Contrasting Stochastic and Support Theory Interpretations of Subadditivity

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Contrasting Stochastic and Support Theory Interpretations of Subadditivity Error and Subadditivity 1 A Stochastic Model of Subadditivity J. Neil Bearden University of Arizona Thomas S. Wallsten University of Maryland Craig R. Fox University of California-Los Angeles RUNNING HEAD: SUBADDITIVITY AND ERROR Please address all correspondence to: J. Neil Bearden University of Arizona Department of Management and Policy 405 McClelland Hall Tucson, AZ 85721 Phone: 520-603-2092 Fax: 520-325-4171 Email address: [email protected] Error and Subadditivity 2 Abstract This paper demonstrates both formally and empirically that stochastic variability is sufficient for, and at the very least contributes to, subadditivity of probability judgments. First, making rather weak assumptions, we prove that stochastic variability in mapping covert probability judgments to overt responses is sufficient to produce subadditive judgments. Three experiments follow in which participants provided repeated probability estimates. The results demonstrate empirically the contribution of random error to subadditivity. The theorems and the experiments focus on within-respondent variability, but most studies use between-respondent designs. We use numerical simulations to extend the work to contrast within- and between-respondent measures of subadditivity. Methodological implications of all the results are discussed, emphasizing the importance of taking stochastic variability into account when estimating the role of other factors (such as the availability bias) in producing subadditive judgments. Error and Subadditivity 3 A Stochastic Model of Subadditivity People are often called on the map their subjective degree of belief to a number on the [0,1] probability interval. Researchers established early on that probability judgments depart systematically from normative principles of Bayesian updating (e.g., Phillips & Edwards, 1966). More recently investigators have observed systematic violations of the additivity principle, one of the most basic axioms of probability theory (Kolmogorov, 1933). Consider disjoint events A, B and their union C=A∪B, and let P(.) be a normative probability measure. Additivity requires that P(A) + P(B) = P(C). For instance, if the probability that the home team wins by at least ten points, P(A), is .30 and the probability that the visiting team wins by at least ten points, P(B), is .10, then probability that the margin of victory is at least ten points, P(C), must be .30 + .10 = .40. In contrast to this normative requirement, numerous studies have shown that judged probability, p(.), usually exhibits subadditive so that p(C ) < p(A) + p(B). Evidence of this pattern is reviewed by Tversky and Koehler (1994) and Fox and Tversky (1998). It has been observed among sports fans (e.g., Fox, 1999; Koehler, 1996), professional options traders (Fox, Rogers & Tversky, 1996), doctors (Redelmeier, Liberman, Koehler & Tversky, 1995), and lawyers (Fox & Birke, 2002). Thus far, researchers typically attribute biases in judged probability to heuristic processes based on memory retrieval, similarity judgment, or other cognitive processes (Bearden & Wallsten, in press; Kahneman, Slovic & Tversky, 1982; Gilovich, Griffin & Kahneman, 2002). In contrast, a growing body of research has shown that some commonly observed patterns of bias can occur when otherwise accurate probability judgments are perturbed by random error (e.g., Erev, Wallsten, & Budescu, 1994; Juslin, Olsson, & Björkman, 1997; Soll, 1996). It is important, therefore, to rule out, or at least account for, response patterns due to stochastic Error and Subadditivity 4 variability before positing complex cognitive mechanisms. The aim of this paper is to contrast explanations of subadditive judgments based on random error with those based on the principles of support theory (Tversky & Koehler, 1994; Rottenstreich & Tversky, 1997). It is difficult to distinguish cognitive accounts of subadditivity from stochastic accounts of this phenomenon because past studies have asked participants to make a single probability judgment of events A, B and C = A∪B, in either between- or within-participant experimental designs. Hence, past studies have not allowed researchers to observe the distribution of error surrounding a particular participant’s judgments of a particular event and diagnose the extent to which such error contributes to subadditivity. In the present studies we aim to fill this gap in the literature by providing opportunities for participants to learn the relative frequencies of events in a controlled learning environment and then eliciting multiple judgments of each event. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. First, we summarize the major cognitive explanations of subadditivity. Next, we show how random error also might explain subadditivity, critically discuss a published test of a particular stochastic model, and develop a very general one. We then present three experiments that examine the extent to which random error can account for subadditivity. (Two of the experiments are described in detail; and one, a replication of Experiment 1, is only summarized.) The paper concludes with a general discussion relating stochastic and support theory explanations of subadditivity. Cognitive interpretations of subadditivity. Traditional accounts of subadditivity associate this phenomenon with the availability heuristic (Tversky & Kahneman, 1973). For instance, Fischhoff, Slovic, and Lichtenstein (1978) asked automobile mechanics to judge the relative frequency of different causes for a car failing to start. Mechanics estimated that a car would fail to start about 22 times in 100 due to causes other than the “battery, fuel system, or engine.” Error and Subadditivity 5 However, when this residual category was broken down into distinct components consisting of “starting system,” “ignition system,” “mischief,” and a new (less inclusive) residual category, a second group of mechanics reported judgments that summed to 44 times in 100. These authors argued that unpacking the catch-all category into specific instances enhanced the accessibility of particular causes and therefore their apparent likelihood (see also Russo & Kolzow, 1994; Ofir, 2000). Likewise, in support theory (Tversky & Koehler, 1994; Rottenstreich & Tversky, 1997) subadditivity is attributed to availability: unpacking a description of an event into more specific constituents may remind people of possibilities that they would have overlooked or enhance their salience. Although availability could contribute to subadditivity in situations where a category of events is partitioned into constituents, it is unlikely to provide a satisfactory account of all instances of subadditivity. First, a number of studies have shown that when descriptions of events (e.g., “precipitation next April 1”) are unpacked into a disjunction of constituents (e.g., “rain or sleet or snow or hail”), judged probabilities sometimes increases, but not as dramatically as the sum of the probabilities of these constituents when they are judged separately (Rottenstreich & Tversky, 1997; Fox & See, 2003). In fact, unpacking descriptions into a disjunction of constituents and a catch-all sometimes leads to a reduction in judged probability. For instance, Sloman, Rottenstreich, Hedjichristidis, Stibel & Fox (2004) found that the median judged probability that a randomly selected death is due to “disease” was .55, the median judged probability that it is due to “heart disease, cancer, stroke, or any other disease” rose to only .60, and the median judged probability that it is due to “pneumonia, diabetes, cirrhosis, or any other disease” actually decreased to .40. Second, subadditivity is typically observed when a dimensional space (e.g., a temperature or a stock market price range) is partitioned into Error and Subadditivity 6 constituents, and it seems implausible that the availability mechanism contributes here. For example, Fox, Rogers, & Tversky (1996) found that most professional options traders in their sample judged the probability of the event “Microsoft Stock (MSFT) will close below $94 per share two weeks from today” to be lower than the sum of his or her estimated probabilities of the events “MSFT will close below $88 per share” and “MSFT will close at least $88 per share but below $94 per share.” Such observations have motivated a second cognitive interpretation of subadditivity: bias toward an “ignorance prior” probability. When respondents assign probabilities simultaneously to each of n events into which a sample space is partitioned, their responses are typically biased toward 1/n for each event (Fox & Clemen, 2004; cf. Van Schie & Van der Pligt, 1994). More generally, when people are asked to judge the probability of single events, their responses are biased toward ½, placing equal credence on the event and its complement, unless a partition of the event space into n > 2 interchangeable events is especially salient (see, Fox & Rottenstreich, 2003; see also Fischhoff & Bruin de Bruine, 1999). Thus, if probabilities of events A, B and A∪B are all biased toward 1/2 then these probabilities will be subadditive. Stochastic interpretations of subadditivity. Despite the appeal of availability and ignorance priors as explanations of subadditivity, it is necessary to consider the extent to which the phenomenon may be an artifact of random perturbations in judgment. Tversky and Koehler (1994) pointed out that subadditivity follows as a consequence of a stochastic model such as Erev, Wallsten, and Budescu’s (1994), which hypothesizes
Recommended publications
  • Duality for Outer $ L^ P \Mu (\Ell^ R) $ Spaces and Relation to Tent Spaces
    p r DUALITY FOR OUTER Lµpℓ q SPACES AND RELATION TO TENT SPACES MARCO FRACCAROLI p r Abstract. We prove that the outer Lµpℓ q spaces, introduced by Do and Thiele, are isomorphic to Banach spaces, and we show the expected duality properties between them for 1 ă p ď8, 1 ď r ă8 or p “ r P t1, 8u uniformly in the finite setting. In the case p “ 1, 1 ă r ď8, we exhibit a counterexample to uniformity. We show that in the upper half space setting these properties hold true in the full range 1 ď p,r ď8. These results are obtained via greedy p r decompositions of functions in Lµpℓ q. As a consequence, we establish the p p r equivalence between the classical tent spaces Tr and the outer Lµpℓ q spaces in the upper half space. Finally, we give a full classification of weak and strong type estimates for a class of embedding maps to the upper half space with a fractional scale factor for functions on Rd. 1. Introduction The Lp theory for outer measure spaces discussed in [13] generalizes the classical product, or iteration, of weighted Lp quasi-norms. Since we are mainly interested in positive objects, we assume every function to be nonnegative unless explicitly stated. We first focus on the finite setting. On the Cartesian product X of two finite sets equipped with strictly positive weights pY,µq, pZ,νq, we can define the classical product, or iterated, L8Lr,LpLr spaces for 0 ă p, r ă8 by the quasi-norms 1 r r kfkL8ppY,µq,LrpZ,νqq “ supp νpzqfpy,zq q yPY zÿPZ ´1 r 1 “ suppµpyq ωpy,zqfpy,zq q r , yPY zÿPZ p 1 r r p kfkLpppY,µq,LrpZ,νqq “ p µpyqp νpzqfpy,zq q q , arXiv:2001.05903v1 [math.CA] 16 Jan 2020 yÿPY zÿPZ where we denote by ω “ µ b ν the induced weight on X.
    [Show full text]
  • Superadditive and Subadditive Transformations of Integrals and Aggregation Functions
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Portsmouth University Research Portal (Pure) Superadditive and subadditive transformations of integrals and aggregation functions Salvatore Greco⋆12, Radko Mesiar⋆⋆34, Fabio Rindone⋆⋆⋆1, and Ladislav Sipeky†3 1 Department of Economics and Business 95029 Catania, Italy 2 University of Portsmouth, Portsmouth Business School, Centre of Operations Research and Logistics (CORL), Richmond Building, Portland Street, Portsmouth PO1 3DE, United Kingdom 3 Department of Mathematics and Descriptive Geometry, Faculty of Civil Engineering Slovak University of Technology 810 05 Bratislava, Slovakia 4 Institute of Theory of Information and Automation Czech Academy of Sciences Prague, Czech Republic Abstract. We propose the concepts of superadditive and of subadditive trans- formations of aggregation functions acting on non-negative reals, in particular of integrals with respect to monotone measures. We discuss special properties of the proposed transforms and links between some distinguished integrals. Superaddi- tive transformation of the Choquet integral, as well as of the Shilkret integral, is shown to coincide with the corresponding concave integral recently introduced by Lehrer. Similarly the transformation of the Sugeno integral is studied. Moreover, subadditive transformation of distinguished integrals is also discussed. Keywords: Aggregation function; superadditive and subadditive transformations; fuzzy integrals. 1 Introduction The concepts of subadditivity and superadditivity are very important in economics. For example, consider a production function A : Rn R assigning to each vector of pro- + → + duction factors x = (x1,...,xn) the corresponding output A(x1,...,xn). If one has available resources given by the vector x =(x1,..., xn), then, the production function A assigns the output A(x1,..., xn).
    [Show full text]
  • A Mini-Introduction to Information Theory
    A Mini-Introduction To Information Theory Edward Witten School of Natural Sciences, Institute for Advanced Study Einstein Drive, Princeton, NJ 08540 USA Abstract This article consists of a very short introduction to classical and quantum information theory. Basic properties of the classical Shannon entropy and the quantum von Neumann entropy are described, along with related concepts such as classical and quantum relative entropy, conditional entropy, and mutual information. A few more detailed topics are considered in the quantum case. arXiv:1805.11965v5 [hep-th] 4 Oct 2019 Contents 1 Introduction 2 2 Classical Information Theory 2 2.1 ShannonEntropy ................................... .... 2 2.2 ConditionalEntropy ................................. .... 4 2.3 RelativeEntropy .................................... ... 6 2.4 Monotonicity of Relative Entropy . ...... 7 3 Quantum Information Theory: Basic Ingredients 10 3.1 DensityMatrices .................................... ... 10 3.2 QuantumEntropy................................... .... 14 3.3 Concavity ......................................... .. 16 3.4 Conditional and Relative Quantum Entropy . ....... 17 3.5 Monotonicity of Relative Entropy . ...... 20 3.6 GeneralizedMeasurements . ...... 22 3.7 QuantumChannels ................................... ... 24 3.8 Thermodynamics And Quantum Channels . ...... 26 4 More On Quantum Information Theory 27 4.1 Quantum Teleportation and Conditional Entropy . ......... 28 4.2 Quantum Relative Entropy And Hypothesis Testing . ......... 32 4.3 Encoding
    [Show full text]
  • An Upper Bound on the Size of Diamond-Free Families of Sets
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Repository of the Academy's Library An upper bound on the size of diamond-free families of sets Dániel Grósz∗ Abhishek Methuku† Casey Tompkins‡ Abstract Let La(n, P ) be the maximum size of a family of subsets of [n] = {1, 2,...,n} not containing P as a (weak) subposet. The diamond poset, denoted Q2, is defined on four elements x,y,z,w with the relations x < y,z and y,z < w. La(n, P ) has been studied for many posets; one of the major n open problems is determining La(n, Q2). It is conjectured that La(n, Q2) = (2+ o(1))⌊n/2⌋, and infinitely many significantly different, asymptotically tight constructions are known. Studying the average number of sets from a family of subsets of [n] on a maximal chain in the Boolean lattice 2[n] has been a fruitful method. We use a partitioning of the maximal chains and n introduce an induction method to show that La(n, Q2) ≤ (2.20711 + o(1))⌊n/2⌋, improving on the n earlier bound of (2.25 + o(1))⌊n/2⌋ by Kramer, Martin and Young. 1 Introduction Let [n]= 1, 2,...,n . The Boolean lattice 2[n] is defined as the family of all subsets of [n]= 1, 2,...,n , and the ith{ level of 2}[n] refers to the collection of all sets of size i. In 1928, Sperner proved the{ following} well-known theorem. Theorem 1.1 (Sperner [24]).
    [Show full text]
  • 5 Norms on Linear Spaces
    5 Norms on Linear Spaces 5.1 Introduction In this chapter we study norms on real or complex linear linear spaces. Definition 5.1. Let F = (F, {0, 1, +, −, ·}) be the real or the complex field. A semi-norm on an F -linear space V is a mapping ν : V −→ R that satisfies the following conditions: (i) ν(x + y) ≤ ν(x)+ ν(y) (the subadditivity property of semi-norms), and (ii) ν(ax)= |a|ν(x), for x, y ∈ V and a ∈ F . By taking a = 0 in the second condition of the definition we have ν(0)=0 for every semi-norm on a real or complex space. A semi-norm can be defined on every linear space. Indeed, if B is a basis of V , B = {vi | i ∈ I}, J is a finite subset of I, and x = i∈I xivi, define νJ (x) as P 0 if x = 0, νJ (x)= ( j∈J |aj | for x ∈ V . We leave to the readerP the verification of the fact that νJ is indeed a seminorm. Theorem 5.2. If V is a real or complex linear space and ν : V −→ R is a semi-norm on V , then ν(x − y) ≥ |ν(x) − ν(y)|, for x, y ∈ V . Proof. We have ν(x) ≤ ν(x − y)+ ν(y), so ν(x) − ν(y) ≤ ν(x − y). (5.1) 160 5 Norms on Linear Spaces Since ν(x − y)= |− 1|ν(y − x) ≥ ν(y) − ν(x) we have −(ν(x) − ν(y)) ≤ ν(x) − ν(y). (5.2) The Inequalities 5.1 and 5.2 give the desired inequality.
    [Show full text]
  • Lecture 1 1 Introduction 2 How to Measure Information? 3 Notation
    CSE533: Information Theory in Computer Science September 28, 2010 Lecture 1 Lecturer: Anup Rao Scribe: Anup Rao 1 Introduction Information theory is the study of a broad variety of topics having to do with quantifying the amount of information carried by a random variable or collection of random variables, and reasoning about this information. In this course, we shall see a quick primer on basic concepts in information theory, before switching gears and getting a taste for a few domains in computer science where these concepts have been used to prove beautiful results. 2 How to measure information? There are several ways in which one might try to measure the information carried by a random variable. • We could measure how much space it takes to store the random variable, on average. For example, if X is uniformly random n-bit string, it takes n-bits of storage to write down the value of X. If X is such that there is a string a such that Pr[X = a] = 1=2, we can save on the space by encoding X so that 0 represents a and all other strings are encoded with a leading 1. With this encoding, the expected amount of space we need to store X is at most n=2 + 1. • We could measure how unpredictable X is in terms of what the probability of success is for an algorithm that tries to guess the value of X before it is sampled. If X is a uniformly random string, the best probability is 2−n. If X is as in the second example, this probability is 1=2.
    [Show full text]
  • MATH 421/510 Assignment 1
    MATH 421/510 Assignment 1 Suggested Solutions January 2018 All exercises from Folland, section 5.1. \Problem 1 (6)" below, for instance, indicates that the first problem on this assignment is Exercise 5.1.6 in Folland. Problem 1 (6). Suppose that X is a finite-dimensional normed space. Let e1; e2; : : : ; en Pn Pn be a basis for X, and define k 1 ajejk1 = 1 jajj. a) k · k1 is a norm on X. Pn n b) The map (a1; : : : ; an) 7! 1 ajej is continuous from K with the usual Euclidean topology to X with the topology defined by k · k1. c) fx 2 X : kxk1 = 1g is compact in X. d) All norms on X are equivalent. (Compare any norm to k · k1.) Solution. a) As always, we need to check positivity, homogeneity, and subadditivity. • Positivity: Pn Let x = j=1 ajej. Then kxk1 ≥ 0. Suppose that x 6= 0. Then aj 6= 0 for some 1 ≤ j ≤ n, and hence n X kxk1 = jaij ≥ jajj > 0 i=1 Conversely, suppose that x = 0. Then aj = 0 for each 1 ≤ j ≤ n, so kxk1 = 0. Pn • Homogeneity: Let x = j=1 ajej as before and let c 2 K. We compute directly: n n n n X X X X kcxk1 = c ajej = (caj)ej = jcajj = jcj jajj = jcjkxk1 j=1 1 j=1 1 j=1 j=1 as required. 1 Pn Pn • Subadditivity: If x = j=1 ajej and b = j=1 bjej, then n n n n X X X X kx + yk1 = (aj + bj)ej = jaj + bjj ≤ jajj + jbjj = kxk1 + kyk1: j=1 1 j=1 j=1 j=1 n b) Let k · k2 denote the Euclidean norm on K .
    [Show full text]
  • SUBADDITIVE FUNCTIONS of ONE REAL VARIABLE by RICHARD
    SUBADDITIVE FUNCTIONS OF ONE REAL VARIABLE I By RICHARD GEORGE LAATSCH" Bachelor of Science Central Missouri State College Warrensburg, Missouri 1953 Master of Arts University of Missouri Columbia, Missouri 1957 Submitted to the Faculty of the Graduate School of the Oklahoma State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY l"lay, 1962 L \ \ \ s (. 0 f . ?. OKLAHOMA STATE UNIVERSITY LIBRARY NOV 8 1962 SUBADDITIVE FUNCTIONS OF ONE REAL VARIABLE Thesis Approved: Thesis Adviser <D�ff/�� ~ ~ffcL~~\, -y1o-z..<A/ [:.. ~ ~~~ Dean of the Graduate School 504544 ii PREFACE This paper is concerned with certain problems in the theory of subadditive functions of a real variable. The basic definitions appear on page 1 and the entire first chapter serves as an introduction and orientation to the remaining materialo Chapter II contains a basic rotation theorem and some lemmas on continuity and boundedness which will be used in later chapters. Chapters III and IV deal with several kinds of extensions of functions which yield or preserve subadditivity; in particular, Chapter III is devoted to the maximal subadditive extension to E = [O ,co) of a subaddi tive function on [O, a]. Contrary to previous work on this topic, no assumptions of continuity are made. The last three chapters are devoted to sets of subad­ ditive functions. Chapter V discusses convergence, espe­ cially uniform convergence, of subadditive functions -­ motivated by a theorem of Bruckner -- and gives an example (the Cantor function) of a monotone subadditive function with unusual propertieso In Chapters VI and VII convex cones of subadditive functions are discussed and the ex­ tremal element problems considered.
    [Show full text]
  • IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management Risk Measures
    IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management Risk Measures Martin Haugh Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research Columbia University Email: [email protected] Reference: Chapter 8 of 2nd ed. of MFE’s Quantitative Risk Management. Risk Measures Let M denote the space of random variables representing portfolio losses over some fixed time interval, ∆. Assume that M is a convex cone so that If L1, L2 ∈ M then L1 + L2 ∈ M And λL1 ∈ M for every λ > 0. A risk measure is a real-valued function, % : M → R, that satisfies certain desirable properties. %(L) may be interpreted as the riskiness of a portfolio or ... ... the amount of capital that should be added to the portfolio so that it can be deemed acceptable Under this interpretation, portfolios with %(L) < 0 are already acceptable In fact, if %(L) < 0 then capital could even be withdrawn. 2 (Section 1) Axioms of Coherent Risk Measures Translation Invariance For all L ∈ M and every constant a ∈ R, we have %(L + a) = %(L) + a. - necessary if earlier risk-capital interpretation is to make sense. Subadditivity: For all L1, L2 ∈ M we have %(L1 + L2) ≤ %(L1) + %(L2) - reflects the idea that pooling risks helps to diversify a portfolio - the most debated of the risk axioms - allows for the decentralization of risk management. 3 (Section 1) Axioms of Coherent Risk Measures Positive Homogeneity For all L ∈ M and every λ > 0 we have %(λL) = λ%(L). - also controversial: has been criticized for not penalizing concentration of risk - e.g. if λ > 0 very large, then perhaps we should require %(λL) > λ%(L) - but this would be inconsistent with subadditivity: %(nL) = %(L + ··· + L) ≤ n%(L) (1) - positive homogeneity implies we must have equality in (1).
    [Show full text]
  • Topological Vector Spaces
    An introduction to some aspects of functional analysis, 3: Topological vector spaces Stephen Semmes Rice University Abstract In these notes, we give an overview of some aspects of topological vector spaces, including the use of nets and filters. Contents 1 Basic notions 3 2 Translations and dilations 4 3 Separation conditions 4 4 Bounded sets 6 5 Norms 7 6 Lp Spaces 8 7 Balanced sets 10 8 The absorbing property 11 9 Seminorms 11 10 An example 13 11 Local convexity 13 12 Metrizability 14 13 Continuous linear functionals 16 14 The Hahn–Banach theorem 17 15 Weak topologies 18 1 16 The weak∗ topology 19 17 Weak∗ compactness 21 18 Uniform boundedness 22 19 Totally bounded sets 23 20 Another example 25 21 Variations 27 22 Continuous functions 28 23 Nets 29 24 Cauchy nets 30 25 Completeness 32 26 Filters 34 27 Cauchy filters 35 28 Compactness 37 29 Ultrafilters 38 30 A technical point 40 31 Dual spaces 42 32 Bounded linear mappings 43 33 Bounded linear functionals 44 34 The dual norm 45 35 The second dual 46 36 Bounded sequences 47 37 Continuous extensions 48 38 Sublinear functions 49 39 Hahn–Banach, revisited 50 40 Convex cones 51 2 References 52 1 Basic notions Let V be a vector space over the real or complex numbers, and suppose that V is also equipped with a topological structure. In order for V to be a topological vector space, we ask that the topological and vector spaces structures on V be compatible with each other, in the sense that the vector space operations be continuous mappings.
    [Show full text]
  • 247A Notes on Lorentz Spaces Definition 1. for 1 ≤ P < ∞ and F : R D → C We Define (1) Weak(Rd) := Sup Λ∣∣{X
    247A Notes on Lorentz spaces Definition 1. For 1 ≤ p < 1 and f : Rd ! C we define ∗ 1=p (1) kfkLp ( d) := sup λ fx : jf(x)j > λg weak R λ>0 and the weak Lp space p d ∗ L ( ) := f : kfk p d < 1 : weak R Lweak(R ) p −p Equivalently, f 2 Lweak if and only if jfx : jf(x)j > λgj . λ . Warning. The quantity in (1) does not define a norm. This is the reason we append the asterisk to the usual norm notation. To make a side-by-side comparison with the usual Lp norm, we note that ZZ 1=p p−1 kfkLp = pλ dλ dx 0≤λ<jf(x)j Z 1 dλ1=p = jfjfj > λgj pλp 0 λ 1=p 1=p = p λjfjfj > λgj p dλ L ((0;1); λ ) and, with the convention that p1=1 = 1, ∗ 1=1 1=p kfkLp = p λjfjfj > λgj 1 dλ : weak L ((0;1); λ ) This suggests the following definition. Definition 2. For 1 ≤ p < 1 and 1 ≤ q ≤ 1 we define the Lorentz space Lp;q(Rd) as the space of measurable functions f for which ∗ 1=q 1=p (2) kfkLp;q := p λjfjfj > λgj q dλ < 1: L ( λ ) p;p p p;1 p From the discussion above, we see that L = L and L = Lweak. Again ∗ k · kLp;q is not a norm in general. Nevertheless, it is positively homogeneous: for all a 2 C, ∗ −1 1=p ∗ (3) kafkLp;q = λ fjfj > jaj λg Lq (dλ/λ) = jaj · kfkLp;q (strictly the case a = 0 should receive separate treatment).
    [Show full text]
  • Topological Vector Spaces
    Topological Vector Spaces Maria Infusino University of Konstanz Winter Semester 2015/2016 Contents 1 Preliminaries3 1.1 Topological spaces ......................... 3 1.1.1 The notion of topological space.............. 3 1.1.2 Comparison of topologies ................. 6 1.1.3 Reminder of some simple topological concepts...... 8 1.1.4 Mappings between topological spaces........... 11 1.1.5 Hausdorff spaces...................... 13 1.2 Linear mappings between vector spaces ............. 14 2 Topological Vector Spaces 17 2.1 Definition and main properties of a topological vector space . 17 2.2 Hausdorff topological vector spaces................ 24 2.3 Quotient topological vector spaces ................ 25 2.4 Continuous linear mappings between t.v.s............. 29 2.5 Completeness for t.v.s........................ 31 1 3 Finite dimensional topological vector spaces 43 3.1 Finite dimensional Hausdorff t.v.s................. 43 3.2 Connection between local compactness and finite dimensionality 46 4 Locally convex topological vector spaces 49 4.1 Definition by neighbourhoods................... 49 4.2 Connection to seminorms ..................... 54 4.3 Hausdorff locally convex t.v.s................... 64 4.4 The finest locally convex topology ................ 67 4.5 Direct limit topology on a countable dimensional t.v.s. 69 4.6 Continuity of linear mappings on locally convex spaces . 71 5 The Hahn-Banach Theorem and its applications 73 5.1 The Hahn-Banach Theorem.................... 73 5.2 Applications of Hahn-Banach theorem.............. 77 5.2.1 Separation of convex subsets of a real t.v.s. 78 5.2.2 Multivariate real moment problem............ 80 Chapter 1 Preliminaries 1.1 Topological spaces 1.1.1 The notion of topological space The topology on a set X is usually defined by specifying its open subsets of X.
    [Show full text]