1 Introduction 2 Bilateral Financial Contracts

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

1 Introduction 2 Bilateral Financial Contracts Notes 1 INTRODUCTION 1. There is already a considerable literature on free banking, with books on the subject by Hayek (1978), L. H. White (1984a, 1989), Selgin (1988), Dowd (1988a, 1989, 1993a), Glasner (1989a), Salsman (1990), Horwitz (1992), and Sechrest (1993). There are also many books that discuss free banking (e.g., Timberlake, 1991, 1993; Cowen and Kroszner, 1994) as well as numerous recent journal articles on it. In addition, there is also a very large earlier literature on the subject (e.g., Wesslau, 1887; Hake and Wesslau, 1890; Meulen, 1934; Smith, 1936; and many others). 2. The use of conjectural history to examine financial and monetary issues has a long pedigree. Menger (1892) made effective use of it, and so did Karl Marx before him. A conjectural history was also used by Meulen (1934), and they have been used more recently by Selgin and White (1987), Selgin (1988a), Dowd (1988b, 1989), Glasner (1989a), Horwitz (1992), Sechrest (1993) and various others. 3. There are many other examples one could choose. Amongst these are medieval Celtic Ireland (Peden, 1977), Viking Iceland (Miller, 1990), and the nineteenth­ century American West (Anderson and Hill, 1979). The reader might also look at Rothbard's (1978) insightful overview of some of these and other historical anarchies. 4. The theory of private legal systems is discussed, among other places, in D. Friedman (1978), Rothbard (1978), the Tannehills (1970) and Wooldridge (1970). As is well-known, Nozick (1974) attacked the viability of free-market law and order by claiming that the anarchy would collapse into an ultra-minimal state, but Nozick's position has itself come under devastating attack from libertarian anarchists whose work suggests that anarchy is indeed stable (e.g., Childs, 1977). I find their arguments very persuasive, but all that matters for my purpose here is that the state keeps 'out of the way'. Readers who have difficulty with libertarian anarchism can therefore assume there is a state if they wish, but only one that adopts a strictly laissezjaire approach towards the financial system. 5. There are of course many specialised financial institutions, as well as 'regular' banks and mutual funds, and some of these specialised institutions (e.g., pension funds and insurance companies) play important roles in the financial system. However, I cannot discuss these institutions here, and can only suggest that readers interested in these institutions look at the relevant specialist literature. 2 BILATERAL FINANCIAL CONTRACTS 1. To the extent that this earlier literature did attempt to explain why particular contract forms are used, it argued that debt was used because of its tax advantages over equity, but there had to be some scope for equity because exclusive reliance on debt would involve excessively high expected bankruptcy costs. However this sort of explanation is very limited: it does not explain why debt was used before it received its modem tax advantages, and debt was issued hundreds of years before income and corporation taxes; it does not explain why debt and equity have the 476 Notes 477 particular features they have; it not explain why there should be bankruptcy costs in the first place; and recent work suggests that it might not be empirically valid anyway (e.g., Mac.IGe-Mason, 1990). We should therefore begin by explaining contract structure in the absence of taxation, and we can always consider taxation at a later stage if we wished to examine its effects (e.g., as in Gertler and Hubbard, 1993). 2. If the constraint that verification is costly is to 'bite', there must be some limit to A's exposure to pecuniary or non-pecuniary penalties, as well as to P' s wealth. If A can expose himself to unlimited penalties, verification costs can be reduced to an arbitrarily low level by making verification stochastic, with a low probability of verification being matched by ferocious penalties if A is found out to be lying. If the penalties and verification costs are suitably chosen, A can be 'trusted' to be telling the truth when he claims that output is low because he has no incentive to lie. The higher the penalty, the lower the required probability of verification, and the lower are verification costs. In the limit verification costs go to zero and the costliness of verification is irrelevant. However, if A's liability is limited, a comparable outcome can also be achieved if P's wealth is unlimited. Instead of imposing ferocious penalties on A if he is verified and found to be lying, P offers him fabulous rewards if he is verified and found to be telling the truth. As the reward rises, the probability of verification required to induce him to tell the truth falls, so verification costs can be reduced to a level arbitrarily close to zero provided that P has sufficient wealth to make his promised rewards credible (see also Guesnerie, 1992, 306-307). 3. These CSV models should not be confused with the superficially similar 'plunder' models of Border and Sobel (1987) and Mookherjee and Png (1989) which arrive at the conclusion that certain forms of non-debt contracts are optimal. These models analyse a fundamentally different problem- the problem faced by brigands and tax collectors in the process of extracting wealth from their unwilling victims - while we are concerned here with situations where people deal with each other by mutual choice. 4. Moral hazard refers to the tendency of insurance to encourage behaviour on the agent's part that produces the event(s) against which the agent is insured. For example, if an agent has fire insurance, he might behave in a way that makes a fire more likely. In this literature, our main focus is the agent's choice of effort, but there can also arise moral hazard over the agent's choice ofproject, where the latter (or strictly speaking, some important feature of it) might be unobservable. This latter type of moral hazard is formally similar to adverse selection, so we shall discuss it in the context of adverse selection in the next sub-section. 5. It is sometimes claimed in the literature that credit rationing can also occur in adverse selection cases where investment projects differ in their degrees of riskiness in ways that the lender cannot observe (e.g., Jaffee and Russell, 1976; Keeton, 1979; Stiglitz and Weiss, 1981). The argument is that higher interest makes marginal profits unworthwhile and, since the borrower's expected profit rises with the riskiness of the project, leads the low-risk projects to be displaced from the pool of investment projects the lender faces. The lender might therefore prefer to keep interest low and ration credit to prevent the expected losses he would face if he raised interest and let the investment pool deteriorate. However, the problem with this line of reasoning is that the optimal contract in these circumstances is actually equity, not debt (see, e.g., Hart, 1986; de Meza and Webb, 1987). The issue of credit rationing does not arise because a loan is a form of debt and there are no loans to ration. 6. The basic idea behind Myers under-investment can be seen through a simple example. Taking all figures to be in net-present-value terms for simplicity, suppose 478 Notes a firm has previously issued debt with a face value of $20 to fund an investment project, and it is now apparent that the project will succeed with probability one­ half and yield a return of $20 that enables the firm Gust) to pay its debt, and that it will fail with probability one-half and yield a return of nothing. (Note, therefore, that the value of the firm to its shareholders is zero.) If the firm has no assets, the expected value of the firm's debt is $10 and the creditors have suffered an expected loss of $10 also. Now suppose that an additional investment opportunity becomes available that requires an input of $10 from the shareholders but yields a return of $15. The new investment is clearly socially worthwhile because it converts $10 into $15, but shareholders will still refuse to fund it because too many of the gains go to existing creditors. If they proceed with it, the total expected shareholder return will consist of $15 (i.e., the return on the new project) plus one-half times $20 (i.e., the expected return on the old project) minus $20 (i.e., the full repayment of the old $10 debt, plus the additional $10 required from the shareholders), or $5. The shareholders therefore expect to lose $5 on the additional investment. The creditors however get repaid their full $20, instead of their currently expected payment of $10, and make an expected gain of $10. The shareholders thus pass up a socially worthwhile investment opportunity, because too many of the expected gains go to debtholders. 7. The legal system therefore has a relatively straightforward task: to ensure that contracts are honoured, period. By contrast, contemporary bankruptcy law often forces courts have to make all sorts of 'judgmental' [sic] decisions: judges have to assess what course of action would be in the best interests of the different parties, how much to 'trust' management that claims it can reorganise a firm successfully, and so on. The need to make such decisions imposes severe burdens on those who have to make them, creates incentives for interested parties to invest resources trying to influence those 'judgmental' decisions, and the process involved can be very time-consuming (especially, for example, if a dissatisfied party appeals a decision). The legal procedure suggested here is far more efficient: the court merely needs to establish facts and then pass a more or less automatic (and presumably reasonably rapid) judgement.
Recommended publications
  • Did Monetary Forces Cause the Great Depresstion? by Peter Temin
    BOOK REVIEWS Did Monetary Forces Cause the Great Depression? A Review Essay by Arthur E. Gandolfi and James R. Lothian* Did Monetary Forces Cause the Great Depression?, by Peter Temin. New York: W. W. Norton, 1976 vi +201 pp. $8.95 (cloth); $3.95 (paper). "Given the magnitude and importance of this event [the Great Depression], it is surprising," states Peter Temin, "how little we know about its causes" (pp. xi, xii). In particular, he says, we have no explanation of why the Depression became so severe. Temin reviews the two major competing explanations, which he calls the "money hypothesis" and the "spending hypothesis." Temin associates the money hypothesis almost exclusively with the account Friedman and Schwartz give in [5, chap. 7]. In their view, it was the banking panics of the 1930s and the subsequent failure of the Federal Reserve to counteract the contractionary monetary effects of those episodes that accounted for the depth and duration of the Depression. The spending hypothesis is the term Temin gives to the explanations advanced by economists working within the Keynesian income- expenditure tradition, who emphasized decreases in various forms of autonomous expenditures as the cause of the Depression. Temin finds both the money and con- ventional spending explanations wanting and goes on to develop one of his own. It is a variant of the spending hypothesis that identifies an autonomous shift of the consumption function as the crucial factor. What's wrong with Friedman and Schwartz's explanation, according to Temin, is that it assumes what should have been tested—the direction of causation between money and income.
    [Show full text]
  • Investment Strategy
    Equity Research MAY 2006 Investment Strategy Approaching an Inflection Point in the Bubble Cycle THERE ARE A NUMBER OF COMMON MISCONCEPTIONS REGARDING ASSET BUBBLES. Bubbles are serial in nature and are often broad events. Contrary to popular belief, neither the bond market nor energy stocks is currently experiencing a bubble episode. Yet, in our opinion, one market that is in a bubble is real estate! THE UNWINDING OF THE REAL ESTATE BUBBLE COULD BROADLY IMPACT FINANCIAL MARKETS FOR YEARS TO COME. The speed with which the housing bubble deflates will have important implications for household spending and could determine how quickly and strongly the Fed increases liquidity again. THE END OF ONE BUBBLE OFTEN TRIGGERS THE BEGINNING OF ANOTHER. A bubble-induced economic slowdown oftentimes leads the Fed to once again inject liquidity into the economy. This phenomenon typically acts as a trigger that paves the way for the beginning of a new asset bubble. AREAS WORTH CONSIDERING AS POTENTIAL FUTURE OPPORTUNITIES ARE ALTERNATIVE FUELS, NANOTECH, AND HEALTH CARE. These are just a few potential areas that could see continued interest generated. While any of these could end up as a disappointment, a significant technological breakthrough at a time when the bubble environment is fertile could be quite profitable. Research Analysts François Trahan Kurt D. Walters Caroline S. Portny (212) 272-2103 (212) 272-2498 (212) 272-5236 [email protected] [email protected] [email protected] Bear Stearns does and seeks to do business with companies covered in its research reports. As a result, investors should be aware that the Firm may have a conflict of interest that could affect the objectivity of this report.
    [Show full text]
  • France À Fric: the CFA Zone in Africa and Neocolonialism
    France à fric: the CFA zone in Africa and neocolonialism Ian Taylor Date of deposit 18 04 2019 Document version Author’s accepted manuscript Access rights Copyright © Global South Ltd. This work is made available online in accordance with the publisher’s policies. This is the author created, accepted version manuscript following peer review and may differ slightly from the final published version. Citation for Taylor, I. C. (2019). France à fric: the CFA Zone in Africa and published version neocolonialism. Third World Quarterly, Latest Articles. Link to published https://doi.org/10.1080/01436597.2019.1585183 version Full metadata for this item is available in St Andrews Research Repository at: https://research-repository.st-andrews.ac.uk/ FRANCE À FRIC: THE CFA ZONE IN AFRICA AND NEOCOLONIALISM Over fifty years after 1960’s “Year of Africa,” most of Francophone Africa continues to be embedded in a set of associations that fit very well with Kwame Nkrumah’s description of neocolonialism, where postcolonial states are de jure independent but in reality constrained through their economic systems so that policy is directed from outside. This article scrutinizes the functioning of the CFA, considering the role the currency has in persistent underdevelopment in most of Francophone Africa. In doing so, the article identifies the CFA as the most blatant example of functioning neocolonialism in Africa today and a critical device that promotes dependency in large parts of the continent. Mainstream analyses of the technical aspects of the CFA have generally focused on the exchange rate and other related matters. However, while important, the real importance of the CFA franc should not be seen as purely economic, but also political.
    [Show full text]
  • US Monetary Policy 1914-1951
    Volatile Times and Persistent Conceptual Errors: U.S. Monetary Policy 1914-1951 Charles W. Calomiris * November 2010 Abstract This paper describes the motives that gave rise to the creation of the Federal Reserve System , summarizes the history of Fed monetary policy from its origins in 1914 through the Treasury-Fed Accord of 1951, and reviews several of the principal controversies that surround that history. The persistence of conceptual errors in Fed monetary policy – particularly adherence to the “real bills doctrine” – is a central puzzle in monetary history, particularly in light of the enormous costs of Fed failures during the Great Depression. The institutional, structural, and economic volatility of the period 1914-1951 probably contributed to the slow learning process of policy. Ironically, the Fed's great success – in managing seasonal volatility of interest rates by limiting seasonal liquidity risk – likely contributed to its slow learning about cyclical policy. Keywords: monetary policy, Great Depression, real bills doctrine, bank panics JEL: E58, N12, N22 * This paper was presented November 3, 2010 at a conference sponsored by the Atlanta Fed at Jekyll Island, Georgia. It will appear in a 100th anniversary volume devoted to the history of the Federal Reserve System. I thank my discussant, Allan Meltzer, and Michael Bordo and David Wheelock, for helpful comments on earlier drafts. 0 “If stupidity got us into this mess, then why can’t it get us out?” – Will Rogers1 I. Introduction This chapter reviews the history of the early (1914-1951) period of “monetary policy” under the Federal Reserve System (FRS), defined as policies designed to control the overall supply of liquidity in the financial system, as distinct from lender-of-last-resort policies directed toward the liquidity needs of particular financial institutions (which is treated by Bordo and Wheelock 2010 in another chapter of this volume).
    [Show full text]
  • The History of Banks in France
    The history of banks in France Alain Plessis Some forms of progress long hindered In the Middle Ages and at the beginning of modern times, banking activities in France experienced a belated and more difficult development than in neighbouring countries such as Italy, the Netherlands or the United Provinces. The overwhelmingly precarious agriculture and a very limited participation on the international exchange scene, the dominant influence of the catholic church as well as the priests' sermons, long denouncing the practice of loaning at interest, and a very hostile mentality towards anything that resembled usury rendered all big merchants suspect and hindered the free development of their activities. Nevertheless the expansion of trade - which first began in the twelfth and thirteenth centuries through the activities of the fairs in Champagne and then through the dynamism of the commercial markets such as the large royal ports or the city of Lyons - as well as the financial needs of the royal government, all made the use of banking practices more and more indispensable. Banking methods, generally invented in Italy, arrived in France: manual exchange transactions and the use of bills of exchange for transferring funds, as well as the credit operations which developed in connection with those operations, deposits, credit transfers and various investment. The bankers in these professions, who sometimes grew quite rich, were primarily foreigners who lived cut off from the national community, especially Italians and Jews. These Italians were called Lombards; in Paris, already a banking city, the moneychangers from Piedmont set themselves up in a street which has since then been called rue des Lombards.
    [Show full text]
  • THE ABRAHAM L. POMERANTZ LECTURE: Don't Blink: Snap Decisions and Securities Regulation, 77 Brook
    Brooklyn Law Review Volume 77 | Issue 1 Article 4 2011 THE ABRAHAM L. POMERANTZ EL CTURE: Don't Blink: Snap Decisions and Securities Regulation Frank Partnoy Follow this and additional works at: https://brooklynworks.brooklaw.edu/blr Recommended Citation Frank Partnoy, THE ABRAHAM L. POMERANTZ LECTURE: Don't Blink: Snap Decisions and Securities Regulation, 77 Brook. L. Rev. (2011). Available at: https://brooklynworks.brooklaw.edu/blr/vol77/iss1/4 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law Journals at BrooklynWorks. It has been accepted for inclusion in Brooklyn Law Review by an authorized editor of BrooklynWorks. THE ABRAHAM L. POMERANTZ LECTURE Don’t Blink SNAP DECISIONS AND SECURITIES REGULATION Frank Partnoy† Modern securities markets move at record speed. Trading decisions are faster than ever. Average investors can immediately acquire information. Rapid technologies have benefits, particularly reduced costs. But fast-moving markets can also be dangerous. Few people had time to think carefully during the financial crisis of 2008 or the “flash crash” of May 6, 2010, when stocks plunged 5-6 percent in minutes and then rebounded almost as quickly. This article explores the consequences of this speed for securities markets. It addresses the extent to which securities regulation should take into account the pace of decision making. It discusses recent scholarly research on snap decisions and suggests legal reforms, some designed to harness the power of quick decisions and others directed at their dangers. It proposes that regulators slow down the markets with proposals ranging from the improbably difficult (steps to respond more deliberately to crises) to the improbably simple (adding a lunch break to the trading day).
    [Show full text]
  • A Study in Comparative Economic History
    PRINCETON STUDIES IN INTERNATIONAL FINANCE NO. 36 The Formation of Financial Centers: A Study in Comparative Economic History Charles P. Kindlebergei INTERNATIONAL FINANCE SECTION DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS PRINCETON UNIVERSITY • 1974 PRINCETON STUDIES IN INTERNATIONAL FINANCE This is the thirty-sixth number in the series PRINCETON STUDIES IN INTERNATIONAL FINANCE, published from time to time by the Inter- national Finance Section of the Department of Economics at Princeton University. The author, Charles P. Kindleberger, is Ford Professor of Economics at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. His work in economic history includes The World in Depression, 1929-1939 (1973) and Eco- nomic Growth in France and Britain, 1851-1950 (1964). He is the author of two Essays in International Finance, The Politics of Inter- national Money and World Language (No. 61, 1967) and Balance- of-Payments Deficits and the International Market for Liquidity (No. 46, 1965). This series is intended to be restricted to meritorious research stud- ies in the general field of international financial problems which are too technical, too specialized, or too long to qualify as ESSAYS. The Sec- tion welcomes the submission of manuscripts for this series. While the Section sponsors the studies, the writers are free to de- velop their topics as they will. Their ideas and treatment may.or may not be shared by the editorial committee of the Section or the mem- bers of the Department. PETER B. KENEN Director Princeton University PRINCETON STUDIES IN INTERNATIONAL FINANCE NO. 36 The Formation of Financial Centers: A Study in Comparative Economic History Charles P. Kindleberger INTERNATIONAL FINANCE SECTION DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRINCETON, NEW JERSEY November 1974 Copyright 0 1974, by International Finance Section Department of Economics, Princeton University Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication Data Kindleberger, Charles Poor, 1910- The formation of financial centers.
    [Show full text]
  • Karlova Univerzita V Praze
    CHARLES UNIVERSITY IN PRAGUE FACULTY OF SOCIAL SCIENCES Institute of Economic Studies Petra Strnadová The banking crisis 1929-1933 Bachelor thesis Prague 2016 Author: Petra Strnadová Supervisor: PhDr. Jaromír Baxa, Ph.D. Academic Year: 2015/2016 Bibliographic note STRNADOVÁ, Petra. The banking crisis 1929-1933. Prague, 2016. Bachelor thesis. Charles University in Prague, Faculty of Social Sciences. Institute of Economic Studies. Supervisor PhDr. Jaromír Baxa, Ph.D. Abstract The issue of banking crises is of a significant importance due to their impact on the economic situation and having revealed the main causes of a bank distress, it should be possible to avoid some of them in the future by taking appropriate measures. The banking crisis during the Great Depression belongs to the biggest crises in the history and provides a great opportunity to properly examine the behaviour of U.S. banks. Therefore, the aim of my thesis is to identify the key moments of the banking crisis, analyse the adopted policies and regulations, reveal the main causes of bank suspensions and to examine the bank balance sheets to state which type of bank was the most resilient. The results implied that the crucial event was a fall of a large investment bank in 1930 that initiated the wave of banking panic when banks started fighting against both illiquidity and insolvency problems. The analysis showed that mutual saving banks were the most successful and that the trust of the public together with insufficient deposit insurance are key factors influencing the bank runs. However, the major drawback is considered to be the excessive risk banks were facing even before the stock market crash.
    [Show full text]
  • Annual Report and Accounts 2009
    HSBC France Annual Report and Accounts 2009 www.hsbc.fr The HSBC Group CCF joined the HSBC Group in July 2000 and changed its legal name to HSBC France on 1 November 2005. Headquartered in London, HSBC is one of the largest banking and financial services organisations in the world. Its international network comprises around 8,000 offices in 88 countries and territories in Europe, the Asia-Pacific region, the Americas, the Middle East and Africa. With listings on the London, Hong Kong, New York, Paris and Bermuda stock exchanges, shares in HSBC Holdings plc are held by over 220,000 shareholders in 121 countries and territories. HSBC provides a comprehensive range of financial services and serves around 100 million customers through two customer groups: Personal Financial Services and Commercial Banking; and two global businesses: Global Banking and Markets, and Private Banking. In 2009, HSBC’s profit before tax was USD 7,079 million and USD 13.3 billion on an underlying basis and excluding goodwill impairment. Profit attributable to shareholders of the parent company was USD 5,834 million. Total assets were USD 2,364 billion at 31 December 2009. Geographical distribution of results – Profit before tax: Year ended 31 December 2009 USDm % Europe 4,009 56.7 Hong Kong 5,029 71.0 Rest of Asia-Pacific 4,200 59.3 Middle East 455 6.4 North America (7,738) (109.3) Latin America 1,124 15.9 Profit before tax 7,079 100.0 This Reference Document was registered with the Autorité des Marchés Financiers on 29 April 2010 in accordance with Article 212-13 of the AMF General Regulation.
    [Show full text]
  • REGISTRATION DOCUMENT and FULL-YEAR FINANCIAL REPORT Contents
    2014 REGISTRATION DOCUMENT AND FULL-YEAR FINANCIAL REPORT Contents FINANCIAL REPORT 213 5 5.1 IFRS Consolidated Financial Statements of Groupe BPCE as at December 31, 2014 214 PRESENTATION OF GROUPE BPCE 3 5.2 Statutory Auditors’ report on the consolidated fi nancial statements 318 1 1.1 Presentation of Groupe BPCE 4 5.3 IFRS Consolidated Financial Statements 1.2 History of the Group 5 of BPCE SA group as at December 31, 2014 320 1.3 Organization of Groupe BPCE 6 5.4 Statutory Auditors’ report on the consolidated 1.4 Key fi gures 2014 9 fi nancial statements 400 1.5 Contacts 11 5.5 BPCE parent company fi nancial statements 402 1.6 Calendar 11 5.6 Statutory Auditors’ report on the fi nancial statements 447 1.7 2014-2017 strategic plan: “Growing Differently” 12 1.8 Groupe BPCE’s Businesses 15 SOCIAL, ENVIRONMENTAL 6 AND SOCIETAL INFORMATION 449 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 29 6.1 Sustainable development strategy and cooperative identity 450 2 2.1 Introduction 30 6.2 Response to economic challenges 456 2.2 Management and Supervisory Bodies 32 6.3 Human resources information 463 2.3 Role and operating rules of governing bodies 65 6.4 Response to environmental challenges 474 2.4 Rules and principles governing the determination of pay and benefi ts 72 6.5 Response to societal challenges 482 2.5 Potential confl icts of interest 84 6.6 CSR reporting methodology 491 2.6 Chairman’s report on internal control and risk 6.7 Report by one of the Statutory Auditors, management procedures for the year ended a designated independent third-party body, on the December
    [Show full text]
  • Government Banking
    Government Banking Government Banking New Perspectives on Sustainable Development and Social Inclusion From Europe and South America Kurt von Mettenheim & Maria Antonieta Del Tedesco Lins © KONRAD ADENAUER FOUNDATION – 2008 EDITORS Kurt von Mettenheim Maria Antonieta Del Tedesco Lins LAYOUT AND DIAGRAMATION Caio Fábio Machado COVER DeSIGN Patrícia Azevedo PRESS Editora Vozes X000 Government Banking : New Perspectives on Sustainable Development and Social Inclusion From Europe and South America / Kurt von Mettenheim & Maria Antonieta Del Tedesco Lins, [editors]. - Rio de Janeiro and Berlin : Konrad Adenauer Foundtion , 2008. 232 p. ; 24 cm. ISBN – 978-85-7504-122-8 1. Government banking. 2. Political economy. 3. Social economy. 4. Microcredit. I. Mettenheim, Kurt von & Lins, Maria Antonieta Del Tedesco. II. Konrad-Adenauer-Stiftung. CDD- 303.4 Table of Contents Introduction, Kurt von Mettenheim 7 Part I – Government Banking in Europe 39 Chapter 1 Community Banking Networks and Financial Exclusion:How Savings Banks and Cooperative Banks Contribute to Financial Inclusion in Germany, Anke Turner and Ingrid Größl 41 Chapter 2 Commitment to Corporate Social Responsibility through Supportive Actions in the Banking Industry, Jean-Yves Saulquin 65 Chapter 3 European savings banks and the future of public banking in advanced economies. The cases of France, Germany, Italy and Spain, Olivier Butzbach 85 Part II – Government Banking in Latin America 127 Chapter 4 From Development Banking to Microfinance: Reflections on the Recent History of Banking
    [Show full text]
  • Débats Économiques Et Financiers N°37
    Débats économiques et financiers N°37 The Real Effects of Bank Runs. Evidence from the French Great Depression (1930-1931) Eric Monnet*, Angelo Riva† and Stefano Ungaro‡ *EHESS, Paris School of Economics and CEPR , [email protected] †European Business School Paris and Paris School of Economics, [email protected] ‡Autorité de Contrôle Prudentiel et de Résolution – Banque de France, [email protected] SECRÉTARIAT GENERAL DE L’AUTORITÉ DE CONTRÔLE PRUDENTIEL ET DE RÉSOLUTION DIRECTION D’ÉTUDE ET D’ANALYSE DES RISQUES LES EFFETS REELS DES RUEES BANCAIRES : L’EXEMPLE DE LA GRANDE DEPRESSION EN FRANCE (1930-1931)4 Eric Monnet, Angelo Riva et Stefano Ungaro Mai 2021 Les points de vue exprimés dans ces Débats Économiques et Financiers n’engagent que leurs auteurs et n’expriment pas nécessairement la position de l’Autorité de Contrôle Prudentiel et de Résolution. Ce document est disponible sur le site de l’Autorité de Contrôle Prudentiel et de Résolution : acpr.banque-france.fr The opinions expressed in the Economic and Financial Discussion Notes do not necessarily reflect views of the Autorité de Contrôle Prudentiel et de Résolution. This document is available on acpr.banque- france.fr 4This research has benefited from research funds granted by the Agence Nationale de la Recherche. Grant Number: ANR‐15‐CE26‐0008 & ANR-17-EURE-0001. We thank Sofiane Bouarif, Victor Degorce, Hadrien Clausse, Emilie Bonhoure, João Castello Branco for excellent research assistance, as well as Pierre-Cyrille Hautcoeur, Germán Forero Laverde, Thomas Breda, Patrice Baubeau, Kris Mitchener, Victor Degorce, Gary Gorton, Eugene White, Jean-Bernard Chatelain, Fabio Braggion, Francesco Manaresi, Guillaume Vuillemey, Paul Dutronc-Postel, and participants at the Financial History Workshop at Goethe University, Paris School of Economics, Sorbonne Alliance Finance Seminar, Institute of Economics of Sant'Anna School of Advanced Studies Seminar, and the Economic History Association 2020 Conference for helpful discussions.
    [Show full text]