct answers on the knowledge questions and asked them to remember their estimates for correctness in hindsight (without looking at the first page of the survey). The hindsight bias manifests itself when respondents originally gave the incorrect

58  The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking answer and lowered their estimate for correctness in hindsight. The larger the difference between the original estimate and estimate in hindsight, the bigger the bias. We follow Bukszar and Connolly (1988) and Slovic and Fischhoff (1977) with this procedure. According to Campbell and Tesser (1983), there should be at least 30 min. between an original judgment and the hindsight judgment. It took the participants about 40-45 min. to fill out our questionnaire, therefore the potential memory bias is not a problem in our study. We used a 3- item scale for hindsight bias ( α=0.75).

Illusory correlation takes place when entrepreneurs see a co-occurrence between two events, when no such co-occurrence exists. Our items are based on the ideas of Tversky and Kahneman (1974). We used common myths about co-occurrences between for example, the fact that a cat has been spayed or neutered and its weight, and between university licenses and the larger size of a company. The 3-item scale has a Cronbach α of 0.67.

We also used the aforementioned general knowledge questions and the estimates of the probability that the answers are correct, to measure overconfidence. We followed the procedure of Forbes (2005), and Brenner, Koehler, Liberman, and Tversky (1996) to develop a 3-item scale ( α=0.82) for overconfidence, however we used other knowledge questions, because questions from literature are somewhat out-dated. The more certain respondents are that they gave the correct answer when in fact they are wrong, the higher level of overconfidence they have. Base-rate fallacy occurs when irrelevant case information is used to make judgments in favor of available statistical information. We used two cases to measure the base-rate fallacy ( α=0.73), both are based on Lynch and Ofir (1989). The first case is about high-tech firms. Respondents have to make an estimate of the probability that a given high-tech firm will fail within the first five years. We start the case description by giving statistical information (the base-rate) about high-tech firms' failures (60%). We also give irrelevant information about the founder's hobbies and social life. When respondents deviate in their predictions from 60%, they exhibit base-rate fallacy. The second case is about purchasing a five-year old car. Similarly, we start by statistical information: "Consumer Reports" suggest that there is a 50% probability that such a car will require major repairs in the 6 th year. We also give irrelevant case information concerning the color and the interior of the car. Respondents are asked to predict the likelihood that the car requires major repairs during the

The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking  59 next year. When respondents deviate from 50%, they show a base-rate fallacy. The more they deviate, the higher the bias. Illusion of control means that people perceive that objectively uncontrollable events are within their control. We measured this construct by a 5-item scale ( α=0.88) based on Simon et al. (2000) and Zuckerman et al. (1996). Items concern, for instance, the accuracy of predictions of future market developments and the perception that everything that happens is a result of the respondent's own doing. The more respondents think that they can accurately predict the market, or that what's happening is always a results of their own doing, the higher level of illusion of control they exhibit. Law of small numbers bias arises when people make their judgments on the basis of a (small) sample, while not taking into account the actual size of this sample. The 3-item scale (α=0.86) is based on Simon et al. (2000) and Mohan-Neill (1995). Items concern basing strategic decisions on the opinion of closest friends and colleagues, on only one source of information, or not basing such decisions on large scale market research. The higher respondents score on these items, the greater law of small numbers bias they exhibit. Regression fallacy concerns an erroneous causal interpretation of regression to the mean. In such situation, there are always two related measurements: one that is extreme and therefore attracts attention, and another that is closer to the mean. We measured regression fallacy by a case that is based on an example of Kahneman and Tversky (1973). The case describes a stable economic environment, which is not likely to grow naturally. The firm's sales increased by 15% two years ago and decreased by 5% one year ago, thus bringing the sales closer to the mean. In order to grow further, the firm increased its advertising budget last year by 25%. As we know, despite that, its sales decreased by 5% due to regression to the mean. Without the advertising campaign, the firm's sales could have decreased by even more than 5%. When respondents conclude that advertising was not effective, they give a causal interpretation of sales decrease in the last year and therefore exhibit regression fallacy. In Appendix A3.1 we also describe the coding algorithm used to recode the hindsight bias, overconfidence, base-rate fallacy and regression fallacy measurements for further analysis.

Independent variables. We measure the rational system ( α=0.94) by the "Need for cognition" scale (Epstein et al., 1996; Pacini and Epstein, 1999) The rational system scale taps the extent to which entrepreneurs are good at and rely on in-depth, hard, and logical thinking.

60  The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking The experiential system ( α=0.98) is measured by the "Faith in intuition" scale (Epstein et al., 1996; Pacini and Epstein, 1999). The experiential system scale taps the extent to which entrepreneurs rely on their gut feelings and instincts, and believe in their hunches. We selected the items for our systems scales from the latest version of the "Need for cognition" and "Faith in intuition" instrument based on the highest factor loadings and correspondence to the conceptual domains listed in the definitions of the rational and experiential system (Pacini and Epstein, 1999).

3.4.3 Analysis We used a number of procedural remedies to diminish potential common method bias (Podsakoff, MacKenzie andLee, 2003). In our study applying archival data or having different respondents was not possible. Therefore, we used a second best option by varying the types of measures. Besides Likert scales, we also used cases for some biases and more objective utility curve-based measures for risk-taking propensity. We shuffled Likert-scale items as well. Finally, we tested for the common method bias statistically. The second-smallest positive correlation among the manifest variables provides a conservative estimate for the common method variance (Malhotra, Kim and Patil, 2006). In our data it was the correlation between the age of the entrepreneur and the number of times the entrepreneur was involved as an early-stage employee (r 2=0.01, p=0.75). As another statistical check, we did the Harman's single-factor test (Podsakoff et al., 2003). We forced all constructs into one factor model in a confirmatory factor analysis. The χ2/df=16.8, indicating an extremely bad fit and significantly worse than the fit of our measurement model, reported in Table 3.2. Therefore, we can conclude there is no significant common method bias in our data. In Table 3.1 we present descriptive statistics and Cronbach α's. Cronbach α's range between 0.73 and 0.98, except for one, which suggests good reliabilities (Nunnally, 1978). Note that overconfidence and hindsight bias have a high correlation, since we intentionally linked both constructs in our measurements 3.

2 Kendall's τ correlation coefficient 3 Neither the VIF-based nor the condition index-based tests indicated any substantial multicollinearity effects (Hair et al.,1998). The VIF for overconfidence and hindsight bias was 4.64 and 4.59 respectively (while the cut-off value is >10). The highest condition index was 27.7. In this case the variance proportion for overconfidence and hindsight bias was 0.21 and 0.18 respectively (while the cut-off value is >0.5).

The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking  61

Table 3.1. Means, standard deviations, correlations, and reliabilities Construct Mean St.Dev. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1. Risk-taking propensity 4.45 2.35 0.87 2. Hindsight bias 1.04 0.94 .27 ** 0.75 3. Illusory correlation 4.65 1.25 .34 ** .20 ** 0.67 4. Overconfidence 5.80 2.42 .35 ** .87 ** .17 ** 0.82 5. Base-rate fallacy 2.62 0.99 .22 ** .05 -.01 .10 0.73 6. Illusion of control 5.11 1.24 .50 ** .28 ** .31 ** .23 ** .30 ** 0.88 7. Law of small numbers 4.71 1.37 .35 ** .39 ** .24 ** .35 ** -.08 .22 ** 0.85 8. Regression fallacy 5.62 2.49 .40 ** .35 ** .06 .40 ** -.04 .24 ** .29 ** - 9. Experiential system 4.46 1.39 .31 ** .30 ** .29 ** .32 ** .06 .29 ** .38** .17 ** 0.98 10. Rational system 3.13 1.19 -.34 ** -.38 ** -.11 * -.35 ** -.04 -.37 ** -.18 ** -.20 ** -.30 ** 0.94 Figures on the diagonal line represent Cronbach's α * p <0.05 ** p<0.01

62  The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking

Table 3.2. Confirmatory factor analysis Construct Factor T-value Item Loading Hindsight bias HIN1 0.68 11.80 HIN2 0.74 13.32 HIN3 0.70 12.71 Illusory correlation COR1 0.63 11.12 COR2 0.54 9. 01 COR3 0.77 11.71 Overconfidence OV1 0.83 15.88 OV2 0.85 16.49 OV3 0.67 12.29 Base -rate fallacy BAS1 0.54 6.61 BAS2 1.07 8.53 Illusion of c ontrol IC1 0.79 15.52 IC2 0.87 17.88 IC3 0.65 11.92 IC4 0.73 14.00 IC5 0.82 16.53 Law of small numbers SN1 0.86 16.90 SN2(R) 0.71 13.16 SN3(R) 0.85 16.50 Experiential system ES1 1.00 24.00 ES2 0.80 16.40 ES3 0.99 23.51 ES4 0.99 23.55 ES5 0.99 23.48 Rational sys tem RS1(R) 0.74 14.78 RS2 0.65 12.47 RS3 0.99 23.65 RS4 0.98 23.14 RS5(R) 0.94 21.38 (R) – the item is reversed χ2=586.09, df=346, RMSEA=0.049, DELTA2=0.98, CFI=0.98, NFI=0.95, NNFI=0.97

The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking  63 Prior to testing the hypotheses, we conducted confirmatory factor analysis on the independent and mediating variables with a metric measurement scale (Hair, Anderson, Tatham and Black, 1998) via Maximum Likelihood estimation in LISREL 8.54. We reviewed each construct and deleted items that loaded on multiple constructs or had low item-to- construct loadings. The measurement model is presented in Table 3.2. Results in Table 3.2 indicate a good fit of the model; χ2/df is 1.69, while RMSEA is 0.049, DELTA2 is 0.98 4, CFI is 0.98, NFI is 0.95 and NNFI is 0.97 (Hair et al., 1998). All loadings on the respective constructs are highly significant (p<0.001), while the standardized loading of each item was greater than 0.5, demonstrating that our scales have convergent validity (Fornell and Larcker, 1981). Moreover, no inter-factor correlations have a confidence interval that contains a value of one (p<0.01) and all item-level correlations between constructs are insignificant, thus we conclude that our scales possess discriminant validity (Bagozzi, Yi and Philips, 1991). The mediating nature of our study strongly favors the use of structural equation modeling (SEM) to test our hypotheses. We base our full latent variable model on the measurement model from CFA with an addition of the one-item construct of regression fallacy and risk-taking propensity as our final dependent variable (Anderson and Gerbing, 1988). We also allow for covariance between overconfidence and hindsight bias and between their error terms, because of the related measures of these two constructs. The model revealed a reasonable fit between the theoretical model and the empirical covariances provided by the sample (Hair et al., 1998); χ2/df is 2.02, RMSEA is 0.059, DELTA2 is 0.97, CFI is 0.96, NFI is 0.93 and NNFI is 0.96.

3.5. Results

Results are presented in Figure 3.2 and in the Appendix B3.1. Our overall hypothesis was that heuristics and biases mediate the relationship between the experiential and rational system and risk-taking propensity. Roughly, our results show that heuristics and biases fully mediate the experiential system risk-taking propensity relationship, while they do not mediate the rational system risk-taking propensity relationship. We compared a full model with direct paths between the experiential and rational system and risk-taking propensity, and without

4 We follow the recommendations of Gerbing and Anderson (1993) in reporting this index

64  The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking

-0.03

0.25*** -0.73** -0.31*** Hindsight bias

Hin Hin Hin ES1 1 2 3

ES2 Experiential ES3 0.38*** system 0.21** 0.01 Illusory correlation ES4

ES5 Cor Cor Cor 1 2 3

0.29*** 0.68** -0.26*** Overconfidence

Ov1 Ov2 Ov3

RP1 0.09 Risk-taking Base-rate fallacy 0.19** RP2 0.04 propensity

RP3 Bas Bas R 1 2

0.22*** 0.36*** -0.28*** Illusion of control

RS1 IC1 IC2 IC3 IC4 IC5 R

RS2 0.38*** Law of small RS3 Rational system 0.26*** -0.02 numbers

RS4 SN2 SN3 SN1 RS5 R R R

0.13* 0.25*** -0.12* Regression fallacy

Reg 1

-0.17**

Figure 3.2. LISREL results for the Systems-Biases-Risk-Taking mediation (standardized solution)

The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking  65 such paths. The model with the extra paths was significantly better ( ∆χ 2= 10.91, df=2, p<0.01), due to a significant path from the rational system to risk-taking propensity. The indirect effect of the rational system on risk-taking propensity along the biases is insignificant, due to the high path coefficients of hindsight bias. When we delete this bias from our model, there is a partial moderating effect of the rational system. We will now consider all hypotheses in more detail. The majority of our results is consistent with hypothesis 1 suggesting a positive relationship between biases and risk-taking propensity. All cognitive biases we studied, except for the hindsight bias, show a significant, positive relationship with risk-taking propensity. In particular, the level of illusory correlation ( β=0.21, p<0.01), the level of overconfidence ( β=0.68, p<0.01), the level of base-rate fallacy ( β=0.19, p<0.01), the level of illusion of control ( β=0.36, p<0.001), the level of law of small numbers ( β=0.26, p<0.001), and the level of regression fallacy ( β=0.25, p<0.001) all have positive impact on risk-taking propensity. However, hindsight bias has a negative relationship with risk-taking propensity (β=-0.73, p<0.01). Hypothesis 2 concerns the relationships between the experiential system and rational system and risk-taking propensity. The rational system has a negative relationship with risk- taking propensity ( β=0.-0.17, p<0.01), while the relationship between the experiential system and risk-taking propensity is insignificant. Thus, we can conclude that hypothesis 2 is partly confirmed. Hypothesis 3 suggests a positive relationship between the experiential system and the biases and a negative relationship between the rational system and the biases. Figure 3.2 shows that the experiential system has positive impact on the level of hindsight bias ( β=0.25, p<0.001), the level of illusory correlation ( β=0.38, p<0.001), the level of overconfidence (β=0.29, p<0.001), the level of illusion of control (β=0.22, p<0.001), the level of the law of small numbers ( β=0.38, p<0.001), and the level of regression fallacy ( β=0.13, p<0.05). The rational system has negative impact on the level of hindsight bias ( β=-0.31, p<0.001), the level of overconfidence ( β=-0.26, p<0.001), the level of illusion of control ( β=-0.28, p<0.001), and the level of regression fallacy ( β=-0.12, p<0.05). Contrary to hypothesis 3, the relationships between the experiential system and the level of base-rate fallacy is insignificant. This also holds for the relationship between the rational system and the level of illusory correlation, the level of base-rate fallacy and the level of the law of small numbers.

66  The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking 3.6. Discussion

3.6.1 Major research findings and theoretical implications In this study, we explore how reason and intuition of entrepreneurs form their cognitive biases that in return influence their risk-taking propensity. Using the dual process theory, we link the cognitive and risk-seeking streams of research. The first stream assumes that in their intuitive decision-making, entrepreneurs are unconscious of the actual risks associated with their decisions; they simply do not see them due to cognitive biases (Simon, Houghton and Aquino, 2000). The second stream assumes that entrepreneurs objectively tolerate more risks, that they are risk-seeking and that they consciously take the risks (Stewart and Roth, 2001; 2004). Using the dual process theory, we show that both perspectives do not exclude, but rather complement each other. In this study, we also follow the recent theoretical developments in other fields by conceptually separating heuristics from biases. These developments suggest that heuristics are the drivers of intuition, while biases are the errors arising due to the use of such heuristics in intuitive thinking (Kahneman, 2003; Kahneman and Frederick, 2002). These refinements allow us to critically assess the different statements and assumptions about entrepreneurial decision-making made by both the cognitive and risk- taking stream of research. As a result, this study improves our understanding of the entrepreneurial decision-making in the following four ways. First, recent theoretical developments in the behavioral decision-making suggested that the traditional cognitive biases are an output of intuition (Kahneman, 2003; Kahneman and Frederick, 2002). However, the results of our study show that it is not always true. Among the seven biases we studied, one bias – base-rate fallacy – is independent of intuitive thinking. Base-rate fallacy occurs when qualitative, often irrelevant information is used to make a probability judgment, ignoring available statistical information about prior probabilities (the base-rate frequency) (Tversky and Kahneman, 1974). It is an interesting case for the dual process theory because our results show that base-rate fallacy is associated with neither experiential nor rational system use, but is still significantly related to risk-taking propensity. A possible explanation is that this bias is not driven by heuristics. At the same time, the base-rate fallacy has many shapes and forms, therefore this finding should not preclude future research. Thus, base-rate fallacy is a unique bias that is just there, influencing entrepreneurial risk-taking irrespectively of how intuitively or rationally entrepreneurs think.

The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking  67 Therefore, the intuitive nature of the cognitive biases should be assumed with certain precautions. Second, in line with the previous statement, previous studies postulated that cognitive biases are a product of non-rational, intuitive thinking, thereby implicitly suggesting that entrepreneurs only have to take their time and think the matter thoroughly through in order to make the biases disappear (Busenitz and Barney, 1997). By introducing rational thinking into our theoretical model, we were able to test this assumption. In fact, thinking rationally can lower the level of only four of the seven biases we studied. This means that illusory correlation, base-rate fallacy and law of small numbers require special debiasing procedures in order to be corrected. Thus, further research should explore which debiasing procedures work for entrepreneurs and what their input is into the quality of decision-making and ventures' performance.

Table 3.3. Evaluation of alternative full models in LISREL Chi-square p RMSEA DELTA2 CFI NFI NNFI (df)

Hypothesized Model 943.48 (468) 0.000 0.059 0.97 0.96 0.93 0.96

Alternative Model (1): A path was suggested from 896.92 (467) 0.000 0.057 0.97 0.97 0.94 0.96 overconfidence to regression fallacy Alternative Model (2): An extra path was suggested 859.86 (466) 0.000 0.054 0.97 0.97 0.94 0.96 from hindsight bias to law of small numbers

In the main model, the illusory correlation and the law of small numbers biases can not be directly corrected by the rational system. However, our alternative models suggested by the Langrangian multiplier indexes (see Table 3.3) show that there may be a direct positive relationship between hindsight bias and the law of small numbers. In this model, there is a significant negative indirect effect of the rational system on the law of small numbers, which means that potentially there is an indirect correction of the law of small numbers via the hindsight bias. This suggests that there may be a more refined certain internal structure between the biases than previously acknowledged. Some biases may be "deeper", evoking

68  The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking other biases. The existence of an internal structure between the biases may also explain the insignificant effect of the rational system on illusory correlation. Future empirical research is necessary to check for such internal structure, and if it exists, explain it theoretically. Third, previous studies found that cognitive biases lead to greater risk-taking, e.g. in terms of decision to start a new venture or to launch a pioneering product (Simon et al., 2000; Simon and Houghton, 2003). Strikingly, our results show that higher levels of biases do not always mean more risk-taking: hindsight bias has a negative effect on risk-taking propensity instead of the hypothesized positive effect. It means that the more entrepreneurs tend to correct a posteriori their mental representation of their a priori judgment, the fewer risks they tend to take. This relationship suggests that risk-takers among entrepreneurs do not tend to have the hindsight bias. Risk-takers, on the contrary, accept their errors and learn better from their mistakes than non risk-takers. Hindsight bias is the only bias we researched that explicitly concerns the past, suggesting that entrepreneurs treat the future and the past differently. They may have the rose-colored glasses when they discover an opportunity, but they become sober-minded when exploiting it. Hindsight bias distorts interpretation of and learning from mistakes. Previous studies suggested that such distortions make strategic decision-making in general and risk management in particular problematic (e.g. McGrarth, 1999). The negative effect of the hindsight bias on risk-taking propensity is also the reason why the total indirect effect of the rational system on risk-taking propensity is insignificant. Further research should considerer these explanations. Finally, our study supports the statement that entrepreneurs are predominantly intuitive decision-makers (Busenitz and Barney, 1997; Simon et al., 2000). Consistent with this statement, entrepreneurs in our sample also score significantly higher on the experiential system than on the rational system (see Table 3.1). However, our findings also emphasize that entrepreneurs are not purely intuitive "creatures. The results showed that the total standardized effects (i.e. including the indirect effects via the biases) of the experiential and rational system on risk-taking propensity are of comparable magnitude (0.28 and -0.25 respectively). This means that although entrepreneurs tend to rely more on their intuition and on rational thinking, both types of thinking have strong impact on entrepreneurial risk-taking. Therefore, the rational side of entrepreneurs is as important as their intuitive decision-making and should not be left out of entrepreneurship research.

The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking  69 Our findings have several important theoretical implications. First, we used the dual process theory to show that rational and intuitive thinking have two distinct effects on entrepreneurial risk-taking propensity. Intuitive and rational thinking are not two extremes of the same concept, but rather two independent systems of thought that can be both extensively used (or not) by entrepreneurs. Second, past studies concentrated on three biases with a special focus on overconfidence (e.g. Forbes, 2005; Simon et al., 2000; Simon and Houghton, 2003). By more than doubling the scope of cognitive biases studied in the entrepreneurship literature simultaneously, we show that limiting such scope may lead to missing the bigger picture. Biases do not have to have similar effects on entrepreneurial actions – they may actually have opposite effects as we show on the example of hindsight bias. We also show that biases are not equally easy to correct, that some biases "lie deeper" than the others do and that there is potentially an internal structure between the biases. Third, by adding a new set of antecedents for risk-taking propensity we revealed the more stable part of cognitive biases. We therefore contribute to the longstanding debate on the context vs. trait nature of the cognitive biases (Baron, 1998; Busenitz and Barney, 1997; Forbes, 2005). Finally, we developed new highly reliable measures for cognitive biases that can be used in future research.

3.6.2 Managerial implications Entrepreneurs can use this model for self-assessment in order to determine to what extent biases contaminate their decision-making. The cognitive biases create a considerable difference between the level of riskiness the entrepreneur himself experiences, and the level of riskiness someone else with similar background and knowledge would observe in these entrepreneur's actions (e.g. Simon et al., 2000). In other words, it creates a difference between the objective risky "reality" and the subjective risky "reality" of the entrepreneur. As a result, entrepreneurial risk-taking propensity becomes unbalanced. Risk-taking propensity has a significant influence in a variety of domains: for example, it determines to the largest extent the marketing program creativity (Andrews and Smith, 1996), influences whether companies choose for acquisitions or licensing to acquire technologies (Steensma and Corley, 2001) and whether they introduce pioneering new products (Simon and Houghton, 2003). Thus, balancing and purifying risk-taking propensity means improving the decision-making in these domains.

70  The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking Scoring high on the level of biases in such an assessment would mean that entrepreneurs have to de-bias their decision-making. This study has simple yet powerful implications on how to get rid of the cognitive biases and balance entrepreneurial risk-taking. The traditional literature on such "debiasing" has focused on the context and task characteristics to design a specific bias-dependent intervention and these strategies vary a lot (e.g. Fischhoff, 1982). However, our results indicate that the more entrepreneurs use the rational system, the less problematic are the cognitive biases. This is true for the hindsight bias, overconfidence, illusion of control, regression fallacy and potentially for law of small numbers. Thus, in order to get rid of these biases, entrepreneurs should simply take the time and think. At the same time, this does not by any sense mean that intuitive thinking should be avoided. Intuition still provides the most efficient way to facilitate the entrepreneurial decision making. What is necessary are the corrective actions from the rational thinking applied to the intuitive thinking. There is however one exception among the biases: hindsight bias. Scoring high on hindsight bias means that the entrepreneur has difficulties learning from the past mistakes. The higher entrepreneurs score on hindsight bias, the fewer risks they take. The results are disastrous: due to this bias, entrepreneurs will fail to learn properly from their mistakes, while taking fewer and fewer risks – eventually this will likely lead to failure of the venture. Because of the lower propensity to take risks, ex-entrepreneur will not likely start a new company and a potential serial entrepreneur will disappear. Thus, hindsight bias is probably the most serious of the cognitive biases. Finally, entrepreneurs may use our model as a guiding tool for their decisions to hire personnel, in particular when hiring new members of the management team. Knowing the driving forces behind their risk-taking propensities may help avoid making unrealistically optimistic decisions regarding new product development, introduction and promotion (Andrews and Smith, 1996; Simon and Houghton, 2003).

3.6.3 Limitations The measurement scale for a given construct should cover the main conceptual domains for this construct (Churchill, 1979). We measured the rational system by the Need for Cognition scale (Cacioppo, Petty, Feinstein and Jarvis, 1996; Epstein et al., 1996). Although this scale is extensively used within the dual process theory, it originally comes

The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk-taking  71 from a different field and does not cover all the conceptual domains set by the rational system definition. An extensive list of these domains can be found for example, in Epstein et al. (1996) and Kahneman (2003). Similarly, Faith in Intuition scale used to measure the experiential system does not fully cover the conceptual domains of this system. Therefore, future research should bridge this gap between theory and measurement. In our research design, we intentionally linked the questions about overconfidence and hindsight bias to the same context in order to be able to directly compare their effects. In particular, answers on the hindsight bias are anchored to answers on the overconfidence bias (see Appendix A3.1). However, we did not find any significant multicollinearity effects between the two constructs. Moreover, we put the overconfidence and hindsight bias questions as far away from each other as possible within the questionnaire. Since it took our respondents about 40-45 minutes to fill in the questionnaire, the time lag between answering the overconfidence questions and answering the hindsight bias questions should be sufficient (Campbell and Tesser, 1983). However, future research with a measure of the hindsight bias with a greater time lag is necessary in order to validate our findings. Alternatively, completely independent measures of overconfidence and hindsight biases may be used. Finally, our dataset consisted of relatively experienced entrepreneurs. In particular, their mean number of years of entrepreneurial experience was 14.5, about 90% are serial entrepreneurs and about 70% were involved in two or three ventures at the same time. On one hand, it means that the problems we identified with the influence biases on entrepreneurial risk-taking are even more profound and that they do not disappear with experience. On the other hand, it is interesting to explore whether these findings hold for less experienced entrepreneurs as well. Moreover, it becomes essential for further research to account for entrepreneurial experience when fine-tuning the cognitive appraisal dimensions of emotions to the population of entrepreneurs.

Risk and uncertainty management strategies  73

Chapter 4

Risk and uncertainty management strategies

In this study, we show that the general intuition that it is better to manage risks and uncertainty than not to manage at all is not true. We do so by exploring the performance consequences of traditional risk and uncertainty management and recently emerged real options reasoning. First, we elaborate on how exactly the strategies from these perspectives manage risk and uncertainty. Then we use real options theory to develop hypotheses about performance consequences of these strategies and changes in their effects in case of markets with established (vs. emerging) technology standards and high (vs. low) network externality effects. We test our hypotheses on a sample of 420 new technology ventures. The results strongly indicate that new technology ventures should avoid being excessively cautious when entering new markets. New technology ventures should also think twice before imitating other firms. Strategies that do generally improve performance are strategic control, strategic cooperation and real options strategy. While existing technology standards appear to have predominantly direct effect on performance of new technology ventures, risk and uncertainty management strategies do perform differently in markets with high direct and indirect network externality effects. Our study contributes to the network externality literature by showing that the effects of direct and indirect network externalities can be actually of opposite direction. We contribute to the real options theory by falsifying one of its main assumptions: real options work better under the conditions of higher uncertainty. Our results show that it is clearly not the case when uncertainty arises from the absence of established technology standards or from presence of direct network externality effects on the firm's market. Finally yet importantly, our results support the theoretical distinction between the

74  Risk and uncertainty management strategies traditional risk management and the real options reasoning by showing that these two types of strategies can have opposite effects in certain circumstances.

4.1 Introduction

If entrepreneurship is about creating new ends or means-ends relationships (Shane and Venkataraman, 2000), then risk and uncertainty are an essential part of all entrepreneurial actions. Thus, the question is not so much about how to get rid of risk and uncertainty, but how to manage them in more general terms. For example, risk management may among others include increasing the level of potential downside loss, i.e. risk, in order to make greater revenues possible. Uncertainty management may include both decreasing uncertainty or leaving it unchanged while cutting it into pieces. So how should new technology ventures manage risk and uncertainty? Although they are often tied together, risk and uncertainty are distinct concepts. Risk is one of the most controversial concepts in the strategic management literature, often criticized for having conceptualizations different from the ones used in the real world (Ruefli, Collins and Lacugna, 1999). Using the insights of the studies of managerial and entrepreneurial risk-taking, we define risk as the downside loss – the maximum possible amount that an entrepreneurial firm may loose. Probability is sometimes included in the definition of risk, however prior studies have shown that the risk in terms of amount of potential loss is more salient to managers and entrepreneurs (March and Shapira, 1987; Sarasvathy, Simon and Lave, 1998). The definitions of uncertainty suffer from their divergence focusing on different drivers such as dynamism, complexity and lack of knowledge instead of the core phenomenon: inability to predict future outcomes. As opposed to risk, uncertainty involves unpredictability: for entrepreneurs, it is unpredictability of the venture payoffs. Uncertainty can be categorized into different types and sources, such as technology, customer, competitor and operational uncertainty (Atuahene-Gima and Li, 2004; Bstieler, 2005; Huchzermeier and Loch, 2001). In this study we will mainly focus on risks and uncertainties arising from the external environment of the venture. Because risk and uncertainty are two different although related concepts, managing risk does not necessarily mean managing uncertainty. Moreover, several ways to manage risk and uncertainty are known.

Risk and uncertainty management strategies  75 Strategies may target both risk and uncertainty at the same time. There are two main streams of strategic management literature studying risk and uncertainty management: one investigating traditional risk management strategies and the other investigating the real options strategy. The strategies from the first stream focus on risk mitigation. For example, risk is immediately reduced in case of strategic avoidance and strategic imitation with little or no additional investments, while strategic control and strategic cooperation involve an additional investment before the level of risk or its probability will decrease (Miller, 1992). The second stream involves the real options strategy, which is also known as the real options reasoning, thinking or logic (Miller and Shapira, 2004; McGrath, 1997,1999). It is a qualitative way to use the real options theory. Under this strategy, firms pursue multiple product options with high growth potential and thus high uncertainty, and invest further in a product option only if uncertainty has been resolved and conditions are favorable. By doing so, firms take calculated risks and create strategic flexibility (McGrath, 1999; McGrath, Ferrier and Mendelow, 2004). Despite the different foci of these two streams, they provide a way to manage both risks and uncertainties simultaneously. There are also things we do not know yet about entrepreneurial risk and uncertainty management. First, the two main streams of research produced five dominant strategies to manage risk and uncertainty. All of these strategies should treat risk and uncertainty differently (Miller, 1992). However, the precise conceptual differences between these strategies are not well elaborated in the literature. The second void refers to the relationship between the risk and uncertainty management strategies and performance: not all strategies are empirically proven to enhance performance. Within the area of real options, a noticeable theoretical effort has been made recently to advance our understanding of the qualitative way to use the real options theory (e.g. Adner and Levinthal, 2004a,b; McGrath et al., 2004). However, the empirical tests of these developments still lag behind. The third gap follows from the previous one and concerns environmental contingencies: under which market and technology development conditions should entrepreneurs choose for which strategies? In our study, we focus on new technology ventures, i.e. spending at least 3% of their total sales on R&D and not older than 15 years (Li and Atuahene-Gima, 2001; Song, Podoynitsyna, van der Bij, Halman, 2008). In order to fill the aforementioned gaps, we first conceptually investigate the differences between the two streams of research: one focusing on the traditional risk management strategies and the other focusing on the real options strategy. We elaborate on them using the dimensions suggested by Bowman and Hurry (1993) as

76  Risk and uncertainty management strategies important in terms of firm performance consequences, i.e. approach to risk, approach to uncertainty and size and timing of investments. Second, we empirically test the new venture performance consequences of five different strategies to manage risk and uncertainty. Third, we investigate the potential contingencies by focusing on two market conditions: pursuing an opportunity in a market with well-accepted industry standards vs. a situation when no standards are known, and pursuing an opportunity in a market with high vs. low network externalities. Both of these market and industry characteristics are crucial for new technology ventures, which research, develop and promote technology-intensive products. Bidding on the right technology that will later on comprise the dominant design in the industry determines to a great extent success of the product (Warner, Fairbank and Steensma, 2006). Network externalities facilitate dominant design selection and increase the likelihood that a given technology standard will be selected as part of the dominant design (Schilling, 2002). Ignoring these two factors can be lethal for a new technology venture, requiring that the venture adjusts its strategies according to these market and industry conditions. Thus, we intend to make a three-fold contribution to the strategic management and entrepreneurship fields. First, we conceptually clarify the differences between the various traditional risk management strategies and real options strategy. Second, we empirically validate performance consequences of both types of strategies. Third, we empirically explore under which circumstances each of the two major types of risk and uncertainty management strategies performs best. This chapter is organized as follows. In the theoretical background section, we present our conceptual model, give background information about the two main streams of research on risk and uncertainty management and describe the differences between the streams. Then we formulate hypotheses regarding the impact of both major types of risk and uncertainty management strategies on new venture performance and the moderating effect of market conditions on these relationships. In the following two sections, we describe the methodological grounds of the study and our results. We finish with a discussion of theoretical and managerial implications of this study, its limitations, and future research directions.

Risk and uncertainty management strategies  77

4.2 Theoretical framework

The core topic in our conceptual model are risk and uncertainty management strategies of entrepreneurial firms. We see ventures choose different strategies. In this study, we compare two major ways to manage risks and uncertainties with respect to their performance consequences: the real options strategy and the more traditional risk and uncertainty management strategies. For simplicity reasons we will call the latter traditional risk management strategies. Traditional risk management strategies target risk and uncertainty mitigation by strategic avoidance, strategic imitation, strategic control, or strategic cooperation (Miller, 1992). Real options strategy is a firm's strategy to manage risk and uncertainty by pursuing multiple product options with high growth potential and high uncertainty, while further investments into a product option are only made if uncertainty has been resolved and conditions are favorable (McGrath, 1999; McGrath et al., 2004). The real options strategy is also known as the real options reasoning, thinking or logic (Miller and Shapira, 2004; McGrath, 1997, 1999). In this study, we examine under which circumstances each of the two ways of managing risk and uncertainty performs best for entrepreneurial firms. We consider two types of circumstances. First, we examine the effects of the existence or non-existence of technology standards in the firm's primary served market. Second, we study the presence of high network externalities in the firm's primary served market. We present our conceptual model in Figure 4.1. Below, we will first discuss the two types of risk management strategies in more detail and then cover the performance effects of these strategies. Afterwards, we will present the two market conditions and their expected moderator effects.

4.2.1 Traditional risk management strategies The approach to risk management has evolved over time. The traditional approach concentrates on strategies for direct reduction of risk and uncertainty, although there are also more refined differences in how these strategies approach risk and uncertainty. The traditional

78  Risk and uncertainty management strategies

Figure 4.1. The conceptual model risk management strategies consist of four main approaches: strategic avoidance, strategic imitation, strategic control, and strategic cooperation 5. For all these four strategies, eventual uncertainty is resolved only after the decision to follow a particular strategy is chosen. These strategies assume investments irreversibility and full commitment. Decisions are made at the beginning of the project. Strategic avoidance occurs when management considers risks and uncertainties associated with operating in a given product or geographic market to be unacceptable. For firms already active in the market, avoidance may involve exiting the market. For firms that are not yet active on the market or have recently entered it – as is the case with new ventures

5 We decided to exclude Miller's (1992) flexibility strategy from the list of traditional risk management strategies in order to ensure content and discriminant validity of the strategy constructs, because flexibility is also an essential part of the real options strategy (McGrath et al., 2004).

Risk and uncertainty management strategies  79 – this strategy may include postponement of operations for which risks are considered unacceptable, initial product introduction to low uncertainty market niches or growth from small scale (Miller, 1992; Shane, 2003). This strategy allows avoiding risk by reducing the marketing and variable production costs. However, its disadvantage is that it decreases potential returns as well. Strategic avoidance decreases market uncertainty by choosing the alternative, more predictable markets. An advantage of this strategy is that it does not require any additional investments. Strategic imitation refers to copying rivals' strategies and technologies (Miller, 1992). Although firms can pursue either differentiation or imitation strategy, they often choose for matching the behavior of rivals in an effort to reduce the risk (Lieberman and Asaba, 2006). Imitation occurs when the firm's products are similar to the main competitors' products, or when manufacturing techniques or product technologies are adopted from other firms. This strategy decreases the risk by reducing the R&D costs and decreases both technology and market uncertainty by copying the actions of competitors. The additional investment necessary for imitation are the costs for information gathering. Strategic control refers to strategies targeted on controlling important environmental contingencies. Strategic control may comprise creating entry barriers to make entry of new competitors problematic. It also may include attempts to increase influence on customers through advertising, and to control supplier relationships by using contractual agreements. Finally, mergers may be negotiated with competitors. This strategy is distinct from strategic avoidance and strategic imitation because it assumes direct interaction with the firm's environment. Prior studies suggest that managers prefer to control environmental variables over considering them as constraints within which they have to operate (Miller, 1992). The control strategy is different from the other three traditional risk management strategies (i.e., strategic avoidance, strategic imitation, strategic cooperation) because it is the only strategy that actually increases the level of risk by the costs necessary to realize this strategy. At the same time, it decreases the probability that the risk will occur and increases the probability of greater returns by controlling the environment. Control strategy decreases market uncertainty by making the actions of the market players more predictable. It involves additional investments in the form of advertising, merger realization and contract arrangement costs. Strategic cooperation refers to involvement in multilateral agreements with other firms (Miller, 1992). Strategic cooperation is relatively well elaborated in prior studies (e.g. Li and

80  Risk and uncertainty management strategies Atuahene-Gima, 2001; Das and Teng, 1998a, 1998b). Risks under strategic cooperation strategy are reduced by sharing with partner(s), resulting in behavioral interdependence between the partners and a reduction of the autonomy of each partner. Cooperative strategies may include joint R&D, joint manufacturing, or joint marketing and sales (Li and Atuahene- Gima, 2001). The cooperation strategy may reduce both technology and market uncertainties. This strategy typically cuts the NPD risk in half, but adds an additional risk of the partner's opportunistic behavior (Das and Teng, 1998a, 1998b). Cooperation decreases the risk by sharing it with the partner(s), however it may also increase returns if there is a synergy between partners' competences allowing to improve the product quality. Strategic cooperation strategy may decrease both technology and market uncertainty by tapping into the expertise of the partner(s). The additional investments necessary for this strategy consist of costs for arranging and maintaining the cooperation.

4.2.2 Real options strategy Real options theory offers an alternative for traditional risk management (Miller and Arikan, 2004). Our use of the real options theory for the exploration of risk management strategies originates from the stream of literature focusing on real options reasoning, logic or thinking (McGrath, 1999; Miller and Arikan, 2004), what McGrath et al. (2004) also called "options reasoning as a heuristic for strategy" and Bowman and Hurry (1993) called "flexibility options". Real options strategy preaches choosing new products with high revenue potential and inherent high payoffs uncertainty and is therefore most useful in case of high technology and/or market uncertainty. At the same time, this strategy involves waiting until uncertainty resolves (or decreases below a certain threshold) before fully committing resources. The main motivation for the real options strategy is increasing final returns. Real options theory allows the decisions to be made both before and after the uncertainty surrounding these decisions has been resolved (Huchzermeier and Loch, 2001). Real options strategy is stricter in this sense because it has an assumption of actions and decision making only after the uncertainties are resolved and the conditions are favorable (McGrath, 1999; Adner and Levinthal, 2004a; 2004b). The core idea of a real option can be formulated as a limited commitment that creates future decision rights (McGrath et al., 2004). Similar to options on financial securities, real options involve discretionary decisions or rights, with no obligations, to acquire or exchange

Risk and uncertainty management strategies  81 the value of the underlying asset for a specified price (Panayi and Trigeorgis, 1998). One characteristic common for new technology ventures is that they have to develop at least one product with a considerable amount of R&D. Thus, the underlying assets for our real options strategy are the new products of the venture. There are six types of real options: option to defer, option to abandon, option to expand or contract, switching option and option to improve (Huchzermeier and Loch, 2001; Trigeorgis, 1993). Defer option refers to waiting until more information becomes available. Abandonment option refers to investment in stages, deciding at each stage, based on newest information, whether to proceed or stop. Expansion/contraction option refers to the possibility to adjust the scale of investment depending on whether market conditions turn out favorably. Switching option refers to changing the mode of operation of an asset, depending on factor prices (e.g. switching the energy source of a plant, or switching raw material suppliers). Improvement option refers to midcourse actions during R&D projects to improve the performance of the products; or to correct their targeting to market needs. For the real options strategy, the final decision delay is essential because a real option gives decision rights in the future and conveys access to future opportunities (Huchzermeier and Loch, 2001; McGrath et al., 2004). There is always a certain time period between option creation and option exercise, otherwise the full commitment would be immediately possible and option creation would be redundant. This time period is necessary in order to receive new information about the developments of the asset underlying the option (new products in our case), which allows for better decision-making. However, even more important, if the option exercise stage was not already conceived at the time of the initial investment, such strategy cannot be characterized as a real options strategy and cannot be distinguished from other less structured investment activities (Adler and Levinthal, 2004a,b). A simulation study by Miller and Arikan (2004) arrived at similar conclusions. Therefore, a real options strategy is a deliberate strategy and there should be a number of in advance formulated criteria as to what outcomes merit continuation with the option. As a result, firms that use real options strategy should show a higher percent of paused and stopped NPD projects than other firms (Adler and Levinthal, 2004a,b). In this study, we will take the above-mentioned considerations into account. The real options strategy limits downside risk (the maximum is the investment to create the option) and increases returns by staged investments. It manages uncertainties by

82  Risk and uncertainty management strategies breaking down the total uncertainty into different, manageable parts at each investment stage. The real options strategy further allows to manage both technology and market uncertainty by creating flexibility, so that how uncertainty is resolved becomes less important or not important at all: the venture has a solution to tackle it. Under this strategy, firms choose new products with high revenue potential and inherent high uncertainty of payoffs. The investments necessary for the real options strategy are additional R&D costs to ensure design flexibility, costs for additional equipment or equipment with more capacity, etc.

4.2.3 Performance consequences of risk management strategies Any new venture may choose from five different risk and uncertainty management strategies described above. In Table 4.1, we summarize the main differences between these strategies in terms of how they approach risk and uncertainty, as well as size and timing of investments necessary for each strategy. These dimensions follow the ones proposed by Bowman and Hurry (1993) to discuss the performance advantages of the real options strategy. We elaborate further on them and extend them for the domain of traditional risk management strategies. Starting a venture comes together with embracing a priori irreducible uncertainty, stemming from the fact that entrepreneurs cannot precisely predict what the market demand for their products will be (Huchzermeier and Loch, 2001; McGrath, 1999; Shane and Venkataraman, 2000). Market payoff determines the extent to which a venture may be called a success and it is therefore crucial to tackle this uncertainty. Besides operational and timing aspects, market payoffs from new products are determined by both their price and characteristics. While price is relatively easy to change and can be experimented with to maximize the payoffs, the characteristics of the products are fixed at the moment of the product launch. Moreover, changing these characteristics and adapting the performance range of the products usually requires additional financing and increases time-to-market. This means that it is crucial for the venture that the product characteristics fit the actual market requirements. How can this risk be managed? In the previous sections we discussed the two major ways to manage risk and uncertainty: the traditional risk management strategies and the real options strategy.

Risk and uncertainty management strategies  83 Table 4.1. Characteristics of risk and uncertainty management strategies

Risk management strategies Dimensions Avoidance Imitation Control Cooperation Real options strategy Increases the level of risk Decreases the risk Decreases the by the costs necessary to Decreases the risk by by reducing the Risk is the price of the real risk by reducing realize this strategy, but sharing it with the Approach towards marketing and options creation. the R&D costs. decreases the probability partner(s), but may also risk (downside variable production Limits risk and increases

Risk May decrease of risk and increases the increase revenues if loss) costs. Also potential probability of greater product quality revenues by staged decreases potential revenues revenues by controlling improves investments revenues the environment Does not directly change the level of any uncertainty. Allows to manage both Decreases technology and market Decreases market technology and Decreases technology Approach towards Decreases market uncertainty by making uncertainty by market and market uncertainty uncertainty uncertainty by making the decisions in stages and choosing the uncertainty by by tapping into the (unpredictability of actions of the market creating flexibility, so that alternative, more copying the expertise of the payoffs) players more predictable how uncertainty is resolved Uncertainty Uncertainty predictable markets actions of partner(s) becomes less important. competitors Chooses new products with high revenue potential and inherent high uncertainty

84  Risk and uncertainty management strategies

Table 4.1. Characteristics of risk and uncertainty management strategies (continued)

Risk management strategies Dimensions Avoidance Imitation Control Cooperation Real options strategy Price for option creation: additional R&D costs, costs Costs for Costs for arranging and No additional Advertising, merger for additional equipment or information maintaining the investments. realization, contract equipment with more Additional gathering. cooperation. Investments are arrangement costs, etc. capacity, etc. Price for option investments Investments are assumed to be Investments are exercise: costs to make the assumed to be Investments are assumed irreversible assumed to be decision plus eventually irreversible to be irreversible irreversible investments due to full commitment Number of 2 decisions: option creation 1 decision 1 decision 1 decision 1 decision decisions and option exercise Partial until option exercise, Type of after that – full. Investing Full Full Full Full commitment further only if the previous Size and timing of investments timing investments and of Size stage meets certain criteria Timing of the full Before Before uncertainty Before uncertainty is Before uncertainty is commitment uncertainty is After uncertainty is resolved is resolved resolved resolved decision resolved

Risk and uncertainty management strategies  85 We first focus on traditional risk management strategies. These strategies are applied immediately after the risk has been detected. They all impact performance, but in a different way. Strategic avoidance and strategic imitation save marketing, variable product and R&D costs, while they increase the predictability of the financial payoffs. Therefore, these strategies will have positive impact on new venture performance. Strategic control does not allow any savings and only involves additional investments; thus, this strategy actually increases downside loss. However, it also allows to significantly increase the revenues . Therefore, we expect a positive impact of this strategy on new venture performance. Finally, strategic cooperation will have positive impact on new venture performance, since it may allow both to save costs and increase revenues. George, Zahra, Wheatley and Kahn (2001), George, Zahra and Wood (2002), and McDougall, Covin, Robinson and Herron (1994) also found a positive relationship between cooperation and new venture performance. Therefore, we hypothesize: Hypothesis 1. Applying traditional risk management strategies – strategic avoidance, strategic imitation, strategic control and strategic cooperation – have a positive impact on new venture performance.

Real options strategy allows for small initial investments to create a potential performance range of the products that fits with perceived market requirement variability. After uncertainty resolves, ventures may choose options with best perspectives and fully invest in them. Not all of the created options will be exercised, but such options create the flexibility necessary to realize a better, thorough match between product specifications and the ultimate market requirements. Therefore, we expect that real options strategy has a positive impact on new venture performance. Thus, we hypothesize: Hypothesis 2. Applying real options strategy has a positive impact on new venture performance.

4.2.4 Moderator: Technology standards In markets where technology standards are well-accepted or formalized, entrepreneurial ventures may act differently compared to markets with emerging or unknown standards. When technologies compete within a particular market the entrepreneurial venture may face a lot of uncertainty. It is hard to predict which technology will prevail and selecting

86  Risk and uncertainty management strategies the wrong technology may result in a huge downside loss (Christensen, Suarez and Utterback, 1998). When a particular technology standard wins over the other alternative standards, the technological uncertainty drastically reduces. A venture wanting to develop and introduce a new product for this market will not have to choose between competing standards anymore. Moreover, the customer requirements will also become clearer. As a result, the potential payoffs will become more certain. Assuming that comparable investments are necessary for alternative technologies and that an independent venture is not likely to fully commit to more than one technology at the same time, the risk (downside loss) will not change. However, the probability of such a risk will decrease, because one of the possible reasons why a venture may fail – betting on the wrong technology – is eliminated. This view is consistent with the evolutionary perspective. Tushman and Anderson (1986, 1997) introduced technology cycles in their evolutionary perspective. These cycles are composed of technological discontinuities that trigger periods of technological and competitive ferment. These turbulent periods are closed with the emergence of a technology standard or a dominant design in the industry as a synthesis of a number of proven concepts. Then a period of diminished ferment comes up. During this period incremental changes in the technology or the dominant design are developed, resulting in a relatively low uncertainty. When technology standards are well known, in general the traditional risk management strategies will have less positive performance consequences. Most of these strategies require extra costs, while part of their effect, in terms of risk and uncertainty reduction, already has been realized autonomously by the selection of the technology standards within the industry. Below, we will explain this for each strategy, strategic avoidance, strategic imitation, strategic control, and strategic cooperation, separately. Strategic avoidance mainly targets to reduce market uncertainty and marketing costs. In markets with known (as opposed to unknown) technology standards, customer requirements become clearer, decreasing the market uncertainty. Choosing for avoidance strategy in this relatively certain market means that the new venture will choose for even more certain market segments within this market and grow from small scale. As a result, avoidance strategy will be less useful in such markets since the market uncertainty is already reduced. Therefore, we expect less positive performance consequences of this strategy when technology standards are known, compared to the situation when technology standards are unknown.

Risk and uncertainty management strategies  87 Strategic imitation is targeted to reduce technology and market uncertainty and R&D costs. Extra costs for information gathering are spent. In a situation with known technology standards, spending of these extra costs is a waste, since technology and market uncertainty already decreased by selection of technology standards, while R&D costs only have to be spent to develop the technology selected. So, we expect that compared to a situation with unknown technology standards, also this strategy has less positive performance consequences. Strategic control targets to reduce market uncertainty by controlling market players through advertising, merging, contracting etc. Of course, these actions need some investments and in circumstances of known technology standards, these investments are (partly) a waste since market uncertainty already has been decreased by selection of the technology standards, thus resulting in less positive performance consequences of this strategy, compared to a situation with unknown technology standards. Strategic cooperation targets to decrease technology and market uncertainty, as well as risk by sharing it. Time investments have to be made to search a partner and build a partnership. Again in a situation of known technology standards, these investments are (partly) wasted because of the resolution of technology and market uncertainty by selection of the technology standards. Therefore, we expect less positive performance consequences of this strategy when technology standards are known, compared to the situation when technology standards are unknown. Thus, we hypothesize: Hypothesis 3. Well-accepted technology standards will negatively moderate the relationship between the traditional risk management strategies strategic avoidance, strategic imitation, strategic control, and strategic cooperation and new venture performance.

When technology standards are not known yet, real options strategy offers the opportunity to make small investments in more than one technology, thus experimenting with the technologies and learning from it (Bowman and Hurry, 1993). However, when standards are accepted, from a technological perspective it is more effective to make large investments in the technology at once. In such situation the performance advantage of the real options strategy will decrease.

88  Risk and uncertainty management strategies Therefore, we hypothesize: Hypothesis 4. Well-accepted technology standards will negatively moderate the relationship between real options strategy and new venture performance.

4.2.5 Moderator: Network externalities The economic perspective suggests that there are two types of network externalities: direct and indirect externalities. Direct externalities come into existence through a direct physical effect of the number of users on the quality of the product. There is an increase in product value associated with having additional users in the network (Katz and Shapiro, 1986). The benefits that a customer derives from buying a telephone or fax machine, clearly depends on the number of other users of the telephone or fax network. Indirect network externalities come into existence when complementary products or services are of importance for the value of the product (Schilling, 2002). One can think of traffic requiring highways, DVD players requiring movies on DVD, and computer software requiring hardware (Rohlfs, 1974; Katz and Shapiro, 1986). New technology ventures act differently in markets with network externality effects as opposed to markets without these effects. Network externality effects in a market enhance the potential value of the products in that market, and, thereby, the likelihood of higher revenues of the firm. However, sales of a product have to reach a critical mass point in the first place, before the mechanism of network effects will be activated. This is exactly the problem that every new venture in such a market will experience. Only from the critical mass point will the value obtained from the good or service be greater or equal to the price paid for it (Wärneryd, 1990). In markets with network externality effects, the initial market uncertainty will be higher: the customers have to rely on primary features of the product, while it remains uncertain whether they will eventually get the additional benefits from the network effect. There is a chance that a venture's product(s) will not reach the critical mass point, while its competitors' product will. This in turn makes the customers hesitate before choosing for a particular product and raises the market uncertainty level. At the same time, assuming that the investments would be comparable, only the probability of failing in such markets will be higher while the potential downside loss will remain the same as in markets without network externality effects.

Risk and uncertainty management strategies  89 Considering the high level of market uncertainty in markets with network externality effects, not all of the strategies we researched will be equally attractive. Some traditional risk management strategies will become more useful, others will become less useful. Among the traditional risk management strategies, the less useful ones are strategic avoidance and strategic imitation. Following the avoidance strategy will simply not let a venture enter such a market. A signal that a product is worth imitating in such a market is the fact that it reached the critical mass point and started benefiting from network externality effects. This means that the imitator's actions will always be lagged. The lag becomes even bigger since the imitator has to develop its product. Finally, the imitator also has to reach the critical mass point. This three-fold lag makes it less probable that the imitating venture ever benefits from network externality effects. The more useful strategies are strategic control and strategic cooperation. They directly influence both customers and competitors on the market. The control strategy tries to influence through establishing market entry barriers or through advertising. The cooperation strategy focuses on influencing customers through better promotion and distribution of the product. By cooperating in these activities, firms can afford bigger budgets and cover more potential customers, which allow them to reach the critical mass point faster. Therefore, we hypothesize: Hypothesis 5a. The higher the network externalities, the weaker the effect of strategic avoidance and strategic imitation on new venture performance.

Hypothesis 5b. The higher the network externalities, the stronger the effect of strategic control and strategic cooperation on new venture performance.

In markets with high network externalities (as opposed to low), there is a higher level of market uncertainty, as we explain below. Although the first intuition would suggest that in case of higher uncertainties the real options strategy would become more useful, we hypothesize otherwise for this moderator. Real options are created under the conditions of high uncertainty and exercised (or not) after the uncertainty has resolved. It is valuable because it creates flexibility to invest in a better option. However, the (additional) uncertainty due to high network externalities can be only resolved after the new products have been developed and launched – i.e. all the major investments have been made. This uncertainty emanates from the fact that it is not clear whether the product can be embedded and accepted

90  Risk and uncertainty management strategies in an already existing network of products, or whether the critical mass point will be reached in case a new network around the product must be created (Wärneryd, 1990). Therefore, the required number of sales is less easily guaranteed in markets with high network externalities as opposed to markets without network externalities. Extensive marketing efforts are required in order to overcome this additional uncertainty, otherwise the product may not gain the additional network benefits. These extra marketing efforts are not required in markets without network externalities. Therefore, we expect that real options strategy will be less positively related to new venture performance in markets with high network externalities, compared to markets with low network externalities. At the same time, a real option constitutes a limited commitment. Decisions are split in two phases – first, when an option is created and second, when an option is exercised (McGrath et al., 2004). The additional uncertainty in markets with high network externality effects will be only resolved after ventures have fully committed to a given product option and fully invested into it. It means that a venture applying real options strategy will either have to keep all the product options open and fully invest into them (which is costly), or choose one or two product options having less information than in markets with low network externalities. Because of the late uncertainty resolution in markets with high network externalities, ventures will be less accurate in their predictions about which product options will be more successful. This means that over the long run, ventures will show worse performance in markets with high externalities as opposed to markets with low externalities. Thus, we hypothesize: Hypothesis 6. The higher the network externalities, the weaker the effect of the real options strategy on new venture performance.

4.3 Methodology

4.3.1 Sample and data collection Our sampling frame consists of 11,029 venture-backed young technology firms in the VentureOne 2001 database and 982 new technology venture firms which were members of the 1995-2000 Inc 500 (a listing of the fastest-growing private companies in the United States, as selected by Inc magazine). The names of the contact person and contact information were obtained from VentureOne 2001 and the Dun & Bradstreet Market Identifiers database.

Risk and uncertainty management strategies  91 2,000 new technology ventures were randomly selected for the survey. In administering the survey, we followed the total design method for survey research (Dillman, 1978). The first mailing packet included a personalized letter, a project fact sheet, the survey, a priority postage-paid envelope with an individually-typed return-address label, and a list of research reports available to participants. The package was sent by priority mail to 2000 selected new ventures. 569 mailing packages were returned due to undeliverable addresses or names. Thus, the adjusted sample was 1,431 new technology ventures. To increase the response rate, we sent four follow-up mailings to the companies. One week after the mailing, we sent a follow-up letter. Two weeks after the first follow-up, we sent a second package with same content as the first package to all non-responding companies. After two additional follow-up letters, we received completed questionnaires from 420 firms, representing a response rate of 29% (420/1431). Our sample represents industries from electronic and electrical equipment (25%), pharmaceutical, drugs, & medicines (12%), industrial machinery & equipment (9%), telecommunications equipment (9%), semiconductors & computer related products (28%), instruments and related products (6%) and other industry segments (11%). The ventures in our sample have the ratio of R&D/revenues of 20% and above, which means that these ventures are highly R&D intensive.

4.3.2 Measurements In our survey, we used existing scales from the literature if possible. When there were no scales available we deduced items from the definitions, examples and ideas in the existing literature. Because of these new scales we had to pre-test the survey. We conducted a pre-test by extensively interviewing eleven entrepreneurs. In the beginning of each interview entrepreneurs told us about the background of their ventures, how they started, how they discovered the opportunity and how the business idea developed over the time. This allowed us to break the ice and better interpret their answers on the questionnaire. In the last part of the interview we used the protocol method and asked the entrepreneurs to "think aloud" as they filled out the English questionnaire (Hunt, Sparkman, Jr., and Wilcox, 1982). The interviews were recorded and two researchers made careful notes of the verbalizations and the thinking process of the entrepreneurs. The analysis of interviews led to changes in wording of instructions and items.

92  Risk and uncertainty management strategies Appendix A4.1 provides the construct reliabilities, the response format employed in the questionnaire, and the details of the measurement items used in this study. Dependent variable. We use three objective measures of new venture performance. First, we ask for return on investment (ROI) in the last fiscal year. Second, we ask for customer retention rate in the primary served market, and third, we measure the rate of sales growth in the last fiscal year. These measures are based on Lambert (1998) and McDougall et al. (1994). We treat these measures as three separate dependent variables. Independent variables. For the traditional strategic risk management strategies we mainly base ourselves on Miller (1992). The 3-item scale of strategic avoidance ( α=0.79) is based on Shane (2003) and Miller (1992), while the 3-item scale of strategic imitation (α=0.81) is taken from Miller (1992) and Gatignon and Xuereb (1997). Strategic control is measured with a 3-item scale ( α=0.86), taken from Miller (1992). Strategic cooperation is also measured with a 3-item scale ( α=0.65). This scale is based on Li and Atuahene-Gima (2001). Real options strategy is measured with a 3-item scale ( α=0.86), based on Huchzermeier and Loch (2001), and McGrath et al. (2004). It measures three basic sources of flexibility that are core for the concept of real options reasoning, following the approach of Churchill, Jr (1979). Moderating variables. The 1-item scale of technology standards is based on Warner et al. (2006). It measures whether the technology standard in the venture's primary served market is well-established or emerging. In our measurements we distinguish between direct and indirect network externalities (Katz and Shapiro, 1985; 1986). Direct network externalities is measured by 2 items ( α=0.72), based on Katz and Shapiro (1985; 1986), while indirect network externalities is measured by 1 item taken from Schilling (2002).

4.3.3 Analysis Table 4.2 displays the descriptive statistics and correlations for the variables in our conceptual model. In our sample, real options strategy is most extensively used, while strategic avoidance is least extensively applied.

Risk and uncertainty management strategies  93

Table 4.2. Descriptive statistics and correlation matrix Mean St.Dev. A B C D E F G H I G ROI A 76.85 78.94 Customer B 47.55 24.17 Retention 0.54 Sales growth C 126.79 66.09 0.49 0.84 Avoidance D 3.57 1.79 -0.08 -0.20 -0.18 Imitation E 4.89 1.15 0.19 0.42 0.45 -0.23 Control F 4.42 1.36 0.28 0.52 0.49 -0.03 0.37 Cooperation G 4.75 1.16 0.35 0.33 0.38 -0.03 0.15 0.17 Real Options H 5.10 1.33 0.30 0.53 0.57 0.00 0.47 0.39 0.28 Tech. Standards I 0.58 0.49 0.17 0.39 0.27 -0.03 0.01 0.07 -0.14 0.04 Direct Netw. Ext. G 4.36 1.74 0.05 0.27 0.21 0.19 0.23 0.07 0.10 0.42 0.04 Indirect Netw. Ext. K 4.75 1.97 0.12 0.41 0.30 -0.03 0.29 0.18 0.17 0.42 0.03 0.66 Correlations above |0.08| are significant at p= 0.05, above |0.12| at p= 0.01, and above |0.16| at p= 0.001

94  Risk and uncertainty management strategies We purified our measurement scales by performing a CFA using Maximum Likelihood estimation in LISREL 8.54. The analysis was carried out for our independent variables, the strategic risk management strategies. We reviewed each construct and deleted items that loaded on multiple constructs or had low item-to-construct loadings. The measurement model is presented in Table 4.3.

Table 4.3. Confirmatory factor analysis and Cronbach ααα's Construct Factor loadings and T-value Item Cronbach's ααα Avoidance α=0.79 AV1 0.85 17.91 AV2 0.70 14.55 AV3 0.72 15.01 Imitation α=0.81 IM1 0.71 15.31 IM2 0.87 20.08 IM3 0.72 15.80 Control α=0.86 CTR1 0.91 22.33 CTR2 0.67 14.85 CTR3 0.88 21.26 Cooperation α=0.65 CO1 0.83 13.38 CO2 0.62 10.87 CO3 0.42 7.58 Real options α=0.86 RO1 0.83 19.60 RO2 0.81 19.10 RO3 0.83 19.78 χ2=219.37, df=80; RMSEA=0.064; DELTA2=0.96; CFI=0.96; NFI=0.94; NNFI=0.94

In Table 4.3 we also report Cronbach α's. They range between 0.79 and 0.86 with an exception for strategic cooperation ( α is 0.65). These outcomes suggest good reliabilities (Nunnally, 1978). Our measurement model has an acceptable fit with χ2/ df is 2.74, RMSEA is 0.064, DELTA2 is 0.96, CFI is 0.69, NFI is 0.94 and NNFI is 0.94 (Hair, Anderson, Tatham and Black, 1998). All loadings on the respective constructs are highly significant (p<0.001), while standardized loadings of the items were in all cases but one, greater than 0.5. Therefore, our scales demonstrate convergent validity (Fornell and Larcker, 1981). Since no inter-factor correlations had a confidence interval containing a value of one (p<0.01) and the multivariate Lagrange multiplier test indicated that all item-level correlations between

Risk and uncertainty management strategies  95 constructs were insignificant (Kim, Cavusgil and Calantone, 2006), we can also conclude that our scales possess discriminant validity. This study tested the hypotheses using ordinary least squares multiple regression. We first examined the main effects of the strategic risk management strategies on the performance variables ROI, customer retention rate and sales growth in models 1, 4 and 7 respectively. Then we added the technology standard variable to our model and examined the moderating effect of the availability of well-accepted technology standards on the strategy performance relationships in models 2, 5 and 8 respectively. Next, we added the network externality variables to our original model and examined the moderating effect of the high direct and indirect network externalities in the primary served markets on the strategy performance relationships in models 3, 6 and 9. As suggested by Kenny and Judd (1984), prior to the regression analysis all variables were mean centered. A multicollinearity test revealed no substantial multicollinearity between the variables in our study (Hair et al., 1998). Finally, we performed a split group analysis to examine the mutual moderating impact of technology standards, direct and indirect network externalities on the strategies- performance relationships. This approach involved creating high and low levels of each moderator variable by performing a mean split (Cohen and Cohen, 1983).

4.4 Results

The results are presented in Table 4.4. They partly support our hypotheses with a number of intriguing exceptions. Hypothesis 1 suggested a positive relationship between traditional risk management strategies and new venture performance. It is supported for strategic control and strategic cooperation with β-coefficients ranging between 0.176 and 0.334 and between 0.173 and 0.279 respectively for the different performance variables; the data partly support our hypothesis for strategic imitation ( β-coefficients range between 0.006 and 0.123) and they do not support our hypothesis for strategic avoidance ( β-coefficients range between -0.063 and -0.165). Consistent with hypothesis 2 a positive relationship between real options strategy and new venture performance is found for all performance variables ( β-coefficients range between 0.147 and 0.345).

Table 4.4. Results of regression analyses ROI Customer retention Sales growth Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 Model 7 Model 8 Model 9 Avoidance H1 (+) -0.063 -0.057 -0.070 -0.165 *** -0.152 *** -0.201 *** -0.138 *** -0.130 *** -0.142 *** Imitation H1 (+) 0.006 0.006 -0.006 0.082 † 0.099 ** 0.054 0.123 ** 0.128 ** 0.103 * Control H1 (+) 0.176 *** 0.167 *** 0.124 * 0.334 *** 0.305 *** 0.294 *** 0.267 *** 0.252 *** 0.247 *** Cooperation H1 (+) 0.279 *** 0.320 *** 0.293 *** 0.173 *** 0.229 *** 0.154 *** 0.215 *** 0.262 *** 0.207 *** Real Options H2 (+) 0.147 ** 0.117 * 0.242 *** 0.315 *** 0.282 *** 0.321 *** 0.345 *** 0.310 *** 0.386 *** Existing Technology 0.193 *** 0.387 *** 0.271 *** Standards (TS) Avoidance * TS H3 (-) 0.005 -0.013 0.009 Imitation * TS H3 (-) -0.066 0.006 -0.067 † Control * TS H3 (-) 0.066 0.112 ** 0.123 *** Cooperation * TS H3 (-) 0.049 0.021 0.042 Real Options * TS H4 (-) -0.044 0.022 -0.017 Direct Network -0.061 0.052 0.024 Externalities (DNE) Avoidance * DNE H5a (-) 0.262 *** 0.145 ** 0.038 Imitation * DNE H5a (-) 0.152 * 0.102 * 0.084 Control * DNE H5b (+) -0.020 0.123 * 0.090 † Cooperation * DNE H5b (+) 0.132 † 0.002 0.039 Real Options * DNE H6 (-) -0.213 *** -0.141 * -0.046 Indirect Network -0.021 0.141 ** 0.019 Externalities (INE) Avoidance * INE H5a (-) -0.167 * -0.094 † -0.069 Imitation * INE H5a (-) -0.130 * -0.041 -0.051 Control * INE H5b (+) -0.034 -0.081 † -0.095 † Cooperation * INE H5b (+) -0.102 0.000 -0.016 Real Options * INE H6 (-) 0.202 ** 0.195 *** 0.134 * F 20.42 *** 11.94 *** 8.02 *** 72.12 *** 62.31 *** 26.89 *** 78.30 *** 49.70 *** 24.62 *** R2 0.198 0.244 0.253 0.466 0.627 0.532 0.486 0.573 0.510 ∆R2 - 0.046 *** 0.055 *** - 0.161 *** 0.066 *** - 0.087 *** 0.024 *** Adj. R 2 0.188 0.223 0.222 0.459 0.617 0.512 0.480 0.561 0.489 † p<0.10; * p<0.05; ** p<0.01; *** p<0.001.

Risk and uncertainty management strategies  97 In general our results do not support hypotheses 3 and 4: we did not find any significant moderating effects between existing technology standards and strategic risk management strategies with the exception of strategic control and strategic imitation. Consistent with hypothesis 3 strategic imitation has a negative interaction with technology standards on sales growth. Contrary to this hypothesis, strategic control has a positive interaction with technology standards on customer retention rate and sales growth. Existing technology standards also have a strong direct positive effect on all performance variables. Hypothesis 5a concerns the negative moderating effect of network externalities on the strategic avoidance and strategic imitation performance relationship. Our findings only partly support this hypothesis. For sales growth we did not find any moderating effects. For ROI and customer retention rate the hypothesis is mainly supported with respect to indirect network externalities. However, direct network externalities appear to be a positive moderator of the strategic avoidance and strategic imitation performance relationship. Hypothesis 5b regards the positive moderating effect of network externalities on the strategic control and strategic cooperation performance relationship. Again this hypothesis is partly confirmed. We found a positive moderating effect of direct network externalities on the strategic control customer retention rate and strategic control sales growth relationship. We also found a positive moderating effect of direct network externalities on the strategic cooperation ROI relationship. However, we found a negative moderating effect of indirect network externalities on the strategic control customer retention rate and strategic control sales growth relationship. All other moderating effects were insignificant. Hypothesis 6, suggesting a negative moderating effect of network externalities on the real options strategy performance relationship, is mainly supported for direct network externalities. However, for indirect network externalities we found a positive moderating effect on the real options strategy performance relationship.

4.5 Discussion

In this study, we compared the performance consequences of different traditional risk and uncertainty management strategies and the recently emerged real options strategy. These strategies represent a scope of possible responses to risks and uncertainties arising from the external environment of the venture, which are harder to influence than those arising from the firm itself. Thus, it is important to study the strategies to mitigate these external risks and

98  Risk and uncertainty management strategies uncertainties. We also investigated the moderating effects of important market characteristics: established technology standards, direct network externality effects and indirect network externality effects. While our main effects hypotheses are largely confirmed, the more exploratory moderator hypotheses delivered a number of surprises. In the total picture of the risk and uncertainty management strategies, only three strategies have unambiguously positive effects on new venture performance: strategic control, strategic cooperation and real options strategy. Among the other two strategies, strategic imitation, does increase sales growth, but does not influence return on investment (ROI) and customer retention rate. Strategic avoidance also has no effect on ROI, but has a negative effect on customer retention rate and sales growth. This runs contrary to the notion of “starting small, growing large”, which is a popular advice for risk management in new ventures (Shane, 2003). Both imitation and avoidance are the most conservative risk management strategies in the set we researched: they involve no or little additional investments to realize the strategy itself and drastically decrease the costs that the venture otherwise would have to incur. The disadvantage of imitation and avoidance is that they also limit the potential revenues of the venture. While in case of strategic imitation the decrease in costs seems to offset the (potential) decrease in revenues, it is not the case for strategic avoidance. Our findings suggest that strategic avoidance – i.e. introducing products to low uncertainty niches first and growing from the small scale – is the only strategy that new technology ventures should avoid. The best overall strategy in terms of ROI is strategic cooperation, in terms of customer retention rate – strategic control and in terms of sales growth – real options strategy. Markets with existing technology standards have a positive direct effect on new venture performance. Their moderating effects arise in case of strategic control, which will additionally improve customer retention and sales growth in such markets. Strategic control is the risk management strategy that most directly influences the external environment of the venture, and it seems also most sensitive for this external environment. Strategic control can be more effectively implemented under existing technology standards probably because new technology ventures can focus their efforts and their scarce resources on a limited group of products that comply with the technology standards. Except in one other case with strategic imitation, the risk and uncertainty management strategies obviously do not show any interaction with existing technology standards. This implies that existence of technology standards does not constitute a significant decrease in technology uncertainty for new

Risk and uncertainty management strategies  99 technology ventures. Thus, there are other important sources of technology uncertainty, more important than technology standards in the market and industry. As a result, research into sources of uncertainty becomes an interesting alley of scientific inquiry. As opposed to technology standards, network externalities can be seen as moderators. They do not have direct effect on new venture performance (except for the effect of indirect network externalities on customer retention rate), but instead strengthen or weaken the effects of the risk and uncertainty management strategies. Three main conclusions about network externalities can be made based on our findings. First, direct and indirect network externalities have opposite moderating effects on new venture performance – i.e., when direct network externalities strengthen the effect of risk and uncertainty management strategies, indirect network externalities weaken them, and vice versa. Second, the traditional risk management strategies and real options strategy also have opposite effects within each type of network externalities: direct network externalities generally weaken the effect of real options and strengthen the effect of traditional risk management strategies, while indirect network externalities generally strengthen the effect of real options strategy and weaken the effect of traditional risk management strategies. Finally, these effects are especially important for ROI and customer retention rate and to a smaller extent for sales growth. A possible explanation for these findings is that firms enact the direct network externalities, when they exist, by increasing the number of users of the firm's products. In order to enact the existing indirect network externalities, firms have to increase the number of complementary products and services (Schilling, 2002). The traditional risk management strategies are actively intervening in the venture's environment, while real options strategy is relatively passive and aims to increase flexibility by preparing several product options as a response to external uncertainty (Huchzermeier and Loch, 2001; McGrath, 2004; Miller, 1992). This means that it is easier to increase the number of the ventures' products users by intervening in the market directly than by building flexibility by real options. Similarly, it is easier to increase the availability of complementary products by pursuing several product options (which may be complementary to each other) than by trying to influence other firms to produce such products. How should managers and entrepreneurs interpret these results? The expectations of the performance potential are often influenced by vivid examples in the entrepreneurial

100  Risk and uncertainty management strategies environment or by the capabilities that new ventures and their staff possess. Our findings allow entrepreneurs to choose more rationally, thereby optimally distributing the scarce resources of their ventures. Strategic avoidance is the only strategy that is detrimental for new venture performance – this kind of cautiousness does not work well for new technology ventures. In order to facilitate the choice among the other four strategies, we present the best risk and uncertainty management strategies under different market conditions in Table 4.5 and 4.6. Knowing in which market(s) a particular venture operates, entrepreneurs can use these results to choose for the risk and uncertainty management strategy with the greatest performance potential. Table 4.5 presents our findings for performance in terms of return on investment (ROI) and Table 4.6 – for performance in terms of customer retention rate and sales growth. Real options strategy dominates the total picture and appears to be the best in six cases, strategic control – in four cases, strategic cooperation – in three cases and imitation – in two cases. In one case, no strategy has performed well. In markets with existing technology standards new technology ventures are better off with strategic control as opposed to real options in markets with emerging technology standards. In markets with high direct network externalities new technology ventures should choose for strategic control as opposed to real options strategy under low direct network externalities. Finally, in markets with high indirect network externalities new technology ventures should go for real options strategy as opposed to strategic control under low indirect network externalities. In most situations, the best risk and uncertainty management strategy remains the best for all performance types. However, the best strategies differ in two cases: under high direct and indirect network externalities and under low direct and indirect network externalities. In these two cases, new technology ventures in markets with existing technology standards should use strategic cooperation to have the best ROI and strategic control to have the best customer retention rate and sales.

Risk and uncertainty management strategies  101 Table 4.5. The best risk and uncertainty management strategies under different market conditions (performance in terms of ROI) Existing technology standards: Technology standards are emerging:

Direct Externalities Direct Externalities

High Low High Low

Cooperation Real Options Real Options Real Options High High

Control Cooperation Imitation Cooperation Low Low Low Low Indirect Indirect Externalities Indirect Externalities

102  Risk and uncertainty management strategies Table 4.6. The best risk and uncertainty management strategies under different market conditions (performance in terms of customer retention and sales growth)

Existing technology standards: Technology standards are emerging:

Direct Externalities Direct Externalities

High Low High Low

Control Real Options Real Options - High High

Control Control Imitation Real Options Low Low Low Indirect Indirect Externalities Indirect Externalities

Risk and uncertainty management strategies  103 There are three potential limitations in our study. Although they do not make our results less valuable, it is important to name them as they simultaneously represent future directions of research. First, we focused on strategies tackling risks and uncertainties arising from the environment external to the new technology venture. Although some of our strategies, like real options, can be also used to manage internal risks and uncertainties of the ventures, external risks and uncertainties remain the greatest challenge for new ventures since they are most difficult to influence and can be relatively easily overlooked. Second, our operationalization of strategic cooperation corresponds to vertical alliances (Kotabe and Swan, 1995) and supply-chain integration (Song et al., 2008) constructs. At the same time, we know that other types of cooperation are important for new technology ventures – such as R&D alliances or linkages with universities (Song et al., 2008). Future research may consider the alternative types of cooperation in the examination of risk and uncertainty management strategies. Finally, since we were not able to identify a survey instrument measuring real options strategy, we had to develop one ourselves. We followed Churchill, Jr. (1979) in developing this new scale and used the items tackling the main dimensions of the real options strategy (Huchzermeier and Loch, 2001; McGrath, 2004). Using this approach, we have operationalized the real options strategy as a reflective construct. However, the real options scale can be also conceived as a formative construct (Jarvis, Mackenzie and Podsakoff, 2003), where each item represents a different kind of real option that a firm can use – i.e. expansion, contraction, switching and so on (Huchzermeier and Loch, 2001). Such a construct would be formative because theoretically firms do not have to use all the different kinds of real options simultaneously. Future research should investigate these different conceptualizations of real options strategy.

4.6 Conclusion

We contribute to the strategic management literature by explicitly comparing the different ways to manage externally determined risk and uncertainty in the context of new technology ventures. To the best of our knowledge, the traditional risk management strategies have never been compared empirically. Although the general intuition would suggest that managing risk and uncertainty is better than not doing that, our results suggest otherwise. Strategic avoidance should not be generally used by new technology ventures – it improves

104  Risk and uncertainty management strategies new venture performance only in a couple of very specific situations. Similarly, strategic imitation has limited impact on performance. Overall, the best traditional strategies are strategic control and strategic cooperation. The need to integrate the findings on risk management strategies has become even more evident with the emergence of the real options. For example, Miller and Arikan (2004) raised doubts about the performance advantages of real options strategy: "[Real] options reasoning may be justified as a way to manage risk, but it may or may not enhance firm value". Our study shows that real options as a strategy to manage risk and uncertainty has definite advantages for the new venture performance. Our contribution to the real options theory is two-fold. First, although real options theory has received considerable attention in the strategic management literature recently, there have been relatively few empirical studies testing the theoretical claims. To the best of our knowledge, our study provides the first empirical test of the real options as a strategy for new technology ventures. We compare real options with more traditional strategies to manage risk and uncertainty and find that although real options is indeed an important strategy, it is not a panacea and the traditional risk management strategies may outperform the real options strategy. The second contribution is related to one of the main assumptions of the real options theory: real options work better under the conditions of uncertainty (Huchzermeier and Loch, 2001; McGrath, 1999). However, our results show that it is clearly not the case when uncertainty arises from the absence of established technology standards or from presence of direct network externality effects on the firm's market. We also contribute to the literature on network externalities by showing the importance of distinguishing between direct and indirect network externality effects. The essence of network externalities is that the utility that a user derives from consumption of the good increases with the number of other agents consuming the good. These effects can have a number of sources including direct physical effect of the number of purchasers on the quality of the product (direct network externality effects) and indirect effect of consumption externalities via complementary products and services (Katz and Shapiro, 1985). Previous studies investigating the effects of these two sources typically find that both of them have positive effect on technology acceptance as part of the dominant design, products' prices and firms' success – indicating that the effects of these two types of network externalities are in the same direction (Brynjolfsson and Kemerer, 1996; Katz and Shapiro, 1985; Schilling,

Risk and uncertainty management strategies  105 2002). Our study contributes to the network externality literature by showing that the effects of direct and indirect network externalities can be actually of opposite direction. Although there may be different reasons to choose for a particular strategy our results suggest that new technology ventures should prioritize the kind of performance they want to optimize and choose the strategy rationally, based on the characteristics of their target market. Both direct and indirect network externalities play an important role in this choice. Our results highlight the importance of distinguishing between direct and indirect network externality effects because they have opposite effects on risk and uncertainty management strategies. Finally yet importantly, our results support the theoretical distinction between the traditional risk management strategies and the real options strategy by showing that these two types of strategies can have opposite effects in certain circumstances.

106  General discussion

Chapter 5

General discussion

The focus of this dissertation is on the entrepreneurial risk-taking. In the previous three chapters, we answered the following main research questions: (1) What kinds of risks do entrepreneurs take? (2) How do they take the risks? (3) What kinds of strategies do they use to manage the risks? Chapter 2, the meta-analysis, gives a comprehensive quantitative review of factors important for the performance of new entrepreneurial firms. Due to the lack of studies examining entrepreneurial risks directly, we decided to focus on the positive side and consider risks as the opposite of success factors: i.e. if it is truly a success factor, then not possessing it would mean a risk for an entrepreneurial firm. While Chapter 2 is focusing on factors that objectively matter for new technology ventures, Chapter 3 presents research about how intuitive and rational thinking of entrepreneurs influence their level of cognitive biases and risk-taking propensity. Chapter 3 can be also seen as an investigation into the mechanism distorting the objective picture of entrepreneurial risks. In Chapter 4, we focus once again on new technology ventures and research the performance effects of five different risk and uncertainty management strategies. We also look at how these effects change in markets with existing vs. emerging technology standards, and markets with direct and indirect network externality effects. We summarize hereunder the most important conclusions for entrepreneurs, their firms and stakeholders. We supplement the discussion by future directions of research per

General discussion  107 chapter. These directions of research are building further on the studies presented in Chapters 2, 3 and 4.

5.1 Discussion of Chapter 2: The meta-analysis of success factors

5.1.1 Conclusions There are very few studies directly studying risks in new technology ventures. In order to reveal the potential risks in this context, we defined a risk as absence of a success factor (factor associated with high performance) and conducted a meta-analysis of the success factors in new technology ventures. We can draw four main conclusions about risk factors from our meta-analysis. First, all studies agree that the following factors represent important risks for new technology ventures: not having supply chain integration, limited scope and breadth of the firm's markets, small age of the firm, small founding teams, low financial resources, low marketing experience of the founders, low industry experience of the founders, and no patent protection. Second, another range of factors emerged that has a strong potential for becoming important risk factors: internationalization, low-cost strategy, market growth rate, marketing intensity, R&D investments, firm size, non-governmental financial support, and university partnerships. Although the importance of these factors varies for different sub-populations of new technology ventures, on average they are also highly significant. Third, having radical innovation strategy and engaging in R&D alliances are very strong risk factors for independent technology ventures. Independent new technology ventures that are still pursuing the radical innovation strategy or engaging in an R&D alliance should make sure that they have the resources and support similar to those of the corporate ventures, for which the same factors are in fact success as opposed to risk factors. Finally, there is a number of factors that are clearly no risk factors. Counter- intuitively, both prior start-up experience and R&D experience were insignificant, that may be a further evidence of overestimation of the role of prior start-up experience. Competition intensity, environmental dynamism and environmental heterogeneity are another three insignificant factors, supporting their role as environmental moderators.

108  General discussion 5.1.2 Future directions of research Since meta-analysis is a future-oriented research technique, this section is relatively long. Our meta-analysis should not and must not preclude future research, but rather stimulate and direct it. Based on our results and implications and current literature (e.g., Gartner, 1985; Timmons and Spinelli, 2004), we suggest a theoretical framework for future research, as depicted by Figure 5.1.

Entrepreneurial Entrepreneurial Team: Members’ characteristics Resources: Experience, knowledge and Financial means and skills investments Values and beliefs Intellectual property Behaviors and leadership Partnerships and networks styles Institutional Strategic and characteristics Organizational Fit: Competitive strategy Structure Processes Performance Systems

Entrepreneurial Opportunity: Opportunity dimensions Environmental characteristics Market characteristics

Figure 5.1. Integrated framework for studying new entrepreneurial firm performance

The theoretical framework consists of five elements, Entrepreneurial Opportunities, Entrepreneurial Team, Entrepreneurial Resources, Strategic and Organizational Fit, and Performance. The dotted lines represent the fit. In general, we suggest to take this framework as a basis for future research and to examine its factors and, in particular, the linkages into more detail in future research. Below, we will define and describe the categories of the framework, list examples of factors in these categories and give future research directions following from our meta-analysis.

General discussion  109 Entrepreneurial Team Entrepreneurial Team is defined as the management team of the new venture (Timmons and Spinelli, 2004). Entrepreneurial Team is a core element of the entrepreneurship phenomenon. Shane and Venkataraman (2000) characterize entrepreneurship as the nexus between the individual and the opportunity. Researchers identified the following factors in this category:

• Members' characteristics (age, attributes, biases, thinking styles, etc.) • Experience, knowledge, and skills • Values and beliefs • Behaviors and leadership styles.

According to our meta-analysis, future research should include cognitive biases and thinking styles, the quality, variety and complementarity of team member experiences, as well as the mediating and moderating influences of the team factors on other antecedent- performance relationships. In this research, industry and marketing experience may be included as control variables, because the literature on new technology ventures performance agrees on the magnitude of the effect of these factors.

Entrepreneurial Opportunity Entrepreneurial Opportunities are those situations in which new goods, services, raw materials, and organizing methods may be introduced and sold at higher price than their cost of production (Shane and Venkataraman, 2000). The contemporary definitions of entrepreneurship emphasize that it is opportunity-driven. Therefore, Entrepreneurial Opportunity is an essential part of the entrepreneurship framework (Eckhardt and Shane, 2003; Shane and Venkataraman, 2000; Timmons and Spinelli, 2004). Researchers distinguish the following factors in this category:

• Opportunity dimensions (type of opportunity, form of opportunity, source of opportunity, etc.) • Environmental characteristics (environmental dynamism, environmental heterogeneity, internationalization, etc.) • Market characteristics (market growth rate, competition intensity, entry barriers, buyer and supplier power, etc.).

110  General discussion Based on our meta-analysis, future research may include the direct examination of opportunity dimensions, as well as the search for moderators of the internationalization performance and the market growth rate – performance relationship. The results of our meta- analysis also suggest that the role of market scope is clear. However, due to its importance this factor may be included as a control variable in further studies.

Entrepreneurial Resources Entrepreneurial Resources include all tangible and intangible assets that a firm may possess and control (Chrisman et al., 1998; Timmons and Spinelli, 2004). Gartner (1985) has identified the resources accumulation process as an essential part of the entrepreneurial functions, while Timmons and Spinelli (2004) consider Entrepreneurial Resources as an important building block of their venture creation framework. Important factors within this category are:

• Financial means and investments (financial resources, non-governmental financial support, R&D investments, etc.) • Intellectual property (patent protection, licensing, etc.) • Partnerships and networks (R&D alliances, supply chain integration, university partnerships, etc.) • Institutional characteristics (firm age, firm size, firm type, size of the founding team, etc.).

From our meta-analysis we suggest to include more qualitative measures of resources into future research, like the value, rareness, non-imitability, and non-substitutability of resources (Barney, 1991). Moreover, we advice more moderator research on the non- governmental financial support performance and the R&D investment performance relationship, as well as the relationships between university partnerships and performance, and firm size and performance. The results of our meta-analysis also suggest that the role of financial resources, patent protection, supply chain integration, firm age and size of the founding team for venture performance is clear. However, these factors may be considered as control variables in future research.

General discussion  111 Strategic and Organizational Fit Strategic and Organizational Fit is defined as the congruence between strategy and organization of the new venture and the driving forces Entrepreneurial Team, Entrepreneurial Opportunity, and Entrepreneurial Resources (Chrisman et al., 1998; Timmons and Spinelli, 2004). Fit regards an important uniting aspect of the various elements of the framework. Gartner (1985) refers to a new venture as a gestalt of individuals, environment, organization, and process dimensions, indicating that all elements in a new venture must be balanced. We consider the following factors in this category:

• Competitive strategy (low cost strategy, market scope, marketing intensity, product innovation, etc.) • Structure • Processes • Systems.

Our meta-analysis suggests more interaction research between competitive strategies and environmental characteristics, such as environmental dynamism and competition intensity. In particular, other competitive strategies than product innovation may be examined.

Performance Our framework suggests that the better the fit between the driving forces and the strategy and organization of the venture, the better the performance. In our meta-analysis we found a broad scope of performance measures, which can also moderate the relationship between different factors and venture performance. In particular, we found this moderating effect for the type of the firm (i.e. independent vs. corporate). Therefore, we suggest to have several performance measures in future new venture research and to experiment with different subsets of performance measures.

5.2 Discussion of Chapter 3: The mechanism of entrepreneurial risk- taking

5.2.1 Conclusions Chapter 3 provides five main insights into entrepreneurial risk-taking. First, entrepreneurial cognitive biases derive from intuition with the exception of base-rate fallacy.

112  General discussion Second, all the seven biases we researched influence entrepreneurial risk-taking in a stable way, by changing the level of the general tendency to take or avoid risks. This implies that although some of these biases can be evoked by the nature of the situation (Simon and Houghton, 2003), taking biased decisions is a persisting characteristic of entrepreneurs. Third, although most biases increase risk-taking, the hindsight bias represents a clear exception. Scoring high on hindsight bias means that entrepreneurs do not learn properly from their past misjudgments and mistakes. The higher entrepreneurs score on hindsight bias, the fewer risks they take. On the long run, this may lead to making the same errors over and over again, failing the venture and not restarting due to lower propensity to take risks. Fourth, more then the half of cognitive biases can be corrected purely by more rational thinking, which represents a universal de-biasing method. Last, but not least, it is not universally clear how much additional rational thinking should there be, because the effects of its influence on biases differ in magnitude. Similarly, the effects of different cognitive biases on risk-taking also vary. Thus, the whole set of biases should be taken into account in order to make a personal recommendation for a particular entrepreneur.

5.2.2 Future directions of research Building upon the discussion within Chapter 3, we can outline another three future research directions. First, we would like to focus on where heuristics and biases derive from: intuition (Kahneman, 2003). How do entrepreneurs build their intuition? Theoretically, there are two main sources of intuitive thinking: prior knowledge and emotions (Sadler-Smith and Shefy, 2004). Emotions have a special place because they can both inform the judgment themselves and prime further decision-making (Forgas, 1995). In the first role, emotions serve as heuristics themselves. The particular kind of emotions – happiness, fear, anger, etc – is directly transformed into the judgment, such as judgment of riskiness (Loewenstein, Weber, Hsee, and Welch, 2001). In their second role, emotions serve as a mechanism determining which part of human knowledge will be further used in a particular judgment via selective attention, and selective encoding and selective retrieval of knowledge (Forgas, 1995). They may similarly determine whether rational or intuitive processes will be activated. In case of intuitive processes, emotions may determine which particular heuristics, such as

General discussion  113 representativeness and availability (Tversky and Kahneman, 1974) will be used in these judgments. While the knowledge part of intuition seems to be at least acknowledged in the entrepreneurship literature (e.g. Shane, 2000), the entrepreneurial emotions and the role they play are largely missing. This gives rise to a whole new set of research questions: When entrepreneurs make decisions intuitively, which part of their intuition do they use the most: knowledge or emotions? In which situations are entrepreneurs particularly prone to using emotions as heuristic for their judgments and what are the consequences of doing that? What are the results of the emotional priming on entrepreneurial decision-making? Future research should clarify these issues. Second, there should be theoretically two heuristics underlying the seven cognitive biases we studied: availability and representativeness (Tversky and Kahneman, 1974). An attempt to reveal a structure of heuristics underlying these biases is a promising avenue of research. Until now scholars in the heuristics and biases stream of research focused on the biases part, while heuristics remained a largely philosophical and theoretical matter. Heuristics – and not the biases – are likely to substantiate a different, sustainable way of thinking, which may be a driver of (sustainable) competitive advantage for entrepreneurial firms (Busenits and Barney, 1997). Biases, which are per definition errors in judgments involving such heuristics (Kahneman, 2003), are rather an indication of how well the rational system of a particular entrepreneur is developed and how much it is capable of detecting and eliminating such biases. Therefore, further research into heuristics and their nature is a promising line of inquiry. A number of questions deserving further attention emerge: Which heuristics cause the entrepreneurial biases? If the biases arise due to the use of heuristics, is it also possible that heuristics instead of biases are a more influential predictor of decision making efficiency and errors? How do the relative advantages of heuristics compare to their relative disadvantages (i.e. biases)? Which heuristics have more advantages than disadvantages and vice versa? Direct measures of heuristics should be developed and used for these questions. Finally, since both intuitive and rational part of entrepreneurs are important, future research may consider the rational heuristics, which derive primarily from the rational system as opposed to the experiential (Frederick, 2002; Gigerenzer, Czerlinski, and Martignon, 2002).

114  General discussion

5.3 Discussion of Chapter 4: Risk and uncertainty management strategies

5.3.1 Conclusions Chapter 4 improves our understanding of entrepreneurial strategies to manage risks and uncertainties arising from the environment of the new technology ventures. First, the results strongly indicate that new technology ventures should avoid being excessively cautious when entering new markets: strategic avoidance (i.e. growing from small scale and choosing for low uncertainty market segments) does not impact return on investment (ROI) and is detrimental for both customer retention and sales growth. New technology ventures should also think twice before imitating other firms. Strategies that do generally improve performance of new technology ventures are strategic control, strategic cooperation and real options strategy. Performance consequences of all strategies may change under certain market circumstances. Existing technology standards appear to have predominantly direct positive effect on performance of new technology ventures and only change the effects of strategic control and strategic imitation. However, risk and uncertainty management strategies perform differently in markets with direct and indirect network externality effects. In particular, direct and indirect network externalities have opposite moderating effects on new venture performance. Similarly, traditional risk management strategies and real options behave differently under a particular kind of network externalities, having opposite moderating effects within both direct and indirect network externalities.

5.3.2 Future directions of research We see this thesis as a step towards a more explicit link between theories of cognition and entrepreneurial behavior and strategic management. In particular, we examined mechanisms of how individual entrepreneurs build their risk-taking propensity and we studied the performance consequences of the risk management strategies these entrepreneurs select on the venture level. This is only the first step to link the theories of cognition and strategic management. Previous research has shown that entrepreneurs take decisions differently compared to other populations; and that there is a certain variation within the population of entrepreneurs

General discussion  115 (Busenitz and Barney, 1997; Forbes, 2005; Stewart and Roth, 2001, 2004). To the extent that entrepreneurs make decisions in a fundamentally different way, which may be a source of the strategic advantage of the firms. This strategic advantage will be sustainable to the extent that these differences are persistent (Busenitz and Barney, 1997). How can future research approach this intriguing gap? The main problem is of methodological nature: while cognition theories are mainly on the individual and group levels, strategic management theories are on the strategic business unit and firm levels. The current solutions to this problem are disaggregating the higher level variable to a lower level, aggregating the lower level variables to the higher level or using the hierarchical linear modeling (HLM). All three approaches have considerable disadvantages. Disaggregation ignores the assumption of observations independence and assesses the impact of higher level units based on the number of lower level units. Aggregation discards potential meaningful lower-level variance (Hofmann, 1997). HLM maintains the appropriate levels of analysis, but this technique is designed to investigate the influence of higher level units on lower level outcomes. In case of research on the intersection of cognition and strategic management research, the lower level variables are those from cognition and higher-level from strategic management. This means that the general conceptual model in such research would have strategic business unit or firm-level variable (e.g. performance) as its dependent variable. This makes HLM unsuitable for this application. The current feasible solution allowing to approach the cognition – strategic management gap is to take a level of analysis where one person is still fully responsible for decisions and takes most of the decisions that have strategic implications for the business unit or the firm. An example of such unit of analysis is the project/product level (Simon and Houghton, 2003). In this case, both the independent variables (cognitive processes of the manager or entrepreneur) and dependent variable (strategic decisions and performance of the product) can be on the same level of analysis. However, this solution discards a considerable part of the strategic management aspects, since the majority of the strategic management decisions are on the products portfolio of the strategic business unit and firm levels. Future research should further explore this promising area of research.

116  General discussion

5.4 Final remarks

The title of this thesis is "Bringing entrepreneurial risk-taking beyond bounded rationality: Risk factors, real options and traditional risk management strategies in new technology ventures". In the main three chapters (2, 3 and 4) we answer the following research questions: (1) What kinds of risks do entrepreneurs take? (2) How do they take the risks? (3) What kinds of strategies do they use to manage the risks? Each chapter presents a different, but complementary answer on how entrepreneurs can improve their risk-taking. Chapter 2 focuses on the particular risks that new technology ventures have. These are objective risks that entrepreneurs have to take care of. Chapter 3 highlights the individual-level mechanism of taking risks. It shows the importance of being aware of the cognitive biases distorting the entrepreneurial vision. By balancing the use of rational and intuitive thinking entrepreneurs can decrease the influence of cognitive biases and improve their risk-taking. Chapter 4 is a firm-level investigation into the risk and uncertainty management strategies that new technology ventures can apply to manage the external risks and uncertainties. We show that it is important to make a distinction between the traditional risk management strategies and real options strategy. We also show how performance consequences of these strategies change under different market conditions. Taken together, our findings can hopefully help bringing entrepreneurial risk-taking beyond bounded rationality.

References

Adner, R., Levinthal, D.A. (2004a). What is not a real option: Considering boundaries for the application of real options to business strategy. Academy of Management Review 29(1): 74-85. Adner, R., Levinthal, D.A. (2004b). Reply: Real options and real tradeoffs. Academy of Management Review 29(1): 120-126. Allinson, C., Hayes, J. (1996). The cognitive style index: A measure of intuition-analysis for organizational research. The Journal of Management Studies 33(1): 119-135. Anderson, J. C., Gerbing, D.W. (1988). Structural equation modeling in practice: A review and recommended two-step approach. Psychological Bulletin 103(3): 411-423. Andrews, J., Smith, D.C. (1996). In search of the marketing imagination: Factors affecting the creativity of marketing programs for mature products. Journal of Marketing Research 33(2): 174-187. Atuahene-Gima, K., Li, H. (2004). Strategic decision comprehensiveness and new product development outcomes in technology ventures. Academy of Management Journal 47(4): 583-597. Bagozzi, R.P., Yi, Y., Philips, L.W. (1991). Assessing construct validity in organizational research. Administrative Science Quarterly 36(3): 421-458. Bamberger, P., Bacharach, S., Dyer, L. (1989). Human Resources Management and Organizational Effectiveness: High Technology Entrepreneurial Startup Firms in Israel. Human Resource Management 28(3): 349-366. Bantel, K.A. (1997). Performance in adolescent, technology-based firms: Product strategy, implementation, and synergy. Journal of High Technology Management Research 8(2): 243-262. Barney, J.B. (1991). Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management 17(1): 99-120. Baron, R.A. (1998). Cognitive mechanisms in entrepreneurship: Why and when entrepreneurs think differently than other people. Journal of Business Venturing 13(4): 275-294. Baron, R.A. (2004). The cognitive perspective: a valuable tool for answering entrepreneurship's basic “why“ questions. Journal of Business Venturing 19(2): 221-239. Baum, J.A.C., Silverman, B.S. (2004). Picking winners or building them? Alliance, intellectual, and human capital as selection criteria in venture financing and performance of biotechnology startups. Journal of Business Venturing 19(3): 411-436. Baum, J.R., Locke, E.A., Kirkpatrick, S.A. (1998). A longitudinal study of the relation of vision and vision communication to venture growth in entrepreneurial firms. Journal of Applied Psychology 83(1): 43-54.

118  References Baum, J.R., Locke, E.A., Smith, K.G. (2001). A multidimensional model of venture growth. Academy of Management Journal 44(2): 292-303. Bloodgood, J.M., Sapienza, H.J., Almeida, J.G. (1996). The internationalization of new high-potential U.S. ventures: Antecedents and outcomes. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 20(4): 61-76. Bowman. E.H., Hurry, D. (1993). Strategy through the option lens: An integrated view of resource investments and the incremental-choice process. Academy of Management Review 18(4): 760-782. Brenner, L.A., Koehler, D.J., Liberman, V., Tversky, A. (1996). Overconfidence in probability and frequency judgments: A critical examination. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 65(3): 212-219. Brockhaus, R.H., Sr. (1980). Risk taking propensity of entrepreneurs. Academy of Management Journal 23(3): 509-520. Brynjolfsson, E., Kemerer, C. F. (1996). Network externalities in microcomputer software: An econometric analysis of the spreadsheet market. Management Science 42(12): 1627-1647. Bstieler, L. (2005). The moderating effect of environmental uncertainty on new product development and time efficiency. Journal of Product Innovation Management 22(3): 267-284. Bukszar, E., Connolly, T. (1988). Hindsight bias and strategic choice: Some problems in learning from experience. Academy of Management Journal 31: 628-641. Busenitz, L.W., Barney, J.B. (1997). Differences between entrepreneurs and managers in large organizations: Biases and heuristics in strategic decision-making. Journal of Business Venturing 12(1): 9-30. Cacioppo, J.T., Petty, R.E., Feinstein, J.A., Jarvis, W.B. (1996). Dispositional differences in cognitive motivation: The life and times of individuals varying in need for cognition. Psychological Bulletin 119(2): 197-253. Camisón-Zornoza, C., Lapiedra-Alcami, R., Segarra-Cipres, M., Boronat-Navarro, M. (2004). A Meta-analysis of Innovation and Organizational Size. Organization Studies 25(3): 331-362. Campbell, J.D., Tesser, A. (1983). Motivational interpretations of hindsight bias: An individual difference analysis. Journal of Personality 51(4): 605-620. Capon, N., Farley, J.U., Hoenig, S. (1990). Determinants of Financial Performance: A Meta-Analysis. Management Science 36(10): 1143-1159. Carpenter, M.A., Pollock, T.G., Leary, M.M. (2003). Testing a model of reasoned risk- taking: Governance, the experience of principals and agents, and global strategy in high-technology IPO firms. Strategic Management Journal 24(9): 803-820. Chamanski, A., Waagø, S. (2001). The Organizational Success of New, Technology- based Firms. Working paper, Norwegian University of Science and Technology: Trondheim, Norway.

References  119 Chrisman, J.J., Bauerschmidt, A., Hofer, C.W. (1998). The determinants of new venture performance: An extended model. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 23(1): 5-30. Christensen, C.M., Bower, J.L. (1996). Customer Power, Strategic Investment, and the Failure of Leading Firms. Strategic Management Journal 17(3): 197-218. Churchill, G.A., Jr. (1979). A paradigm for developing better measures of marketing constructs. Journal of Marketing Research 16(1): 64-73. Cohen, J., Cohen, P. (1983). Applied multiple regression/ correlation analysis for Behavioral Sciences . Lawrence Erlbaum Associates: Hillsdale, NJ. Cooper, R.G. (1984). How New Product Strategies Impact on Performance. Journal of Product Innovation Management 2(1): 5-18. Covin, J.G., Slevin, D.P. (1989). Strategic management of small firms in hostile and benign environments. Strategic Management Journal 10(1): 75-87. Covin, J.G., Slevin, D.P., & Heeley, M.B. (2001). Strategic decision making in an intuitive vs. technocratic mode: Structural and environmental considerations. Journal of Business Research 52(1): 51-67. Cristensen, C.M., Suarez, F.F., Utterback, J.J. (1998). Strategies for survival in fast- changing industries. Management Science 44(12): S207-S220. Das, T.K., Teng, B.S. (1998a). Between trust and control: Developing confidence in partner cooperation in alliances. Academy of Management Review 23(3): 481-512. Das, T.K., Teng, B.S. (1998b). Resource and risk management in the strategic alliance making process. Journal of Management 24(1): 21-42. Denes-Raj, V., Epstein, S. (1994). Conflict between intuitive and rational processing: When people behave against their better judgment. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 66(5): 819–829. Dillman, D.A. (1978). Mail and telephone surveys: The total design method . John Wiley & Sons, Inc.: New York, NY. Doutriaux, J. (1991). High-Tech Start-Ups, Better Off with Government Contracts than with Subsidies: New Evidence in Canada. IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management 38(2): 127-135. Doutriaux, J. (1992). Emerging High-Tech Firms: How Durable Are Their Comparative Start-Up Advantages? Journal of Business Venturing 7(4): 303-322. Dowling, M.J., McGee, J.E. (1994). Business and technology strategies and new venture performance. Management Science 40(12): 1663-1677. Drucker, P. (1985). Innovation and Entrepreneurship. Harper and Row: New York, NY. Eckhardt, J.T., Shane, S.A. (2003). Opportunities and entrepreneurship. Journal of Management 29(3): 333-349. Eisenhardt, K.M., Schoonhoven, C.B. (1990). Organizational Growth: Linking Founding Team, Strategy, Environment, and Growth Among U.S. Semiconductor Ventures, 1978-1988. Administrative Science Quarterly 35(3): 504-529.

120  References Epstein, S. (1994). Integration of the cognitive and the psychodynamic unconscious. American Psychologist 49(8): 709-724. Epstein, S., Pacini, R., Denes-Raj, V., Heier, H. (1996). Individual differences in intuitive- experiential and analytical-rational thinking styles. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 71(2): 390-405. Fischhoff, B. (1982). Debiasing. In D. Kahneman, P. Slovic and A. Tversky (Eds.), Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases: 422-444.: Cambridge University: Press New York, NY. Fischhoff, B., Lichtenstein, S., Slovic, P., Derby, S.L., Keeney, R.L. (1981). Acceptable risk . Cambridge University Press: New York, NY. Fischhoff, B., Slovic, P., Lichtenstein, S. (1977). Knowing with certainty: The appropriateness of extreme confidence. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance 3(4): 552-564. Forbes, D.P. (2005). Are some entrepreneurs more overconfident than others? Journal of Business Venturing 20(5): 623-640. Forgas, J.P. (1995). Mood and Judgment: The affect infusion model (AIM). Psychological Bulletin, 117(1): 39-66. Fornell, C., Larcker, D.F. (1981). Evaluating structural equation models with unobservable variables and measurement error. Journal of Marketing Research 18(1): 39-50. Frederick, S. (2002). Automated Choice Heuristics. In T. Gilovich, D. Griffin and D. Kahneman (Eds.), Heuristics and biases: The psychology of intuitive judgment: 548-558. Cambridge University Press: New York, NY. Gartner, W.B. (1985). A Conceptual Framework for Describing the Phenomenon of New Venture Creation. Academy of Management Review 10(4): 696-706. Gatinon, H., Xuereb, J.M. (1997). Strategic orientation of the firm and new product performance. Journal of Marketing Research 34(1): 77-90. Gemunden, H.G., Ritter, T., Heydebreck, P. (1996). Network configuration and innovation success: An empirical analysis in German high-tech industries. International Journal of Research in Marketing 13(5): 449-462. George, G., Zahra, S.A., Wheatley, K.K., Khan, R. (2001). The effects of alliance portfolio characteristics and absorptive capacity on performance: A study of biotechnology firms. Journal of High Technology Management Research 12(2): 205-226. George, G., Zahra, S.A., Wood, D.R. (2002). The effects of business-university alliances on innovative input and financial performance: A study of publicly traded biotechnology companies. Journal of Business Venturing 17(6): 577-609. Gerbing, D.W., Anderson, J.C. (1993). Monte Carlo evaluations of goodness-of-fit indices for structural equation models. In K.A. Bollen and J.S. Long (Eds.), Testing structural equation models: 40-65. Sage: Newbury Park, CA. Gerwin, D., Barrowman, N. (2002). An evaluation of research on integrated product development. Management Science 48(7): 938-953.

References  121 Gigerenzer, G., Czerlinski, J., Martignon, L. (2002). How Good Are Fast and Frugal Heuristics? In T. Gilovich, D. Griffin and D. Kahneman (Eds.), Heuristics and biases: The psychology of intuitive judgment: 559-581. Cambridge University Press: New York, NY. Griffin, D.W., Varey, C.A. (1996). Towards a consensus on overconfidence. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 65(3): 227-231. Hair, J. F., Anderson, R.E., Tatham, R.L., Black, W.C. (1998). Multivariate data analysis . 5th edition, Prentice-Hall International, Inc.: Upper Saddle River, NJ. Henard, D.H., Szymanski, D.M. (2001). Why some new products are more successful than others. Journal of Marketing Research 38(3): 362-375. Hofmann, D.A. 1997. An overview of the logic and rationale of hierarchical linear models. Journal of Management, 23(6): 723-744. Huchzermeier, A., Loch, C.H. (2001). Project management under risk: Using the real options approach to evaluate flexibility in R&D. Management Science 47(1): 85- 101. Hunt, S.D., Sparkman, R.D. Jr., Wilcox, J.B. (1982). The pretest in survey research: issues and preliminary findings. Journal of Marketing Research 19(2): 269-273. Hunter, J.E., Schmidt, F.L. (1990). Methods of Meta-Analysis: Correcting Error and Bias in Research Findings . Sage: Newbury Park, CA. Hunter, J.E., Schmidt, F.L. (2004). Methods of Meta-Analysis: Correcting Error and Bias in Research Findings . 2 nd Edition, Sage: Thousand Oaks, CA. Jarvis, C.B., MacKenzie, S.B., Podsakoff, P.M. (2003). A critical review of construct indicators and measurement model misspecification in marketing and consumer research. Journal of Consumer Research 30(2): 199-218. Johnson S., Van de Ven, A.H. (2002). A framework for entrepreneurial strategy. In Strategic Entrepreneurship -Creating a New Mindset , Hitt MA, Ireland RD, Camp SM, Sexton DL (eds). Blackwell Publishers: Oxford. Kahneman, D. (2003). A perspective on judgment and choice. American Psychologist 58(9): 697-720. Kahneman, D. Frederick, S. (2002). Representativeness revisited: Attribute substitution in intuitive judgment. In T. Gilovich, D. Griffin & D. Kahneman (Eds.), Heuristics and biases: The psychology of intuitive judgment: 49-81. Cambridge University Press: New York, NY. Kahneman, D., Tversky, A. (1973). On the psychology of prediction. Psychological Review 80(4): 237-251. Kahneman, D., Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47(2): 263-292. Katz, M.L., Shapiro, C. (1985). Network externalities, competition and compatibility. The American Economic Review 75(3): 424-440. Katz, M.L., Shapiro, C. (1986). Technology adoption in the presence of network externalities. The Journal of Political Economy 94(4): 822-841.

122  References Kazanjian, R.K., Drazin, R. (1990). A state-contingent model of design and growth for technology based new ventures. Journal of Business Venturing 5(3): 137-155. Kazanjian, R.K., Rao, H. (1999). Research note: The creation of capabilities in new ventures - A longitudinal study. Organization Studies 20(1): 125-142. Kenny, D.A., Judd, C.M. (1984). Estimating the non-linear and interactive effects of latent variables. Psychological Bulletin 96(1): 201-210. Keizer, J.A., Halman, J.I.M., and Song, M. (2002). From experience: Applying the risk diagnosing methodology. Journal of Product Innovation Management 19(3): 213-232. Kim, D., Cavusgil, S.T., Calantone, R.J. (2006). Information systems innovations and supply chain management: Channel relationships and firm performance. Academy of Marketing Science Journal 34(1): 40-54. Knight, F.H. (1921). Risk, Uncertainty and Profit . reprinted in 1957. Kelley and Millman: New York, NY. Kotabe, M., Swan, K. S. (1995). The role of strategic alliances in high-technology new product development. Strategic Management Journal 16(8): 621-636. Lambert, R.A. (1998). Customer satisfaction and future financial performance Discussion of are non financial measures leading indicators of financial performance? An analysis of customer satisfaction. Journal of Accounting Research 36(special issue): 37-46. Langer, E.J. (1975). The illusion of control. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 32(2): 311-328. Langer, E.J., Roth, J. (1975). Heads I win, tails it's chance: The illusion of control as a function of the sequence of outcomes in a purely chance task. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 32(6): 951-955. Lazear, E.P. (2004). Balanced Skills and Entrepreneurship. The American Economic Review 94(2): 208-211. Lee, C., Lee, K., Pennings, J.M. (2001). Internal capabilities, external networks, and performance: A study on technology-based ventures. Strategic Management Journal 22(6/7): 615-640. Lefebvre, L., Langley, A., Harvey, J., Lefebvre, E. (1992). Exploring the Strategy- Technology Connection in Small Manufacturing Firms. Production and Operations Management 1(3): 269–284. Li, H. (2001). How does new venture strategy matter in the environment-performance relationship? Journal of High Technology Management Research 12(2): 183- 204. Li, H., Atuahene-Gima, K. (2001). Product innovation and the performance of new technology ventures in China. Academy of Management Journal 44(6): 1123- 1134. Li, H., Atuahene-Gima, K. (2002). The adoption of agency business activity, product innovation, and performance in Chinese technology ventures. Strategic Management Journal 23(6): 469-490.

References  123 Lieberman, M.B., Asaba, S. (2006). Why do firms imitate each other? Academy of Management Review 31(2): 366-385. Loewenstein, G.F., Weber, E.U., Hsee, C.K., Welch, N. (2001). Risk as Feelings. Psychological Bulletin, 127(2): 267-286. Lumme, A. (1998). Local selection environment nurturativeness in determining the fitness of new, technology-based firms: derivation and validation of a model. PhD thesis. Helsinki University of Technology: Helsinki. Lynch, J.G.J., Ofir, C. (1989). Effects of cue consistency and value on base-rate utilization. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 56(2): 170-181. Malhotra, N.K., Kim, S.S., Patil, A. (2006). Common method variance in is research: A comparison of alternative approaches and a reanalysis of past research. Management Science 52(12): 1865-1883. March, J.G., Shapira, Z. (1987). Managerial perspectives on risk and risk-taking. Management Science 33(1): 1404-1418. Marino, K.E., De Noble, A.F. (1997). Growth and early returns in technology-based manufacturing ventures. Journal of High Technology Management Research 8(2): 225-242. McDougall, P.P., Covin, J.G., Robinson, R.B., Jr., Herron, L. (1994). The effects of industry growth and strategic breadth on new venture performance and strategy content. Strategic Management Journal 15(7): 537-554. McDougall, P.P., Oviatt, B.M. (1996). New venture internationalization, strategic change, and performance: A follow-up study. Journal of Business Venturing 11(1): 23-40. McGee, J.E., Dowling, M.J. (1994). Using R&D cooperative arrangements to leverage managerial experience: A study of technology-intensive new ventures. Journal of Business Venturing 9(1): 33-48. McGee, J.E., Dowling, M.J., Megginson, W.L. (1995). Cooperative strategy and new venture performance: The role of business strategy and management experience. Strategic Management Journal 16(7): 565-580. McGinnis, M.A. (1984). The key to strategic planning: Integrating analysis and intuition. Sloan Management Review 26(1): 45-52. McGrath, R.G. (1997). A real options logic for initiating technology positioning investments. Academy of Management Review 22(4): 974-996. McGrath, R.G. (1999). Real options reasoning and entrepreneurial failure. Academy of Management Review 24(1): 13-30. McGrath, R.G., Ferrier, W.J., Mendelow, A.L. (2004). Response: real options as engines of choice and heterogeneity. Academy of Management Review 29(1): 86-101. Miles, G., Preece, S.B., Baetz, M.C. (1999). Dangers of dependence: The impact of strategic alliance use by small technology-based firms. Journal of Small Business Management 37(2): 20-29. Miller, D., Toulouse, J.-M. (1986). Chief executive personality and corporate strategy and structure in small firms. Management Science 32(11): 1389-1409.

124  References Miller, K.D. (1992). A framework for integrated risk management in international businesses. Journal of International Business Studies 23(2): 311-331. Miller, K.D., Arikan,A.T. (2004). Technology search investments: Evolutionary, option reasoning and option pricing approaches. Strategic Management Journal 25(5): 473-485. Miller, K.D., Shapira, Z. (2004). An empirical test of heuristics and biases affecting real option valuation. Strategic Management Journal 25(3): 269-284. Mohan-Neill, S.I. (1995). The influence of firm's age and size on its environmental scanning activities. Journal of Small Business Management 33(4): 10-21. Montoya-Weiss, M.M., Calantone, R. (1994). Determinants of new product performance: A review and meta-analysis. Journal of Product Innovation Management 11(5): 397-417. Mullins, J.W., Forlani, D., Walker, O.C.J. (1999). Effects of organizational and decision- maker factors on new product risk taking. The Journal of Product Innovation Management 16(3): 282-294. Nunnally, J.C. (1978). Psychometric theory . 2 nd ed. McGraw-Hill: New York. OECD. (1997). SME, Job creation and growth. Paris. Pacini, R., Epstein, S. (1999). The relation of rational and experiential information processing styles to personality, basic beliefs, and the ratio-bias phenomenon. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 76(6): 972-987. Palich, L.E., Cardinal, L.B., Miller, C.C. (2000). Curvilinearity in the diversification- performance linkage: An examination of over three decades of research. Strategic Management Journal 21(2): 155-174. Panayi, S., Trigeorgis, L. (1998). Multi-stage real options: The cases of information infrastructure and international bank expansion. Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 38(Special issue): 675-692. Podsakoff, P.M., MacKenzie, S.B., Lee, J.Y., Podsakoff, N.P. (2003). Common method biases in behavioral research: A critical review of the literature and recommended remedies. Journal of Applied Psychology 88: 879-903. Porter, M.E. (1980). Competitive Strategy . Free Press: New York, NY. Qian, G., Li L. (2003). Profitability of small- and medium-sized enterprises in high-tech industries: The case of the biotechnology industry. Strategic Management Journal 24(9): 881-887. Robinson, K.C., McDougall, P.P. (2001). Entry barriers and new venture performance: A comparison of universal and contingency approaches. Strategic Management Journal 22(6/7): 659-685. Rohlfs, J. (1974). A theory of interdependent demand for a communication service. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 5(1): 16-37. Rosenthal, R. (1991). Meta-analytic procedures for social research . Sage: Newbury Park, CA.

References  125 Ruefli, T.W., Collins, J.M., Lacugna, J.R. (1999). Risk measures in strategic management research: Auld lang syne? Strategic Management Journal 20(2): 167-194. Russo, J.E., Schoemaker, P.J.H. (1992). Managing overconfidence. Sloan Management Review 33(2): 7-17. Sadler-Smith, E., Shefy, E. (2004). The intuitive executive: Understanding and applying "gut feel" in decision-making. The Academy of Management Executive, 18(4): 76-91. Sarasvathy, D.K., Simon, H.A., Lave, L. (1998). Perceiving and managing business risks. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 33(2): 207-225. Schilling, M.A. (2002). Technology success and failure in winner-take-all markets: The impact of learning orientation, timing and network externalities. Academy of Management Journal 45(2): 387-398. Schneider, S.L., Lopes, L.L. (1986). Reflection in preferences under risk: Who and when may suggest why. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance 12(4): 535–548. Seiders, K., Riley, E. (1999). Stock Price Performance of Internet Firms: Identification of Key Drivers. In P.D. Reynolds (Ed.), Proceedings of the nineteenth Annual Entrepreneurship Research Conference (Frontiers of Entrepreneurship Research): 392-405. Babson College: Babson Park, MA. Shane, S. (2003). A general theory of entrepreneurship: The individual-opportunity nexus . Edward Elgar: Northampton, MA. Shane, S., Venkataraman, S. (2000). The promise of entrepreneurship as a field of research. Academy of Management Review 25(1): 217-226. Shane, S.A. (2000). Prior knowledge and the discovery of entrepreneurial opportunities. Organization Science 11(4): 448-469. Shane, S.A., Stuart, T. (2002). Organizational endowments and the performance of university start-ups. Management Science 48(1): 154-170. Shane, S.A., Venkataraman, S. (2000). The promise of entrepreneurship as a field of research. Academy of Management Review 25(1): 217-226. Silver, A. D. (1985). Venture capital: The complete guide for investors . John Wiley & Sons Inc: New York, NY. Simon, M., Houghton, S.M. (2003). The relationship between overconfidence and the introduction of risky products: Evidence from a field study. Academy of Management Journal 46(2): 139-149. Simon, M., Houghton, S.M., Aquino, K. (2000). Cognitive, biases, risk perception and venture formation: How individuals decide to start companies. Journal of Business Venturing 15(2): 113-134. Simon, M., Houghton, S.M., & Savelli, S. (2003). Out of the frying pan...? Why small business managers introduce high-risk products. Journal of Business Venturing 18(3): 419-440. Sitkin, S.B., Pablo, A.L. (1992). Reconceptualizing the determinants of risk behavior. Academy of Management Review 17(1): 9-38.

126  References Sitkin, S.B., Weingart, L.R. (1995). Determinants of risky decision-making behavior: A test of the mediating role of risk perceptions and propensity. Academy of Management Journal 38(6): 1573-1592. Sloman, S.A. (2002). Two systems of reasoning. In T. Gilovich, D. Griffin and D. Kahneman (Eds.), Heuristics and biases: The psychology of intuitive judgment: 49-81. Cambridge University Press: New York, NY. Slovic, P. Fischhoff, B. (1977). On the psychology of experimental surprises. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance 3(4): 544-551. Song, M., Podoynitsyna, K. Bij, H. van der, Halman, J.I.M. (2008). Success factors in new ventures: A meta-analysis. Journal of Product Innovation Management 25(1): 7– 27. Stanovich, K.E., West, R.F. (2000). Individual differences in reasoning: Implications for the rationality debate? Behavioral and Brain Sciences 23(5): 645-726. Steensma, H.K., Corley, K.G. (2001). Organizational context as a moderator of theories on firm boundaries for technology sourcing. Academy of Management Journal 44(2): 271-290. Stewart, W.H., Jr., Roth, P.L. (2001). Risk propensity differences between entrepreneurs and managers: A meta-analysis review. Journal of Applied Psychology 86(1): 145-153. Stewart, W.H., Jr., Roth, P.L. (2004). Data quality affects meta-analytic conclusions: A response to Miner and Raju (2004) concerning entrepreneurial risk propensity. Journal of Applied Psychology 89(1): 14-21. Stuart, R.W., Abetti, P.A. (1986). Field study of start-up ventures – part II: predicting initial success. In R. Ronstadt, J.A. Hornaday, R. Peterson and K.H. Vesper (Eds.) Proceedings of the sixth Annual Entrepreneurship Research Conference (Frontiers of Entrepreneurship Research): 21-39. Babson College: Babson Park, MA. Timmons, J.A., Spinelli, S. (2004). New venture creation: entrepreneurship for the 21 st century . McGraw-Hill/Irwin: New York, NY. Trigeorgis, L. (1993). Real options and interactions with financial flexibility. Financial Management 22(3): 202-224. Tushman, M.L., Anderson, P. (1986). Technological discontinuities and organization environments. Administrative Science Quarterly 31(3): 439-465. Tushman, M.L., Anderson, P. (1997). Managing strategic innovation and change . Oxford University Press: New York, NY. Tversky, A., Kahneman, D. (1974). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Science 185(4157): 1124-1131. Walls, M.R., Dyer, J.S. (1996). Risk propensity and firm performance: A study of the petroleum exploration industry, Management Science 42(7): 1004-1021. Warner, A.G., Fairbank, J.F., Steensma, H.K. (2006). Manageming uncertainty in a formal standards-based industry: A real options perspective on acquisition timing. Journal of Management 32(2): 279-298.

References  127 Wärneryd, K. (1990). Legal restrictions and monetary evolution. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 13(1): 117-124. Zahra, S.A., Bogner, W.C. (2000). Technology strategy and software new ventures' performance: Exploring the moderating effect of the competitive environment. Journal of Business Venturing 15(2): 135-173. Zahra, S.A., Covin, J. (1993). Business Strategy, Technology Policy and Company Performance. Strategic Management Journal 14(6): 451–478. Zahra, S.A., Ireland, R.D., Hitt, M.A. (2000). International expansion by new venture firms: International diversity, mode of market entry, technological learning, and performance. Academy of Management Journal 43(5): 925-950. Zahra, S.A., Matherne, B.P., Carleton, J.M. (2003). Technological Resource Leveraging and the Internationalisation of New Ventures. Journal of International Entrepreneurship 1(2): 163-186. Zahra, S.A., Neubaum D.O., Huse M. (1997). The effect of the environment on export performance among telecommunications new ventures. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 22(1): 25-46. Zuckerman, M., Knee, C.R., Kieffer, S.C., Rawsthorne, L., Bruce, L.M. (1996). Beliefs in realistic and unrealistic control: Assessment and implications. Journal of Personality 64(2): 435-464.

Appendix A: Measures

A2.1. Scales of the most important meta-factors from Chapter 2

Original Meta-factor Study Sources Scales ααα Construct MARKET and OPPORTUNITY Market scope 10,11 - - Number of products in market - Rate your firm relative to your competitors over the last three years on the extent to which it has: Product Covin and Slevin - Placed emphasis on developing new products through allocation of 15,16 Product innovation Innovation (1989); Zahra and substantial financial resources 0.83 17 Strategy Covin (1993) - Developed a large variety of new product lines - Increased the rate of new product introductions to the market - Increased it overall commitment to develop and market new products Rate on 4 (for technology) and 5-point scales: Eisenhardt and Explorativeness - Newness of the core technology of the firm Schoonhoven 18 of the entry - Newness of the target markets served by the firm 0.72 (1994); Stuart and strategy - Newness of the competition faced by the firm Abetti (1986); etc. - Newness of the users of the offering Rate on the 5-point scale if the statement is true or not true: Cooper (1984); - Introduces more new products than the competition. Lefebvre et al - Introduces products to the market faster than competitors. 28 Product upgrades 0.71 (1992); Zahra and - Has reduced the time between the development and market introductions Covin (1993) of new products. - Introduces many new products to the market.

130  Appendices

ENTREPRENEURIAL TEAM Industry experience 22 Prior industry experience of Combined number of years that the members of the founding management - - management team spent in previous positions that were in similar industries or markets team RESOURCES Financial resources 11 - - Venture assets - 8, 14, Firm age 22, 23, - - Year of incorporation / # of years since establishment - 29, 31 Firm type 10, 29 - - If the venture was independent or corporate - Rate on the 5-point scale if the statement is true or not true: Cooper (1984); - Holds important patent rights. Lefebvre et al Patent protection 28 Copyrights - Has more patents than its key competitors. 0.71 (1992); Zahra and - Uses licensing agreements extensively to sell its products. Covin (1993) - Has increased its patenting efforts over the past three years. R&D alliances 10,11 - - Number of joint R&D, patent swaps, technology transfers and joint ventures - Rate on the 5-point scale if the statement is true or not true: Cooper (1984); - Uses joint ventures for R&D Lefebvre et al 28 External sources - Is heavily engaged in strategic alliances 0.73 (1992); Zahra and - Collaborates with universities and research centers in R&D Covin (1993) - Contracts out a major portion of its R&D activities Size of founding 9 Team size - Number of founders - team Rate on the 5-point scale: - Importance of suppliers as discussion partners Gemunden, Ritter Supply chain Cooperation with - Importance of suppliers for generating new product ideas 5 and Heydebreck 0.92 integration suppliers - Importance of suppliers for conventionalizing new products (1996) - Importance of suppliers for developing new products - Importance of suppliers for testing new products 10,11 - - Number of outsourcing and distribution links -

Appendices  131

A3.1. Constructs, measurement items, and construct reliabilities for Chapter 3

Dependent variable

Risk-taking propensity (α=0.87) We present different scenarios below. Assuming that given probabilities are accurate, what would you choose if you have to make a decision now without additional information?

RP1 (Taken from Mullins et al., 1999): 1. I would always choose the following scenario (please check one answer only): □ A: an 80% chance of winning $400 and 20% chance of winning nothing, or □ B: receiving $320 for sure 2. I would always choose the following scenario (please check one answer only): □ A: receiving $300 for sure, or □ B: a 20% chance of winning $1,500 and 80% of winning nothing 3. I would always choose the following scenario (please check one answer only): □ A: a 90% chance of winning $200 and 10% chance of winning nothing, or □ B: receiving $180 for sure 4. I would always choose the following scenario (please check one answer only): □ A: receiving $160 for sure, or □ B: a 10% chance of winning $1,600 and 90% chance of winning nothing 5. I would always choose the following scenario (please check one answer only): □ A: a 50% chance of winning $500 and 50% chance of winning nothing, or □ B: receiving $250 for sure Coding algorithm : IF score=risky option THEN coding=1; ELSE coding=0; Final coding=sum of all 5 sub-codings.

RP2 (New, based on Schneider and Lopes, 1986): 6. I would always choose the following scenario (please check one answer only): □ receiving $900 for sure, □ a 90% chance of winning $1,000 and 10% chance of winning nothing, □ a 80% chance of winning $1,125 and 20% chance of winning nothing, □ a 70% chance of winning $1,286 and 30% chance of winning nothing, □ a 60% chance of winning $1,500 and 40% chance of winning nothing, □ a 50% chance of winning $1,800 and 50% chance of winning nothing, □ a 40% chance of winning $2,250 and 60% chance of winning nothing, □ a 30% chance of winning $3,000 and 70% chance of winning nothing, □ a 20% chance of winning $4,500 and 80% chance of winning nothing, or □ a 10% chance of winning $9,000 and 90% chance of winning nothing

132  Appendices RP3 (New, based on Schneider and Lopes, 1986) (R): 7. I would always choose the following scenario (please check one answer only): □ a 10% chance of winning $100,000 and 90% chance of winning nothing, □ a 20% chance of winning $50,000 and 80% chance of winning nothing, □ a 30% chance of winning $33,333 and 70% chance of winning nothing, □ a 40% chance of winning $25,000 and 60% chance of winning nothing, □ a 50% chance of winning $20,000 and 50% chance of winning nothing, □ a 60% chance of winning $16,667 and 40% chance of winning nothing, □ a 70% chance of winning $14,286 and 30% chance of winning nothing, □ a 80% chance of winning $12,500 and 20% chance of winning nothing, □ a 90% chance of winning $11,111 and 10% chance of winning nothing, or □ receiving $10,000 for sure

Mediating variables

Hindsight bias ( α=0.75) (New items, following Bukszar and Connolly, 1988; and Slovic and Fischhoff, 1977) (On the last page of the survey) Below are three questions which assesses your confidence on your answer to earlier questions (please do not turn the pages back and change any answers). HIN1. Earlier we asked you which country (Canada or New Zealand) has a higher percentage of entrepreneurs. Let’s assume that the correct answer is New Zealand. Knowing this new information, please answer the following question (score: 0-100%): • If your answer was New Zealand, how confident were you that New Zealand would be the correct answer? • If your answer was Canada, how confident were you that Canada would be the correct answer?

HIN2. Earlier we asked you whether London or Beijing is farther away from Seattle. Let’s assume that the correct answer is Beijing. Knowing this new information, please answer the following question (score: 0-100%): • If your answer was Beijing, how confident were you that Beijing would be the correct answer? • If your answer was London, how confident were you that London would be the correct answer?

HIN3. Earlier we asked you whether Nissan or Toyota was founded earlier. Let’s assume that the correct answer is Nissan. Knowing this new information, please answer the following question (score: 0-100%): • If your answer was Nissan, how confident were you that Nissan would be the correct answer? • If your answer was Toyota, how confident were you that Toyota would be the correct answer? Coding algorithm : IF answer on the question from overconfidence measure was correct THEN coding=0; ELSE coding = (score from overconfidence – score from hindsight).

Illusory correlations ( α=0.67)

Appendices  133 (New items based on existing data from different fields; following Tversky and Kahneman, 1974) Below we list some personality characteristics. Please circle the number next to each statement that best represents your degree of disagreement or agreement (where 1=Strongly Disagree; 4=Neutral; 7=Strongly Agree; and numbers between 1 and 7 represent the varying degrees). COR1. Big businesses will often ruin the small ones. COR2. Universities are more likely to license to big companies. COR3. Cats that are spayed or neutered automatically gain weight.

Overconfidence bias ( α=0.82) (New items, following Forbes, 2005; and Brenner et al., 1996) (On the first page of the survey) Below are some challenging questions. One of the two possible answers is correct. Please work through the questions quickly and check the box with response that best represents your answer. OV1. Which country has a higher percentage of entrepreneurs: Canada or New Zealand? How sure are you? (score: 50% … 100%) OV2. What is farther away from Seattle: London or Beijing? How sure are you with your answer to this question? (score: 50% … 100%) OV3. Which company was founded earlier: Nissan or Toyota? How sure are you with your answer to this question? (score: 50% … 100%) Coding algorithm : IF answer is correct THEN coding=score-5; ELSE coding=score.

Base-rate fallacy (α=0.73) We present some hypothetical scenarios below. Please give us your opinion for each of the scenarios. BAS1. (New case) National statistics show that around 60% of funded high-tech startups failed in the first five years. John has just received funding from a VC to start up a high-tech firm. During your lunch today, one of John’s friends told you that he and John like to watch NFL games together and that John is well liked by his friends. What is your estimated probability that John's company will fail within the first five years? (0-100%) Coding algorithm : IF score>=6 THEN coding=score-6; ELSE coding=6-score.

BAS2. (Case taken from Lynch and Ofir, 1989; and adjusted based on pre-test) Your friend Tom is looking for a 5 year old used car and asks for your help. "Consumer Reports" suggests that 50% of this model will require some major repairs during the 6 th year. Tom just called you to let you know that he went to look at the car. He really likes the exterior color and the leather seats. What is your estimated probability that Tom will need some major repairs next year? (0-100%) Coding algorithm : IF score>=5 THEN coding=score-5; ELSE coding=5-score.

Illusion of control ( α=0.88) (Taken from Simon et al., 2000; and Zuckerman et al., 1996)

134  Appendices Below we list some personality characteristics. Please circle the number next to each statement that best represents your degree of disagreement or agreement (where 1=Strongly Disagree; 4=Neutral; 7=Strongly Agree; and numbers between 1 and 7 represent the varying degrees). IC1. I can accurately predict total market demand for my venture's product and services for the next 3 years. IC2. I can accurately predict when larger competitors would enter the market. IC3. I can succeed at making this venture a success, even though many others would fail. IC4. There is no such thing as misfortune; everything that happens to us is the result of our own doing. IC5. In each and every task, not finishing successfully reflects a lack of motivation.

Law of small numbers ( α=0.85) (Modified from Simon et al., 2000; and Mohan-Neill, 1995) Below we list some personality characteristics. Please circle the number next to each statement that best represents your degree of disagreement or agreement (where 1=Strongly Disagree; 4=Neutral; 7=Strongly Agree; and numbers between 1 and 7 represent the varying degrees). SN1. When making strategic decisions, it is sufficient to ask the opinion of a few of my closest friends and colleagues. SN2. When making strategic decisions, I always use more than one source of information. (R) SN3. I do not make decisions until I have results of large scale market research. (R)

Regression fallacy (New, following the example from Kahneman and Tversky, 1973) We present some hypothetical scenarios below. Please give us your opinion for each of the scenarios. Assuming that your firm operates in a stable economic environment. Two years ago, the sales of your products increased by 15%. You made a decision to increase your advertising budget by 25% last year. However, you just got a report showing that the sales decreased by 5% last year. How likely would you conclude that the advertising was not effective? (0-100%)

Independent variables

Experiential system ( α=0.98) (Taken from Epstein et al., 1996; Pacini and Epstein, 1999) Below we list some personality characteristics. Please circle the number next to each statement that best represents your degree of disagreement or agreement (where 1=Strongly Disagree; 4=Neutral; 7=Strongly Agree; and numbers between 1 and 7 represent the varying degrees). ES1. I like to rely on my intuitive impressions. ES2. Using my gut feelings usually works well for me in figuring out problems in my life. ES3. I believe in trusting my hunches. ES4. Intuition can be a very useful way to solve problems. ES5. I often go by my instincts when deciding on a course of action.

Appendices  135 Rational system ( α=0.94) (Taken from Epstein et al., 1996; Pacini and Epstein, 1999) Below we list some personality characteristics. Please circle the number next to each statement that best represents your degree of disagreement or agreement (where 1=Strongly Disagree; 4=Neutral; 7=Strongly Agree; and numbers between 1 and 7 represent the varying degrees). RS1. I try to avoid situations that require thinking in depth about something. (R) RS2. I enjoy solving problems that require hard thinking. RS3. I am much better at figuring things out logically than most people. RS4. I have a logical mind. RS5. I don't reason well under pressure. (R)

(R) Indicates a reversed item

136  Appendices

A4.1. Constructs, measurement items, and construct reliabilities for Chapter 4

Dependent variables

Return on Investment (taken from and based on Lambert, 1998 and McDougall et al., 1994): Please provide your best estimates for the following information about your firm: The return on investment in the last fiscal year: ______%

Customer retention rate (taken from and based on Lambert, 1998 and McDougall et al., 1994): Please provide your best estimates for the following information about your firm: Customer retention rate in your primary served market: ______%

Sales growth rate (taken from and based on Lambert, 1998 and McDougall et al., 1994): Please provide your best estimates for the following information about your firm: The rate of sales growth in the last fiscal year: ______%

Independent variables

Strategic avoidance (based on Miller, 1992 and Shane, 2003) ( α=0.79) Please rate the following statements (7-point Likert scale: 0=strongly disagree to 7=strongly agree): 1. We tend to introduce our products to market niches with low uncertainty first 2. We tend to postpone a market entry if the market is too uncertain 3. We prefer to grow from small scale to large scale when entering a new market

Strategic imitation (taken from and based on Gatignon and Xuereb, 1997 and Miller, 1992) (α=0.81) Please rate the following statements (7-point Likert scale: 0=strongly disagree to 7=strongly agree): 1. Overall, our products are similar to our main competitors' products 2. For our products, we imitate certain manufacturing techniques of other firms 3. We follow our competitors in moving into new markets

Strategic control (based on Miller, 1992) ( α=0.86) Please rate the following statements (7-point Likert scale: 0=strongly disagree to 7=strongly agree): 1. We try to increase entry barriers for new competitors to enter our primary served market 2. We try to influence consumers through advertising 3. We try to use contractual agreements with suppliers for all of our products

Strategic cooperation (taken from Li and Atuahene-Gima, 2001) ( α=0.65) Please rate the following statements (7-point Likert scale: 0=strongly disagree to 7=strongly agree):

Appendices  137 1. We have cooperative agreements with other firms to manufacture our products 2. We collaborate with other firms to promote our products 3. We jointly distribute our products with other firms

Real options strategy (based on Huchzermeier and Loch, 2001; McGrath et al., 2004): (α=0.86) Please rate the following statements (7-point Likert scale: 0=strongly disagree to 7=strongly agree): 1. We invest in new products in stages to allow management to decide whether or not to proceed with the projects based on newest information available 2. When developing a new product, we always make sure that we can expand the scale of this project if market conditions turn out to be more favorable than expected. 3. When developing new products, we try to keep our technological design options open until we have enough information to make a choice.

Moderating variables

Markets with technology standards (based on Warner, Fairbank and Steensma, 2006) The technology standards in our primary served markets are (please check one only): □ Well-established □ Emerging

Markets with high direct network externalities (based on Katz and Shapiro, 1985,1986) (α=0.72) Please rate the following characteristics of your firm and its market (7-point Likert scale: 1= strongly disagree; 7= strongly agree): 1. In our primary served markets, the values of our product to customers depends not only on the features of the products themselves, but also on the number of people who are using these products 2. In our primary served markets, the price customers are willing to pay for a product increases as more people adopt the product

Markets with high indirect network externalities (based on Schilling, 2002) Please rate the following characteristics of your firm and its market: In your primary served markets, the importance of the availability of complementary products and/or services is: (7-point Likert scale: 1= very low; 7= very high)

Appendix B: Additional tables

B2.1. Methodological characteristics of the articles included in the meta-analysis

Performance Venture Min Max # Article Country Industry Sample type N Measure Origin Age Age Bamberger, Bacharach and Electronics, computer, VC-backed and other Not 1 Israel Financial 0 10 35 Dyer 1989 biotechnology and related DBs indicated Semicondu ctors, magnetic media, Not 2 Bantel 1997 US measuring and controlling General General DBs 5 12 166 indicated devices, optical instruments, etc Bloodgood, Sapienza and Medical products, commercial Not 3 US Financial IPO and VC-backed 0 5 61 Almeida 1996 research, computers, etc indicated Carpenter, Pollock and Leary Electrical and electronic 4 US Financial IPO Independent 0 10 97 2003 equipment IT, electronics, mechanical Not 5 Chamanski and Waagø 2001 Norway engineering, biotechnology, high- Financial General DBs 0 10 55 indicated tech consultancy Government support 6 Doutriaux 1991 Canada Electronics, telecom and related Financial Both 0 8 73 programs

Government support 7 Doutriaux 1992 Canada Electronics, telecom and related Financial Both 0 8 73 programs

8 Dowling and McGee 1994 US Telecom equipment Financial IPO Independent 0 ** 52

Eisenhardt and Schoonhoven 9 US Semiconductors Financial General DBs Independent 4 4*** 66 1990 George, Zahra, Wheatley and 10 US Biotechnology Financial IPO Both 0 ** 143 Khan 2001

Appendices  139 Performance Venture Min Max # Article Country Industry Sample type N Measure Origin Age Age George, Zahra and Wood 11 US Biotechnology Financial IPO Both 0 ** 147 2002 12 Kazanjian and Drazin 1990 US Electronics, computer and related Financial VC-backed Independent 0 15 105 Computer hardware and related 13 Kazanjian and Rao 1999 US Financial VC-backed Independent 0 15 71 equipment

Electrical and electronic products, 14 Lee, Lee and Pennings 2001 Korea Financial General DBs Independent 0 ** 137 biotechnology, software

IT, telecom, computing, electronics, optic-mechanic and Financial and 15 Li 2001 China General DBs Both 0 8 184 electri c products, new energy and market materials, biotechnology, etc IT, telecom, computing, electronics, optic-mechanic and 16 Li and Atuahene-Gima 2002 China General General DBs Both 0 8 184 electric products, new energy and materials, biotechnology, etc IT, telecom, computing, electronics, optic-mechanic and Financial and 17 Li and Atuahene-Gima 2001 China General DBs Both 0 8 184 electric products, new energy and market materials, biotechnology, etc Telecom, electronic and industrial 18 Lumme 1998 Finland Financial General DBs Independent 0 5 88 equipment, chemicals, etc Medical and navigation Not 19 Marino and De Noble 1997 US Financial IPO 1 16 28 equipment and instruments indicated Financial and 20 McDougall and Oviatt 1996 US Computer and telecom equipment General DBs Both 0 8 62 market McDougall, Covin, Robinson 21 US Computer and telecom equipment Financial General DBs Independent 0 8 123 and Herron 1994 Electronics, computing, telecom 22 McGee and Dowling 1994 US Financial IPO Independent 0 8 210 and related

140  Appendices

Performance Venture Min Max # Article Country Industry Sample type N Measure Origin Age Age Telecom and computing McGee, Dowling and 23 US equipment, prof. and scientific Financial IPO Independent 0 8 210 Megginson 1995 instruments Electrical and electron ic products, Government support Not 24 Miles, Preece and Baetz 1999 Canada General 0 ** 112 software programs indicated 25 Qian and Li 2003 US Biotechnology Financial General DBs Independent 5 ** 67 Robinson and McDougall Electronics, computer, 26 US Financial IPO Independent 0 6 115 2001 biotechnology and related Not 27 Seiders and Riley 1999 US Internet Financial IPO 0 ** 38 indicated

Financial and 28 Zahra and Bogner 2000 US Software General DBs Both 0 8 116 market

Medical products, software, 29 Zahra, Ireland and Hitt 2000 US Financial International Both 0 6 321 telecom, semiconductors, etc. Zahra, Matherne and Carleton 30 US Software Financial International Both 0 8 67 2003 Zahra, Neubaum and Huse Not 31 US Telecom equipment Financial General DBs 0 8 121 1997 indicated * - interaction effect significant at 0.05 level ** - no information was reported in the study; study included on the basis of means and standard deviations *** - correlation matrix was given for the companies in their 4th year

Appendices  141

B2.2. Publication sources of the studies included in this meta-analysis

Number of Publication Source: studies in meta- analysis Academy of Management Journal 2 Administrative Science Quarterly 1 Doctoral dissertation 1 Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 2 Frontiers of Entrepreneurship Research Conference papers 1 Human Resource Management 1 IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management 1 Internal report/working paper 1 Journal of Business Venturing 6 Journal of High Technology Management Research 4 Journal of International Entrepreneurship 1 Journal of Small Business Management 1 Management Science 1 Organization Studies 1 Strategic Management Journal 7

142  Appendices

B3.1. LISREL results for the Systems-Biases-Risk-Taking mediation (standardized solution)

Hindsight Law of Illusory Over- Base-rate Illusion of Regression Independent Risk-taking bias small correlation confidence fallacy control fallacy variables: propensity (H3a and numbers (H3a and b) (H3a and b) (H3a and b) (H3a and b) (H3a and b) b) (H3a and b) Hindsight bias (H1a) -0.73** Illusory correlation (H1b) 0.21 ** Overconfidence (H1c) 0.68 ** Base-rate fallacy (H1d) 0.19 ** Illusion of control (H1e) 0.36 *** Law of small numbers 0.26 *** (H1f) Regression fallacy (H1g) 0.25 *** Experiential system (H2a) -0.03 a 0.25 *** 0.38 *** 0.29 *** 0.09 0.22 *** 0.38 *** 0.13 * Rational system (H2b) -0.17 **b -0.31 *** 0.01 -0.26 *** 0.04 -0.28 *** -0.02 -0.12 * Significance levels are based on unstandardized coefficients * p<0.05; ** p<0.01; *** p<0.001 a Total std. effect of the Experiential system on Risk-taking propensity is 0.28 b Total std. effect of the Rational system on Risk-taking propensity is -0.25 Model fit: χ2=943.48, df=468, RMSEA=0.059, DELTA2=0.97, CFI=0.96, NFI=0.93, NNFI=0.96

Appendices  143 Appendix C: Formulas

C2.1. Formulas for variances calculations

Var total = Var real +Var artif +Var s.e. , where :

Var total : variance of the observed correlatio ns from the primary studies;

Var real : real variance of the population correlatio n;

Var artif : variance due to artifacts (dichotomi zation and reliabilit ies);

Var s.e. : variance due to sampling error.

Var real = Var total −Var artif −Var s.e.

95% confidence interval is 1.96 Var real

Meta - factor is moderated if Var real > 25% Var total

n 2 oo oo ∑[Ni (r i − r ) ] i=1 Var total = n ,

∑ Ni i=1 where : roo i : observed correlatio n of the primary study i;

roo : weighted average of the observed correlatio ns of the primary studies, n oo ∑ Ni r i i=1 oo so that r = n .

∑ Ni i=1   2 2 2 2 Var ( Rxx ) Var ( Ryy )  Var = ρ A V = ro V = ro + artif    Rxx Ryy   2 2   2 2   2 2   2 2  1 − r  D 2 1 − r  1 − r  D 1 − r   oo   1    oo    oo    oo   Var s.e. = + ∑   −1  = + ∑  .0 5625   ad  Ndi −1 Ndi −1 N −1 di=1    N −1 di=1      

Summary  145 Short summary

Entrepreneurial risk-taking beyond bounded rationality:

Risk factors, cognitive biases and strategies of new technology ventures

Entrepreneurship is inherently associated with the notion of risk. This dissertation consists of three main parts approaching entrepreneurial risk from different perspectives. The first part is about the risk and success factors that new technology ventures have to deal with. The second part is about how experienced entrepreneurs take risks. Finally, the third part is about strategies that should be followed to manage risks and uncertainties surrounding new technology ventures.

The thesis starts with a systematic quantitative exploration of existing research on success factors of new technology ventures. The absence of such factors represents risks that new technology ventures should avoid. We use meta-analysis (Hunter and Schmidt, 1990; 2004) – a technique allowing to directly compare the results of extant studies by correcting for sample size differences, measurement quality and eventual dichotomization of variables. We found that scholars agree about the importance of only about half of the researched factors. Among them, supply chain integration and broad market scope are the most crucial success factors, while such factors as prior start-up and R&D experience are surprisingly not related to performance of new technology ventures – at least not directly. Potentially the strongest success and risk factors are among the factors that researchers disagreed upon. Part of researchers' disagreement can be resolved by considering the differences in the samples they used. For example, for independent new technology ventures such factors as R&D alliances and product innovation turned out to be strong risk factors, while in samples with corporate ventures those were strong success factors. Our review of research on new technology ventures also indicated that there is little known about the more precise mechanism of risk-taking applied by entrepreneurs: there is a lack of studies of entrepreneurial decision-making in situations involving risk and of the strategies entrepreneurs use to mitigate those risks.

146  Summary The second part of the thesis digs deeper into how entrepreneurs take risks. Fast and straight-forward intuitive decision-making is particularly useful for entrepreneurs, which are often operating in complex and dynamic contexts with high time pressures. However, intuition comes together with cognitive biases – errors in intuitive judgment arising due to the heuristic nature of intuition. In this study we investigate a total of seven biases. For example, overconfidence bias is the failure to know the limits of one's knowledge resulting in unjustified confidence in one's own judgments. Simply put: it is not what you know, but whether you know what you know and what you do not know. Another bias, base-rate fallacy, occurs when only qualitative information is used to make a probability judgment, ignoring available statistical information about prior probabilities (the base-rate frequency). It is important since research shows that people tend to ignore statistics when at least some qualitative information is available. What makes the bias really problematic is that base-rate fallacy will still exist even if the qualitative information is irrelevant for the decision. These and other cognitive biases can potentially distort the risks picture and result in a wrong strategic decision. We use dual process theory in order to explore whether rational and intuitive thinking can help respectively avoid and strengthen the effects of the cognitive biases on the entrepreneurial risk-taking. To answer this question, we use a dataset of 289 experienced American entrepreneurs. The overall results show that while intuition strengthens entrepreneurial risk-taking only indirectly via cognitive biases, rational thinking can both diminish the influence of biases and decrease entrepreneurial risk-taking directly. Thus, the more entrepreneurs think, the fewer risks they take. At the same time, intuition only infuses risk-taking when entrepreneurs do not filter out the cognitive biases. Focusing on biases in more detail, all the seven biases we investigated are significantly related to the risk-taking propensity of entrepreneurs. However, six of the seven biases increase risk-taking, while one of them – hindsight bias – actually leads to risk-averse behavior. Rational thinking can correct the influence of four of the seven biases. Three biases – illusory correlation, base-rate fallacy and law of small numbers – can not be corrected by rational thinking. All the biases expect for base-rate fallacy derive from intuitive thinking.

Summary  147 As a result, this study shatters three myths about entrepreneurs. First, that all entrepreneurial cognitive biases come from intuition; second, that all biases lead to greater risk-taking; and third, that entrepreneurs only have to take their time and think to make the biases disappear. Further, we found support for the statement that experienced entrepreneurs are predominantly intuitive decision-makers.

In the third part of the thesis, the effectiveness of the major risk and uncertainty management strategies of new technology ventures is compared under three conditions: when they operate in markets with existing technology standards, in markets with high direct and in markets with high indirect externalities. Direct network externalities cause an increase in product value associated with having additional users in the network, such as in case of telephone or MSN messenger. Indirect network externalities come into existence when complementary products or services are of importance for the value of the product, such as in case of DVD players and movies on DVD. We evaluate four traditional risk management strategies (avoidance, imitation, control and cooperation) and the more recent real options strategy, which is seen primarily as an uncertainty management strategy. Avoidance strategy concerns being extremely cautious with the ventures’ actions on the market – such as introducing products first to low-uncertainty niches and growing from small scale. Imitation strategy includes imitating competitors’ products and entries into new markets as well as other firms’ manufacturing techniques. Control strategy involves trying to increase entry barriers for competitors, influence customers and use specific agreements with suppliers. Cooperation strategy covers cooperation with other firms in terms of manufacturing, promoting and distributing the venture’s products. Finally, real options strategy involves creating different new product development options and targets stepwise, staged investment in one or more of these options. The investments are made only when more information becomes available and uncertainty surrounding these product options is resolved. As such real options represent a limited commitment that creates future decision rights and improves managerial flexibility. Each risk and uncertainty management strategy requires certain costs in order to be realized. Knowing which strategy works best under which conditions should allow new technology ventures to utilize their limited resources in a more efficient manner.

148  Summary We test our hypotheses using a dataset of 420 new technology ventures in the USA. The results indicate that in general new technology ventures should completely refrain from the avoidance strategy since it does not affect their profits and is detrimental for their customer retention rate and sales. New technology ventures should reconsider imitating other firms, since it does not affect their profits and only slightly improves the sales growth. Control, cooperation and real options strategies are generally very beneficial for the performance of new technology ventures. Well-established technology standards in the markets do not change the effectiveness of risk and uncertainty management strategies, but do strongly improve the performance of new technology ventures. Thus, new technology ventures should avoid participating in markets with emerging technology standards. As opposed to technology standards, both types of externalities do not influence performance directly, but do change the effectiveness of the risk and uncertainty management strategies. Not only do we find an opposite effect of direct and indirect network externalities on the effectiveness of the risk and uncertainty management strategies, but we also find an opposite effect for traditional risk management strategies and the real options strategy in markets with network externalities. In particular, direct network externalities improve the effectiveness of traditional risk management strategies and lower the effectiveness of the real options strategy, while indirect network externalities decrease the effectiveness of traditional risk management strategies and improve the effectiveness of the real options strategy.

This thesis aims to help entrepreneurs and organizations involved in their coaching and financing distinguish the factors that are important for new technology ventures' success, be aware of how different thinking processes influence entrepreneurial risks-taking decisions and learn which risk and uncertainty management strategies are best to follow. By challenging the implicit assumptions of both researchers and practitioners, the results of these three studies may help bringing entrepreneurial risk-taking beyond bounded rationality and improve the performance of entrepreneurial firms.

149 About the author

Ksenia Podoynitsyna was born in Moscow, Russia on December 14, 1980. In 2002 she graduated with cum laude from Moscow Aviation Institute (Technical University). She did her graduation project at Global Risk Management Solutions department of PricewaterhouseCoopers. Her Master’s thesis focused on Monte-Carlo simulations in risk evaluation of software implementation projects. Soon after graduation she moved to the Netherlands and did a couple of projects as IT systems administrator. This dissertation is a result of the PhD research Ksenia conducted in the Organization Science and Marketing Group within the Department of Technology Management at Eindhoven University of Technology between 2003 and 2007. Her major research interests include risk and uncertainty management, entrepreneurial cognition and creativity templates in new product development and business models of new ventures.

151 ECIS dissertation series

1. Wynstra, J.Y.F. (10-09-1998). Purchasing involvement in product development. Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 320 pp. 2. Koops, B.J. (06-01-1999). The crypto controversy. A key conflict in the information society. SOBU Eindhoven/Tilburg, 301 pp. 3. Timmer, M.P. (18-10-1999). The dynamics of Asian manufacturing. Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 261 pp. 4. Punt, P.T.I.J. (21-12-2000). Effectieve en robuuste organisatieveranderingen in het productcreatieproces. Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 356 pp. 5. Rozemeijer, F.A. (14-09-2000). Creating corporate advantage in purchasing. Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 251 pp. 6. Wouters, J.P.M. (16-11-2000). Customer service as a competitive marketing instrument: an industrial supply chain perspective. Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 264 pp. 7. Bekkers, R.N.A. (15-06-2001). The development of European mobile telecommunication standards. Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 575 pp. 8. Migchels, N.G. (04-09-2001). The ties that bind. Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 193 pp. 9. Yamfwa, F.K. (02-10-2001). Improving manufacturing performance in LDC's. Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 229 pp. 10. Premaratne, S.P. (24-04-2002). Entrepreneurial networks and small business development: The case of small enterprises in Sri Lanka. Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 276 pp. 11. Vos, J.P. (18-06-2002). The making of strategic realities: An application of the social systems theory of Niklas Luhmann, Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 276 pp. 12. Berends, J.J. (07-02-2003). Knowledge sharing in industrial research, Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 248 pp. 13. Lemmens, C.E.A.V. (02-12-2003). Network dynamics and innovation: The effects of social embeddedness in technology alliance blocks, Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 154 pp. 14. Echtelt van, F.E.A. (04-03-2004). New product development: shifting suppliers into gear, Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 370 pp. 15. Beerkens, B.E. (15-09-2004). External acquisition of technology. Exploration and exploitation in international innovation networks. Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 160 pp.

152

16. Nuvolari, A. (23-09-2004). The making of steam power technology: A study of technological change during the British Industrial Revolution. Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 207 pp. 17. Heimeriks, K.H. (15-02-2005). Developing alliance capabilities. Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 198 pp. 18. Dijk van, M. (23-02-2005). Industry evolution and catch up. The case of the Indonesian pulp and paper industry. Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 219 pp. 19. Raven, R.P.J.M. (21-06-2005). Strategic niche management for biomass. Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 321 pp. 20. Jacob, J. (02-05-2006). International technology spillovers and manufacturing performance in Indonesia. Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 203 pp. 21. Bakema, F. (13-09-2006). The emergence of a competitive group competence in a research group: a process study. Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 352 pp. 22. Lim, A.S. (12-10-2006), Power battles in ICT standards-setting process: Lessons from mobile payments. Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 228 pp. 23. Kemp, J.L.C. (29-11-2006), Configurations of corporate strategy systems in knowledge-intensive enterprises: an explorative study. Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 334 pp . 24. Antioco, M.D.J. (20-12-2006), Service orientations of manufacturing companies: Impact on new product success. Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 161 pp. 25. Kesidou, E. (17-04-2007), Local knowledge spillovers in high-tech clusters in developing countries: The case of the Uruguayan software cluster. Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 221 pp. 26. Ho, H.C. M. (24-04-2007), On explaining locational patterns of R&D activities by multinational enterprises. Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 250 pp. 27. Van de Vrande, V.J.A. (07-11-2007), Not : Managing corporate innovation in the new era. Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 155 pp. 28. Schepers, J.J.L. (31-01-2008), Me and you and everyone we know: Social influences and processes in technology adoption. Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 153 pp. 29. Menzel, H.C. (26-03-2008). Intrapreneurship-conducive culture in industrial R&D: The design of a simulation game to create awareness and provide insight. Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 206 pp. 30. Podoynitsyna, K.S. (11-06-2008), Entrepreneurial risk-taking beyond bounded rationality: Risk factors, cognitive biases and strategies of new technology ventures. Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 152 pp.