Measuring the Natural Rate of Interest Redux

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Measuring the Natural Rate of Interest Redux FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO WORKING PAPER SERIES Measuring the Natural Rate of Interest Redux Thomas Laubach Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System John C. Williams Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco October 2015 Working Paper 2015-16 http://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/working-papers/wp2015-16.pdf Suggested citation: Laubach, Thomas, John C. Williams. 2015. “Measuring the Natural Rate of Interest Redux.” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2015-16. http://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/working-papers/wp2015-16.pdf The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Measuring the Natural Rate of Interest Redux Thomas Laubach Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and John C. Williams Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco October 31, 2015 Abstract Persistently low real interest rates have prompted the question whether low interest rates are here to stay. This essay assesses the empirical evidence regarding the natural rate of interest in the United States using the Laubach-Williams model. Since the start of the Great Recession, the estimated natural rate of interest fell sharply and shows no sign of recovering. These results are robust to alternative model specifications. If the natural rate remains low, future episodes of hitting the zero lower bound are likely to be frequent and long-lasting. In addition, uncertainty about the natural rate argues for policy approaches that are more robust to mismeasurement of natural rates. The views expressed here are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of others in the Federal Reserve System. We thank Ben Pyle for excellent research assistance. Contact information: Laubach: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington, DC 20551; email: [email protected]; Williams: Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, 101 Market St., San Francisco, CA 94105; email: [email protected]; phone: 415-974- 2121. Year after year of extraordinarily low interest rates in the United States and elsewhere have prompted the question whether low interest rates are a permanent feature of the future economic landscape. The answer to this question has important implications for the economy, asset prices, and monetary policy. A great deal has been written on why the equilibrium or “natural” real interest rate may be low in the future, with the theory of secular stagnation one prominent example (Summers 2014). In this essay, we assess the empirical evidence regarding the historical behavior of the natural rate of interest in the United States, with a particular focus on the period since the outbreak of the global financial crisis. We then turn to implications for monetary policy. Our analysis centers on the model that we developed to measure highly persistent movements in the natural rate of interest (Laubach and Williams 2003). According to this model, since the start of the Great Recession the natural rate of interest has fallen to, and remained at, historically very low levels near zero. This is in part explained by a significant decline in the trend growth rate of the economy, but other factors that are harder to pin down are also at play. We find no evidence that the natural rate has moved back up even with the economy close to fully recovered from the Great Recession. These results are robust to alternative approaches to estimating the natural rate of interest and the output gap. In the final part of this essay we consider two key policy implications of a variable natural rate of interest in general, and of the decline and subsequent low level of the natural rate since the Great Recession in particular. First, uncertainty about the natural rate of interest argues in favor of policy approaches that deemphasize the role of the natural rate in policy decisions and therefore make these decisions more robust to potentially mismeasured natural rates. Second, if the natural rate were to remain as low as it has been since 2008, episodes in which short-term 1 interest rates would be constrained from below would become more frequent and long-lasting, and unconventional policy tools may continue to play an important role in the future. Defining the natural rate of interest Knut Wicksell (1898) famously characterized the natural rate of interest: “There is a certain rate of interest on loans which is neutral in respect to commodity prices, and tends neither to raise nor to lower them.” We operationalize this notion by defining the natural rate as the real short-term interest rate consistent with the economy operating at its full potential once transitory shocks to aggregate supply or demand have abated. Implicit in this definition is the absence of upward or downward pressures on the rate of price inflation relative to its trend. Our definition takes a “longer-run” perspective, in that it refers to the level of real interest rates expected to prevail, say, five to 10 years in the future, after the economy has emerged from any cyclical fluctuations and is expanding at its trend rate. In contrast, other research has focused on short-term fluctuations in the natural rate of interest, assuming the longer-run value is constant (Neiss and Nelson 2003, Woodford 2003, Andres et al., 2009, Barsky et al., 2014, Curdia et al., 2015, Goldby et al., 2015). These studies define the natural rate to be the real interest rate that would prevail if all prices were flexible. However, we do not view this as a competing or contradictory approach to defining the natural rate; rather, the short-term perspective is complementary to our longer-run approach. Figure 1 portrays a highly stylized model of the determination of the natural rate. The downward-sloping line, labelled the IS curve, shows the negative relationship between aggregate spending and the real interest rate. The vertical line indicates the level of potential GDP, which is assumed to be unrelated to the real interest rate for this diagram. In principle, potential GDP may 2 also a function of the real rate, but this modification does not affect the basic point of the analysis. At the intersection of the IS curve and the potential GDP line, real GDP equals potential, and the real interest rate equals the natural rate of interest. The natural rate of interest may change over time owing to highly persistent structural shifts in aggregate supply and demand. For example, Laubach (2009) finds that increases in long-run projections of federal government budget deficits are related to increases in expected long-term real interest rates. In Figure 1, an increase in long-run projected budget deficits moves the IS curve to the right, implying a higher natural rate. As discussed by Bomfim (1997), Laubach and Williams (2003), Congressional Budget Office (2014), International Monetary Fund (2014), Council of Economic Advisers, 2015, Hamilton et al. (2015), and Pescatori and Turunen (2015), there are myriad influences on the natural rate, including, but not limited to, productivity growth, demographics, and the evolution of the global economy. Univariate time series estimates Although it is relatively straightforward to define the natural rate of interest, it is more challenging to pin it down quantitatively. If the natural rate were close to constant over time and there were no trend in the inflation rate, a reasonable estimate would be the sample mean of actual real interest rates. For example, the ex post real fed funds rate--defined as the nominal effective federal funds rate less the percent change in the personal consumption expenditures price index over the prior year-- has averaged about 2% over the past 50 years. If history were a good guide, then one would expect real interest rates to return to 2% in the future. However, factors affecting supply and demand evolve over time, shifting the natural rate around. If these 3 movements are sufficiently large and persistent, the long-term average is a poor predictor of the natural rate of interest. A standard way to allow for persistent changes is to compute multi-year averages of past values. Figure 2 illustrates this approach, showing the ten-year moving average of ex post real short-term interest rates in the United States and the corresponding figure for the median real short-term interest rate across 17 advanced economies. The data are from an updated version of the Schularick and Taylor (2012) data set. One observation stands out from this figure: there are sizable swings in average real interest rates that persist for decades. Other more sophisticated statistical approaches use time-series filtering techniques that try to separate longer-term trends from short-term variations. Figure 3 shows three such sets of estimates of the medium- or longer-term trends using the Hodrick-Prescott filter, the bandpass filter, and an unobserved components stochastic volatility model (Stock and Watson 2007). The five-year moving average of real interest rates is also shown for comparison. Although such univariate time series methods could in principle work well at estimating the natural rate of interest when inflation and economic activity are relatively stable, they are likely to be unreliable during periods when this is not the case, indicating that real interest rates have deviated from the natural rate for some time. For example, during the late 1960s and much of the 1970s, inflation trended steeply upward in the United States, which suggests that the real funds rate was below the natural rate on average. Similarly, real interest rates were very high during the period of the Volcker disinflation of the early 1980s, when inflation fell sharply.
Recommended publications
  • Measuring the Natural Rate of Interest: International Trends and Determinants
    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO WORKING PAPER SERIES Measuring the Natural Rate of Interest: International Trends and Determinants Kathryn Holston and Thomas Laubach Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System John C. Williams Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco December 2016 Working Paper 2016-11 http://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/working-papers/wp2016-11.pdf Suggested citation: Holston, Kathryn, Thomas Laubach, John C. Williams. 2016. “Measuring the Natural Rate of Interest: International Trends and Determinants.” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2016-11. http://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/working- papers/wp2016-11.pdf The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Measuring the Natural Rate of Interest: International Trends and Determinants∗ Kathryn Holston Thomas Laubach John C. Williams December 15, 2016 Abstract U.S. estimates of the natural rate of interest { the real short-term interest rate that would prevail absent transitory disturbances { have declined dramatically since the start of the global financial crisis. For example, estimates using the Laubach-Williams (2003) model indicate the natural rate in the United States fell to close to zero during the crisis and has remained there into 2016. Explanations for this decline include shifts in demographics, a slowdown in trend productivity growth, and global factors affecting real interest rates. This paper applies the Laubach-Williams methodology to the United States and three other advanced economies { Canada, the Euro Area, and the United Kingdom.
    [Show full text]
  • Endogenous Money and the Natural Rate of Interest: the Reemergence of Liquidity Preference and Animal Spirits in the Post-Keynesian Theory of Capital Markets
    Working Paper No. 817 Endogenous Money and the Natural Rate of Interest: The Reemergence of Liquidity Preference and Animal Spirits in the Post-Keynesian Theory of Capital Markets by Philip Pilkington Kingston University September 2014 The Levy Economics Institute Working Paper Collection presents research in progress by Levy Institute scholars and conference participants. The purpose of the series is to disseminate ideas to and elicit comments from academics and professionals. Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, founded in 1986, is a nonprofit, nonpartisan, independently funded research organization devoted to public service. Through scholarship and economic research it generates viable, effective public policy responses to important economic problems that profoundly affect the quality of life in the United States and abroad. Levy Economics Institute P.O. Box 5000 Annandale-on-Hudson, NY 12504-5000 http://www.levyinstitute.org Copyright © Levy Economics Institute 2014 All rights reserved ISSN 1547-366X Abstract Since the beginning of the fall of monetarism in the mid-1980s, mainstream macroeconomics has incorporated many of the principles of post-Keynesian endogenous money theory. This paper argues that the most important critical component of post-Keynesian monetary theory today is its rejection of the “natural rate of interest.” By examining the hidden assumptions of the loanable funds doctrine as it was modified in light of the idea of a natural rate of interest— specifically, its implicit reliance on an “efficient markets hypothesis” view of capital markets— this paper seeks to show that the mainstream view of capital markets is completely at odds with the world of fundamental uncertainty addressed by post-Keynesian economists, a world in which Keynesian liquidity preference and animal spirits rule the roost.
    [Show full text]
  • Natural and Neutral Rates of Interest
    Garrison 2 As theory and policy have developed, the terms “natural rate” and “neutral rate,” though seeming synonyms, provide a contrast between pre-Keynesian and post-Keynesian thinking. Although “natural” and “neutral” are sometimes used NATURAL AND NEUTRAL RATES OF INTEREST almost interchangeably, there is an important conceptual distinction in play: The natural rate of interest is a rate that emerges in the market as a result of borrowing IN THEORY AND POLICY FORMULATION and lending activity and governs the allocation of the economy’s resources over time. The neutral rate of interest is a rate that is imposed on the market by wisely ROGER W. GARRISON chosen monetary policy and is intended to govern the overall level of economic activity at each point in time. Exploring this distinction and its implications can go a long way towards understanding the current state of central-bank policymaking Interest has a title role in many pre-Keynesian writings as it does in Keynes’s own and the difficulties that the Federal Reserve creates for the market economy. General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money (1936). Eugen Böhm Bawerk’s Capital and Interest (1884), Knut Wicksell’s Interest and Prices (1898) and Gustav Cassel’s The Nature and Necessity of Interest (1903) readily come to THE NATURAL RATE OF INTEREST mind. The essays in F. A. Hayek’s Prices, Interest and Investment (1939), which both predate and postdate Keynes’s book, focus on the critical role that interest So named by Swedish economist Knut Wicksell, the natural rate of interest is the rates play in coordinating production plans with consumption preferences.
    [Show full text]
  • Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model
    University College Dublin, Advanced Macroeconomics Notes, 2020 (Karl Whelan) Page 1 Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model As this is the second module in a two-module sequence, following Intermediate Macroeco- nomics, I am assuming that everyone in this class has seen the IS-LM and AS-AD models. In the first part of this course, we are going to revisit some of the ideas from those models and expand on them in a number of ways: • Rather than the traditional LM curve, we will describe monetary policy in a way that is more consistent with how it is now implemented, i.e. we will assume the central bank follows a rule that dictates how it sets nominal interest rates. We will focus on how the properties of the monetary policy rule influence the behaviour of the economy. • We will have a more careful treatment of the roles played by real interest rates. • We will focus more on the role of the public's inflation expectations. • We will model the zero lower bound on interest rates and discuss its implications for policy. Our model is going to have three elements to it: • A Phillips Curve describing how inflation depends on output. • An IS Curve describing how output depends upon interest rates. • A Monetary Policy Rule describing how the central bank sets interest rates depend- ing on inflation and/or output. Putting these three elements together, I will call it the IS-MP-PC model (i.e. The Income- Spending/Monetary Policy/Phillips Curve model). I will describe the model with equations.
    [Show full text]
  • On Falling Neutral Real Rates, Fiscal Policy, and the Risk of Secular Stagnation
    BPEA Conference Drafts, March 7–8, 2019 On Falling Neutral Real Rates, Fiscal Policy, and the Risk of Secular Stagnation Łukasz Rachel, LSE and Bank of England Lawrence H. Summers, Harvard University Conflict of Interest Disclosure: Lukasz Rachel is a senior economist at the Bank of England and a PhD candidate at the London School of Economics. Lawrence Summers is the Charles W. Eliot Professor and President Emeritus at Harvard University. Beyond these affiliations, the authors did not receive financial support from any firm or person for this paper or from any firm or person with a financial or political interest in this paper. They are currently not officers, directors, or board members of any organization with an interest in this paper. No outside party had the right to review this paper before circulation. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect those of the Bank of England, the London School of Economics, or Harvard University. On falling neutral real rates, fiscal policy, and the risk of secular stagnation∗ Łukasz Rachel Lawrence H. Summers LSE and Bank of England Harvard March 4, 2019 Abstract This paper demonstrates that neutral real interest rates would have declined by far more than what has been observed in the industrial world and would in all likelihood be significantly negative but for offsetting fiscal policies over the last generation. We start by arguing that neutral real interest rates are best estimated for the block of all industrial economies given capital mobility between them and relatively limited fluctuations in their collective current account.
    [Show full text]
  • Kalecki's Critique of Wicksellianism and the Miss-Specification of Negative Interest Rates
    Kalecki's Critique of Wicksellianism and the Miss-specification of Negative Interest Rates Jan Toporowski In the discussion over negative (or even near-zero) interest rates, the case for such extremely low or negative interest rests on three arguments: an appeal to a 'natural' rate of interest that is thought to be negative at a time of 'secular stagnation'; a belief that ‘in the absence of inflation real interest rates cannot fall far enough to clear the world market for savings’ (‘The Economist September 24 2016, p. 23); and/or a belief that money accumulations need to be taxed, rather than rewarded with interest, in order to force them into circulation. In this paper it is argued that these arguments do not hold. The latter two arguments for negative interest rates, are familiar to readers of Keynes’s General Theory and therefore do not require repetition of the argument that interest rates do not clear ‘savings’ (as supposed, for example, in Bernanke 2005), or that economic activity does not respond to incentives for monetary circulation (see Ilgmann 2016). It is the presumed relationship between ‘natural’ or equilibrium ‘real’ rates of interest, and ‘real’ money rates of interest, that is the axis on which contemporary macroeconomic theory and policy revolves. This paper therefore concentrates on clarifying that relationship by showing how the arguments for negative interest rates miss- specify the function of interest in a business economy with a sophisticated financial system. The focus of the discussion on the constraints faced by short term interest rates which would otherwise resolve the growth problems of market economies, distracts from a much more serious problem arising from policies of interest rates around the zero bound and quantitative easing, namely the flattening of the yield curve that weakens the structure of the financial system.
    [Show full text]
  • Joint Estimation of the Natural Rate of Interest, the Natural Rate of Unemployment, Expected Inflation, and Potential Output
    WORKING PAPER SERIES NO 797 / AUGUST 2007 JOINT ESTIMATION OF THE NATURAL RATE OF INTEREST, THE NATURAL RATE OF UNEMPLOYMENT, EXPECTED INFLATION, AND POTENTIAL OUTPUT ISSN 1561081-0 by Luca Benati 9 771561 081005 and Giovanni Vitale WORKING PAPER SERIES NO 797 / AUGUST 2007 JOINT ESTIMATION OF THE NATURAL RATE OF INTEREST, THE NATURAL RATE OF UNEMPLOYMENT, EXPECTED INFLATION, AND POTENTIAL OUTPUT 1 by Luca Benati and Giovanni Vitale 2 In 2007 all ECB publications This paper can be downloaded without charge from feature a motif http://www.ecb.int or from the Social Science Research Network taken from the €20 banknote. electronic library at http://ssrn.com/abstract_id=1003972. 1 The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect those of the European Central Bank. 2 Both authors: European Central Bank, Kaiserstrasse 29, D-60311, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; e-mail: [email protected] and [email protected] © European Central Bank, 2007 Address Kaiserstrasse 29 60311 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Postal address Postfach 16 03 19 60066 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Telephone +49 69 1344 0 Internet http://www.ecb.europa.eu Fax +49 69 1344 6000 Telex 411 144 ecb d All rights reserved. Any reproduction, publication and reprint in the form of a different publication, whether printed or produced electronically, in whole or in part, is permitted only with the explicit written authorisation of the ECB or the author(s). The views expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect those of the European Central Bank. The statement of purpose for the ECB Working Paper Series is available from the ECB website, http://www.ecb.europa.
    [Show full text]
  • Effects of the Quantitative Easing Policy: a Survey of Empirical Analyses
    Effects of the Quantitative Easing Policy: A Survey of Empirical Analyses Hiroshi Ugai This paper surveys the empirical analyses that examine the effects of the Bank of Japan’s (BOJ’s) quantitative easing policy (QEP), which was implemented from March 2001 through March 2006. The survey confirms a clear effect whereby the commitment to maintain the QEP fostered the expectations that the zero interest rate would continue into the future, thereby lowering the yield curve centering on the short- to medium-term range. There were also phases in which an increase in the current account balances held by financial institutions at the BOJ bolstered this expec- tation. While the results were mixed as to whether expansion of the monetary base and altering the composition of the BOJ’s balance sheet led to portfolio rebalancing, generally this effect, if any, was smaller than that stemming from the commitment. When viewing the QEP’s impact on Japan’s economy through various transmission channels, many of the analyses suggest that the QEP created an accommodative environment in terms of corporate financing. In particular, the QEP contained finan- cial institutions’ funding costs from the market and staved off financial institutions’ funding uncertainties. The QEP’s effect on raising aggregate demand and prices was often limited, due largely to the then progressing corporate balance-sheet adjustment, as well as the zero bound constraint on interest rates. Keywords: Zero interest rate policy; Quantitative easing policy; Commitment; Zero bound constraint on interest rates; Deflation JEL Classification: E43, E44, E51, E52, E58 Monetary Affairs Department, Bank of Japan (currently, General Manager, Okayama Branch) (E-mail: [email protected]) The author would like to thank Kosuke Aoki, London School of Economics, and many Bank of Japan (BOJ) colleagues including Kunio Okina, Hideo Hayakawa, Shigenori Shiratsuka, Nobuyuki Oda, Takeshi Kimura, Koichiro Kamada, Naohiko Baba, Ippei Fujiwara, and Tomohiro Sugo for their valuable comments.
    [Show full text]
  • Calculating the Natural Rate of Interest: a Comparison of Two Alternative Approaches by Thomas A
    Economic Brief October 2015, EB15-10 Calculating the Natural Rate of Interest: A Comparison of Two Alternative Approaches By Thomas A. Lubik and Christian Matthes The natural rate of interest is a key concept in monetary economics because its level relative to the real rate of interest allows economists to assess the stance of monetary policy. However, the natural rate cannot be observed; it must be calculated using identifying assumptions. This Economic Brief compares the popular Laubach-Williams approach to calculating the natural rate with an alternative method that imposes fewer theoretical restrictions. Both approaches indicate that the natural rate has been above the real rate for a long time. The natural rate of interest is one of the key constantly react to economic shocks, gives rise concepts for understanding and interpreting to a natural rate of interest akin to Wicksell’s macroeconomic relationships and the effects of original concept. Woodford’s innovation was to monetary policy. Its modern usage dates back show how the natural rate relates to economic to the Swedish economist Knut Wicksell, who in fundamentals such as productivity shocks or 1898 defined it as the interest rate that is com- changes in consumers’ preferences. Moreover, patible with a stable price level.1 An increase in an inflation-targeting central bank can steer the the interest rate above its natural rate contracts economy toward the natural rate and price sta- economic activity and leads to lower prices, bility by conducting policy through the applica- while a decline relative to the natural rate has tion of a Taylor rule, which links the policy rate to the opposite effect.
    [Show full text]
  • The Natural Rate of Interest in Emerging Asia: Long-Term Trends and the Impact of Crises
    ADBI Working Paper Series THE NATURAL RATE OF INTEREST IN EMERGING ASIA: LONG-TERM TRENDS AND THE IMPACT OF CRISES Kensuke Tanaka, Prasiwi Ibrahim, and Sybrand Brekelmans No. 1263 May 2021 Asian Development Bank Institute Kensuke Tanaka and Prasiwi Ibrahim are from the Organisation for Economic Co- operation and Development, and Sybrand Brekelmans is from Bruegel. The views expressed in this paper are the views of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views or policies of ADBI, ADB, its Board of Directors, or the governments they represent. ADBI does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this paper and accepts no responsibility for any consequences of their use. Terminology used may not necessarily be consistent with ADB official terms. Working papers are subject to formal revision and correction before they are finalized and considered published. The Working Paper series is a continuation of the formerly named Discussion Paper series; the numbering of the papers continued without interruption or change. ADBI’s working papers reflect initial ideas on a topic and are posted online for discussion. Some working papers may develop into other forms of publication. Suggested citation: Tanaka, K., P. Ibrahim, and S. Brekelmans. 2021. The Natural Rate of Interest in Emerging Asia: Long-Term Trends and the Impact of Crises. ADBI Working Paper 1263. Tokyo: Asian Development Bank Institute. Available: https://www.adb.org/publications/natural-rate- interest-emerging-asia Please contact the authors for information about this paper. Email: [email protected], [email protected], [email protected] Authors would like to thank Raluca Maran for her useful inputs, Alexander Hume for his support, and Annabelle Mourougane and Kimiaki Shinozaki (both are from the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development [OECD]) for their comments on earlier drafts of this paper.
    [Show full text]
  • Keynes After Sraffa and Kaldor: Effective Demand, Accumulation and Productivity Growth Alcino F. Camara-Neto and Matías Verne
    DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES Keynes after Sraffa and Kaldor: Effective demand, accumulation and productivity growth Alcino F. Camara-Neto and Matías Vernengo Working Paper No: 2010-07 University of Utah Department of Economics 260 S. Central Campus Dr., Rm. 343 Tel: (801) 581-7481 Fax: (801) 585-5649 http://www.econ.utah.edu 1 Keynes after Sraffa and Kaldor: Effective demand, accumulation and productivity growth Alcino F. Camara-Neto Dean, Law and Economic Sciences Center, Federal University of Rio de Janeiro Matías Vernengo University of Utah Federal University of Rio de Janeiro Abstract This paper analyzes to what extent John Maynard Keynes was successful in showing that the economic system tends to fluctuate around a position of equilibrium below full employment in the long run. It is argued that a successful extension of Keynes’s principle of effective demand to the long run requires the understanding of the contributions by Piero Sraffa and Nicholas Kaldor. Sraffa provides the basis for the proper dismissal of the natural rate of interest, while the incorporation by Kaldor of the supermultiplier and Verdoorn’s Law allows for a theory of the rate of change of the capacity limit of the economy. Keywords: History of Macroeconomic Thought, Macroeconomic Models JEL Classification: B24, E10 Acknowledgements: The authors thank Thomas Cate for his careful reading and comments to a preliminary version of the paper. 2 Introduction One of the most controversial propositions in macroeconomics is that the economy is driven by demand. In The General Theory , Keynes clearly argued that the system would fluctuate in the long run around a position considerably below full employment.
    [Show full text]
  • SECTION ONE R- Star: the Natural Rate and Its Role in Monetary Policy Volker Wieland
    CHAPTER TWO The Natural Rate SECTION ONE R- Star: The Natural Rate and Its Role in Monetary Policy Volker Wieland WHAT IS R- STAR AND WHY DOES IT MATTER? The natural or equilibrium real interest rate has taken center stage in the policy debate on the appropriate stance for monetary policy in the United States and elsewhere. In Taylor- style rules for mon- etary policy, this rate is oft en denoted by r- star. This discussion draws on results from three recent research papers. The titles of these contributions speak directly to the available empirical evi- dence and the problems encountered in modeling and estimating r- star: “Finding the Equilibrium Real Interest Rate in a Fog of Policy Deviations” (Taylor and Wieland 2016), “Instability, Imprecision and Inconsistent Use of Equilibrium Real Interest Rate Estimates” (Beyer and Wieland 2017), and “Little Decline in Model- Based Estimates of the Long- Run Equilibrium Interest Rate” (Wieland and Wolters 2017). The equilibrium real interest rate can be defi ned by using a simple aggregate demand relationship, as shown in Figure 2.1.1. 46 Wieland FIGURE 2.1.1. Aggregate demand, potential GDP, and r- star The solid lines in Figure 2.1.1 display the aggregate demand curve in real interest rate and GDP space. The equilibrium rate r* corresponds to the realization of aggregate demand—that is, the equilibrium of investment demand and aggregate savings— when GDP corresponds to the level of equilibrium output (poten- tial GDP). Mathematically, this relationship can be expressed as follows: y = y* – β(r – r*) + αx (1) The parameter β determines the sensitivity of aggregate demand to the real interest rate.
    [Show full text]