<<

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES

COMMON VERSUS CURRENCY UNION: THE U.S. CONTINENTAL DOLLAR AND DENOMINATIONAL STRUCTURE, 1775-1776

Farley Grubb

Working Paper 21728 http://www.nber.org/papers/w21728

NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 November 2015

The views expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research.

NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer- reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications.

© 2015 by Farley Grubb. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Common Currency versus Currency Union: The U.S. Continental Dollar and Denominational Structure, 1775-1776 Farley Grubb NBER Working Paper No. 21728 November 2015, Revised December 2015 JEL No. E42,E52,H77,N11

ABSTRACT

I use denominational structure (the spacing and size of monetary units) to explain how the Continental Congress attempted to manage a successful common currency when sub-national political entities were allowed to have separate and run independent monetary policies. Congress created a common currency that was too large to use in ordinary transactions. Congress hoped this currency would be held for post-war redemption and would not circulate as money during the war. As such, it would not contribute to wartime . By contrast, individual currencies were emitted in small enough denominations to function as the domestic medium of exchange.

Farley Grubb University of Delaware Economics Department Newark, DE 19716 and NBER [email protected] Common Currency versus Currency Union: The U.S. Continental Dollar and Denominational Structure, 1775-1779

(12/5/15) Farley Grubb1

I use denominational structure (the spacing and size of monetary units) to explain how the Continental Congress attempted to manage a successful common currency when sub-national political entities were allowed to have separate currencies and run independent monetary policies. Congress created a common currency that was too large to use in ordinary transactions. Congress hoped this currency would be held for post-war redemption and would not circulate as money during the war. As such, it would not contribute to wartime inflation. By contrast, individual state currencies were emitted in small enough denominations to function as the domestic medium of exchange.

At the beginning of the American Revolution, the Continental Congress created a common inside paper currency for the colonies/states in rebellion—the Continental dollar. Congress did not create a union of state currencies or a true currency union.

Individual states retained their sovereign power to issue their own separate inside paper monies, and they issued such throughout the Revolution (Newman 2008; Ratchford 1941, p. 34). Congress overlaid a common inside paper currency onto a nation where sub- national political entities continued to operate independent monetary and fiscal policies and issue their own unique inside paper monies.2 No exchange agreements between

Continental dollars and the myriad of state currencies existed in the first years of the war.

I show how the initial circumstances of rebellion, and the secret political

1 Professor and NBER Research Associate, Economics Department, University of Delaware, Newark, DE 19716, USA. E-mail: [email protected]. Web-page: http://www.lerner.udel.edu/faculty-staff/faculty/farley- grubb. A preliminary version was presented in the DAMIN (Dépréciation de l’Argent Monétaire et relations Internationales) Workshop on “Conflict Potentials in Monetary Unions,” at the University of Applied Sciences, Warburg, , 27 Nov. 2015. Helpful comments by the participants and editorial assistance from Tracy McQueen are gratefully acknowledged. 2 All colonial, state, and congressional currencies were comprised of paper monies only. No coins in these currencies were created. Foreign coins, which were typically considered scarce, were the only coins in use in North America in this period.

1 machinations of delegates to the Continental Congress, led to a common currency rather than a currency union. I use relative denominational structure to infer the monetary policies adopted to make this common currency succeed. This is a new perspective on the

Continental dollar—one never before addressed in the literature.

Congress understood the problems of creating a common currency where sub- national political entities were allowed to emit their own monies and run their own monetary policies. Given these circumstances and constraints, Congress made reasonable choices to maximize the system’s chance of success. In the end, the demands of a long and expensive war overwhelmed this currency system. The adoption of the U.S.

Constitution in 1789 ended the sovereign power of states to issue their own currencies, thus paving the way toward a true currency union for the new nation (Grubb 2006).

After 1776, the Continental dollar collapsed in value and became near worthless by the end of the Revolution. Because of this, the literature portrays the creation of the

Continental dollar as an act done by desperate people who did not know what they were doing monetarily (Bolles 1969, vol. 1; Bullock 1900, pp. 60-78; Phillips 1966; Ratchford

1941, pp. 33-9). However, many of the people lauded as founding-father geniuses for creating the U.S. Constitution in 1787, especially regarding how monetary powers were structured, were the same people who created the Continental dollar currency system in

1775 (Grubb 2006). Being declared geniuses on one occasion and ignoramuses on another, when dealing with the same monetary issues, is incoherent history. This paper attempts to rationalize the behavior of these Americans regarding the creation of the

Continental dollar and so make their actions consist and coherent over time.

The paper proceeds as follows: First, I explain the circumstances that led

2 Congress to create a common currency rather than a currency union. Second, I explain how denominational structure reveals the intentions behind the monetary policies chosen.

Third, I measure the denominational structure of the Continental dollar and show that it differed both from modern currencies and from contemporary American colonial and state currencies. I use this evidence to explain how Congress attempted to rationalize this common currency system and make it work. This is the first use of denominational structure to interpret actual choices that I know of. An epilogue assesses the outcome of Congress’ efforts.

A Common Currency or a Currency Union?

The united colonies assembled in a Second Continental Congress in Philadelphia on 10 May 1775 to discuss a common response to the conflict between Massachusetts and the British Crown. The battles of Lexington and Concord had already occurred and the British forces, which had retreated to Boston, were now under siege by Massachusetts militia. Resources and men were on the move from other colonies to support the

Massachusetts revolutionaries. Congress, with no legal authority, decided to make itself the united revolutionary government. Congress’ immediate problem was marshaling resources for a united effort against the British occupying Boston.

In the spring of 1775, independence was not yet the dominant sentiment. It would take a full year of open warfare—victory in the battle for Boston, the pending battle for

New York, and the campaigns against British Canada—before Congress would declare independence on 4 July 1776 (Randall 1990, pp. 133-317; Tindall 1988, pp. 210-20).

While the provision of congressional resources helped sustain the near year-long siege of

3 Boston, it quickly became clear that marshalling congressional resources for a united effort against the British would not be a one-off exercise.

As these events unfolded, Congress had to improvise a monetary and and do so under extreme wartime duress and questionable political legitimacy. It was an improvised extralegal revolutionary body without any constitutional structure of organization. As such, it exercised power by common consent of the colonies as represented by their delegates in Congress. Congress had no enforcement power to the public or the states. The Articles of Confederation were not laid before Congress until

November of 1777, and they were not ratified by the states until March 1781 (Journals of the Continental Congress (JCC hereafter), v. 9, pp. 907-28; v. 19, p. 233; Tindall 1988, pp. 247-8).

On the second day of the Congress, with the war raging outside of Boston, the state of Massachusetts informed Congress that it was issuing interest-bearing bonds redeemable in two years at face value in specie to pay for its emergency war expenses. It asked Congress to receive these bonds and help give them a currency throughout the colonies (JCC, v. 2, pp. 24-6; Smith 1976, v. 1, pp. 470-1). In early June, New

Hampshire gave Massachusetts bonds legal tender status within New Hampshire.

In response to these developments, New York sent instructions to its delegation in

Congress, instructions that were not to be made public or disclosed to the other delegates, to dissuade Congress from adopting the currencies emitted by individual states or in any way obligating states to accept other states’ currencies. New York delegates opposed a union of state currencies or a currency union. Instead, New York’s delegates were instructed to push Congress to issue its own common currency and obligate the “United

4 States” as a group to its redemption. New York saw this as the best way to protect itself

against unreasonable monetary obligations imposed on it by neighboring states (Bolles

1969, v. 1, pp. 24-32; Phillips 1866, pp. 17-24; Smith 1976, v. 1, pp. 419, 442; Sparks

1832, v. 1, pp. 38-40).

When Congress acted on 23 June 1775, it adopted what New York had

recommended, namely an independent common paper currency issued by Congress and

not a union of individual state paper monies (Grubb 2008, 2013; JCC, v. 2, pp. 105-6).

This common paper currency—the Continental dollar—was to be redeemed at face value

in specie equivalents after the war in prorated shares by each state. Continental dollars

paid no interest between wartime emission and post-war redemption. They were, in

effect, zero-coupon bonds (Grubb 2011a, 2013). Congress also obligated the states as a

group to cover any shortfalls caused if some states failed to meet their post-war

redemption obligations. Congress, however, had no power to enforce these obligations. In

addition, each state remained free to issue its own separate paper money and run its own

independent monetary and fiscal policy.

How could such a monetary system succeed? Was the Continental dollar doomed at birth, or was there a rational monetary policy that offered some potential for success?

The Second Continental Congress acted as if controlling denominational structure would give this currency system some prospect of success.

Denominational Structure

Denominational structure is the numerical spacing between denomination values, and the relative real value of the denominational set. I assume that the money creator selects a denominational structure to achieve some purpose. As such, the choices made

5 can be used to infer monetary policy intentions, even when those intentions are not

directly articulated by the money creator. The Continental dollar was new money. As

such, Congress was free to choose any denominational structure it wanted. This

denominational structure is used to infer the monetary policy Congress selected to

rationalize their currency system and give it some potential for success.

a. Denominational Theory

Denominational theory assumes the goal of the money creator is to minimize the

cost of completing transactions, namely to minimize the cost of making change. This goal

is the same as maximizing the medium-of-exchange usage of the money created. Telser

(1995) mathematically shows that creating a currency with the fewest units needed to

execute all transactions entails choosing a denominational spacing that has a factor of 3, namely 1, 3, 9, 27, and so on. The denominational spacing factor is found by taking the value of a given denomination and dividing it by the value of the immediately preceding

denomination. Dividing the sum of these factors over all sequential denominational

pairings by the number of pairings equals the average denomination factor for a given

currency. The denomination factor, both for individual pairings and for the average of all

pairings, has a lower bound of one.

Telser’s analysis only considers minimizing the cost of producing the monetary

units needed to execute all transactions, and it assumes all monetary units have the same

cost of production. By contrast, minimizing the cost of making transactions from the

consumer’s perspective entails incorporating computational ease and historical

familiarity. Ease of computation puts considerable weight on units divisible by 5 and on having a denomination factor of 2. Such cost considerations push denominational

6 structures, conditional on being able to make change in all transactions in said money,

toward incomplete binary-decimal triplets, i.e. 1, 2, 5; 10, 20, 50; and so on. When such

computational cost minimizing considerations are added to minimizing the cost of

currency production, the full cost minimizing denominational spacing yields average

denomination factors between 2 and 3 (Tschoegl 1997, Van Hove 2001, Wynne 1997).

For example, the modern U.S. dollar has the following spacing between

denominations: 0.01, 0.05, 0.10, 0.25, 0.50, 1.00, 2.00, 5.00, 10.00, 20.00, 50.00, and

100.00. The denomination factors are: 5, 2, 2.5, 2, 2, 2, 2.5, 2, 2, 2.5, and 2, respectively,

with an average of 2.41. The factor of 2 dominates—the mode factor, with an occasional

higher factor that is the result of making the next higher non-zero denomination number

divisible by 5. The average denomination factor for the is 2.18, and for the Yen is

3.06—with both currencies having a mode factor of 2.

Besides optimal denominational spacing, relative denominational size also

matters in achieving the goal of maximizing the use of the currency as a circulating

medium of exchange. If the smallest denominations of a currency are large relative to the

value of goods being exchanged, then the ability to use that currency as the transacting

medium is reduced. Either many transactions cannot take place or change must be made

in some other money, barter goods, or book credit. If making change entails using

alternative monies, then these alternative monies will dominate the medium of exchange.

The currency in question will be pushed toward being hoarded as a store of value,

exported if it is outside money, or used only in the occasional large transaction. This

outcome is the result of an indivisibility of the currency at the lower-valued end of its denominational range (Redish and Weber 2008, Sumner 1990, Wallace and Zhou 1997).

7 In summary, the objective of an optimal denominational structure, namely optimal

spacing and value size, is to maximize the use of the currency as a circulating medium of

exchange, i.e. to make it easy and feasible to execute all transactions in the economy with

that money. This result also implies being able easily to make change in that money. The

considerations that yield this outcome include minimizing the cost of making

computations for consumers, minimizing the cost of monetary-unit production for the

money creator, and setting the lower-valued denominations in the range of the value of

most transactions desired by society.

Why create a currency with a denominational structure that makes it difficult to use that currency as a medium of exchange? One answer would be to mitigate its effect on prices. Under the simple quantity theory of money, increases in the quantity of money

(Mx), given the velocity of circulation of that money (Vx), must drive up prices (P) given

production constraints on real output (Y), see equation 1 (Bordo 1987, Fisher 1912).

(1) MxVx = PY (where Mx = money issued by sub-national entities, Vx = the velocity of circulation of that money, P = prices expressed in that money, and Y = real output)

Suppose that Mx is not controlled by the central authority, but is controlled by sub-national political entities. How can the central authority create its own common currency, Mz, to pay for emergency military expenses, then overlay it on top of these sub-

national currencies, but not affect P? Under the simple quantity theory of money, if the central authority creates a currency whose circulation (Vz) is reduced to near zero by its

3 denominational structure, P would not be affected. Equation 2 adds Mz to equation 1.

However, as Vz → 0, equation 2 → equation 1, and there is little inflationary effect from

adding Mz to the mix of currencies. The new common currency is held as a store of value

3 The simple quantity theory of money dominated American thinking in this era, see Bullock (1900, p. 65); Davis (1964); JCC (v. 9, p. 954); Sumner (1968, v. 1, pp. 43-4).

8 for future liquidation. Mx continues to be the primary circulating medium of exchange.

(2) MxVx + MzVz = PY (where Mz = money issued by the national authority, Vz = the velocity of circulation of that money)

For this strategy to succeed, money entrepreneurs must not be able to undo the

denominational constraint placed on Mz’s usage as a circulating medium of exchange. A money entrepreneur could undo the above strategy by accepting deposits of Mz bills that

were denominationally difficult to circulate and, for a small fee, issuing private money

claims on those deposits that were denominationally easy to circulate. The Mz bills taken

on deposit provide the reserves, redeemable upon demand, for the private money issued.

Even without a fractional reserve structure, namely even with 100 percent reserves

backing this private money, this process puts the full value of Mz into circulation, thus

undoing the effort to restrict Mz’s contribution to wartime inflation.

In the late eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries, this process was essentially

what private and publically chartered banks did, namely take in deposits and issue their

own private as claims against those deposits, with the banknotes circulating as

a local inside currency. Banks and banknotes, however, did not exist in colonial America,

largely due to British restrictions on chartering corporations. The exigencies of war

meant that even with the removal of British restrictions, banks were unlikely to form

during the Revolution. The Bank of North America, chartered in 1781, was the first

successful U.S. bank (Grubb 2016; Hammond 1991, pp. 3-67).4 Without money

entrepreneurs, and the risk of their undoing a denominational control strategy, controlling

the wartime circulation of Mz through selection of a restrictive denominational structure,

4 Running a bank where the bank’s reserves were an inside paper money rather than an outside money, such as specie coins, was also unknown and untried in this era. Backing an inside paper money, such as banknotes, with another inside paper money as its reserves, such as Federal government bonds, would not be tried in the U.S. before the National Banking Act of 1864.

9 thus mitigating Mz’s contribution to wartime inflation, had some chance of success.

I show that the above strategy was chosen by the Continental Congress during the

Revolution, and that it is consistent with Congress wanting to maximize the potential success of its common currency system. It was a rational strategy given the circumstances and constraints faced by Congress and given state resistance to forming a true currency union. Its failure was not preordained. b. American Colonial and Revolution Era Denominational Spacing

Congress established the denominational structure for each emission of

Continental dollars in each emission’s authorizing resolution. There were 11 separate emissions, the first being in 1775 and the last being in 1779. Appendix Table A1 reports the denominational structure separately for each of these 11 emissions in terms of the percent of units and the percent of their face value issued per each denomination for that emission, as well as for the cumulative total for all Continental dollars ever emitted.

Table 1 uses the data in Appendix Tables A1, A2, and A3 to construct the average, mode, and range of denomination factors for all Continental dollars ever emitted, and for the currencies issued by Virginia, Pennsylvania, New , and New

York during the Seven Years War and during the first years of the American Revolution.

For comparative purposes, Table 1 also reports similar information for the Euro, Yen, and

U.S. dollar modern currencies. The comparison to state currencies during the Revolution is restricted to pre-1778 because on 22 November 1777 Congress asked the states to restrict their emission of large-valued bills, thus altering the desired denomination factor for their post-1777 emissions (JCC, v. 7, p. 125; v. 9, pp. 955-6). The comparison to colonial currencies is restricted to the Seven Years War, 1755-1764, to have similar

10 Table 1 Denominational Spacing ______Colony/ Nation Currency Factor Average Factor Mode Factor Range ______Modern Nations U.S. Dollar 2.41 2.00 2.00 to 5.00

Euro 2.18 2.00 2.00 to 2.50

Yen 3.06 2.00 2.00 to 5.00

1775-1779 (American Revolution) U.S. Continental Dollar 1.36 1.50 1.08 to 2.50

1775-1777 (American Revolution) Virginia Currency 1.39 1.25 1.20 to 2.00

Pennsylvania Currency 1.30 1.25/1.33 1.07 to 1.60

New Jersey Currency 1.84 2.00 1.25 to 2.00

New York Currency 1.60 1.50 1.33 to 2.00

1755-1764 (Seven Years War) Virginia Currency 1.82 2.00 1.25 to 2.00

Pennsylvania Currency 1.62 1.33/1.50 1.25 to 2.50

New Jersey Currency 1.84 2.00 1.25 to 2.00

New York Currency 1.73 2.00 1.25 to 2.00 ______Sources: Derived from Appendix Tables A1, A2, and A3. Notes: The factor spacing is calculated by taking the value (Xt) of a denomination (dt) at location (t) and dividing it into the value of the next higher denomination, i.e. (Xt+1dt+1 / Xtdt). The average factor spacing is the summation of factor spacing across the full range of denominations emitted into circulation, i.e. N [∑ (Xt+1dt+1 / Xtdt)] / (N – 1) Where N = the complete sequential list of denominations. t = 1

circumstances to the Continental dollar, namely large emergency wartime paper money

emissions that had occurred within the lifetime experience of most congressmen in 1775.

11 Compared with modern and contemporary North American currencies, the

Continental dollar had a relatively low average, mode, and minimum denomination factor. Its denominations were more tightly spaced than other currencies. This pattern was not unique, however. The average, mode, and range of the Continental dollar’s denomination factor were comparable to Virginia and Pennsylvania state currencies issued at the same time. It was, however, unprecedented in prior experience. Colonial paper money emissions under similar circumstances yielded denomination factors with substantially higher average and mode values.

While possessing lower average denomination factors than modern currencies, colonial currencies had the same mode factor as modern currencies. Comparing denomination factors, the Continental dollar had an 88 and 29 percent lower average, and a 33 and 25 percent lower mode, than that for modern and for recent colonial currencies, respectively. The denominational spacing of the Continental dollar was unusual.

A closer examination of the denominational spacing within individual emissions of Continental dollars in Appendix Table A1 reveals that the denominational spacing was odder than that revealed in Table 1. Each emission has a concentration of units in the denomination sequence of 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, and 8. I have not found such a core denominational sequence for any other money. For eight of the first nine emissions, 78 to

88 percent of the units issued were in this sequence. For the total emission of Continental dollars, 53 percent of the units issued were in this sequence. This denominational spacing is not only unconventional and unprecedented, but downright bizarre and inexplicable.

No one has noted this before or commented on its oddity. What was Congress thinking?

What were they up to?

12 The explanation for this bizarre denominational spacing cannot be simple

ignorance. Most congressmen had either been closely involved with or lived under the

paper money regimes of the colonies they represented. Congress selected the

congressmen with prior experience with colonial paper monies to craft the Continental

dollar, such as Benjamin Franklin and Richard Smith. In 1775 and 1776, Congress

extensively debated how to structure the Continental dollar system it created (Grubb

2011a, 2013).

While the sequence, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, and 8, is generally an inexplicable

denominational spacing, a reasonable explanation may be related to the fact that

Continental-dollar bills were relative large in value (see the next section). Most of these bills were used to pay soldiers salaries. Soldiers’ pay was fixed by Congress in June and

July of 1775 at the same time it was deciding on the denominational structure of the initial emissions of Continental dollars (Grubb 2011a, 2013; JCC, v. 2, pp. 89-90, 93-4,

209-10, 220-3). Soldiers’ pay absorbed nearly half of all Continental dollars emitted through 1776 (Grubb 2011b, p. 275). American army privates were paid 80 Continental dollars per year. Privates were the primary recipients of military pay, receiving 78 percent of the money paid to each military company.

The unusual denominational spacing of the Continental dollar becomes sensible if

Congress intended to pay soldiers in the fewest bills necessary, and thus in large-valued bills that would be difficult to use as a circulating currency. Three month’s pay for a

private, 20 Continental dollars, could be accommodated with one or various

combinations of three, four, or five large-valued bills. One month’s pay for a private after

clothing deductions, 5 Continental dollars, could be accommodated with one or various

13 combinations of two large-valued bills. For higher ranked military personal, paying them

with a few large-valued bills was even easier. As such, the strange denominational

spacing of the Continental dollar and its unusual denominational size were linked.

Congress’ behavior is consistent with their hoping that soldiers would simply hold

their pay, being in large-valued bills, as assets for future liquidation post-war. Congress’

behavior is consistent with their thinking that soldiers spending their pay as money would

be too difficult given the bills’ large value. Thus, the emissions of Continental dollars

would not function as a circulating medium of exchange for everyday transactions. As

such, it would not contribute to wartime inflation.

c. American Colonial and Revolution Era Denominational Value Sizes

Appendix Tables A1, A2, and A3 convert the denominational units of the

Continental dollar and of various colonial and state currencies into comparable values,

namely Spanish dollars, pounds sterling, and 2012 U.S. dollars. Table 2 and Figure

1 use the conversion into 2012 U.S. dollars to compare the value of these denominations,

as well as to provide a sense of the relative magnitude of these values. Table 2 and Figure

1 show that the Continental dollar consisted of relatively large-valued bills with 82

percent being over $50 and 69 percent being over $100 in 2012 U.S. dollar value. Only 4

percent were under $10 and none were under $5 in value. Large-valued bills were

difficult to use as a medium of exchange without making change in some other currency,

barter goods, or book credit. Some sense of the large value of a Continental one-dollar bill can be taken from Congress’ payment of one Continental dollar per week in 1775 to cover an enlisted man’s entire weekly subsistence expense while waiting in quarters post- recruitment to join the Continental army (JCC, v. 3, pp. 289, 309, 322, 415, 419).

14 Table 2 Distribution of Denominational Sizes by Number of Units Emitted ______Measured in 2012 U.S. Dollar Equivalents Percentage Below Percentage Above Currency $5 $10 $15 $20 $50 $100 ______1775-1779 (American Revolution) U.S. Continental Dollar 0.00 3.69 7.38 11.07 81.91 69.27

1775-1777 (American Revolution) Virginia Currency 0.00 23.72 47.43 47.43 42.36 34.51

Pennsylvania Currency 56.00 65.40 72.90 74.80 18.70 11.40

New Jersey Currency 0.00 41.40 41.40 55.80 31.80 11.90

New York Currency 31.90 53.80 57.80 76.40 14.40 7.20

1755-1764 (Seven Years War) Virginia Currency 0.00 31.20 48.00 48.00 35.30 22.40

Pennsylvania Currency 26.80 38.80 50.20 50.20 36.10 14.20

New Jersey Currency 0.00 41.00 41.00 50.30 53.00 27.20

New York Currency 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 95.70 91.60 ______Sources: Derived from Appendix Tables A1, A2, and A3.

By contrast, state currencies issued during the first years of the Revolution had a substantial proportion that were small-valued bills, e.g. 56 and 32 percent of

Pennsylvania and New York bills were under $5 in 2012 U.S. dollar value, respectively, and 24 and 41 percent of Virginia and New Jersey bills were under $10 in value, respectively. State currencies during the Revolution were similar in value size to colonial currencies issued during the Seven Years War, with the exception of New York. New

York only issued large-valued bills during the Seven Years War. New York’s behavior during the Seven Years War was the one exception to the general colony/state pattern of

15

Figure 1 Percentage of Units Issued Below the Listed Value

Source: Derived from Appendix Tables A1, A2, and A3. Notes: The lines are accumulated percentages to that point. 2012 U.S. Dollar equivalents are used to provide a common metric for comparison. Separate lines for New Jersey in 1755-64 and in 1776 were not drawn because they were approximately the same.

issuing a preponderance of small-valued bills. As such, it provides the one precedent for

Congress issuing only large-valued bills during the Revolution.

Why New York issued only large-valued bills during the Seven Years War has not been previously noted nor the reasons behind it explained. Whether this example influenced Congress’ denominational choice for the Continental dollar is unknown. The

coincidence is suggestive, given the fact that New York shifted to small-valued bills for

its emissions in 1775-1777 as though there was an intentional policy to separate state and

16 congressional monies by denominational sizes.

John Hanson II (1979, 1980a, 1980b) noted the high proportion of small-valued bills issued by colonial governments and argued that this behavior was an intentional effort by each colony to make their paper money easy to use as a medium of exchange in local transactions. The corollary implication is that only issuing large-valued bills was an intentional effort to restrict the bills’ use as a circulating medium of exchange. Several pieces of evidence are consistent with Congress intentionally making Continental dollars large-valued bills therefore hoping that the bills would not circulate as money, but instead be held like bonds for post-war liquidation.

First, as large-valued as the smallest Continental-dollar bill was in 1775, a congressional committee that included Benjamin Franklin recommended on 11 January

1776 that the first two emissions, totaling six million Continental dollars, be called in and replaced with even larger denominations (JCC, v. 3, pp. 367-8; Smith 1978, v. 3, p. 83).5

Second, Congress through the first seven emissions did not make, or request that the states make, the Continental dollar a legal tender. Without legal tender status, purveyors in the marketplace could refuse to accept payment in Continental dollars. In particular, they could refuse to make change in other currencies when offered large-valued

Continental-dollar bills. Third, when Congress on 22 November 1777 asked the states to curtail their emission of state paper monies, Congress explicitly exempted the emission of small-valued state currencies from this request, explicitly noting the necessity of making change in some currency other than Continental dollars (JCC, v. 9, pp. 955-6).

Finally, colonial paper money acts often included a reserve sum of bills to be

5 This proposal was not adopted largely because it included paying annual interest on the bills issued. Congress thought paying annual interest was impractical because they had no revenue source.

17 printed for the sole purpose of replacing worn, torn, and ragged bills that were no longer fit to remain in circulation. Citizens would bring these unfit bills to the issuing treasury and receive new replacements, with the unfit bills being destroyed by the treasury. The size of these reserve funds provides a gauge of how extensively these bills were expected to circulate hand-to-hand, and thus experience wear and tear, as a local medium of exchange.

For example, the New Jersey emissions of 1733, 1737, and 1769 (the 1769 emission being disallowed by the Crown) each set aside enough extra bills to replace 25 percent of the amount authorized. These emissions had a 16- to 20-year circulation life

(Bush 1977, pp. 427-8, 474-87; 1982, pp. 523-47). The New Jersey emission of June

1756 set aside enough extra bills to replace 20 percent of the amount authorized. This emission had a seven-year circulation life (Bush 1980, pp. 413-25). Finally, the New

Jersey emission of 1746 set aside enough extra bills to replace 60 percent of the amount authorized (Bush 1980, pp. 21-8).

Maryland provides a similar example. The Maryland emission of 1733 set aside enough extra bills to replace 12 percent of the amount authorized (Archives of Maryland, v. 40, pp. 28-31, 266-9). The Maryland emission of 1770 set aside enough extra bills to replace 6 percent of the amount authorized. This emission had a 12-year circulation life.

The Maryland treasury reported that 3.4 percent of this emission had been replaced within the first three years of being placed in circulation. This rate of replacement, if it continued, would exhaust the amount of extra bills set aside for that purpose well before the circulation life of that emission came to an end. As a result, Maryland increased the amount of replacement bills in its next paper money act. The Maryland emission of 1774

18 set aside enough extra bills to replace 28 percent of the amount authorized. This emission also had a 12-year circulation life (Celia and Grubb, 2016). Such evidence makes it hard to deny that colonial paper money experienced extensive hand-to-hand usage as a medium of exchange.

By contrast, Congress only once authorized a reserve of Continental-dollar bills to be printed for the sole purpose of replacing worn bills that could no longer continue in circulation (Grubb 2008, pp. 283-4). On 5 January 1776 Congress authorized “the sum of ten thousand dollars, be struck, for the purpose of exchanging ragged and torn bills of the continental currency; that the bills, making this sum…be lodged in the treasury, to be applied to the sole purpose aforesaid.” (JCC, v. 4, p. 32) A total reserve of 10,000

Continental dollars represented only 0.005 percent of the total emission of Continental dollars and only 0.17 percent of the 17 February 1776 emission of Continental dollars.

This behavior is consistent with Congress expecting Continental-dollar bills not to experience significant hand-to-hand circulation as a medium of exchange and so not experience wear and tear.6

Epilogue

The Second Continental Congress chose to create a common inside paper currency rather than a currency union for the colonies/states in rebellion. They overlaid this common currency on top of states issuing their own inside paper monies and running their own fiscal and monetary policies. Congress’ choice regarding denominational structure of its currency is consist with a rational strategy to maximize the prospects of success for the common currency system adopted. State monies were in low-valued

6 Only a small amount of replacement bills would be required if the need was primarily to replace bills damaged in storage say due to water seepage, as opposed to damaged by hand-to-hand circulation.

19 denominations and so functioned as the local medium of exchange. Congress’

Continental dollars were in high-valued denominations and so were difficult to use as a

medium of exchange. They were to be held as if they were bonds for liquidation after the

war. Thus, the common currency would not contribute to wartime inflation. No linkages

between state monies and the common currency were instituted before 1777. With a short

war, this strategy had reasonable prospects of success. It, however, unraveled by mid-

Revolution.

When the primary use of Continental dollars was to pay soldiers, no legal tender

law was required. Soldier had to accept them as pay. If soldiers could not effectively

spend them, but had to hold them as if they were bonds for post-war redemption, no

congressional funding issues were threatened. After 1776, however, the majority of

congressional spending was on military supplies purchased in the marketplace rather than

on soldiers’ pay (Grubb 2011b, p. 275). In the marketplace, purveyors could refuse

Continental dollars because the bills had no legal tender status. Thus, Congress on 14

January 1777 asked the states to make Continental dollars legal tender within their

respective states (JCC, v. 7, p. 36).

The states moved quickly to accommodate this request. For example,

Pennsylvania made Continental dollars legal tender after 6 February 1777, Delaware after

22 February 1777, and Virginia after 5 May 1777. By the eighth new emission of

Continental dollars, authorized on 22 May 1777, Continental dollars were a legal tender.7

Once they were made legal tender, Continental dollars could be easily used as a medium

7 See Cushing (1981, v. 2, part 1, pp. 599-602); Grubb (2011a); Hening (1969, v. 9, pp. 297-8); Statutes at Large of Pennsylvania (1903, v. 9, pp. 34-40). When a state made the Continental dollar a legal tender within its jurisdiction, this established a legal equivalence between Continental dollars and that state’s paper money. The two monies were now linked, and the exchange of one for the other could be enforced.

20 of exchange. Purveyors could not refuse them nor refuse making change in other

currencies when offered Continental dollars. The establishment of legal tender status

helped make Vz > 0 which in turn allowed increases in Continental dollars to contribute

to wartime inflation.

Second, the massive volume of Continental dollar emissions, given a long and

costly war, overwhelmed Congress’ denominational control strategy. By early 1779,

some 200 million Continental dollars in face value had been emitted. If held and treated

like bonds, the expected redemption of such a volume of bills was now so far in the

future that it reduced the value of Continental dollars by 1778 to being small-valued bills

in present value terms (Grubb 2008, 2011a, 2013). At these low present values, they

could be easily used as a medium of exchange, especially in terms of making change. A

quantity theoretic assessment yields the same outcome, namely an excessive amount of

Continental dollars emitted would depreciate their value until they were now small-

valued bills easily used as a medium of exchange.

The last emissions of Continental dollars were denominationally restructured to

be even larger-valued bills (in face value). Congress, apparently, was trying to offset the loss of value discussed above and so make the bills large-valued again, see Appendix

Table A1. This effort did not succeed. The Continental dollar collapsed to 2.5 percent of face value by 1780. It ceased to circulate shortly thereafter (Grubb 2011a, 2013).

The common currency versus currency union problem for the U.S. was finally resolved by the adoption of the U.S. Constitution in 1789. States lost the constitutional power to issue their own currencies. This paved the way toward forming a true currency union for the new nation (Grubb 2006).

21 References

Archives of Maryland, vol. 1-72. 1883-1972. Baltimore: Maryland Historical Society.

Bolles, A. S. 1969. The Financial History of the from 1774 to 1789, vols. 1-3. New York: Augustus M. Kelly, [original 1884].

Bordo, M. D. 1987. Equation of exchange. In Eatwell, J., Milgate, M., and Newman, P., (eds.), The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. London: Macmillan, v. 2, pp. 175-177.

Bullock, C. J. 1900. Essays on the Monetary History of the United States. New York: Macmillan.

Bush, B. (ed.) 1977. Laws of the Royal Colony of New Jersey, 1703-1745. Trenton, NJ: New Jersey State Library, Archives and History Bureau.

Bush, B. (ed.) 1980. Laws of the Royal Colony of New Jersey, 1746-1760. Trenton, NJ: New Jersey State Library, Bureau of Archives and History.

Bush, B. (ed.) 1982. Laws of the Royal Colony of New Jersey, 1760-1769. Trenton, NJ: New Jersey State Library, Archives and History Bureau.

Celia, J. and Grubb, F. 2016. Non-legal-tender paper money: the structure and performance of Maryland’s bills of credit, 1767-1775. Economic History Review, forthcoming.

Cushing, J. D. (ed.) 1981. The First Laws of the State of Delaware, vol. 2, part 1. Wilmington, DE: Michael Glazier, State Printer of Delaware.

Davis, A. M. 1964. Colonial Currency Reprints, 1682-1751, vols. 1-4. New York: Augustus M. Kelly.

Fisher, I. 1912. The Purchasing Power of Money. New York: Macmillan.

Grubb, F. 2006. The U.S. Constitution and monetary powers: an analysis of the 1787 Constitutional Convention and the Constitutional transformation of the U.S. Monetary system. Financial History Review 13, 43-71.

Grubb, F. 2008. The Continental dollar: how much was really issued? Journal of Economic History 68: 283-91.

Grubb, F. 2011a. The Continental dollar: initial design, ideal performance, and the credibility of congressional commitment. National Bureau of Economic Research, working paper #17276, http://www.nber.org/papers/w17276.

Grubb, F. 2011b. The distribution of Congressional spending during the American

22 revolution, 1775-1780: the problem of geographic balance. In S. Conway and R. Torres Sánchez (eds.). The Spending of the States—Military Expenditure during the long Eighteenth Century: Patterns, Organisations, and Consequences, 1650- 1815. Saabrücken, Germany: VDM Verlag Dr. Müller GmbH & Co. KG, 257- 284.

Grubb, F. 2013. The Continental dollar: how the American Revolution was financed with paper money—initial design and ideal performance. National Bureau of Economic Research, working paper #19577, http://www.nber.org/papers/w19577.

Grubb, F. 2016. Is paper money just paper money? Experimentation and variation in the paper monies issued by the American colonies from 1690 to 1775. Research in Economic History, forthcoming.

Hammond, B. 1991. Banks and Politics in America. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press [original 1957].

Hanson, J. R. II. 1979. Money in the colonial American economy: an extension. Economic Inquiry 17, 281-286.

Hanson, J. R. II. 1980a. Small notes in the American colonies. Explorations in Economic History 17, 411-420.

Hanson, J. R. II. 1980b. The economic development of the thirteen continental colonies, 1720 to 1775: a critique. William and Mary Quarterly 37, 165-175.

Hening, W. W. (ed.) 1969. The Statutes at Large; being a Collection of all the Laws of Virginia from the First Session of the Legislature, in the Year 1619, Vols. 6-9. Charlottesville, VA: University Press of Virginia [original: Richmond, VA: Franklin Press, 1819-1821].

Journals of the Continental Congress, 1774-1789, Vols. 1-34. 1904-1937. Washington D.C.: Government Printing Office (JCC in the text).

McCusker, J. J. 1978. Money and Exchange in Europe and America, 1600-1775. Chapel Hill, NC: University of North Carolina Press.

Newman, E. P. 2008. The Early Paper Money of America. Iola, WI: Krause Publications, (5th edition).

Phillips, H. Jr. 1866. Continental Paper Money: Historical Sketches of American Paper Currency, Second Series. Roxbury, MA: W. Elliot Woodward.

Randall, W. S. 1990. Benedict Arnold: Patriot and Traitor. New York: Barnes & Noble Books.

23 Ratchford, U. B. 1941. American State Debts. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.

Redish, A. and Weber, W. E. 2008. Coin sizes and payments in commodity money systems. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Research Department Staff Report 416.

Smith, P. H. 1976-1994. Letters of Delegates to Congress, 1774-1789, Vols. 1-21. Washington, DC: Library of Congress.

Sparks, J. 1832. The Life of Gouverneur Morris, with Selections from his Correspondence and Miscellaneous Papers in Three Volumes. Boston: Gray & Bowen.

Statutes at Large of Pennsylvania, vols. 9-10. 1903-1904. Harrisburg, PA: W.M. Stanley Ray, State Printer of Pennsylvania.

Sumner, S. B. 1990. The transactions and hoarding demand for currency. Quarterly Review of Economics and Business 30, 75-85.

Sumner, W. G. 1968. The Financier and the Finances of the American Revolution, vols. 1-2. New York: Augustus M. Kelly [original 1891].

Telser, L. G. 1995. Optimal denominations for coins and currency. Economic Letters 49, 425-427.

Tindall, G. B. 1988. America: A Narrative History. New York: W. W. Norton, 2nd edn.

Tschoegl, A. E. 1997. The optimal denomination of currency. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 29, 546-554.

Van Hove, L. 2001. Optimal denominations for coins and bank notes: in defense of the principle of least effort. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 33, 1015-1021.

Wallace, N. and Zhou, R. 1997. A model of a currency shortage. Journal of Monetary Economics 40, 555-572.

Wynne, M. A. 1997. More on optimal denominations for coins and currency. Economic Letters 55, 221-225.

24 Appendix Table A1 Denominational Structure of the Continental Dollar in Face Values per Emission, 1775-1779 ______In $: In May 10, 1775 Nov. 29, 1775 Feb. 17, 1776 May 9, 1776 July22, 1776 Nov. 2, 1776 Feb. 26, 1777 c d Spanish 2012 #1: $3,000,000 #2: $3,000,000 #3: 4,000,000 #4: $5,000,000 #5: $5,000,000 #6: $5,000,000 #7: $5,000,000

Silver U.S. Units Value Units Value Units Value Units Value Units Value Units Value Units Value a Dollars Dollars % % % % % % % % % % % % % % ______0.17 5.2 …. …. …. …. 18.85 2.50 …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. 0.33 10.3 …. …. …. …. 18.85 5.00 …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. 0.50 15.5 …. …. …. …. 18.85 7.50 …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. 0.67 20.7 …. …. …. …. 18.85 10.00 …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. 1.00 31.0 11.21 1.63 12.50 2.78 4.10 3.26 12.50 2.78 …. …. …. …. …. …. 2.00 62.0 11.21 3.27 12.50 5.56 4.10 6.52 12.50 5.56 12.50 3.08 12.50 3.08 12.50 3.08 3.00 93.0 11.21 4.90 12.50 8.33 4.10 9.78 12.50 8.33 12.50 4.62 12.50 4.62 12.50 4.62 4.00 124.0 11.21 6.53 12.50 11.11 4.10 13.04 12.50 11.11 12.50 6.15 12.50 6.15 12.50 6.15 5.00 155.0 11.21 8.17 12.50 13.89 2.05 8.15 12.50 13.89 12.50 7.69 12.50 7.69 12.50 7.69 6.00 186.0 11.21 9.80 12.50 16.67 2.05 9.78 12.50 16.67 12.50 9.23 12.50 9.23 12.50 9.23 7.00 217.0 11.21 11.43 12.50 19.44 2.05 11.41 12.50 19.44 12.50 10.77 12.50 10.77 12.50 10.77 8.00 248.0 11.21 13.07 12.50 22.22 2.05 13.04 12.50 22.22 12.50 12.31 12.50 12.31 12.50 12.31 20.00 620.0 2.70 7.87 …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. b 30.00 930.0 7.63 33.33 …. …. …. …. …. …. 12.50 46.15 12.50 46.15 12.50 46.15 35.00 1,085.0 …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. 40.00 1,240.0 …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. 45.00 1,395.0 …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. 50.00 1,550.0 …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. 55.00 1,705.0 …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. 60.00 1,860.0 …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. 65.00 2,015.0 …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. 70.00 2,170.0 …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. 80.00 2,480.0 …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. ______100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 ______

25 Appendix Table A1—Continued ______May 20, 1777 April 11, 1778 Sept. 26, 1778 Jan. 14, 1779 1775-1779 In $: In e f #8: $16,500,000 #9: $25,000,000 #10: $75,001,080 #11: $95,051,695 Total Spanish 2012 Units Value Units Value Units Value Units Value Units Value Silver U.S. a % % % % % % % % % % Dollars Dollars ______…. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. 3.69 0.04 0.17 5.2 …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. 3.69 0.08 0.33 10.3 …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. 3.69 0.12 0.50 15.5 …. …. …. …. …. …. …. …. 3.69 0.17 0.67 20.7 …. …. …. …. …. …. 5.43 0.15 3.33 0.22 1.00 31.0 12.50 3.08 12.50 3.33 …. …. 5.43 0.29 6.32 0.85 2.00 62.0 12.50 4.62 12.50 4.17 …. …. 5.43 0.44 6.32 1.27 3.00 93.0 12.50 6.15 12.50 5.00 …. …. 5.43 0.59 7.60 2.04 4.00 124.0 12.50 7.69 12.50 5.83 12.50 2.27 5.43 0.74 9.30 3.13 5.00 155.0 12.50 9.23 12.50 6.67 …. …. …. …. 6.34 2.56 6.00 186.0 12.50 10.77 12.50 16.67 12.50 3.18 …. …. 8.44 3.97 7.00 217.0 12.50 12.31 12.50 25.00 12.50 3.64 …. …. 8.44 4.54 8.00 248.0 …. …. …. …. 12.50 9.09 7.07 2.94 4.31 5.80 20.00 620.0 12.50 46.15 12.50 33.33 12.50 13.64 7.07 5.75 7.69 15.52 30.00 930.0 …. …. …. …. …. …. 7.07 6.70 1.12 2.64 35.00 1,085.0 …. …. …. …. 12.50 18.18 7.07 7.66 4.50 12.11 40.00 1,240.0 …. …. …. …. …. …. 7.07 8.62 1.12 3.39 45.00 1,395.0 …. …. …. …. 12.50 22.73 7.07 9.58 3.22 10.83 50.00 1,550.0 …. …. …. …. …. …. 7.07 10.54 1.12 4.15 55.00 1,705.0 …. …. …. …. 12.50 27.27 7.07 11.49 3.22 12.99 60.00 1,860.0 …. …. …. …. …. …. 7.07 12.45 1.12 4.90 65.00 2,015.0 …. …. …. …. …. …. 5.43 10.30 0.86 4.05 70.00 2,170.0 …. …. …. …. …. …. 5.43 11.77 0.86 4.63 80.00 2,480.0 ______100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 ______Sources: JCC (v. 2, pp. 105, 207; v. 3, p. 398; v. 4, pp. 164, 381; v. 5, p. 651; v. 6, pp. 918, 1047; v. 7, p. 161; v. 8, pp. 377, 646; v. 9, pp. 873, 993; v. 10, pp. 28, 83, 175, 223, 309, 337, 365; v. 11, pp. 524, 627, 732; v. 12, pp. 884, 962, 1100, 1218; v. 13, pp. 64, 139, 209, 409; v. 14, pp. 548, 557-8, 688, 848-9; v. 15, pp. 1076, 1172, 1285, 1325); Newman (2008, pp. 62-73).

26 Notes: $ = Spanish silver dollars—what the Continental dollar, at face value, was denominated in. a From http://eh.net “measuring worth—relative value of U.S. Dollars” using the 1775 to 2012 CPI conversion algorithm. b On 25 July 1775, Congress ordered $1,000,000 struck in $30 bills (JCC v. 2, p. 207). This is not possible. Either $999,990 or $1,000,020 can be struck, but not $1,000,000. Which was done and whether other denominations from emission #1 were adjusted to accommodate the $1,000,000 target in $30 bills is not known. The number $999,990 is used here for percentage calculation purposes. c Newman (2008, p. 64) presents erroneous denominational counts for the November 29, 1775 emission. See instead, JCC (v. 3, p. 398). d Only $3,937,220 were printed. Which denominations were shorted is not known. The $4,000,000 number is used for percentage calculation purposes. e This is a gross emission number (total bills printed). Out of this gross emission, $41,500,000 were swapped for the emissions of 20 May 1777 and 11 April 1777 (emissions #8 and #9), yielding a net new emission of $53,551,695. Which bills by denomination were swapped is not known, so the denomination structure is reported on the gross rather than on the net new emission total. f This is out of total scheduled printings ($241,552,775) and not net new emissions ($199,989,995). Not all bills were printed, and some printed bills were simply swapped for other bills previously emitted, which explains the difference in these two sums. Which denomination totals were affected by nonprinting and currency swaps is unknown. See notes b, d, and e.

27 Appendix Table A2 Face Value Denominational Structure of Colonial Paper Monies during the Seven Years War, 1755-1764 ______$: Face Value Virginia 1757-1762 | Pennsylvania New Jersey New York $: Face Value Face Value in in £VA | Denom- 1755-64 £PA 1755-64 £NJ 1755-64 £NY Face Value in in Value Spanish 2012 Denom- 560,107 370,588 | inations 1,307,931 550,000 374,998 347,603 72,600 340,000 Value Spanish 2012

in Silver U.S. inations Units Value | £PA, £NJ, Units Value Units Value Units Value in Silver U.S. £S Dollars Dollars £VA % % | & £NY % % % % % % £S Dollars Dollars ______0.0400 0.1739 5.39 0.0500 15.6 1.2 | 0.0125 8.1 0.2 …. …. …. …. 0.0094 0.0409 1.26 0.0500 0.2174 6.74 0.0625 15.6 1.5 | 0.0167 6.3 0.3 …. …. …. …. 0.0125 0.0545 1.69 0.1000 0.4348 13.48 0.1250 16.8 3.2 | 0.0250 6.2 0.4 …. …. …. …. 0.0188 0.0817 2.53 0.2000 0.8696 26.96 0.2500 16.8 6.3 | 0.0375 6.2 0.6 …. …. …. …. 0.0282 0.1226 3.80 0.4000 1.7391 53.91 0.5000 12.9 9.7 | 0.0500 6.2 0.7 15.1 0.8 …. …. 0.0376 0.1635 5.07 0.8000 3.4783 107.83 1.0000 12.9 19.4 | 0.0750 5.8 1.0 11.7 1.0 …. …. 0.0564 0.2452 7.60 1.6000 6.9565 215.65 2.0000 2.8 8.5 | 0.1000 5.7 1.4 …. …. …. …. 0.0752 0.3269 10.13 2.4000 10.4348 323.48 3.0000 2.8 12.8 | 0.1250 5.7 1.7 …. …. …. …. 0.0940 0.4086 12.67 4.0000 17.3913 539.13 5.0000 2.8 21.3 | 0.1500 …. …. 9.3 1.5 …. …. 0.1128 0.4904 15.20 8.0000 34.7876 1,078.42 10.0000 1.1 16.2 | 0.2500 13.8 8.2 …. …. 4.4 0.2 0.1880 0.8173 25.34 ______| 0.3000 …. …. 10.8 3.5 …. …. 0.2256 0.9807 30.40 100 100 | 0.5000 12.0 14.2 …. …. 4.1 0.4 0.3759 1.6345 50.67 | 0.6000 …. …. 10.8 7.0 …. …. 0.4511 1.9614 60.80 | 0.7500 9.9 17.7 15.0 12.1 …. …. 0.5639 2.4518 76.01 | 1.0000 11.2 26.5 …. …. 5.7 1.2 0.7519 3.2690 101.34 | 1.5000 …. …. 15.3 24.8 …. …. 1.1278 4.9036 152.01 | 2.0000 …. …. …. …. 31.1 13.3 1.5038 6.5381 202.68 | 2.5000 1.5 9.1 …. …. …. …. 1.8797 8.1726 253.35 | 3.0000 …. …. 8.6 27.8 3.6 2.3 2.2556 9.8071 304.02 | 4.0000 …. …. …. …. 0.8 0.7 3.0075 13.0762 405.36 | 5.0000 1.5 18.1 …. …. 24.1 25.7 3.7594 16.3452 506.70 | 6.0000 …. …. 3.3 21.5 …. …. 4.5113 19.6143 608.04 | 10.0000 …. …. …. …. 26.3 56.2 7.5188 32.6905 1,013.41 ______100 100 100 100 100 100 ______Sources: See the notes to Appendix Tables A1 and A3; Bush (1980, pp. 314-5, 348-9, 373-4, 417, 466, 501, 517, 549, 572-3, 631-2, 673-4; 1982, pp. 83-4, 135-6, 207-8, 299-300); Hening (1969, v. 7, pp. 82-3, 175, 259-60, 350, 360-1, 498); McCusker (1978, p. 10); Newman (2008, pp. 259-61, 281-3, 336-43). Notes: Shillings and pence are converted to decimalized pounds. At face value, 1.25£VA = 1£S and 1.33(£PA, £NJ, £NY) = 1£S. Pre-1772, 1£S = $4.34783.

28 Appendix Table A3 Face Value Denominational Structure of State Paper Monies during the American Revolution, 1775-1777 ______Value New York | Pennsylvania New Jersey $: Face Value | Virginia Value In 1775-77 $ | Denom- 1775-77 £PA 1776 £NJ Face Value in in | 1775-76 £VA in 2012 Denom- 757,868 750,000 | inations 1,307,931 550,000 346,882 175,000 Value Spanish 2012 | Denom- 460,796 447,404 2012

U.S. inations Units Value | £PA, Units Value Units Value in Silver U.S. | inations Units Value U.S.

Dollars $ % % | & £NJ % % % % £S Dollars Dollars | £VA % % Dollars ______2.02 0.0650 14.0 0.9 | 0.0125 14.0 0.6 …. …. 0.0094 0.0427 1.32 | 0.0500 5.33 0.27 5.64 3.88 0.1250 17.9 2.3 | 0.0167 14.0 0.8 …. …. 0.0125 0.0568 1.76 | 0.0625 18.39 1.18 7.05 5.17 0.1667 4.0 0.7 | 0.0250 14.0 1.2 …. …. 0.0188 0.0855 2.65 | 0.1000 5.33 0.55 11.27 7.75 0.2500 17.9 4.5 | 0.0375 14.0 1.8 …. …. 0.0282 0.1282 3.97 | 0.1250 18.38 2.37 14.09 10.33 0.3333 4.0 1.3 | 0.0500 4.7 0.8 23.4 2.3 0.0376 0.1709 5.29 | 0.2500 6.31 1.63 28.18 15.50 0.5000 18.6 9.4 | 0.0750 4.7 1.2 18.0 2.7 0.0564 0.2564 7.95 | 0.3750 3.90 1.51 42.27 20.67 0.6667 4.0 2.7 | 0.1000 4.7 1.6 …. …. 0.0752 0.3418 10.60 | 0.5000 3.95 2.03 56.36 31.00 1.0000 5.3 5.3 | 0.1250 2.8 1.2 …. …. 0.0940 0.4273 13.25 | 0.6250 3.90 2.51 70.45 62.00 2.0000 3.6 7.3 | 0.1500 1.9 1.0 14.4 4.3 0.1128 0.5127 15.89 | 1.0000 10.15 10.45 112.73 93.00 3.0000 3.6 10.9 | 0.2000 2.1 1.5 …. …. 0.1504 0.6836 21.19 | 1.2000 5.33 6.59 135.27 155.00 5.0000 3.6 18.2 | 0.2500 0.4 0.3 …. …. 0.1880 0.8545 26.49 | 1.5000 5.33 8.23 169.09 310.00 10.0000 3.6 36.5 | 0.3000 2.1 2.2 12.3 7.3 0.2256 1.0255 31.79 | 2.0000 5.00 10.30 225.45 ______| 0.4000 1.9 2.7 …. …. 0.3008 1.3673 42.39 | 3.0000 3.52 10.88 338.18 100 100 | 0.5000 2.7 4.8 …. …. 0.3759 1.7086 52.97 | 4.0000 0.43 1.79 450.91 | 0.6000 1.9 4.0 10.8 12.9 0.4511 2.0505 63.57 | 5.0000 1.78 9.18 563.64 | 0.7000 0.2 0.5 …. …. 0.5263 2.3923 74.16 | 8.0000 1.31 10.80 901.82 | 0.7500 0.4 1.0 9.1 13.6 0.5639 2.5632 79.46 | 10.0000 0.30 3.11 1,127.27 | 0.8000 2.1 5.8 …. …. 0.6015 2.7341 84.76 | 12.0000 1.35 16.62 1,352.73 | 1.0000 4.6 16.1 …. …. 0.7519 3.4177 105.95 | ______| 1.5000 2.4 12.3 6.5 19.3 1.1278 5.1264 158.92 | 100 100 | 2.0000 3.2 21.9 …. …. 1.5038 6.8354 211.90 | | 2.5000 0.2 1.8 …. …. 1.8797 8.5441 264.87 | | 3.0000 …. …. 4.5 27.0 2.2556 10.2527 317.83 | | 4.0000 0.8 11.2 …. …. 3.0075 13.6704 423.78 | | 5.0000 0.2 3.7 …. …. 3.7594 17.0882 529.73 | | 6.0000 …. …. 0.9 10.7 4.5113 20.5059 635.68 | ______100 100 100 100 ______

29 Sources: See the notes to Appendix Tables A1 and A2; McCusker (1978, p. 10); Newman (2008, pp. 259-61, 286-90, 350-7, 444-6). Notes: $ = Spanish silver dollars. £S = pounds sterling. £VA = Virginia pounds. £PA =Pennsylvania pounds. £NJ = New Jersey pounds. £NY = New York pounds. Post-1772, 1£S = $4.54545. For Virginia, to get the value in 2012 U.S. dollars, take the denomination value * 0.8 * 4.54545 * 31; For Pennsylvania and New Jersey, take the denomination value * 0.75188 * 4.54545 * 31. New York state money was denominated in Spanish silver dollars, thus to get the value in 2012 U.S. dollars, just take the denomination value * 31.

30

31