The Matthew Effect and Federal Taxation

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Matthew Effect and Federal Taxation University of Florida Levin College of Law UF Law Scholarship Repository UF Law Faculty Publications Faculty Scholarship 9-2004 The Matthew Effect and Federal Taxation Martin J. McMahon Jr. University of Florida Levin College of Law, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.ufl.edu/facultypub Part of the Law and Society Commons, Taxation-Federal Commons, Taxation-Federal Estate and Gift Commons, and the Tax Law Commons Recommended Citation Martin J. McMahon, Jr., The Matthew Effect and Federal Taxation, 45 B.C. L. Rev. 993 (2004), available at http://scholarship.law.ufl.edu/facultypub/399 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at UF Law Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in UF Law Faculty Publications by an authorized administrator of UF Law Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. THE MATTHEW EFFECT AND FEDERAL TAXATION MARTIN J. MCMAHON, JR.* For whosoever hath, to him shall be given, and he shall have more abun- dance; But whosoever hath not, from him shall be taken away even that he hath. -Matthew 25:29 Abstract: The "Matthew Effect" is a synonym for the well-known collo- quialism, "the rich get richer and the poor get poorer." This Article is about the Matthew Effect in the distribution of incomes in the United States and the failure of the federal tax system to address the problem. There has been a strong Matthew Effect in incomes in the United States over the past few decades, with an increasing concentration of income and wealth in the top one percent. Nevertheless, there has been a con- tinuing trend of enacting disproportionately large tax cuts for those at the top of the income pyramid. Neither economic theory nor empirical evidence supports the argument that these tax cuts increase incentives to save, invest, and work. A growing body of economic literature sup- ports the thesis that economic inequality impedes economic growth in- stead of fostering it. Furthermore, in a modern industrialized democ- racy, most of what everyone earns is attributable to infrastructure created by society acting through government. Paradoxically, public concern with increasing economic inequality is not matched by opposi- tion to tax legislation that delivers vastly disproportionate benefits to the super-rich. This Article suggests that future tax legislation ought to miti- gate the Matthew Effect rather than enhance it. INTRODUCTION The term, the "Matthew Effect," was coined by sociologist Robert K. Merton in 1968 based on the passage from the Gospel of Matthew * Clarence J. TeSelle Professor of Law, University of Florida College of Law. I would like to thank Alice G. Abreu, Christopher H. Hanna, Paul R. McDaniel, David M. Richard- son, and James R. Repetti for their helpful comments on earlier drafts of this Article. All opinions expressed herein and any remaining errors are my own. 993 Boston College Law Review [Vol. 45:993 in the epigram.1 "Put in less stately language, the Matthew Effect con- sists in the accruing of greater increments of recognition for particu- lar scientific contributions to scientists of considerable repute and the withholding of such recognition from scientists who have not yet made their mark."2 The Matthew Effect is not limited to the context in which Robert Merton first coined it. More generally, it is a synonym for the well-known colloquial aphorism, "The rich get richer and the poor get poorer." This Article is about the Matthew Effect in the dis- tribution of incomes in the United States and the failure of the fed- eral tax system to address the Matthew Effect. Over twenty years ago, economist Paul Samuelson observed, "If we made an income pyramid out of a child's blocks, with each layer $1000 of income, the peak would be far higher than the portraying 3 Eiffel Tower, but most of us would be within a yard of the ground." Things have changed a lot since then, and things have changed little since then. The peak is higher, but most people are still in essentially the same place. During the last two decades of the twentieth century, the distribution of incomes and wealth in the United States reached levels of inequality that have not been seen since the Roaring Twen- ties. Although the "Roaring Nineties," as the decade was labeled by Joseph E. Stiglitz, might have been "the world's most prosperous dec- ade,"4 the prosperity was not spread around. The data indicate that a very small number of people garnered an overwhelming amount of the increase in incomes and wealth in that decade, as well as in the prior decade. Between 1947 and 1997, median family income (in constant dol- lars) grew by 122%. 5 Ninety-one percent of this growth, however, oc- curred before 1970. Between 1979 and 1997, average household be- fore-tax income grew by nearly one-third in real terms, but that growth was shared unevenly across the income distribution. Average income for households in the top quintile rose by more than one-half, while average income for the middle quintile increased by only 10% I See Matthew 25:29; Robert K. Merton, The Matthew Effect in Science, 159 SCIENCE 56, 58 (1968). 2 Merton, supra note 1, at 58. 3 PAUL SAMUELSON, ECONOMICS 80 (11th ed. 1980). 4 JOsEPH E. STIGLITZ, THE ROARING NINETIES (2003) (referencing cover). 5 Daniel H. Weinberg et al., Fifty Years of U.S. Income Data from the Current Population Survey: Alternatives, Trends, and Quality, 89 AM. ECON. REV. 18, 20 (1999) (indicating growth in the median family income from $20,102 to $44,368 (in 1997 dollars)). 20041 The Matthew Effect &Federal Taxation and average income for the lowest quintile decreased slightly.6 In- come growth at the very top of the distribution was even greater. Av- erage before-tax income in 1997 dollars for the top 1% of households more than doubled, rising from $420,000 in 1979 to more than $1 7 million in 1997. Inequality continued to increase in the late-1990s. During the 1950s and 1960s, family income inequality decreased, but the tide changed after 1969, and through the last three decades of the twentieth century income inequality increased. 8 Nevertheless, the federal tax system did little to ameliorate the increasing economic ine- quality. Prior to 1982, high marginal rates at the top had some redis- tributive effects. Redistributive effects were reduced as a result of the rate reductions in the Economic Recovery Act of 1981 (the "1981 Act"), and after the Tax Reform Act of 1986 (the "1986 Act"), the redistribu- tive effect of the income tax was relatively low.9 Adoption of the 39.6% bracket in 1993 increased the redistributive effects of the income tax, but redistribution decreased again as a result of the reduction in capital gains rates in 1997. As of 2000, the redistributive effect of the income tax was somewhat less than it was in the early 1980s, although it was somewhat greater than it was in the early 1990s.10 As we move into the new millennium, however, recent changes in the federal tax system pre- sage a decreasing role not only in redistribution, but in mitigation of vast disparities in income and wealth. Since the inauguration of the Bush Administration1" in 2000, there have been three major tax acts, which have reduced significantly the tax burden of the super-rich, while handing out small change to everyone else. Part I of this Article examines in detail the increasing concentra- tion of income and wealth in the top 1%, and particularly within much narrower cohorts near the top of the top 1%, that has occurred 6 CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, EFFECTIVE FEDERAL TAX RATES, 1979-1997, at 6, 7 & fig.l-5 (2001), available at http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/30xx/doc3089/EffectiveTaxRate.pdf (last modified Nov. 13, 2001). 7 See id. at 10, 11, 170-71 app.J. Although the Congressional Budget Office did not in- clude comprehensive data for years after 1997, the study states that the rapid rise in the share of income going to the top of the distribution continued at least into 1998 and 1999. See id. 8 SeeWeinberg et al., supra note 5, at 21. 9Thomas B. Petska et al., New Estimates of the Distributionof Individual Income and Taxes, in 2002 PROCEEDINGS OF THE 95TH ANNUAL NATIONAL TAX ASSOCIATION CONFERENCE ON TAXATION 342, 350 (2003). 10Id. at 349. 11 All references to the "Administration" or the "Bush Administration" are to the George W. Bush Administration unless otherwise indicated. Boston College Law Review [Vol. 45:993 over the past twenty-five years. 12 This Part demonstrates the strong Matthew Effect in incomes in the United States over that period. The super-rich are pulling away from everyone by so much and at a rate so fast that the fact that incomes of many households at the bottom and in the middle have stagnated, or even fallen in constant dollars, has been obscured by ever increasing per capita income-a false talisman of progress because it obscures distributional issues. Part II discusses the distribution of after-tax income and wealth in the United States in recent years. 13 Wealth and income levels are highly correlated. This Part describes the increasing disparity in after- tax incomes, particularly the rate at which the amount and share of total after-tax income of the top 0.5%, and even of smaller cohorts further toward the top of the income pyramid, are growing relative to everyone else. Moreover, the share of wealth owned by the super-rich is growing even faster than its share of income.
Recommended publications
  • The Matthew Effect in Empirical Data
    The Matthew effect in empirical data Matjazˇ Perc∗ Faculty of Natural Sciences and Mathematics, University of Maribor, Koroskaˇ cesta 160, SI-2000 Maribor, Slovenia The Matthew effect describes the phenomenon that in societies the rich tend to get richer and the potent even more powerful. It is closely related to the concept of preferential attachment in network science, where the more connected nodes are destined to acquire many more links in the future than the auxiliary nodes. Cumulative ad- vantage and success-breads-success also both describe the fact that advantage tends to beget further advantage. The concept is behind the many power laws and scaling behaviour in empirical data, and it is at the heart of self-organization across social and natural sciences. Here we review the methodology for measuring preferential attachment in empirical data, as well as the observations of the Matthew effect in patterns of scientific collabora- tion, socio-technical and biological networks, the propagation of citations, the emergence of scientific progress and impact, career longevity, the evolution of common English words and phrases, as well as in education and brain development. We also discuss whether the Matthew effect is due to chance or optimisation, for example related to homophily in social systems or efficacy in technological systems, and we outline possible directions for future research. Keywords: Matthew effect, preferential attachment, cumulative advantage, self-organization, power law, empirical data I. INTRODUCTION tally on the assumption that an initially small advantage in numbers may snowball over time [29]. The Gibrat law of pro- portional growth [30], inspired by the assumption that the size The Gospel of St.
    [Show full text]
  • CHALLENGING the MATTHEW EFFECT International Exchange of Publications in Four Finnish Learned Societies Until the Second World War
    COMMENTATIONES SCIENTIARUM SOCIALIUM 76 Johanna Lilja CHALLENGING THE MATTHEW EFFECT International Exchange of Publications in Four Finnish Learned Societies until the Second World War THE FINNISH SOCIETY OF SCIENCE AND LETTERS HELSINKI 2012 COMMENTATIONES SCIENTIARUM SOCIALIUM Editor: Leif Nordberg Copyright © 2012 by Johanna Lilja and The Finnish Society of Science and Letters Cover design: Maarit Inbar Front cover: Based on illustration from the Gospel of St. Matthew, woodcut on the New Testament (Se wsi Testamenti) 1548. Back cover: The postcard sent on February 12th 1913 by Zeitschrift für wissenschaftliche Insektenbiologie to the Societas pro Fauna et Flora Fennica (National Library of Finland, the Archive of the Societas pro Fauna et Flora Fennica). The series Commentationes Scientiarum Socialium is part of the publishing cooperation between the Finnish Society of Science and Letters and the Finnish Academy of Science and Letters, established in 1996. Distributor: Bookstore Tiedekirja Kirkkokatu 14, FIN-00170 HELSINKI, Finland Tel +358-9-635 177 [email protected] www.tiedekirja.fi ISSN 0355-256X ISBN 978-951-653-391-2 Vammalan Kirjapaino Oy Sastamala 2012 ABSTR ACT Lilja, Johanna (2012). Challenging the Matthew Effect. International Exchange of Publications in Four Finnish Learned Societies until the Second World War. Com- mentationes Scientiarum Socialium 76. 352 p. ISBN 978-951-653-391-2, ISSN 0355- 256X. The Finnish Society of Science and Letters. Helsinki. The thesis addresses the international exchange of publications of Finnish learned so- cieties from the early nineteenth century until the Second World War. Exchange of publications refers to the regular and mutual delivery of books and journals between institutions.
    [Show full text]
  • The Matthew and Matilda Effects: the Phenomenon of Under-Recognition in Science
    The Matthew and Matilda effects: the phenomenon of under-recognition in science. Assignment written by Diana Grajales Abellán. October 2016. Lund University. Modern science is built based on cooperation, trust, competence and fairness between collaborative projects that involve a group of researchers (graduate students, PhDs, post-docs, senior researchers…). Furthermore, it is often seen that the research group extends the network to different collaborations and relationships with other colleagues. This cooperative way of building knowledge facilitates the trustworthiness of society in research (1). However, science is not completely objective, and it can be affected by psychological and social factors that determine the scientific paradigm of the moment, as Thomas Kuhn proposed in 1962 (2). Two good examples of these social factors that compromise scientific objectivity are the Matthew and Matilda effects. In short, the Matthew effect describes that contributions made by “high standing” scientists are the most visible ones, while contributions from less-known scientists are unnoticed. On the other hand, the Matilda effect explains that the work made by women scientists is sometimes seen as work of lower-quality compared to similar work made by their male peers. In this assignment, I will try to review both effects and explain some characteristics examples of both phenomenon. The Matthew effect was first described by the sociologist Robert K. Merton in 1968. The idea refers to the possibility that research done by well-known and renowned scientists receives greater attention than scientific work performed by emerging scientists. This phenomenon would comprise factors such as number of publications, number of citations, publication in high-impact journals, relevant work at universities, founding, etc.
    [Show full text]
  • The Matthew Effect in Science, II : Cumulative Advantage and The
    The Matthew Effect in Science, II Cumulative Advantage and the Symbolism of Intellectual Property By Robert K. Merton* HE SUBJECT OF THIS ESSAY is a problem in the sociology of science T that has long been of interest to me. That problem, a candid friend tells me, is somewhat obscured by the formidable title assigned to it. Yet, properly deci- phered, the title is not nearly as opaque as it might at first seem. Consider first the signal emitted by the Roman numeral II in the main title. It informs us that the paper follows on an earlier one, “The Matthew Effect in Science, ” which I finally put into print a good many years ago.’ The ponderous, not to say lumpy, subtitle goes on to signal the direction of this follow-on. The first concept, cumulative advantage, applied to the domain of science, refers to the social processes through which various kinds of opportunities for scientific inquiry as well as the subsequent symbolic and material rewards for the results of that inquiry tend to accumulate for individual practitioners of science, as they do also for organizations engaged in scientific work. The concept of cumulative advantage directs our attention to the ways in which initial comparative advan- tages of trained capacity 7 structural location , and available resources make for successive increments of ad vantage s uch that the gaps between the hav es and the have-nots in science (as in other domains of social life) widen until dampened by countervailing processes. The second phrase in the subtitle directs us to the distinctive character of intellectual property in science.
    [Show full text]
  • |||GET||| Robert K. Merton Sociology of Science and Sociology As
    ROBERT K. MERTON SOCIOLOGY OF SCIENCE AND SOCIOLOGY AS SCIENCE 1ST EDITION DOWNLOAD FREE Craig Calhoun | 9780231151139 | | | | | Robert K. Merton This notion of functional alternative is important because it alerts sociologists to the similar functions different institutions may perform and it further reduces the tendency of functionalism to imply approval of the status quo. There are very few other books in sociology. Retrieved The Craft of Sociology. In other words, Merton believes that the American Dream is a cultural ideal, but the ways in which people go about obtaining it are Robert K. Merton Sociology of Science and Sociology as Science 1st edition the same. The Free Press. In Merton married his fellow sociologist and collaborator, Harriet Zuckerman. The sociology of science was a field that Merton was very interested in and remained very passionate about throughout his career. Likens Victor A. Edward B. Ravetz, American Scientist "The essays not only exhibit a diverse and penetrating analysis and a deal of historical and contemporary examples, with concrete numerical data, but also make genuinely good reading because of the wit, the liveliness and the rich learning with which Merton writes. Solomon Shirley Ann Jackson. He was also influenced by Lawrence Joseph L. The Sociology of Georg Simmel. Biochemical Journal. October Advances in Protein Chemistry. In Merton became the first sociologist to be awarded the US National Medal of Science[15] for "founding the sociology of science and for his pioneering contributions to the study of social life, especially the self-fulfilling prophecy and the unintended consequences of social action. Merton initially as a stage name for his magic performances.
    [Show full text]
  • The Luke Effect and Federal Taxation: a Commentary on Mcmahon's the Matthew Effect and Federal Taxation, 45 B.C.L
    Boston College Law Review Volume 45 Issue 5 The State Of Federal Income Taxation Article 3 Symposium: Rates, Progressivity, And Budget Processes 9-1-2004 The ukL e Effect and Federal Taxation: A Commentary on McMahon's The aM tthew ffecE t and Federal Taxation Deborah H. Schenk Follow this and additional works at: http://lawdigitalcommons.bc.edu/bclr Part of the Taxation-Federal Commons Recommended Citation Deborah H. Schenk, The Luke Effect and Federal Taxation: A Commentary on McMahon's The Matthew Effect and Federal Taxation, 45 B.C.L. Rev. 1129 (2004), http://lawdigitalcommons.bc.edu/bclr/vol45/iss5/3 This Symposium is brought to you for free and open access by the Law Journals at Digital Commons @ Boston College Law School. It has been accepted for inclusion in Boston College Law Review by an authorized editor of Digital Commons @ Boston College Law School. For more information, please contact [email protected]. THE LUKE EFFECT AND FEDERAL TAXATION: A COMMENTARY ON MCMAHON'S THE MATTHEW EFFECT AND FEDERAL TAXATION DEBORAH H. SCHENK * Abstract: Professor Martin J. McMahon, Jr.'s Article demonstrates that the rich are getting richer and the poor poorer in the United States, that something must be done to deal with increasing income inequality, and that income tax rates should be more progressive. Increasing tax rates on the super-rich as he suggests, however, will not eliminate these problems by itself. There is no way to decrease income inequality without increasing rate progressivity on a wider range of taxpayers. To do so would be politically problematic, and it therefore seems unlikely that these problems can be solved through the federal tax system.
    [Show full text]
  • Tracing Scientific Influence
    Tracing scientific influence Andrea Scharnhorst†, Eugene Garfield‡ † Royal Netherlands Academy of Arts and Sciences (KNAW) The Virtual Knowledge Studio for the Humanities and Social Sciences ‡ Thomson Reuters Scientific (formerly ISI) [email protected] July 5, 2021 1 Abstract Scientometrics is the field of quantitative studies of scholarly activity. It has been used for systematic studies of the fundamentals of scholarly practice as well as for evaluation purposes. Although advocated from the very beginning the use of scientometrics as an additional method for science history is still under explored. In this paper we show how a scientometric analysis can be used to shed light on the reception history of certain outstanding scholars. As a case, we look into citation patterns of a specific paper by the American sociologist Robert K. Merton. 1 Introduction Scientometrics is a field of information and communication sciences devoted to quantitative studies of science. The term was coined by V.V. Nalimov and Z.M. Mul’chenko as title of a book about the measurement of scientific activity. [35] The systematic study of systems of thoughts was and still is inherent part of philosophy. But the growth of the academic system after World War II, the need for accountability of public spending, the increasing role of technological innovation for economic wealth, and critical debates about the role of science for society lead to a formation of a new special field devoted to the study of arXiv:1010.3525v1 [physics.soc-ph] 18 Oct 2010 scholarly activity. In this newly emerging field the more traditional epistemic and historical perspective has been combined with studying the sciences as a social system using approaches from social-psychology, sociology, and cultural studies.
    [Show full text]