<<

The Natural Rate and its Usefulness for Making

By ROBERT BARSKY,ALEJANDRO JUSTINIANO,LEONARDO MELOSI∗

Wicksell characterizes the natural rate as the terms of the gaps between output and the real in- real that yields price stability and terest rate from their natural counterparts. Sub- would equate real saving and investment in an stituting the consumer’s static labor supply con- 1 (otherwise equivalent) nonmonetary Walrasian dition wt pt (s− yt ϕnt ) into the usual economy. Cobb Douglas− specification= + of log real marginal cost, mc and rearranging, mc can be expressed There is a certain rate of inter- t t in terms of (log) output y and technology a as est on loans which is neutral in re- t t 1 ϕ α 1 ϕ 1 spect to commodity prices, and tends s− 1+α yt 1+α at log(1 α). Set- + − − − − − neither to raise nor to lower them. ting this expression equal to the inverse desired This is necessarily the same as the markup µ (presumed constant over time) and − rate of interest which would be deter- solving for the associated flexible price level n mined by supply and demand if no use of output yt , we characterize natural output as were made of money and all lending yn ψn a ϑn, where ψn 1 ϕ t ya t y ya s 1(1 +α) ϕ α were effected in the form of real capi- = n + ≡ − − + + and ϑ y is (for our purposes) an inessential con- tal goods (- Interest and stant. Prices, 1898 p .102) The consumer Euler equation with ct yt , = In identifying the price stabilizing rate with including a time-varying second-order precau- the real general equilibrium rate Wicksell gets tionary saving term associated with the condi- close to describing what has been labeled the di- tional variance, V art yt 1 , is yt Et yt 1 + 1 =1 + − vine coincidence of the benchmark New Key- s it Et π t 1 ρt 2 s− V art yt 1 . − + −  − n  + nesian Model (Woodford, 2003; Blanchard and The natural rate of interest rt must satisfy n   n  1 1  n  Gali, 2007). In this context, the notion of a nat- Et 1yt 1 s rt ρt 2 s− V art yt 1 ; + = − + + ural rate of interest is unambiguous and most where ρt is the (possibly time-varying) clearly meaningful. Therefore, for motivation subjective  rate of time preference. Sim- and as a point of comparison with the richer ple algebraic manipulations lead to n 1 n 1 2 n model used later in the quantitative analysis, we r ρ s Et 1y s V art y . t = t + − t 1 − 2 − t 1 begin by describing the natural rate in the canon- Substituting in for the growth+ of natural output+ ical New Keynesian (NK, hereafter) model with- one can write the following definition for the n out wage stickiness and capital accumulation as natural rate rt : the real interest rate prevailing in an economy n 1 n with flexible prices. rt ρt s− ψ ya Et 1at 1 = + + Following the derivations of the canonical NK 2 1 2 n   model in Gali (2008), we characterize the ex- (1) s− ψ ya V art at 1 . −2 + pressions for the marginal cost, the Euler equa-     tion for consumption and the Phillips Curve in If we write the Euler equation in terms of the n output gap, yt yt y , i.e. the difference ˜ ≡ − t ∗ Barsky: Bank of Chicago, Univer- between actual and natural output, and impose sity of Michigan, and NBER; [email protected]. limT Et yt T 0 so that the gap-creating Justiniano: Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago; alejan- →∞ ˜ + = [email protected]. Melosi: Federal Reserve Bank of   Chicago; [email protected]. Todd Messer provided 1We follow Gali’s (2008) notation, with n and ϕ denoting excellent research assistance. The views in this paper are solely labor and the inverse Frisch elasticity, respectively, but depart the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as from him by using s for the intertemporal elasticity of sub- reflecting the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or stitution. The loglinear aggregate production function reads any other person associated with the Federal Reserve System. yt at (1 α) nt . = + − 1 2 PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MONTH YEAR consequences of sticky prices do not last forever, I. A State-of-the-Art DSGE Model we can also see that Though the canonical New Keynesian model ∞ n of the last section provides motivation and intu- (2) yt s Et rt k rt k . + ˜ = − k 0 − + ition for the natural rate and its determinants, it X=  is far too stylized to be taken directly to the data. The last expression makes evident that the out- For that purpose, we build on the well-known put gap is the sum of all future real interest framework by Smets and Wouters (2007), which rate gaps, defined as the deviations of the ex- has been shown to fit the data well. Compared ante real rate, it Et π t 1, from the natural with the stylized model of the last section, the n − + rate, rt . Finally, from the NK Phillips curve, Smets and Wouters’ model includes price and π t β Et π t 1 kyt , closing the output gap wage stickiness, backward-looking components = + + ˜ yt also stabilizes inflation. Thus we have shown: in wage and price setting, habit formation, non- ˜   separable utility in consumption and leisure as The natural rate is increasing in the sub- • well as investment subject to adjustment costs. jective rate of time preference, ρt , and In addition to stationary variations in the level the expected growth rate of technology, of technology, it is buffeted by shocks to the Et 1at 1 , and decreasing in the con- marginal efficiency of investment and stochastic + ditional variance of future technology, variations in wage and price markups.   V art at 1 . Increases in patience, i.e. + There is an additional disturbance that Smets declines in ρt , (often labelled discount fac- and Wouters call a “risk shock”. As described   n tor or "beta" shocks) lower r , as does a below, in our model risk shocks play a promi- reduction in expected productivity growth nent role in explaining business cycle fluctua- and higher uncertainty about future pro- tions and a major role in triggering the Great ductivity (due to an increase in precaution- Recession. Although this shock is of course not ary savings, or equivalently the increased identical to the uncertainty shock in the stylized attractiveness of a safe asset). model (indeed, we log-linearize, thereby remov- An interest rate path in which the actual ing the role of risk) – it is analogous on the con- • real rate is always equal to the natural rate sumer side, in that it lowers the required return achieves both an output gap of zero (in the to saving and reduces consumption. The "risk sense that output is at natural, i.e. flexible shock", however, is not simply isomorphic to price equilibrium level) and zero inflation. a "beta shock" because it acts as a wedge and thus does not imply that the reduction in con- Equation (1) shows that an uncertainty shock sumption in recessions gets channelled into in- is isomorphic to the discount shock and indeed vestment. may provide one attractive structural interpreta- We introduce some important departures in tion of that rather reduced-form construct. Al- specification from Smets and Wouters (2007), n which are now described, together with the em- though movements in rt due to realistic aggre- gate technological uncertainty is rather small for pirical rationale for their inclusion and the data reasonable calibrations, it can be far larger if brought to inform them. The reader is referred to heterogeneous agents face idiosyncratic shocks the Online Appendix for additional details. Be- (Aiyagari and Gertler 1991 and Huggett 1993). ginning with the interest rate rule, policymakers Thus in a richer economy uncertainty shocks can are assumed to respond to four quarter averages have a significant depressing effect on the nat- of current, expected and two lags of inflation, ural rate (Guerrieri and Lorenzoni 2011).2 and the deviation of GDP from the model’s lin- ear trend.3 Second, based on the evidence pre- 2At least two other disturbances that could provide an under- lying foundation for discount shocks come to mind Eggertsson their own funds, efforts to reduce the durables stock in response and Krugman (2012) sketch a two agent economy in which a loss to downward revisions of permanent income also lower the nat- of net worth forces deleveraging and hence reduced consumption ural rate much in the fashion of a beta shock (Hall 2011). on the part of the borrower group, requiring a fall in the real in- 3Smets and Wouters assume instead responses to quarter terest rate to induce a compensating increase in the consumption over quarter inflation and deviations of output –unadjusted for of the lenders. But even when agents purchase durables with utilization– from the model-based natural level of output, as well VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE THE NATURAL RATE OF INTEREST 3 sented in Gurkaynak, Sack and Swanson (2005), and Wouters we add two price and one wage se- we incorporate Forward Guidance (henceforth, ries, long-run expected inflation, as well as 4 and FG) regarding the future conduct of monetary 10 quarters of market-based federal funds rate policy. Following the methodology in Camp- expectations in the first and second subsamples, bell et al. (2012) and Campbell, Fisher and Jus- respectively. tiniano (2012), agents receive news regarding the future paths of the federal funds rate, gov- Defining the Natural Rate in the Richer Economy. erned by two latent variables referred to as the Target and Path factors.4 FG is informed with market-based expectations of the fed funds rate Unlike the canonical model in the first part of obtained from Fed Funds, Eurodollar and OIS the paper, a richer economy, which is subject to futures contracts. Hence, the model accounts for inefficient supply shocks (e.g., shocks to markup agents’ evolving expectations regarding the du- or other cost-push shocks), does not appear to ration of the zero lower bound (ZLB) since the have a unique, unambiguous definition of the Great Recession. natural interest rate (or output). One might de- Third, we introduce a slow moving inflation fine the natural rate as the rate that would prevail drift in the policy rule. This primarily ac- if both wages and prices were perfectly flexible counts for the stability of long-run expected in- (and, as Woodford 2003 stresses, expected to be flation since 1997, but will also capture, in re- so henceforth). However, if "cost-push" –also duced form, the effects –if any–of unmodeled known as markup– shocks create inefficiencies, uncoventional policy actions on agents’ inflation the associated flexible wage and price equilib- expectations. The drift is informed by matching rium would not be "welfare relevant" (Woood- model-based average expected inflation over the ford, 2003). Thus, in our empirical model we next 40 quarters with median 10 year expected choose to define the natural real interest rate inflation from the Survey of Professional Fore- and level of output, as those that would have casters. prevailed in an economy with neither nominal Fourth and finally, instead of matching the rigidities nor shocks to price and wage markups. As such, we could have referred to these natural model’s concepts of price and wage inflation 6 with a single series for each, we rely on multiple levels as (2nd best) "efficient". indicators. This approach diminishes the impor- tance of markup shocks for cyclical fluctuations, II. The Natural Rate Is Volatile and as shown by Boivin and Giannoni (2006) for the Procyclical case of goods prices, and by Justiniano, Prim- iceri and Tambalotti (2013) for wages. For this Figure 1 presents the filtered (one-sided) and reason, our estimate of the natural rate is quite smoothed (two-sided) estimates of the natural robust to the interpretation of these disturbances rate (on a quarterly basis), which follows a as efficient or inefficient (Section IV). highly procyclical pattern characterized by fairly The estimation sample is 1990q1-2013q2, al- pronounced swings. Perhaps surprisingly, we do lowing for a break in all parameters in 2008q3, not observe a substantially larger drop during the and centering the prior for the admittedly short Great Recession than in the previous two down- second subsample at the first subsample esti- 5 turns. However, in stark contrast with earlier mates. To the seven observables used in Smets recessions, it has remained persistently negative since 2008. This last finding is mainly explained as the change in this gap. 4The target factor is the only common component correlated by the highly persistent negative risk shock that with changes in the current federal funds rate. Therefore, the according to our model triggered the Great Re- path factor is more intepretable as the forward guidance compo- cession and is responsible for the ensuing slow nent of monetary policy. 5More precisely, we first estimate through 2008q3 using a prior almost identical to Smets and Wouters. This mode becomes 6As noted by Blanchard and Gali (2007), this is not the the center of the prior for the second subsample, with the initial- fully efficient "first best" equilibrium because of the steady state ization of the filter based on the mean and variance of the state markup associated with monopolistic competition, but that dis- in 2008q3. The beginning of the sample is determined by the tortion is not under the control of the monetary authority, and availability of fed funds futures data. would require a fiscal solution. 4 PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MONTH YEAR recovery. line in the top panel of Figure 2 shows the in- ferred output gap –defined as the difference be- tween actual and the natural level of output— under the estimated interest rate rule. The dashed line captures instead the counterfactual output gap that would have arisen under a quasi Wicksellian rule of the form

n (3) it rt φπ Et π t 1 = + + that is, had the Federal Reserve tracked the nat- ural rate period by period.7 The counterfac- tual economy is characterized by a consider- able reduction in the output gap, even during the Great Recession, as well as by remarkably reduced variability thereof. The bottom panel Figure 1: One-sided (filtered) and two-sided shows the inefficiency gap (also known as the (smoothed) estimate of the natural rate. labor wedge), which following Gali, Gertler and Lopez-Salido (2007), is defined as the wedge be- tween the marginal rate of substitution between III. Stabilization Properties of the Wicksellian Policy consumption and leisure and the marginal pro- ductivity of labor. This turns out to be essen- As discussed in the introductory part of the tially the reciprocal of the output gap and once paper, tracking the natural rate would accom- again it is drastically reduced under rule (3). plish full macroeconomic stabilization in mod- els where the divine coincidence holds. Unfortu- nately, even in the absence of inefficient markup shocks, this policy does not necessarily deliver such a desirable outcome in the presence of both price and wage rigidities (Woodford, 2003 p. 443, Gali 2008, Chapter 6). Additional trade- offs arise from the presence of real inefficiencies –as we have interpreted markups–which do not affect the (second best) efficient economy and hence the natural rate of interest. In section IV we gauge the robustness of our results to the al- ternative interpretation of markups. Even if setting the nominal interest rate to tar- get the natural rate is not guaranteed to achieve Figure 2: Output and Inefficienct Gaps under estimated full stabilization of inflation and the output gap, interest rule and when track the natural rate. according to our model pursuing this policy would have considerably diminished the volatil- ity of these variables in the last twenty-five As previously mentioned, in principle closing years, including the Great Recession. Therefore, the output or inefficiency gap could bring about despite departures from the divine coincidence - significant costs in terms of the stabilization of and abstracting from the implementation issues price and wage inflation. However, in our model that we address in section IV - the natural rate of interest still seems to be a useful summary sta- 7We use the term quasi Wicksellian since in our model such tistic for poliycmakers. a rule need not stabilize the price level, and, relatedly, to differ- In what follows we compare macroeconomic entiate it with Giannoni’s (2012) Wicksellian rules that explicitly respond to deviations of the price level from trend. We feed the outcomes depending on the assumptions regard- smoothed sequence of all shocks (including markups) and re- ing the conduct of monetary policy. The solid place the estimated interest rule with (3), setting φ 1.0001. π = VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE THE NATURAL RATE OF INTEREST 5 this is not the case. Indeed, the ratios of ob- But, can such a policy prescription be imple- served (nominal) wage inflation variance to the mented in practice? counterfactual variance had policy tracked the A natural question is the extent to which the natural rate are 3.7 and 23.3 in the first and sec- ZLB on nominal interest rates represents a con- ond subsamples respectively, suggesting that a straint. Figure 3 sheds light on this issue by pre- considerable degree of wage inflation stabiliza- senting the actual path of the federal funds rate tion can also be achieved by following the rule (on a quarterly basis) together with the counter- (3). The fall in the corresponding ratios for price factual rate had monetary policy tracked the nat- inflation is more moderate at 1.9 and 1.7. ural rate. The ZLB would have bound our quasi Overall, our results echo the findings in Jus- Wicksellian policy rule in the three recessions of tiniano, Primiceri and Tambalotti (2013), and as the sample, questioning the feasibility and the in their case, rest on the predominance of de- stabilizing properties of this rule in practice. mand fluctuations, such as the risk shock, which move price and quantities in same direction, and on the smaller contribution of price and wage markup shocks to fluctuations in economic ac- tivity. These authors further characterize opti- mal policy–a fairly involved task in our model– and show that it essentially involves closing the output gap, as we have defined it here. Our find- ings suggest in turn that tracking the natural rate would stabilize this output gap as well as infla- tion in prices and wages. However, character- izing the distance of this prescription from opti- mal monetary policy –and particularly the extent to which it implies a larger degree of inflation stabilization– is beyond the scope of this short paper. Figure 3: Actual and counterfactual Federal Funds We conclude by addressing the desirability Rate (quarterly basis). of history dependence by augmenting the quasi Wicksellian rule with a term corresponding to the previous period’s output gap, The pervasiveness of the ZLB in the last twenty-five years requires the to be n (4) it rt Et π t 1 φx xt 1 able to raise short-term inflation expectations in = + + + − recessions so as to attain a negative real rate as History dependence is a common theme in the required by the quasi Wicksellian rule. Follow- optimal design of monetary policy rules in the ing Eggertsson and Woodford (2003), this can presence of inefficient disturbances (Woodford, be achieved, for instance, through a commitment 2003, Chapter 7). We obtain that the inertial by the central bank to raising the nominal inter- rule above would allow policymakers to attain est rate slowly at the time the natural rate will even further reductions in the variability of both become positive in order to affect expectations output and inefficiency gaps, at the expense of already when the ZLB is binding.8 A way to no discernible increase in the variability of wage implement the policy suggested by Eggertsson and price inflation, for values of φx ranging be- and Woodford is for the central bank to make ex- tween 0.1 and 0.3. plicit statements, often called forward guidance,

IV. Implementability 8Krugman (1998) and Werning (2012) have also advocated the use of this type of policy to provide more accommodation In Section III, we showed that a Generalized when the policy rate is stuck at its zero bound. Bianchi and Wicksellian policy rule would accomplish sub- Melosi (2013) show that committing to systematically inflating away the portion of public debt accumulated during severe eco- stantial macroeconomic stabilization compared nomic downturns would also be a powerful device to raise short- to our empirical Taylor-type reaction function. term inflation expectations. 6 PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MONTH YEAR about the future path of short-term interest rates. tions has been quite variable and highly pro- Indeed, our model suggests that Forward Guid- cyclical. The natural rate turned negative in the ance contributed considerably to real activity in last three recessions and has remained persis- 2003-04 as well as since the more explicit lan- tently depressed since 2008. We find that the guage adopted by the FOMC in August 2011.9 natural rate could be a useful summary statistic Another concern for implementability is the for the Federal Reserve in so far as policy de- availability of real time estimates of this latent signed to track it would significant stabilize the variable as well as the seemingly implausible output and inefficient gaps while also decreas- requirement of discerning efficient from ineffi- ing the variability of price and wage inflation. cient fluctuations.10 On the first issue, note that Nevertheless, the recurrently binding zero lower one-sided and two-sided estimates of the natural bound, and the difficulty of computing the nat- rate are reasonably close (Figure 1). On the sec- ural rate in real time pose non-trivial challenges ond, it is interesting that overall the contours of for adopting the natural interest rate as an imple- the natural rate as well as the stabilization prop- mentable target of monetary policy. erties of (3) for the output gap are quite robust to assuming all markups are not efficient (base- REFERENCES line) or the polar opposite case in which they are treated as efficient fluctuations, and therefore in- Aiyagari, S. Rao, and Mark Gertler. 1991. cluded in the definition of the natural rate of in- “Asset returns with transactions costs and terest and output.11 As mentioned earlier, this uninsured individual risk.” Journal of Mone- robustness property stems from the diminished tary Economics, 27(3): 311–331. importance of these shocks –compared to mod- Bianchi, Francesco, and Leonardo Melosi. els without multiple indicators and idiosyncrac- 2013. “Escaping the Great Recession.” CEPR tic disturbances– in explaining real fluctuations. Discussion Paper 9643. Finally, in this short article we do not directly address other important issues such as the ap- Blanchard, Olivier, and Jordi Gali. 2007. propriate characterization of the uncertainty sur- “Real Wage Rigidities and the New Keyne- rounding our estimates of the natural rate, in- sian Model.” Journal of Money, Credit and cluding its sensitivity to alternative specifica- Banking, 39(s1): 35–65. tions of the model. Boivin, J., and M. Giannoni. 2006. “DSGE Models in a Data-Rich Environment.” NBER V. Concluding Remarks Working Paper, 0332. A fairly rich DSGE model indicates that since Campbell, Jeffrey R., Charles Evans, Jonas 1990 the natural real rate of interest, defined D. M. Fisher, and Alejandro Justiniano. as the real rate of an efficient economy with 2012. “Macroeconomic effects of Federal Re- neither nominal stickiness nor cost-push distor- serve Forward Guidance.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. 9According to our estimates forward guidance (given by the path factor) contributed almost a full percentage point to quar- Campbell, Jeffrey R., Jonas D. M. Fisher, terly GDP growth (on a quartertly basis) in 2003 and since 2011. and Alejandro Justiniano. 2012. “Mone- Conversely, it dragged GDP by roughly 1 percent at the trough tary Policy Forward Guidance and the Busi- of the Great Recession. ness Cycle.” mimeo Federal Reserve Bank of 10As noted by Woodford (2003, p.454), it is often difficult quantitatively to tell whether a particular real disturbance distorts Chicago. the economy towards inefficiency or simply affects the efficient level of output and interest rates. Eggertsson, Gauti B., and Michael Woodford. 11More precisely, when treating price markup shocks as ef- 2003. “The Zero Interest-rate Bound and Op- ficient, the natural rate exhibits the same cyclical pattern, but is timal Monetary Policy.” Brookings Paper on slightly more volatile, particularly during times of large increases Economic Activity. in oil prices, e.g. 2006. Our quasi Wicksellian rule continues to almost fully stabilize the output gap, somewhat less so the inef- Eggertsson, Gauti B., and Paul Krugman. ficiency gap, and achieves a bigger reduction in the variability of price and wage inflation. Wage markup shocks leads to negligi- 2012. “Debt, Deleveraging, and the Liq- ble differences with our baseline. uidity Trap: A Fisher-Minsky-Koo Ap- VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE THE NATURAL RATE OF INTEREST 7

proach.” The Quarterly Journal of Eco- Woodford, Michael. 2003. Interest and prices: nomics, 127(3): 1469–1513. Foundations of a theory of monetary policy. Princeton, New Jersey:Princeton University Gali, Jordi. 2008. Monetary Policy, Inflation, Press. and the Business Cycle: An Introduction to the New Keynesian Framework. Princeton University Press. Gali, Jordi, Mark Gertler, and David J. Lopez-Salido. 2007. “Markups, Gaps, and the Welfare Costs of Business Fluctuations.” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 89(1): 44–59. Giannoni, Marc P. 2012. “Optimal interest rate rules and inflation stabilization versus price- level stabilization.” Staff Reports, Federal Re- serve Bank of New York, 546. Guerrieri, Veronica, and Guido Lorenzoni. 2011. “Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings, and the Liquidity Trap.” NBER Working Pa- pers 17583. Gurkaynak, Refet S, Brian Sack, and Eric Swanson. 2005. “Do Actions Speak Louder Than Words? The Response of Asset Prices to Monetary Policy Actions and Statements.” In- ternational Journal of Central Banking, 1(1). Hall, Robert E. 2011. “The Long Slump.” American Economic Review, 101(2): 431–69. Huggett, Mark. 1993. “The risk-free rate in heterogeneous-agent incomplete-insurance economies.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 17(5-6): 953–969. Justiniano, Alejandro, Giorgio E. Primiceri, and Andrea Tambalotti. 2013. “Is There a Tradeoff Between Inflation and Output Sta- bilization?” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 1–31. Krugman, Paul R. 1998. “It’s Baaack: Japan’s Slump and the Return of the Liquidity Trap.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activ- ity, 29(2): 137–206. Smets, Frank R., and Raf Wouters. 2007. “Shocks and Frictions in U.S. Business Cy- cles: A Bayesian DSGE Approach.” Ameri- can Economic review, 97(3): 586–606. Werning, Ivan. 2012. “Managing a Liquid- ity Trap: Monetary and Fiscal Policy.” MIT working paper.