Exporting Spillovers: Firm-Level Evidence from Argentina

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Exporting Spillovers: Firm-Level Evidence from Argentina LAURIER Business & Economics DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES 2008-02 EC: EXPORTING SPILLOVERS: FIRM-LEVEL EVIDENCE FROM ARGENTINA Facundo Albornoz and Maurice Kugler Department of Economics Tel: 519.884.1970 Wilfrid Laurier University, Fax: 519.888.1015 Waterloo, Ontario, Canada www.wlu.ca/sbe N2L 3C5 Exporting Spillovers: Firm-Level Evidence from Argentina∗ Facundo Albornoz† Maurice Kugler‡ February 13, 2008 Abstract We investigate whether exporting firms generate possibilities for productivity enhancement by other firms through spillovers. While spillovers have been analyzed when domestic learn from foreign-owned firms, we consider the possibility of learning from firms that export, irrespective of ownership origin. We find evidence consistent with learning from exporters to upstream producers. Foreign-owned firms that do not export do not generate spillovers. Therefore, our results suggest that export activity, as opposed to foreign direct investment (FDI) per se,isassociatedwithknowledgediffusion to input suppli- ers.Indeed, the results suggest that FDI subsidies to foster technology spillovers may well be dominated by certain export promotion strate- gies. In addition, removing barriers to exports can prove less costly than removing barriers to FDI inflows. JEL-Classification: O30, F10 Keywords: Exporting, Spillovers, FDI, Supply-Chain Linkages ∗We would like to thank for helpful conversations Matthew Cole, Rob Elliott, Ricardo Hausmann, Dani Rodrik, and Ernesto Stein. †University of Birmingham. ‡Wilfrid Laurier University, the Centre for International Governance Innovation, and Center for International Development at Harvard University. 1 1 Introduction The observation that multinational corporation (MNC) affiliates tend to have higher productivity than manufacturers surrounding them, has led re- searchers to investigate whether foreign direct investment (FDI) inflows cre- ate learning opportunities for firms in the host country. Also, it is now a well established fact that exporter firms, whether domestically or foreign owned, are more productive, more skill intensive and more innovative (e.g. Bernard, Jensen, Redding, and Schott (2007)). The motivation of the current paper is that, as in the case of MNC sub- sidiaries, the superior productivity of exporter firms may generate learn- ing opportunities for other firms. While there are many empirical studies of learning within firms associated to export status, there is little evidence about learning between firms associated with export activity. In this paper, we investigate the evidence on technology spillovers from exporters, both domestic and foreign owned, using firm level data from Argentina's manu- facturing survey data between 1992 and 2001. The evidence on FDI spillovers in developing countries shows that the presence of MNCs in downstream sectors is associated with higher produc- tivity of domestic firms in upstream sectors (e.g. Kugler (2006) and Javorcik (2004)). Furthermore, in some contexts, evidence on spillovers is associated with the activities of exporting MNC subsidiaries only and not the rest of subsidiaries (e.g. Blyde, Kugler, and Stein (2004)). This may be due to both less concern about technology leakage by exporting MNC subsidiaries as they are not competing for the host country market and to more scope for demonstration effects as exporters tend to have higher productivity. Firm heterogeneity means that there is potential learning from activities from other domestic firms, and not only MNCs. More generally, it may well be that the generation of spillovers by a firm is not due to its affiliation with a MNC but rather to its exporter status. We explore this possibility and find robust evidence consistent with spillovers from exporters only. In terms of policy, the findings are of interest because it may be much less costly at the margin to remove barriers to export activity than to FDI inflows, and removal of such barriers may prove a catalyst to export-led growth (e.g. Hausmann, Hwang, and Rodrik (2007) and Pack (1987)). 2 Data Our analysis is based on data from the manufacturing firm-level surveys conducted by the National Institute of Statistics and Censuses in Argentina 2 (INDEC). The data constitute a representative sample of the manufacturing sector and account for more than 50% of total sector sales and 60% of total exports. The surveys cover the periods 1992-1996 and 1998-2001 respectively and collect data on about 1200 firms, with roughly 700 of appearing in both samples. For details on the data set see INDEC (2002). We use a balanced panel of 673 firms providing information on sector, ownership structure, exports, imports, output, labor, skill structure, R&D expenditures, three-digit ISIC sector and TFP. TFP is the only variable that is not directly provided by the survey. The TFP variable is calculated from measures of capital stock1, labor2 and real gross output3, and implementing the Olley and Pakes (1996) method.4 Table 1 reports the summary statistics for the resulting data set. 3 Export linkages We develop measures of exporter presence within a sector and in downstream sectors following Aitken and Harrison (1999), Javorcik (2004) and Blyde, Kugler, and Stein (2004). X First, WITHINjt measures the presence of exporters in the sector in the following way: P XF Y X i8i2j ijt ijt WITHINjt = P (1) i8i2j Yijt Where XFijt is an indicator variable taking the value 1 if exports represent 5 more than 5% of total sales. Yijt stands for firm’s output. Notice that X WITHINjt increases with the output of exporters and their number in the sector. 1The capital stock includes machinery and equipment; office, accounting and computing machinery; electrical machinery and apparatus; motor vehicles, trailer and semi-trailers; and other transport equipment. 2Labor is measured by the number of workers. 3Real gross output is calculated by adjusting the reported sales for changes in inven- tories of finished goods and deflating the resulting value by the Producer Price Index for the appropriate three-digit ISIC sector. 4For details on the calculations of the capital stock and the TFP see Albornoz and Ercolani (2007). 5We use 5% as the threshold, rather than the mere observation of foreign sales in a particular year, to avoid misclassification error. Also, we have checked that the results are not sensitive to using of higher shares of foreign sales to define exporters. This is consistent with the observation by Bernard et al. (2007) that for most exporter firms sales abroad account for a relatively small share of revenue. 3 X Second, UP ST REAMjt is a measure of the presence of exporters in the sectors that are being supplied by the sector to which the firm in question belongs. This variable is a proxy for the knowledge acquired through contacts with costumers. The implicit assumption is that exporters, as firms with higher productivity and requiring high quality inputs, may share technical knowledge with their suppliers. The indicator takes the form: X X UP ST REAMjt = δjkWITHINkt (2) k if k6=j where δjk is the proportion of sector j output supplied to sector k, derived from Argentina's I/O matrix. In order to investigate whether the impact of spillovers varies across the F type of source firms, we define: WITHINjt where F stands alternatively for Domestic X, MNC X and MNC. We construct these variables in a similar way than in (1) except for the fact that XFijt indicates different types of firms. XFijt takes the value of 1 if the source firm is a domestically owned exporter (Domestic X), an exporter belonging to a MNC (MNC X) or MNC subsidiaries irrespectively of export status, respectively. F We define as well UP ST REAMjt in a way that immediately follows from (2). Table 2 provides the summary statistics for the linkages variables. 4 Estimation To examine the relationship between firm productivity and linkages with exporters, we estimate the following estimation: ∆ ln TFPi;t =β0 + γ1lnT F Pi;t−1 + γ2SRi;t−1 + γ3R&Di;t−1+ γ4FSi;t−1 + γ5WITHINj(i);t−1 + γ6UP ST REAMj(i);t−1+ τ + τj(i) + αi + "i;t; where ∆TFPit = ln(TFPi;t) − ln(TFPi;t−1) and TFPi;t stands for total factor productivity of firm i at time t. To rule out that the estimated coef- ficients simply reflect co-movement due to transitory shocks, we include ag- gregate time trends (τ). Furthermore, we include sector specific time trends (τj(i)) where j(i) stands for the sector to which firm i belongs, and we al- low for firm specific fixed effects (αi). As pointed out by Hanson (2005), if there were shocks which at the same time boost sectoral and downstream exports while making domestic plant productivity higher, and we do not con- trol for sector specific time trends, then we may interpret wrongly positive 4 estimated coefficients on the sectoral export activity variables, WITHINj(i)t 6 and UP ST REAMj(i)t, as reflecting spillovers. In addition to our key export measures, we include classic potential deter- minants of productivity such as the share of foreign capital (FS), skill ratio (SR) and the share of R&D over output. Finally, all variables in the right hand side are lagged to avoid contemporaneous feedback effects. 5 Results In Table 2, we report only results based on the Two-step System General- ized Methods of Moments analysis (System GMM).7 In the first column, we estimate a specification without discriminating export activity by firm owner- ship. The variable UP ST REAM has a positive association with plant TFP , even after controlling for both aggregate and sector specific time trends. The variable WITHIN measuring export activity in the plant's own sector does not have an effect on TFP . There is no evidence of firm learning from exporter firms in the same sector. When we discriminate exporters by ownership, we find that both domestic and foreign owned exporter activities in downstream sectors are associated with higher plant productivity.
Recommended publications
  • Allied Social Science Associations Atlanta, GA January 3–5, 2010
    Allied Social Science Associations Atlanta, GA January 3–5, 2010 Contract negotiations, management and meeting arrangements for ASSA meetings are conducted by the American Economic Association. i ASSA_Program.indb 1 11/17/09 7:45 AM Thanks to the 2010 American Economic Association Program Committee Members Robert Hall, Chair Pol Antras Ravi Bansal Christian Broda Charles Calomiris David Card Raj Chetty Jonathan Eaton Jonathan Gruber Eric Hanushek Samuel Kortum Marc Melitz Dale Mortensen Aviv Nevo Valerie Ramey Dani Rodrik David Scharfstein Suzanne Scotchmer Fiona Scott-Morton Christopher Udry Kenneth West Cover Art is by Tracey Ashenfelter, daughter of Orley Ashenfelter, Princeton University, former editor of the American Economic Review and President-elect of the AEA for 2010. ii ASSA_Program.indb 2 11/17/09 7:45 AM Contents General Information . .iv Hotels and Meeting Rooms ......................... ix Listing of Advertisers and Exhibitors ................xxiv Allied Social Science Associations ................. xxvi Summary of Sessions by Organization .............. xxix Daily Program of Events ............................ 1 Program of Sessions Saturday, January 2 ......................... 25 Sunday, January 3 .......................... 26 Monday, January 4 . 122 Tuesday, January 5 . 227 Subject Area Index . 293 Index of Participants . 296 iii ASSA_Program.indb 3 11/17/09 7:45 AM General Information PROGRAM SCHEDULES A listing of sessions where papers will be presented and another covering activities such as business meetings and receptions are provided in this program. Admittance is limited to those wearing badges. Each listing is arranged chronologically by date and time of the activity; the hotel and room location for each session and function are indicated. CONVENTION FACILITIES Eighteen hotels are being used for all housing.
    [Show full text]
  • Export Dynamics in Colombia: Firm-Level Evidence
    Faculty Research Working Papers Series Export Dynamics in Colombia: Firm-Level Evidence Jonathan Eaton New York University Marcela Eslava Universidad de Los Andes Maurice Kugler John F. Kennedy School of Government – Harvard University James Tybout Pennsylvania State University October 2007 RWP07-050 The views expressed in the KSG Faculty Research Working Paper Series are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect those of the John F. Kennedy School of Government or of Harvard University. Faculty Research Working Papers have not undergone formal review and approval. Such papers are included in this series to elicit feedback and to encourage debate on important public policy challenges. Copyright belongs to the author(s). Papers may be downloaded for personal use only. NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES EXPORT DYNAMICS IN COLOMBIA: FIRM-LEVEL EVIDENCE Jonathan Eaton Marcela Eslava Maurice Kugler James Tybout Working Paper 13531 http://www.nber.org/papers/w13531 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 October 2007 We gratefully acknowledge Banco de la República de Colombia for its support to this project, both financially and in terms of data access. We also thank Pietro Bonaldi, Monica Hernández, and Miguel Rueda for excellent research assistance, as well as Enrique Montes for expert data advice. Finally we are grateful to Costas Arkolakis, Sascha Becker, Gene Grossman, Ricardo Hausmann, Elhanan Helpman, Dalia Marin, Marc Melitz and participants in the CEPR conference on "Globalization and the Organization of Firms", as well as members of the Board of Governors of Banco de la República de Colombia, for valuable comments. The views expressed herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research.
    [Show full text]
  • School Vouchers, Labor Markets and Vocational Education
    School Vouchers, Labor Markets and Vocational Education By: Eric Bettinger Michael Kremer Maurice Kugler Carlos Medina Christian Posso Juan E. Saavedra No. 1087 2019 Bogotá - Colombia - B ogotá - Bogotá - Colombia - Bogotá - Colombia - Bogotá - Colombia - Bogotá - Colombia - Bogotá - Colombia - Bogotá - Colombia School Vouchers, Labor Markets and Vocational Education By ERIC BETTINGER, MICHAEL KREMER, MAURICE KUGLER, CARLOS MEDINA, CHRISTIAN POSSO AND JUAN E. SAAVEDRA* The opinions contained in this document are the sole responsibility of the authors and do not commit Banco de la República nor its Board of Directors Abstract We provide evidence on the long-run impact of vouchers for private secondary schools, evidence collected twenty years after students applied for the vouchers. Prior to the voucher lottery, students applied to either an academic or vocational secondary school, an important mediating factor in the vouchers’ impacts. We find strong tertiary education and labor market effects for those students who applied to vocational schools with almost no impact on those who applied to academic schools. The labor market gains for vocational students are strongest at the top of the distribution and null at the bottom of the distribution. We find additional long- run impacts on consumption, and teen-age fertility. The expected net present value of benefits to participants and to taxpayers was large and positive implying that the program was welfare improving unless net externalities were large and negative. JEL Codes: E51, H24, I22, I23, I26, J13 Keywords: school choice, scholarships, formal earnings, access to higher education, access to consumer credit, fertility. _____________________ * Bettinger: Stanford University, [email protected]; Kremer: Harvard University, [email protected]; Kugler: George Mason University, [email protected]; Medina and Posso: Banco de la República de Colombia, [email protected], [email protected]; Saavedra: University of Southern California, [email protected]).
    [Show full text]
  • Does Insurance Promote Economic Growth? Evidence from the UK
    Does Insurance Promote Economic Growth? Evidence from the UK Maurice Kugler and Reza Ofoghi * July 2005 Abstract The first conference of UNCTAD in 1964 acknowledged the development of national insurance and reinsurance markets as essential aspects of economic growth. Yet, evidence from cointegration analysis by Ward and Zurbruegg (2000) showed there was no long run relationship between growth in the insurance industry and economic growth for some OECD countries, including the UK and the US, by using the total value of written insurance premia. However, it is surprising that an industry which in the case of the UK is the largest in Europe, and the third largest in the world, had no effect on the economic activity. As Granger (1990) claimed, it is possible to have cointegration at the aggregate level and not at the disaggregate level and vice versa. We use the components of insurance premia to find a long run relationship between development in insurance market size and economic growth for most components by using Johansen’s λTrace and λ max cointegration tests. This evidence implies there is a possibility that Ward and Zurbruegg ’s results were affected by the aggregation problem. In addition, because cointegration analysis does not provide information about possible patterns (Demand-following and Supply- leading), we used causality tests. Results show for most cases, we have a long run relationship between insurance market size and economic growth rather than a cyclical effect. Keywords: Insurance, risk sharing, economic growth, aggregation problem JEL Codes: O47, G0, C32 * Corresponding address: Economics Division , School of Social Sciences, University of Southampton, Highfield, Southampton, Hampshire, SO17 1BJ, United Kingdom.
    [Show full text]
  • Export Dynamics in Bangladesh Exploring the Data
    Policy brief 3007 | June 2012 Jonathan Eaton, James Tybout, Kala Krishna Bee Yan Aw and Andrés Rodríguez-Clare Export Dynamics in Bangladesh Exploring the Data In brief • Successful economic development is invariably associated with growth and diversification of export-oriented industries. • This study seeks to collect and analyze sources of data that illustrate the evolution of Bangladeshi exports over the last four decades and identify opportunities and challenges for future growth. • Bangladesh’s success in expanding apparel exports is unlikely to continue over the next decade. Therefore, Bangladesh should exmine policies to encourage industry upgrading in apparel and diversification into ther industries and countries. • The main advantage Bangladesh has had in apparel is low wages, as opposed to high productivity. However, recent pressure for wage increases and unionization are halting this. There is not much evidence of a long term trend toward quality upgrading or movement into more sophisticated products or into major new markets. • Export diversification, as seen in Korea for example, is not seen nor guaranteed. Despite accumulation of skills and knowledge, market and institutional failures imply that the emergence of new export industries is not as natural as it might seem. • Recommendations: • Bangladesh should explore options for quality upgrading and export diversification. • Policies need to ensure successful contract completion by sellers and buyers. • Bangladesh should establish a reputation for high performance in production and exporting in new areas and markets. Ideas for growth www.theigc.org Policy Motivation “We recommend that Successful economic development is invariably associated with the growth and Bangladesh examine diversification of export-oriented industries.
    [Show full text]
  • Human Progress and the Rising South
    Edited by: Khalid Malik • Maurice Kugler Human Progress and the Rising South UNDP Human Development Report Office Human Progress and the Rising South Edited by: Khalid Malik • Maurice Kugler Empowered lives. ResilientUnited nations Nations. Development Programme Human Development Report Office 304 E. 45th Street, 12th Floor New York, NY 10017 http://hdr.undp.org/ UNDP Human Development Report Offi ce 304 E. 45th Street, 12th Floor New York, NY 10017 Tel: +1 212-906-3661 Fax: +1 212-906-5161 http://hdr.undp.org/ UNDP Human Development Report The Human Development Report series has been published by UNDP since 1990 as independent, empirically grounded analyses of major development issues, trends and policies. Additional resources related to the 2013 Human Development Report can be found online at http://hdr.undp.org, including complete editions or summaries of the Report in more than 20 languages, a collection of Human Development Research Papers commissioned for the 2013 Report, interactive maps and databases of national human development indicators, full explanations of the sources and methodologies employed in the Report’s human development indices, country profi les and other background materials as well as previous global, regional and national Human Development Reports. United Nations Development Programme UNDP partners with people at all levels of society to help build nations that can withstand crisis, and drive and sustain the kind of growth that improves the quality of life for everyone. On the ground in 177 countries and territories, we offer global perspective and local insight to help empower lives and build resilient nations. The views expressed in this publication are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of the United Nations, including UNDP, or the UN Member States.
    [Show full text]
  • Curriculum Vitae – March 2011
    Curriculum Vitae – March 2011 1. PERSONAL DATA Name RAPOPORT , Hillel Professional Address CID, Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, 79 JFK Street, Rubenstein Bldg, Cambridge, MA 02138 Tel: +1 – 617 – 496 80 97; Fax: +1 – 617 – 496 87 53 Email [email protected] Homepage http://www.biu.ac.il/soc/ec/rapoport/rapoport.htm 2. EMPLOYMENT Positions 2009- Visiting Research Fellow , Center for International Development, and Visiting Professor, Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University . 2007- Associate Professor , Department of Economics, Bar-Ilan University , Israel 2007- Professor , EQUIPPE, University of Lille , France Other affiliations 2006- CReAM, University College London ( External Research Fellow ) 2007- IRES, Université Catholique de Louvain ( Extramural Fellow ) 2007- CEPREMAP , Paris ( Research Associate ) 2010- Kiel Institute for the World Economy (International Research Fellow ) Past positions 2003-08 Associate Faculty , Eitan Berglas School of Economics, Tel-Aviv University 2001-03 Visiting Research Fellow , Stanford Center for International Development and Visiting Assistant Professor , Dept. of Economics, Stanford University 3. DEGREES/AWARDS/RESEARCH GRANTS Degrees, Awards, Fellowships 2009 Growth Lab Research Fellowship , Center for International Development, Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University . 2008 Developing Countries Prize 2008 , Justus Liebig Universität Giessen , awarded for distinguished research on “migration and development”. 2003 Milken Institute Award for Distinguished Economic Research , The Milken Institute , Los Angeles, April. 2001 Annual Junior Research Fellowship , Stanford Center for International Development (SCID), Stanford University . 1993 PhD in Economics, University of Paris II (Panthéon-Assas). 1 Research grants and contracts (since 2005) 2010 University of Luxembourg , project on A World Database on Immigration Law and Policy – the IMPALA Project , 2010-12.
    [Show full text]
  • International Trade When Inequality Determines Aggregate Demand*
    International Trade when Inequality Determines Aggregate Demand* Maurice Kugler Department of Economics University of Southampton Southampton, SO17 1BJ, U.K. January, 2001 Abstract The model in this paper characterizes the pattern of international trade, and technological innovation and imitation between industrialized and developing regions, when preferences are nonhomothetic. By and large, models of the dynamics of North-South trade impose the assumption of unit income elasticity for all consumption goods. This assumption is relaxed to incorporate the insight from Engel’s Law: The budget share allocated to necessities falls with income. Since the composition of individual consumption depends on income, aggregate demand for newly invented goods depends not only on the distribution of income across countries but also within countries. To account for the impact of income distribution, preferences are introduced where consumers rank indivisible goods according to a hierarchy of both needs and desires. In the model, the distribution of wealth is unequal in the less developed country and even in the industrialized country. Then, the composition of the aggregate consumption basket in the integrated economy depends on both inter- and intra-national inequality. Hence, a demand channel is identified through which inequality affects the international trade pattern. Empirical evidence from a panel of bilateral trade data among 58 countries, for which adequate income distribution measures exist, and spanning three decades supports the conjecture that high inequality in a trading partner country yields less bilateral trade flows through lower imports, after controlling for both observed and unobserved heterogeneity. Keywords: Nonhomothetic preferences; inequality; aggregate import demand; pattern of international trade.
    [Show full text]
  • CID Working Paper No. 184 :: Factor Adjustments
    Factor Adjustments after Deregulation: Panel Evidence from Colombian Plants Marcela Eslava, John Haltiwanger, Adriana Kugler and Maurice Kugler CID Working Paper No. 184 September 2008 © Copyright 2008 Marcela Eslava, John Haltiwanger, Adriana Kugler, Maurice Kugler and the President and Fellows of Harvard College Working Papers Center for International Development at Harvard University Factor Adjustments after Deregulation: Panel Evidence from Colombian Plants∗ Marcela Eslava, John Haltiwanger, Adriana Kugler and Maurice Kugler† September 2008 Abstract We analyze employment and capital adjustments using plant data from the Colom- bian Annual Manufacturing Survey. We estimate adjustment functions for capital and labor as a non-linear function of the gaps between desired and actual factor levels, allowing for interdependence in adjustments of the two factors. In addition to non-linear employment and capital adjustments in response to market fundamen- tals, we find that capital shortages reduce hiring and labor surpluses reduce capital shedding. We also find that after factor market deregulation in Colombia in 1991, factor adjustment hazards increased on the job destruction and capital formation margins. Finally, we find that completely eliminating frictions in factor adjustment would yield a substantial increase in aggregate productivity through improved alloca- tive efficiency. Yet, the actual impact of the Colombian deregulation on aggregate productivity through factor adjustment was modest. Keywords: Reallocation, joint factor adjustment,
    [Show full text]
  • Econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) (Ed.) Periodical Part NBER Reporter Online, Volume 2006 NBER Reporter Online Provided in Cooperation with: National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), Cambridge, Mass. Suggested Citation: National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) (Ed.) (2006) : NBER Reporter Online, Volume 2006, NBER Reporter Online, National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), Cambridge, MA This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/61989 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu NBER Reporter NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH Reporter OnLine at: www.nber.org/reporter WINTER 2006/7 Program Report IN THIS ISSUE Program Report Productivity 1 Productivity Research Summaries Exchange Rate Regimes … 10 Microeconomic Evidence on Contagion … 13 Ernst R.
    [Show full text]
  • Are Bilateral Remittances Countercyclical?
    Are Bilateral Remittances Countercyclical? Jeffrey Frankel CID Working Paper No. 185 September 2009 Copyright 2009 Jeffrey Frankel and the President and Fellows of Harvard College Working Papers Center for International Development at Harvard University Sep.4 , 2009 Are Bilateral Remittances Countercyclical? Jeffrey Frankel Presented at panel on “Macroeconomic Impacts of Migration and Remittances,” May 26, 2009, at conference on Immigration and Global Development: Research Lessons on How Immigration and Remittances Affect Prosperity Around the World, co-hosted by the Center for Global Development in Washington DC and the Center for International Development at Harvard University. The author wishes to thank Olga Romero for dedicated research assistance; Erik Lueth and Marta Ruiz-Arranz for generously making data available; Maurice Kugler, Hillel Rapoport and conference participants for comments; and Robert Hildreth, CID, and the MacArthur Foundation for support. Abstract By putting together a relatively large data set on bilateral remittances of emigrants, this paper is able to shed light on the important hypothesis of smoothing. The smoothing hypothesis is that remittances are countercyclical with respect to income in the worker’s country of origin (the recipient of the remittance), while procyclical with respect to income in the migrant’s host country (the sender of the remittance). The econometric results confirm the hypothesis. This affirmation of smoothing is important for two reasons. First, it suggests that remittances should be placed on the list of criteria for an optimum currency area. Second, it brings into doubt plans by governments in some developing countries to harness remittances for their own use, in that government spending in these countries generally fails the test of countercyclicality which remittances pass.
    [Show full text]
  • The World Bank Economic Review
    Volume 32 • Number 1 2018 ISSN 0258-6770 (PRINT) ISSN 1564-698X (ONLINE) THE WORLD BANK THE WORLD BANK 1818 H Street, NW Washington, DC 20433, USA Public Disclosure Authorized ECONOMIC REVIEW World Wide Web: http://www.worldbank.org/ E-mail: [email protected] Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wber/issue/32/1 by Joint Bank-Fund Library user on 09 August 2019 Volume 32 • 2018 • Number 1 THE WORLD BANK ECONOMIC REVIEW Migrant Labor Markets and the Welfare of Rural Households in the Developing World: Evidence from China Alan de Brauw and John Giles The Impact of the Syrian Refugee Crisis on Firm Entry and Performance in Turkey Yusuf Emre Akgündüz, Marcel van den Berg, and Wolter Hassink Public Disclosure Authorized Inventor Diasporas and the Internationalization of Technology Ernest Miguélez The Impact of Rural Pensions in China on Labor Migration Karen Eggleston, Ang Sun, and Zhaoguo Zhan When the Cat’s Away … The Effects of Spousal Migration on Investments on Children Lucia Rizzica Can Parental Migration Reduce Petty Corruption in Education? Lisa Sofie Höckel, Manuel Santos Silva, and Tobias Stöhr SYMPOSIUM OF PAPERS FROM THE 8TH AFD-WORLD BANK MIGRATION AND DEVELOPMENT CONFERENCE Guest editors: David McKenzie, Caglar Ozden, and Hillel Rapoport The Long-Term Impacts of International Migration: Evidence from a Lottery Public Disclosure Authorized John Gibson, David McKenzie, Halahingano Rohorua, and Steven Stillman Migration and Cross-Border Financial Flows Maurice Kugler, Oren Levintal, and Hillel Rapoport Heterogeneous Technology Diffusion and Ricardian Trade Patterns William R. Kerr Pages 1–220 How and Why Does Immigration Affect Crime? Evidence from Malaysia Caglar Ozden, Mauro Testaverde, and Mathis Wagner Migrant Remittances and Information Flows: Evidence from a Field Experiment Catia Batista and Gaia Narciso ISBN 978-0-19-880922-7 academic.oup.com/wber 9 780198 809227 Public Disclosure Authorized WBER.J_32_1_Cover.indd 1 23/02/18 5:40 PM subscriptions: A subscription to The World Bank Economic Review (ISSN 0258-6770) comprises 3 issues.
    [Show full text]