Consequences of the Euro: Monetary Union, Economic Disunion?

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Consequences of the Euro: Monetary Union, Economic Disunion? VOL. 11, NO. 2 • APRIL 2016 DALLASFED Economic Letter Consequences of the Euro: Monetary Union, Economic Disunion? by Enrique Martínez-García and Valerie Grossman } ABSTRACT: Forming a ineteen countries in the flexibility, and labor mobility across bor- monetary union brings the European Union have adopted ders lessen the costs associated with a the euro since 1999, surrender- monetary union and make it more likely benefits of a shared currency N ing independence over their for a currency area to be optimal for its but also—as the experience monetary policy with the expectation members. It also suggests that deepening of the euro area shows in that commercial and political ties would cross-border capital flows or enactment the years following the global deepen. of policies to redistribute fiscal benefits A monetary union can lower transac- among union members can provide a financial crisis—significant tion costs and increase price transpar- degree of risk sharing and ease the bur- costs associated with the ency and competition, creating trade and den of a monetary union. loss of monetary policy financial opportunities. Countries reap The theory was put to a test when 11 independence and exchange these benefits based on their ability to European Union member states debuted exploit them. Similarly, the loss of mon- the euro in 1999: Austria, Belgium, rate flexibility. etary policy independence affects some Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, countries much more than others. Luxembourg, Netherlands, Portugal and Experience suggests that the euro area Spain. Greece joined in 2001, followed is far from the “optimal currency area” by Slovenia in 2007, Cyprus and Malta in economists envisioned in the 1960s and 2008, Slovakia in 2009, Estonia in 2011, that its advocates foresaw. Among the Latvia in 2014 and Lithuania in 2015 reasons: diverging business cycles across (Chart 1). member countries, wage (and price) With such a varied group of countries, rigidities and limited mobility of labor a situation can arise in which aggregate and capital between euro economies. demand in one of them, say Spain, weak- ens at the same time that it strengthens in Case for Monetary Union another country, say Germany. Absent a The theory of optimal currency areas, currency union, such divergence could be developed in the early 1960s, outlines addressed by pursuing relatively expan- when the benefits of a shared currency sive monetary policy (lowering the policy outweigh the costs associated with the rate, for example) in Spain while tighten- loss of monetary policy independence ing monetary policy (raising the rate) in and exchange-rate flexibility.1 Germany. The idea behind the theory is that However, when the two countries are similar business cycles, price and wage bound by a shared currency and common Economic Letter Similarly, a monetary union can Chart The European Union and the Euro Area in 2015 reduce the cost of adjusting to diverging 1 demand among countries through risk sharing with members. Such sharing can occur through capital markets (stock and Euro area bond markets) and cross-country fiscal Other members of the European Union transfers, such as unemployment insur- ance. The benefits of a common monetary policy diminish as risk-sharing mecha- nisms weaken. Euro’s Benefits The perceived benefits of the euro stem from expanding trade, lowering transaction costs and facilitating cross- border flows of labor, capital and informa- tion. During the euro’s first eight years, a remarkable degree of nominal conver- gence occurred, most evident in interest rates on government debt. Euro backers cited the compression of long-term inter- Chart est rates among member countries as Euro-Area Long-Term Borrowing Costs Converge Before 2008 indicative of the success of the monetary 2 (10-year government bond yields) union (Chart 2). Percent Monetary policy autonomy prior to 30 the euro led to differences among coun- Jan. 1, 1999: Euro launched tries that were reflected in long-term 25 interest rate spreads. After adopting Jan. 1, 2001: the euro, countries such as Spain could 20 Greece joins borrow at essentially the same rates as Germany. Spreads above Germany’s 15 relatively safe borrowing cost re-emerged in 2008 with the global financial crisis 10 in spite of a shared monetary policy because of heightened country risks. 5 Dissimilarities across Europe grew, under- scoring the costs that come with sacrific- 0 ’80 ’85 ’90 ’95 ’00 ’05 ’10 ’15 ing monetary policy independence. Greece Ireland Finland Portugal Belgium Luxembourg Monetary Union Limitations Spain France Netherlands Italy Austria Germany Before the euro, Spain and Germany NOTE: Shaded areas show euro-area recessions, according to the Center for Economic Policy Research. pursued different economic policies tai- SOURCES: European Central Bank; Center for Economic Policy Research. lored to their own domestic conditions. Such behavior emerged with the 1992 recession. monetary policy, that’s not possible, creat- Looking at the U.S. in 1992, econo- Spain faced relatively weak aggregate ing a need for other mechanisms to share mists Olivier Blanchard and Lawrence demand and rapidly rising unemploy- risks and absorb shocks. Without recourse Katz examined the response to rising ment during the recession. Spanish to a nominal exchange rate devalution, the unemployment.2 The states share a cur- policymakers chose to provide monetary real (inflation-adjusted) value of the mon- rency (the dollar) and a monetary policy. accommodation, devaluing the peseta etary union’s currency can still decline In a well-functioning monetary union twice to stimulate economic activity and when wages and prices fall within an such as the U.S., adjustment often occurs boost demand (Chart 3). Germany, deal- area—an adjustment known as an internal through the movement of unemployed ing with a fiscal expansion arising from devaluation. Reduced costs of production workers to states with better opportuni- unification of West and East Germany, in one country will allow it to gain market ties and, to a lesser extent, through lower continued to pursue the tighter monetary share for its exports and boost economic wages (internal devaluation), the econo- policy stance it had taken since 1989. activity through external trade. mists argued. The two countries could pursue differ- 2 Economic Letter • Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas • April 2016 Economic Letter ing monetary policies because each had Chart its own currency. Exchange Rates Become Fixed with Euro Adoption When Spain and Germany adopted the 3 euro in 1999, they lost their ability to con- Deutsche mark/peseta duct monetary policy independently and to use the exchange rate as a policy instru- 0.028 Spain joins Euro European adoption 0.026 ment. The European Central Bank set Union monetary policy beginning in 1999 based 0.024 on the economic conditions of the larger 0.022 monetary union rather than in response to the particular needs of Spain or Germany. 0.020 The costs of a single currency with a 0.018 one-size-fits-all monetary policy became 0.016 Devaluations apparent during the 2008–09 recession, 0.014 when domestic economic conditions deteriorated abruptly and began to sig- 0.012 nificantly differ among euro-area nations, 0.010 including Spain and Germany (Chart 4). ’80 ’85 ’90 ’95 ’00 ’05 ’10 ’15 Germany was hit harder than Spain NOTES: Shaded areas show euro-area recessions, according to the Center for Economic Policy Research. The Deutsche mark was Germany’s currency and the peseta was Spain’s before the introduction of the euro. during the downturn but consistently SOURCES: Federal Reserve Board; Center for Economic Policy Research. outperformed the euro area during the recovery. Spain, meanwhile, significantly underperformed. The stance of monetary Chart Euro-Area Conditions Diverge After 2008–09 Global Recession policy became too restrictive for Spain, which suffered a severe economic contrac- 4 (Cumulative growth of real GDP since 2008) tion and high unemployment. Spain could Percent no longer unilaterally employ the tools it 8 formerly used to combat a slowdown and Spain 6 boost exports—lower interest rates and Euro area exchange rate devaluation. 4 Germany A weak recovery took hold in the euro area in 2009–12—but with significant dif- 2 ferences across countries. The 2010–12 sovereign debt crisis that was particularly 0 pronounced in the so-called periphery –2 countries, which included Spain, accentu- 3 ated the problem. The recovery firmed –4 up and became broad based as public finances improved during 2012–15. –6 2008–09 2009–12 2012–15 Labor Markets SOURCES: European Commission; authors’ calculations. Spain’s struggles and those of the other countries in the euro-area periphery since 2008 have raised questions about the Table costs of a common currency. The ability Spain’s Costly Change Since 2008: to undertake an internal devaluation has 1 Lower Labor Costs, Higher Out-Migration proven to be limited because European Spain Euro area Germany labor markets remain quite rigid and sub- ject to national wage setting. In such an 2009–12 2012–15 2009–12 2012–15 2009–12 2012–15 environment, wages and prices within a Real unit labor costs (%) –5.64 –1.53 –0.97 –0.56 –0.54 –0.05 country adjust slowly to changing econom- Unemployment rate (diff). 6.90 –2.50 1.80 –0.40 –2.20 –0.60 ic conditions. Although Spain regained Working-age population (%) –0.79 –2.28 –0.09 –0.25 0.37 1.64 some external competitiveness primarily Government debt over GDP (diff.) 32.71 15.25 12.97 2.19 7.21 –8.06 by lowering its labor costs, unemployment rose sharply—6.9 percentage points during NOTES: The table shows percent changes for the periods 2009–12 and 2012–15 in real unit labor costs and the working-age population.
Recommended publications
  • Does a Currency Union Affect Trade? the Time Series Evidence
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a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
    [Show full text]
  • Currency Unions
    Currency Unions The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters Citation Alesina, Alberto, and Robert J. Barro. 2002. Currency unions. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117(2): 409-436. Published Version http://dx.doi.org/10.1162/003355302753650283 Citable link http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:4551795 Terms of Use This article was downloaded from Harvard University’s DASH repository, and is made available under the terms and conditions applicable to Other Posted Material, as set forth at http:// nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:dash.current.terms-of- use#LAA CURRENCY UNIONS* ALBERTO ALESINA AND ROBERT J. BARRO Common currencies affect trading costs and, thereby, the amounts of trade, output, and consumption. From the perspective of monetary policy, the adoption of another country's currency trades off the benefits of commitment to price stability (if a committed anchor is selected) against the loss of an independent stabilization policy. We show that the type of country that has more to gain from giving up its own currency is a small open economy heavily trading with one particular large partner, with a history of high infiation and with a business cycle highly correlated with that of the potential "anchor." We also characterize the features of the optimal number of currency unions. I. INTRODUCTION In 1947 there were 76 countries in the world; today there are 193. The growth of the numher of countries has led to a large increase in the numher of currencies in circulation; un- less one helieves that a country is, hy definition, an "optimal currency area," either there were too few currencies in 1947, or there are too many today.
    [Show full text]
  • Currency Union As a Panacea for Ills in Africa: a New Institutional Framework and Theoretical Consideration
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive Currency Union as a Panacea for ills in Africa: A New Institutional Framework and Theoretical Consideration Abban, Stanley Kwame Nkrumah University of Science and Technology 11 December 2020 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/105459/ MPRA Paper No. 105459, posted 25 Jan 2021 20:11 UTC 1.0 INTRODUCTION A currency union is a union to which two or more countries agree to surrender their monetary sovereignty to adopt an official currency issued by a Central Bank tasked with formulating and implementing monetary policy. Currency union came to light when there was a need for choosing a suitable exchange rate regime as an improvement on the fixed exchange rate. Comparatively, currency union is superlative to fixed exchange rate due to equalization of price through the laid down nominal convergence criteria and the introduction of a common currency to ensure greater transparency in undertaking transactions (Rose, 2000; Abban, 2020a). Currency union is touted to emanate several gains and has the potential to be disastrous based on the conditionality among member-states. Empirical studies emphasize the main advantages of currency union membership lies with the elimination of exchange rate volatility to increase savings, relaxation of policies that hinder the free movement of persons and capital to improve trade and tourism, price transparency to intensify trade, and the ability to induce greater Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) to stimulate intra-trade flows (Rose, 2000; Micco et al., 2003; Aristotelous & Fountas, 2009; Rodriguez et al, 2012). The key areas that benefit from currency union membership include production, the financial market, the labour market, tourism, the private sector, the political environment among others (Karlinger, 2002; Martinez et al, 2018; Formaro, 2020).
    [Show full text]
  • France À Fric: the CFA Zone in Africa and Neocolonialism
    France à fric: the CFA zone in Africa and neocolonialism Ian Taylor Date of deposit 18 04 2019 Document version Author’s accepted manuscript Access rights Copyright © Global South Ltd. This work is made available online in accordance with the publisher’s policies. This is the author created, accepted version manuscript following peer review and may differ slightly from the final published version. Citation for Taylor, I. C. (2019). France à fric: the CFA Zone in Africa and published version neocolonialism. Third World Quarterly, Latest Articles. Link to published https://doi.org/10.1080/01436597.2019.1585183 version Full metadata for this item is available in St Andrews Research Repository at: https://research-repository.st-andrews.ac.uk/ FRANCE À FRIC: THE CFA ZONE IN AFRICA AND NEOCOLONIALISM Over fifty years after 1960’s “Year of Africa,” most of Francophone Africa continues to be embedded in a set of associations that fit very well with Kwame Nkrumah’s description of neocolonialism, where postcolonial states are de jure independent but in reality constrained through their economic systems so that policy is directed from outside. This article scrutinizes the functioning of the CFA, considering the role the currency has in persistent underdevelopment in most of Francophone Africa. In doing so, the article identifies the CFA as the most blatant example of functioning neocolonialism in Africa today and a critical device that promotes dependency in large parts of the continent. Mainstream analyses of the technical aspects of the CFA have generally focused on the exchange rate and other related matters. However, while important, the real importance of the CFA franc should not be seen as purely economic, but also political.
    [Show full text]
  • Currency Unions and Trade: a Post‐EMU Reassessment Reuven Glick and Andrew K
    Currency Unions and Trade: A Post‐EMU Reassessment Reuven Glick and Andrew K. Rose* Revised Draft: March 18, 2016 Comments Welcome Abstract In our European Economic Review (2002) paper, we used pre‐1998 data on countries participating in and leaving currency unions to estimate the effect of currency unions on trade using (then‐) conventional gravity models. In this paper, we use a variety of empirical gravity models to estimate the currency union effect on trade and exports, using recent data which includes the European Economic and Monetary Union (EMU). We have three findings. First, our assumption of symmetry between the effects of entering and leaving a currency union seems reasonable in the data. Second, our preferred methodology indicates that EMU has boosted exports by around 50%. While other estimation techniques yield different results, a panel approach with both time‐varying country and dyadic fixed effects on a large span of data (across both countries and time) seems to deliver insensitive and reliable results. Third, different currency unions have different trade effects. Keywords: gravity, exports, bilateral, common, fixed, time‐varying, country, specific. JEL Classification Numbers: F15, F33 Reuven Glick Andrew K. Rose (correspondence) Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Haas School of Business 101 Market St., University of California San Francisco CA 94105 Berkeley, CA USA 94720‐1900 Tel: (415) 974‐3184 Tel: (510) 642‐6609 Fax: (415) 974‐2168 Fax: (510) 642‐4700 E‐mail: [email protected] E‐mail: [email protected] * Glick is Group Vice President for International Research, Economic Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.
    [Show full text]
  • The Euro's Impact on France's Trade with Adopting And
    The Euro’s Impact on France’s Trade with Adopting and Non-adopting Countries Julie DeRoo March 1st 2004 The Euro’s Impact on France’s Trade with Adopting and Non-adopting Countries Julie DeRoo ABSTRACT A major economic reason for the introduction of the euro was the conviction that, by eliminating the exchange risks within the European Union (EU), a common currency would intensify the commercial relations between member countries. Whether the EU’s outlook is affected by, or just coincides with, the introduction of the euro is a fascinating question. Consequently, this paper studies the impact of the euro on France’s trade with adopting and non-adopting countries. Using a model à la Rose, I calculate the Euro’s impact on French trade with 20 OECD countries. I find that there is a strong impact of sharing the European common currency on bilateral trade flows, and this effect grows with the time span over which the common currency has been shared. I estimate that French trade increased by 33% with Euro countries due to the introduction of the Euro. These results are not only encouraging for the future of the EU as a whole but are also interesting for future adopting countries. 2 Contents 1- Introduction a. Introduction to the Euro b. Survey of Empirical Literature 2- Methodology a. Data Set b. Model Specifications 3- Empirical Analysis and Results 4- Results Comparison with Earlier Studies 5- Conclusion 6- Table 1- Estimation Results 7- Table 2-Data Sources 8- Bibliography 3 I-Introduction Introduction to the Euro In 1999, eleven member countries of the European Union abandoned their independent currencies to adopt the Euro and the rigid institutional commitments attached to a currency union.
    [Show full text]
  • Regional Currency Areas: a Few Lessons from the Experiences of the Eurosystem and the CFA Franc Zone
    Regional currency areas: a few lessons from the experiences of the Eurosystem and the CFA franc zone Marc-Olivier Strauss-Kahn1 1. Introduction Contemporaneously with the run-up to European economic and monetary union (EMU) and the successful introduction of the euro, the issue of whether or not to adopt common currency arrangements, from regional currency areas (RCAs) to currency boards and even the unilateral adoption of a foreign currency, has ranked high among the topics discussed by the policymakers of many countries. As suggested recently by Alesina and Barro (2001, 2002), two main factors may have contributed to this renewed and sustained interest in exchange rate arrangements. One may be, rather obviously, the ongoing process of globalisation, which could be briefly characterised as the remarkable and steady increase in international trade in goods, capital and services over the recent period. The other, which is subtler, may be the increased emphasis that has been put by policymakers on price stability, as opposed to active macroeconomic stabilisation, as a primary goal for monetary policy. These changes have led to a general reassessment of the benefits and costs for smaller open economies of constituting an RCA. Although a number of criteria must be fulfilled (such as increased trade integration), the costs of relinquishing monetary policy autonomy at a national level may seem more and more likely to be outweighed by the benefits. The latter include reduction of transaction costs in external trade and increased price stability when anchoring to partner economies with a better inflation track record or a lower long-term inflation rate.
    [Show full text]
  • Prospects for a Monetary Union in the East Africa Community: Some Empirical Evidence
    Department of Economics and Finance Working Paper No. 18-04 , Guglielmo Maria Caporale, Hector Carcel Luis Gil-Alana Prospects for A Monetary Union in the East Africa Community: Some Empirical Evidence May 2018 Economics and Finance Working Paper Series Paper Working Finance and Economics http://www.brunel.ac.uk/economics PROSPECTS FOR A MONETARY UNION IN THE EAST AFRICA COMMUNITY: SOME EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE Guglielmo Maria Caporale Brunel University London Hector Carcel Bank of Lithuania Luis Gil-Alana University of Navarra May 2018 Abstract This paper examines G-PPP and business cycle synchronization in the East Africa Community with the aim of assessing the prospects for a monetary union. The univariate fractional integration analysis shows that the individual series exhibit unit roots and are highly persistent. The fractional bivariate cointegration tests (see Marinucci and Robinson, 2001) suggest that there exist bivariate fractional cointegrating relationships between the exchange rate of the Tanzanian shilling and those of the other EAC countries, and also between the exchange rates of the Rwandan franc, the Burundian franc and the Ugandan shilling. The FCVAR results (see Johansen and Nielsen, 2012) imply the existence of a single cointegrating relationship between the exchange rates of the EAC countries. On the whole, there is evidence in favour of G-PPP. In addition, there appears to be a high degree of business cycle synchronization between these economies. On both grounds, one can argue that a monetary union should be feasible. JEL Classification: C22, C32, F33 Keywords: East Africa Community, monetary union, optimal currency areas, fractional integration and cointegration, business cycle synchronization, Hodrick-Prescott filter Corresponding author: Professor Guglielmo Maria Caporale, Department of Economics and Finance, Brunel University London, Uxbridge, Middlesex UB8 3PH, UK.
    [Show full text]
  • An Optimal East African Monetary Union? Optimum Currency Area Theory and Policy Recommendations for a Sustainable Monetary Union
    Copenhagen Business School Copenhagen, 15 May 2019 An Optimal East African Monetary Union? Optimum Currency Area Theory and Policy Recommendations for a Sustainable Monetary Union submitted by Florian Preis (115684) Dominik Michael Thomas Rappe (115701) supervised by Professor Svend Erik Hougaard Jensen Master’s Thesis, MSc in Advanced Economics and Finance Department of Economics Pages: 119 Characters: 268,346 Acknowledgements Throughout the process of working on this thesis, we have received a great deal of support for which we are truly grateful. First and foremost, we want to thank our supervisor Professor Svend Erik Hougaard Jensen for his patient guidance, readiness to give invaluable advice, and fuelling our interest in the topic. Professor Lisbeth La Cour was able to offer proficient guidance related to the methodology of our econometric models. Her expertise and willingness to help are much appreciated. We want to further extent our sincere gratitude to Dr. Pantaleo Joseph Kessy, who significantly contributed to the relevance of this thesis by sharing insightful resources and perspectives. In addition, we want to thank Dr. Richard Kiplangat Siele for his local judgement and understanding of the topic. We truly enjoyed speaking to our interview partners. Furthermore, we want to thank the reviewers for their thoughtful comments and suggestions. Last but not least, we are grateful for our friends at Copenhagen Business School, who made this Master’s programme a delightful journey. Finally, we would like to thank our families, in particular our parents, for their everlasting support. Copenhagen Business School Copenhagen, May 2019 Florian Preis Dominik Michael Thomas Rappe i Abstract This thesis examines the feasibility of the proposed East African Community Monetary Union.
    [Show full text]
  • Currency Unions and Trade: a Post‐EMU Mea Culpa
    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO WORKING PAPER SERIES Currency Unions and Trade: A Post‐EMU Mea Culpa Reuven Glick Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Andrew K. Rose University of California, Berkeley Haas School of Business July 2015 Working Paper 2015-11 http://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/working-papers/wp2015-11.pdf Suggested citation: Glick, Reuven, Andrew K. Rose. 2015. “Currency Unions and Trade: A Post‐EMU Mea Culpa.” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2015-11. http://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/working-papers/wp2015-11.pdf The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Currency Unions and Trade: A Post‐EMU Mea Culpa Reuven Glick and Andrew K. Rose* Revised Draft: July 17, 2015 Abstract In our European Economic Review (2002) paper, we used pre‐1998 data on countries participating in and leaving currency unions to estimate the effect of currency unions on trade using (then‐) conventional gravity models. In this paper, we use a variety of empirical gravity models to estimate the currency union effect on trade and exports, using recent data which includes the European Economic and Monetary Union (EMU). We have three findings. First, our assumption of symmetry between the effects of entering and leaving a currency union seems reasonable in the data but is uninteresting. Second, EMU typically has a smaller trade effect than other currency unions; it has a mildly stimulating effect at best.
    [Show full text]
  • European Economic and Monetary Integration, and the Optimum Currency Area Theory
    EUROPEAN ECONOMY Economic Papers 302| February 2008 European economic and monetary integration and the optimum currency area theory Francesco Paolo Mongelli EUROPEAN COMMISSION EMU@10 Research In May 2008, it will be ten years since the final decision to move to the third and final stage of Economic and Monetary Union (EMU), and the decision on which countries would be the first to introduce the euro. To mark this anniversary, the Commission is undertaking a strategic review of EMU. This paper constitutes part of the research that was either conducted or financed by the Commission as source material for the review. Economic Papers are written by the Staff of the Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs, or by experts working in association with them. The Papers are intended to increase awareness of the technical work being done by staff and to seek comments and suggestions for further analysis. The views expressed are the author’s alone and do not necessarily correspond to those of the European Commission. Comments and enquiries should be addressed to: European Commission Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs Publications B-1049 Brussels Belgium E-mail: [email protected] This paper exists in English only and can be downloaded from the website http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/publications A great deal of additional information is available on the Internet. It can be accessed through the Europa server (http://europa.eu) ISBN 978-92-79-08227-6 doi: 10.2765/3306 © European Communities, 2008 European Economic and Monetary Integration, and the Optimum Currency Area Theory Francesco Paolo Mongelli (ECB)∗ Abstract: This essay follows the synergies and complementarities between European Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) and the optimum currency area (OCA) theory.
    [Show full text]
  • The Case of the CFA Franc in West Africa
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Koddenbrock, Kai; Sylla, Ndongo Samba Working Paper Towards a political economy of monetary dependency: The case of the CFA franc in West Africa MaxPo Discussion Paper, No. 19/2 Provided in Cooperation with: Max Planck Sciences Po Center on Coping with Instability in Market Societies (MaxPo) Suggested Citation: Koddenbrock, Kai; Sylla, Ndongo Samba (2019) : Towards a political economy of monetary dependency: The case of the CFA franc in West Africa, MaxPo Discussion Paper, No. 19/2, Max Planck Sciences Po Center on Coping with Instability in Market Societies (MaxPo), Paris This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/202323 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence.
    [Show full text]