Formation of the Economic Thought of Karl Marx 1843 to Capital

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Formation of the Economic Thought of Karl Marx 1843 to Capital Ernest Mandel The Formation of the Economic Thought of Karl Marx 1843 to Capital Translated by Brian Pearce 1971 [1967] Contents 1. From the Critique of Private Property to the Critique of Capitalism 9 2. From Condemning Capitalism to Providing a Socioeconomic Vindication of Communism 27 3. From Rejection to Acceptance of the Labor Theory of Value 40 4. A First General Analysis of the Capitalist Mode of Production 52 5. The Problem of Periodic Crises 67 6. Perfecting the Theory of Value, the Theory of Surplus Value, and the Theory of Money 79 7. The Grundrisse, or the Dialectics of Labor Time and Free Time 100 8. The Asiatic Mode of Production and the Historical Pre-Conditions for the Rise of Capital 116 9. The Final Shaping of the Theory of Wages 140 10. From the Economic and Philosophic Manuscripts to the Grundrisse: From an Anthropological to a Historical Conception of Alienation 154 11. Progressive Disalienation Through the Building of Socialist Society, or Inevitable Alienation in Industrial Society? 187 Bibliography 211 7 I From the Critique of Private Property to the Critique of Capitalism Marx and Engels did not travel the same route to arrive at the ideas they came to share. “They had in common the same philo­ sophical starting point, namely, Hegel’s dialectics, [Bruno] Bauer’s ‘self-consciousness,’ and Feuerbach’s humanism; they then made the acquaintance of British and French socialism, but whereas this became for Marx the means whereby he ordered his thoughts regarding the struggles and aspirations of his epoch, for Engels the same role was played by British industry.” 1 This difference resulted, no doubt, from differences in charac­ ter and temperament—the more speculative nature of Marx’s genius, the greater impetuousness of Engels’. Chance and material circumstances also played a part, however. While Marx emigrated from Germany to France, Engels was sent to England to learn the conduct of business affairs, and there came into contact with the reality of large-scale capitalist industry. It was the shock of this encounter with the contradictions of bourgeois society that was to decide the course of his thinking for the rest of his life.1 2 1. Franz Mehring, in Aus dem literarischen Nachlass von Karl Marx und Friedrich Engels, 1841-1850, Vol. I, p. 359. 2. “While in Manchester, it was tangibly brought home to me that the economic facts, which have so far played no role or only a contemptible one in the writing of history, are, at least in the modern world, a decisive historical force; that they form the basis for the origin of the present-day class antagonism; that these class antagonisms, in the countries where they have become fully developed, thanks to large-scale industry, hence espe­ cially in England, are in their turn the basis of the formation of political parties and of party struggles, and thus of all political history.” (Frederick 9 10 The Formation of the Economic Thought of Karl Marx If Marx developed almost unaided the entire economic “panel” of Marxist theory, it is to Engels that the credit is due for having been the first to urge Marx to take up the study of political econ­ omy and for having grasped, in a “brilliant sketch,” the central importance of this science for communism.3 This “sketch,” writ­ ten at the end of 1843, was the first economic work by either of the two friends; Ryazanov correctly ascribes it a “very great im­ portance in the history of the development [of the beginnings] of Marxism.” 4 It must be emphasized that it was also Engels who, though two years Marx’s junior, was the first to declare himself openly a communist and to regard as necessary and inevitable a radical revolution which would abolish private property. As early as the end of 1842, when he was only just twenty-two, Engels ended an article on the Prussian monarchy by predicting a bourgeois revolution, and began an article on Britain by an­ nouncing the approach of a social revolution.5 At that same time, in an article published in the Rheinische Xeitung (“Der Kom- munismus und die Augsburger Allgemeine Zeitung”), Marx was still rejecting communism, while stressing the need to study it thoroughly in order to be able to criticize it adequately.6 Nev­ ertheless, the two founders of scientific socialism were already attacking the problem from the same angle: by criticizing the neo-Hegelian conception of the state, by discovering the exist­ ence of social classes, and by analyzing the inhuman effects of private property and competition. We are able in both cases to follow the trajectory of their thinking from point to point: from criticism of religion to criti­ cism of philosophy; from criticism of philosophy to criticism of Engels, On the History of the Communist League, in Karl Marx and Fred­ erick Engels, Selected Works, Vol. Ill, pp. 173-190. The piece was written as an introduction to the 1885 German edition of Marx’s pamphlet Reve­ lations About the Cologne Communist Trial.) 3. Marx expresses this opinion of the Outlines of a Critique of Political Economy in his Preface to A Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy. (Selected Works, Vol. I, p. 504.) 4. Marx and Engels, Historisch-kritische Gesamtausgabe (MEGA), I, 2, pp. lxxii and lxxiii. 5. Ibid., I, 2, pp. 346 and 351. 6. Ibid., I, 1, 1, p. 263. From Private Property to Capitalism 11 the state; from criticism of the state to criticism of society—that is, from criticism of politics to criticism of political economy, which led to criticism of private property. With Marx, however, the purely theoretical aspect was to re­ main predominant throughout this period, and the evolution of his thought was to result in the Introduction to the Critique of the Hegelian Philosophy of Right (end of 1843 and beginning of 1844). With Engels it was the practical aspect, the criticism of British bourgeois society, that took the ascendancy, both in the Outlines of a Critique of Political Economy and in Die Lage Englands (The Condition of England), which appeared in the journal Deutsch-Franzosische Jahrbûcher ^t the same time as Marx’s well-known critique. It is generally accepted that Marx took little interest in politi­ cal economy during his university studies. The list that has come down to us of the books he studied while at Berlin university does not include a single one devoted to this subject.7 In a letter of September 28, 1892, to Franz Mehring, Engels, discussing Marx’s years at the universities of Bonn and Berlin, writes: “He knew nothing whatever about political economy. ...” 8 Nevertheless, Pierre Naville is right in seeking to mitigate the excessively hard-and-fast character of this view. In fact, Hegel himself had been profoundly affected in his youth by economic studies, in particular by the work of Adam Smith;9 Marx saw 7. D. I. Rosenberg, Die Entwicklung der ôkonomischen Lehre von Marx und Engels in den Vierziger Jahr en des 19. Jahrhunderts, p. 35. 8. Marx and Engels, Ausgevoahlte Briefe, p. 541. 9. It was Plekhanov who first emphasized the importance of Hegel as a precursor of historical materialism, by his according to economic develop­ ment a central place in the explanation of what is specific in each nation or civilization. The relevant articles by Plekhanov appeared in 1891 in Die Neue 2,eit and were reprinted in La Revue Internationale, No. 22, April- June 1950. In his masterly work, Der funge Hegel, Georg Lukacs studied in detail the economic ideas of the young Hegel. In particular, he showed the cen­ tral position occupied by labor in Hegelian anthropology. Hegel wrote in 1803-1804: “The greater the extent to which labor is carried on with the help of machinery, the less is its value, and the longer it has to be carried on in this way.” This sentence constitutes a brilliant anticipation of what Marx and Engels were to write forty years later. (Georg Lukacs, Der junge 12 The Formation of the Economic Thought of Karl Marx the Hegelian system as a veritable philosophy of labor. “When he read the Phenomenology of Mind, the Philosophy of Right, and even the Science of Logic, Marx thus not only discovered Hegel but already, through him, was aware of that part of clas­ sical political economy which was assimilated and translated into philosophical terms in Hegel’s work; so that Marx would not have gone about his systematic criticism of civil society and the state according to Hegel if he had not already found in the lat­ ter’s writings certain elements which were still live, such as the theory of needs, the theory of appropriation, or the analysis of the division of labor.” 10 11 Marx had already moved from philosophy to politics, the first step in his intellectual development, when he became editor of the Rheinische Zeitung in 1842. His fundamental position con­ tinued to be one of struggle for a “human” state; he still took his stand on “human rights” in general, on the struggle against feudal survivals. Like Hegel, he considered that the state should be “the realization of freedom.” 11 But even at this stage he had discov­ ered a contradiction between this ideal notion of the state and the fact that the Stànde (estates) represented in the provincial diet of the Rhineland strove to “drag the state down to the level of the idea of private interest.” In other words, as soon as he tackled a current political problem—namely, the new law on theft of wood—he came up against the problem of social classes.
Recommended publications
  • A History of Economic Thought Isaac Ilych Rubin
    H. H. P y B M H A History of Economic Thought MCTOPMJI. by 3K0H0MMHECK0R Isaac Ilych Rubin MblC/IM Translated and edited by Donald Filtzei K30AHHE TPETbS co Bioporo aono^HEHHoro Poc/dapimatHHQio Ytewto Coatma Afterword tonyu&HO 4 xanetmu jr*t6noto MCOOUM 9M tyso* by Catherine Colliot-Thelene LINKS rOCyflAPCTBEHHOE H3^ATE^bCTBO MOCKBA * 1 9 2 9 * /lEHHHfPAJl Isaac Ilych Rubin was born in Russia in 1886 In 1905 he became an active participant in the 75 Russian revolutionary movement After the Bolshevik seizure of power he worked as a .^7/3 professor of Marxist economics and in 1926 became research associate at the Marx-Engels Institute In 1930 he was airested. An official Soviet philosopher wrote that: 'The followers First published as htoriya ekonomicheskoi of Rubin and. the Menshevizing Idealists. mydi (Gosizdat RSFSR) This translation treated Marx's revolutionary method in the taken, with the permission of the New York spirit.,, of Hegelianism The Communist Public Library, from a copy of the second Party has smashed these trends alien to Marx- printing of the second, revised Russian edition ism'. (Rosenthal, quoted by Rornan Rozdolsky (1929) in that library's possession in The Making of Marx's Capital?) Rubin was Ihis edition first published in 1979 by imprisoned, accused of belonging to an organi- Ink Links Ltd., zation that never existed, forced to 'confess' to 271, Kentish Town Road participating in events that never took place, London NW5 2JS and finally removed from among the living Between 1924 and 1930 Rubin completed Translation
    [Show full text]
  • Thomas Hodgskin and Economic Progress; a Radical Reconstruction of His Endogenous Growth Theory
    THOMAS HODGSKIN AND ECONOMIC PROGRESS; A RADICAL RECONSTRUCTION OF HIS ENDOGENOUS GROWTH THEORY F.G. Day PhD 2009 THOMAS HODGSKIN AND ECONOMIC PROGRESS; A RADICAL RECONSTRUCTION OF HIS ENDOGENOUS GROWTH THEORY Frederick George Day A thesis submitted in fulfilment of the requirements of the Manchester Metropolitan University for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy Department of Economics The Manchester Metropolitan University June 2009 1 Declaration I confirm that no part of this thesis has been submitted for the award of a qualification at this or any other university. 2 Abstract By means of a close reading of early 19th century economic works, and by reconstructing aspects of Thomas Hodgskin‘s political economy, this thesis presents an exposition of those parts of his work that contributed to his position on growth. Rather than concentrating on his ideas on capital, we have centred on his concept of political economy as a science concerned with labour as the sole creator of wealth. We present his political economy as having labour as its focal point within a hypothetical pure market economy. From here he sought a foundation to economic growth derived from human action rather than capital or other material circumstances. Hodgskin saw human knowledge and the use of technology as the starting point that would, from his perspective, lead inevitably to those economic conditions that produce improvements in economic welfare and by doing so allow for an increase in population. In order to demonstrate his ideas on growth, we reconstruct his concepts of what was natural and artificial to equate to the modern notions of endogenous and exogenous.
    [Show full text]
  • 1. the Damnation of Economics
    Notes 1. The Damnation of Economics 1. One example of vice-regal patronage of anti-economics is Canada’s ‘Governor General’s Award for Non-Fiction’. In 1995 this honour was bestowed upon John Raulston Saul’s anti-economic polemic The Unconscious Civilization (published in 1996). A taste of Saul’s wisdom: ‘Over the last quarter-century economics has raised itself to the level of a scientific profession and more or less foisted a Nobel Prize in its own honour onto the Nobel committee thanks to annual financing from a bank. Yet over the same 25 years, economics has been spectacularly unsuc- cessful in its attempts to apply its models and theories to the reality of our civili- sation’ (Saul 1996, p. 4). See Pusey (1991) and Cox (1995) for examples of patronage of anti-economics by Research Councils and Broadcasting Corporations. 2. Another example of economists’ ‘stillness’: the economists of 1860 did not join the numerous editorial rebukes of Ruskin’s anti-economics tracts (Anthony, 1983). 3. The anti-economist is not to be contrasted with the economist. An economist (that is, a person with a specialist knowledge of economics) may be an anti- economist. The true obverse of anti-economist is ‘philo-economist’: someone who holds that economics is a boon. 4. One may think of economics as a disease (as the anti-economist does), or one may think of economics as diseased. Mark Blaug: ‘Modern economics is “sick” . To para- phrase the title of a popular British musical: “No Reality, Please. We’re Economists”’ (Blaug 1998, p.
    [Show full text]
  • Karl Marx and the Marxist School
    See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.net/publication/321255666 Karl Marx and the Marxist School Working Paper · November 2017 DOI: 10.13140/RG.2.2.27320.03847 CITATIONS READS 0 15,446 1 author: Scott Carter University of Tulsa 19 PUBLICATIONS 59 CITATIONS SEE PROFILE Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects: From Pool of Profits to Surplus and Deficit Industries View project All content following this page was uploaded by Scott Carter on 23 November 2017. The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file. 1 Karl Marx and the Marxist School Scott Carter, The University of Tulsa ([email protected])1 • Marx was a working class revolutionary thinker whose economic theories were designed for a mass working class audience • Marx’s economic thought developed as a sustained critique of Classical Political Economy and addressed many of the short-comings in the labor theory of value of that approach • Marx’s method of historical materialism considers social formations as evolving and developing from earlier forms often through revolutionary struggle • Marx’s contribution to the Classical labor theory of value includes the notion of the value of labor power and theory of surplus-value defined as the exploitation of the unpaid labor of workers • Marx’s theory of surplus value expresses itself in an understanding of the division of the working-day into necessary and surplus labor time which serves as the foundation upon which his economic theories are built • Marx’s economic theories are rich and includes among other things theories of accumulation, circuits of revenue and capital, schemes of social reproduction, crisis theory and the falling rate of profit, the reserve army of labor, and the transformation of values into prices of production 0.
    [Show full text]
  • SHORTCUT to SERFDOM a Reader’S Guide
    SHORTCUT TO SERFDOM A Reader’s Guide BRITTANY HUNTER Shortcut to Serfdom A Reader’s Guide Essays from the Foundation for Economic Education Contents Introduction 5 1. The Individual Built the Modern World 6 2. You’re All a Bunch of Collectivists 9 3. If You Give the State an Inch, It Will Take a Mile 12 4. Technology Is Not Pro-Monopoly 16 5. Hayek Warned Us About Obamacare 20 6. Why the Rule of Law Matters, Even If It Doesn’t 25 Exist 7. Venezuela Proves There Is No Political Freedom 29 Without Economic Freedom 8. There Is No Such Thing As Equality, and Thank 35 Goodness 9. What Hayek Gets Wrong About a Universal Basic 40 Income 10. Why the Worst Humans Are Able to Rise to 46 Power 11. Education Is the State’s Greatest Tool for 51 Propaganda 12. Socialist Academics Contributed to the Rise of the 55 Third Reich 13. England Inches Down the Road to Serfdom 62 14. Hayek Was Right, Welfare Is False Philanthropy 68 15. The International Road to Serfdom 74 16. The Road to Serfdom: What Is Past Is Prologue 81 Introduction efore October 2017, I had never actually completed F.A. Hayek’s, The Road to Serfdom. I am completely comfortable admitting that. Still, like many who are intrigued with Hayek’s ideas but Black the willpower to read the entire book, I alway list The Road to Serfdom as one of my most influential readings. To be sure, I had read the few chapters that were assigned to me by my school’s token libertarian political science professor.
    [Show full text]
  • Ca.506Ec.Cwk (WP)
    CATALOGUE OF SUBUN-SO BOOK STORE No.506 2010 item no.1442 ◇◆◇◆ GENERAL ECONOMICS ◇◆◇◆ 1 ABEL (C.) & LEWIS (C.M.)(Ed.) LATIN AMERICA, ECONOMIC IMPERIALIISM AND THESTATE: The Political economy of the External connection from Independence to the Present. Athlone press,1985. xiv,540pp. dw. 3,000 2 ABEL (M.) DYNAMISCHE WIRTSCHAFTSFUHRUNG. Fuhrungslehre fur die Betriebspraxis. Wiesbaden: Dr.Th.Gabler, 1961. 260pp. 3,000 3 ABRAHAM-FROIS (G.) & BERREBI (E.) THEORY OF VALUE, PRICES AND ACCUMULATION. A mathematical integration of Marx, von Neumann and Sraffa. Cambridge U.P., 1979. 260pp. lar.8vo. dw. 5,000 4 ADDY (S.O.) CHURCH AND MANOR A Study in English Economic History. (1912) Kelley, 1970. xxx,473pp. 3,000 5 AGAZZINI (M.) LA SCIENCE DE L'ECONOMIE POLITIQUE, Ou principes de laformation, du progres, et de la decadence de la richesse et application de ces principes a L'administration economique des nations. Paris: Londres, Bossange,1822.First Ed.,1 engraved plate and 13 folding tables. xv,389pp. 3/4 calf & marbled boads. spine rubbed. title page. 2 stamped. owner's sign. 42,000 6 ALISON (A.) THE PRINCIPLES OF POPULATION, and their connection with Human Happiness. Edinburgh: W.Blackwood, 1840. First Ed. 2 vols. half cloth with boards. cover & spine worn. in recently slip-case. 102,900 - 1 - 7 ALT (J.E.) & SHEPSLE (K.A.)(Ed.) PERSPECTIVES ON POSITIVE POLITICAL ECONOMY. Cambridge U.P., 1990. 268pp. lar.8vo. 8,000 8 ANTHONY (M.) & BIGGS (N.) MATHEMATICS FOR ECONOMICS AND FINANCE. Methods and modeling. Cambridge U.P., 1997. 394pp. lar.8vo. pb. 4,200 9 ASTLE (W.E.) SHIPOWNERS' CARGO LIABILITIES AND IMMUNITIES.
    [Show full text]
  • Theories of Surplus-Value, Part II, Pp
    W O R K E R S O F A L L C O U N T R I E S, U N I T E! *(vL u(vX THEO9IE% of %U9™©U%-V(©UE V o l u m e IV o f C a p i t a l PART III A PROGRESS PUBLISHERS Moscow 1971 TRANSLATED FROM THE GERMAN BY JACK COHEN AND S. W. RYAZANSKAYA EDITED BY S. W. RYAZANSKAYA AND RICHARD DIXON К. MAPKC TEOPИИ ПPИБABOЧHOЙ CTOИMOCTИ (IV том «Капzтала») Чacть III Ha ahgjuvckom rflke From Marx to Mao M L Digital Reprints 2016 www.marx2mao.com First printing 1971 Printed in the Union of Soviet Socialist Republics PUBLISHER’S NOTE This translation has been made from Karl Marx, Theorien über den Mehr- wert, Teil 3, Dietz Verlag, Berlin, 1962. The arrangement of the material and the notes correspond on the whole to the Russian edition of Marx- Engels, Collected Works, Vol. 26, Part III, Moscow, 1964, prepared by the Institute of Marxism-Leninism in Moscow, where the manuscript of the work is kept. We have attempted to keep the translation as closely as possible to the original. When, for the sake of clarity, it has been found necessary to insert a few words these are enclosed in square brackets. In order to avoid confu- sion, the square brackets occasionally used by Marx in the manuscript have been replaced either by pointed brackets < > or, when the passages en- closed were longer, by braces ! ∃. Quotations from French, German and Italian authors are given in En- glish in the text and are reproduced in the original language in the Appen- dix.
    [Show full text]
  • Genocide Studies and Prevention: an International Journal
    Genocide Studies and Prevention: An International Journal Volume 11 Issue 2 Article 2 10-2017 Full Issue 11.2 Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarcommons.usf.edu/gsp Recommended Citation (2017) "Full Issue 11.2," Genocide Studies and Prevention: An International Journal: Vol. 11: Iss. 2: 1-128. DOI: http://doi.org/10.5038/1911-9933.11.2 Available at: https://scholarcommons.usf.edu/gsp/vol11/iss2/2 This Front Matter is brought to you for free and open access by the Open Access Journals at Scholar Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Genocide Studies and Prevention: An International Journal by an authorized editor of Scholar Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. ISSN 1911-0359 eISSN 1911-9933 Genocide Studies and Prevention: An International Journal Volume 11.2 - 2017 ii ©2017 Genocide Studies and Prevention 11, no. 2 iii Genocide Studies and Prevention: An International Journal http://scholarcommons.usf.edu/gsp/ Volume 11.2 - 2017 Susan Braden, Christian Gudehus, and Douglas Irvin-Erickson Editors’ Introduction ................................................................................................................1 Translation Heinrich Popitz Social Norms .............................................................................................................................3 Articles Sarah Federman Genocide Studies and Corporate Social Responsibility: The Contemporary Case of the French National Railways (SNCF) .....................................................................................................13
    [Show full text]
  • Marx and Germany
    Communism and Nationalism This page intentionally left blank Communism and Nationalism Karl Marx Versus Friedrich List Roman Szporluk New York Oxford OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS 1988 Oxford University Press Oxford New York Toronto Delhi Bombay Calcutta Madras Karachi Petaling Jaya Singapore Hong Kong Tokyo Nairobi Dar es Salaam Cape Town Melbourne Auckland and associated companies in Beirut Berlin Ibadan Nicosia Copyright © 1988 by Oxford University Press, Inc. Published by Oxford University Press, Inc., 200 Madison Avenue, New York, New York 10016 Oxford is a registered trademark of Oxford University Press All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise, without the prior permission of Oxford University Press. Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Szporluk, Roman. Communism and nationalism. Bibliography: p. Includes index. 1. Nationalism and socialism. 2. Marx, Karl, 1818-1883—-Views on nationalism. 3. List, Friedrich, 1789-1846—Views on nationalism. I. Title. HX550.N3S95 1988 320.5'32 87-10993 ISBN 0-19-505102-5 135798642 Printed in the United States of America on acid-free paper For Mary Ann, Ben, Larissa, and Michael This page intentionally left blank Preface In 1977 I began to teach a course at the University of Michigan called "Socialism and Nationalism." The course was based on the idea that in the historical epoch inaugurated by the French and Industrial revolutions, socialism and nationalism addressed very similar—if not identical—ques- tions, but gave different answers to them, provided competing programs for their realization, and in general, offered alternative visions of the world.
    [Show full text]
  • „Ricardische Sozialisten”?
    ERNST NOLTE THOMAS HOPKINS UND T. R. EDMONDS - ZWEI VERGESSENE ,,RICARDISCHE SOZIALISTEN"? ZUGLEICH EIN BEITRAG ZUR BEGRIFFSKLARUNG Im Paragraphen 2 der Misere de la philosophic fiihrt Marx in der Polemik gegen Proudhon drei Titel von englischen ,,Sozialisten" an, in denen langst vor Proudhon ,,die egalitare Anwendung der Ricardoschen Theorie" vor- geschlagen worden sei: Nous pourrions citer a M. Proudhon: VEconomie politique de Hopkins, 1822; William Thompson: An Inquiry into the Principles of the distribution of wealth, most conducive to human happiness, 1824; T. R. Edmonds: Prac- tical, moral and political Economy, 1828; etc., etc., et quatre pages d'etc.1 Marx zitiert jedoch nichts aus einem dieser Werke, sondern setzt sich im folgenden mit dem ,,bemerkenswerten Werk" des ,,englischen Kommuni- sten" J. F. Bray Labour's wrongs and labour's remedy von 1839 auseinander, um den Nachweis zu fiihren, daU die Herleitung des Wertes aus der Arbeitszeit und damit Proudhons Grundthese lediglich die gegenwartigen Verhaltnisse spiegele und mithin keineswegs geeignet sei, das Wesen der kiinftigen sozialistischen Gesellschaft zu charakterisieren. Die Bedeutung dieser Stelle ist leicht zu erkennen. Zum ersten Mai nimmt Marx hier eine Kenntnis der sogenannten ,,ricardischen Soziali- sten" in Anspruch, die nach der These angesehener Autoren wie G. D. H. Cole, L. Brentano und R. Michels die eigentlichen Vorlaufer seines ,,wissenschaftlichen Sozialismus" gewesen sind. In den Okonomisch-phi- losophischen Manuskripten und in der Deutschen Ideologic zitiert oder erwahnt er zwar die ,,biirgerlichen Okonomen" Smith und Ricardo und die franzosischen Sozialisten Proudhon und Pecqueur bzw. Blanc, aber von denjenigen, die meist als die Hauptvertreter des ,,ricardischen Sozia- lismus" angesehen werden, namlich von William Thompson, Thomas Hodgskin, John Gray und John F.
    [Show full text]
  • Lessons Learned from German Sociology, 1933–45: Contexts and Content Wiebke Keim
    Lessons learned from German sociology, 1933–45: contexts and content Wiebke Keim To cite this version: Wiebke Keim. Lessons learned from German sociology, 1933–45: contexts and content. Social Science in Context. Historical, Sociological, and Global Perspectives, Nordic Academic Press, pp.95 - 114, 2013, 978-91-87351-04-4. halshs-01077333 HAL Id: halshs-01077333 https://halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-01077333 Submitted on 24 Oct 2014 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. Keim, Wiebke (2013): Lessons learned from German sociology 1933-45: Contexts and content. In: Danell, Rickard; Larsson, Anna; Wisselgren, Per (Hg.): Social Science in Context. Historical, Sociological, and Global Perspectives, Lund: Nordic Academic Press: 95-114. – Manuscript – Lessons learned from German sociology, 1933–45: contexts and content Wiebke Keim This essay deals with a specific historical context for sociology: the period 1933–45 in Germany. It raises questions about the definition and self-definition of the discipline.i How far did the given historical,
    [Show full text]
  • Elements of a Formal Sociology of the Financial Markets
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Langenohl, Andreas Article Analyzing expectations sociologically: Elements of a formal sociology of the financial markets economic sociology_the european electronic newsletter Provided in Cooperation with: Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies (MPIfG), Cologne Suggested Citation: Langenohl, Andreas (2010) : Analyzing expectations sociologically: Elements of a formal sociology of the financial markets, economic sociology_the european electronic newsletter, ISSN 1871-3351, Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies (MPIfG), Cologne, Vol. 12, Iss. 1, pp. 18-27 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/155958 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the
    [Show full text]