Egypt's Development and Mubarak's Inheritance

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Egypt's Development and Mubarak's Inheritance INSTITUTE OF CURRENT WORLD AFFAIRS )JV-I American Research Center in Egypt 2, Midan Kasr al-Doubara Garden City Cairo Apri 1986 EGYPT'S DEVELOPMENT AND MUBARAK'S INHERITANCE by Dr. Dirk J. Vandewalle It is almost five years since president Anwar Sadat was killed by Muslim extremists and Husni Mubarak assumed leadership over Egypt the Arab world's most populous country. With Sadat disappeared one of the last members of those who had actively participated in the coup that brought Gamal Abdul Nasser to power in 1952. Except for a few select holdovers from this "1952 Generation" their place in Egyptian politics is now being occupied by the "October Generation" the new men who fought the war against Israel in 1973. Demographics play an important part in understanding today's Egypt in more ways than one. Half of all Egyptians now alive were born after 1952. For them the revolution which once galvanized Egyptians and the Arab world alike no longer invokes the imagery and legitimacy it once held for Nasser's and Sadat's generation. Although Nasser remains a symbol he is often referred to here much in the same way as Americans talk about George Washington. Upon closer questioning few of Egypt's youngest generation know little about Nasser or what he stood for in the Arab world. Husni Mubarak both personally and symbolically marks a break with Egypt's most recent past. For Gamal Abdul Nasser and Anwar Sadat politics had been a lifelong passion. Mubarak has always been a professional soldier first a reluctant politician second. Throughout the political tumult of the early World War II post-war years he quietly pursued his studies at the Egyptian War College, became the commander of Cairo West air base and after the dismissal of his own senior officers in the wake of the 1967 war assumed the position of chief of staff of the air force. He seemed destined for a distinguished military career until to his own and others" surprise Anwar Sadat appointed him vice president in 1975. Dirk Vandewalle is the North Africa Fellow of the Institute of Current World Affairs. His interest is the political economy of Egypt and North Africa in particular the development strategies of Egypt Algeria Cibya, Tunisia and Morocco in the last two decades. Iubarak was forty-seven years old when his political career began. A plodding workaholic determined to leave his mark on Egyptian political life once he became part of it, he quickly consolidated his own power base within the government. By the time Sadat was killed, Mubarak had become thoroughly familiar with the political system and the day-to-day running of the country. He controlled the National Democratic Party and, as important in a country in which police control remains an important ingredient of power, the Supreme National Security Council. He promised to be what ohn Waterbury once called a on qrant someone who would manage Egypt's problems in a competent, albeit perhaps unimaginative, style. But it was seemingly that kind of leadership Egypt was in dire need of in the I780s. Mubarak's aim since coming to power has not been, as it was for Nasser and Sadat to refashion Egypt's economic character, but rather to cope with the formidable strains it must now labor under. lany of these bottlenecks result from his predecessors' experiments and I shall have quite a bit more to say about these lingering structural problems in my reports. The economic legacy of both former presidents casts a large shadow. In less than three decades Egypt has experimented successively with a socialist form of development in cooperation with the East and then, after Nasser's death in 1970 modified this approach in favor of development with the aid of Western capital and know-how. The modification was formally announced in 1974. It is usually referred to as in.film.h., translated either as liberalization or, perhaps less accurate since Egypt never completely cut itself off from foreign investment, as the =Open Door" policy. Whatever the translation, infitah was meant to attract private and western investment to the country and was an attempt to move away from the centralized economic decision making that existed under Nasser. Needless to say, this rapid change of approaches extracted an economic toll about which the Egyptian press academics, and policy makers still keep up heated debates. Only nominal economists contend that economic decisions can be neutral or value-free, and one suspects they have never been to any developing country or at least not to Egypt. The ruler ultimately includes in his choice a number of issues that include concerns far beyond economic inclinations. Both Nasser's socialism and Sadat's infitah were in effect strong ideological expressions which in turn created circles of support and opposition and refashioned (or were shaped by) the political arena. What is often referred to as the =cruel dilemmas of development" hint at these issues beyond economics. Ultimately the choice of economic policy in Egypt as well as the choice of superpower to support this choice, touches upon internal social relations, the lives and fates of the Egyptian population involved (or as the case might be, no___t involved). Nasser and Sadat chose conscientiously for what they perceived to be in the ultimate interest of Egypt, and their speeches invariably reflect the view that their economic policies no matter how radically different they turned out to be would lead to social justice and equity. One shouldn't belittle these efforts, nor always accept them at face value. As hope to show, the story of development in Egypt as elsewhere includes a number of economic gaffes, political intrigues, outright corruption and venality, and a generous dose of political propaganda. 1::)5v By sheer size, geographical position, population, and cultural hegemony, Egypt has played an important (although initially isolated) role in the Arab world since the West intruded upon the Middle East in the 19th century. Its cultural predominance, literary and liberal ambitions, and an economy relatively sophisticated for the area and time period, had produced a feeling of preeminence among Egyptian elites. Egypt rejected Arab nationalism initially in favor of a more Egyptian nationalism, in part because its leaders felt that the Arab nationalism that engulfed the Middle East at the time was parochial and often subservient to the West. Not until 1945 and the creation of the Arab League did Egyptian nationalism blend with a more regional Arab nationalism. It was a movement Egypt was bound to lead, and whose presence shaped its direction and content in crucial ways. From then on the concern over Egypt's position in any New Arab Order has remained of great concern to Egypt and the other Arab countries alike. If observers, disagree on the creation, endurance, and demise of these elusive New Arab Orders, there seems to be little disagreement that in any such creation Egypt's role will be crucial. The creation of the Arab League in 1945, the Egyptian revolution of 1952, the Bandung conference of 1955, the political experiments of the 1960s within the Middle East, the Ramadan war of 1973 and, above all, the OPEC period during the 1970s all were interpreted to mark a turning point for the Arab world and for its role internationally. The I770s in particular, with their abundant wealth and the accumulation of billions of petrodollars, produced a euphoria that the Middle East now truly had the means to transform itself into a new Camelot. Sadat's infitah policies were in part an effort to profit from this new reality. He hoped that a combination of Arab capital, #lestern technology, and Egyptian manpower would propel his country once more into becoming a powerhouse for the region. What Sadat hoped for in essence was the creation of another New Arab Order in which his country would once again play a leading role. But in the 1970s the initiative seemingly slipped into the hands of the oil states as Egypt became the pauperized, patronized and after the CampDavid agreements, ostracized poorer cousin of the region. = The early part of this story has been recounted by George Antonius, one of ICWA's earlier fellows. His book, The Arab Awakeninq_ (London: Hamilton, 1938 various reprints) remains important for the early history of the Arab national movement. It was dedicated to Charles Crane. 2 Not surprisingly, one of the better books that appeared in the early 1980s on Egypt and its potential new role in the Middle East, carried as its subtitle "Egypt and the New Arab Order." And not surprisingly either, only four years after its publication, many of the options, prescriptions, and analyses offered by some o/ its contributors to confirm the beginning of this new order have already been negated by the rapid change of events in the region. Malcolm H. Kerr and El Sayed Yassin, Ric.h..a.n.d_.Lo.pr States in the Middle East. Eqvot and the New Arab Order (Cairo: University of Cairo Press, 1982). D3v But by the early 1980s this self-proclaimed New Arab Order had proven as elusive as its precursors, wracked by internal disagreements and international economic pressures. The global recession after 1980, and a number of assorted ills indicated how fragile it had been. Host of the oil-exporting countries, with perhaps Libya remaining as the last great spender of petrodollars, started to retrench. Private sectors who until then had been neglected, were given a new lease on life. Reserves dropped precipitously. The unity of OPEC, fragile at the best of times now unravelled slowly as Saudi Arabia was no longer willing (and able) to guide the organization and defection seemed to offer the greatest potential for reaping diminishing benefits.
Recommended publications
  • Rethinking U.S. Economic Aid to Egypt
    Rethinking U.S. Economic Aid to Egypt Amy Hawthorne OCTOBER 2016 RETHINKING U.S. ECONOMIC AID TO EGYPT Amy Hawthorne OCTOBER 2016 © 2016 Project on Middle East Democracy. All rights reserved. The Project on Middle East Democracy (POMED) is a nonpartisan, nonprofit, Washington, D.C. based 501(c)(3) organization. The views represented here do not necessarily reflect the views of POMED, its staff, or its Board members. Limited print copies are also available. Project on Middle East Democracy 1730 Rhode Island Avenue NW, Suite 617 Washington DC 20036 www.pomed.org CONTENTS I. Introduction. 2 II. Background . .4 III. The Bilateral Economic Aid Program: Understanding the Basics. 16 IV. Why Has U.S. Economic Aid Not Had A Greater Positive Impact? . 18 V. The Way Forward . 29 VI. Conclusion . 34 PROJECT ON MIDDLE EAST DEMOCRACY 1 RETHINKING U.S. ECONOMIC AID TO EGYPT I. INTRODUCTION Among the many challenges facing the next U.S. administration in the Middle East will be to forge an effective approach toward Egypt. The years following the 2011 popular uprising that overthrew longtime U.S. ally President Hosni Mubarak have witnessed significant friction with Egypt over issues ranging from democracy and human rights, to how each country defines terrorism (Egypt’s definition encompasses peaceful political activity as well as violent actions), to post-Qaddafi Libya, widening a rift between the two countries that began at least a decade ago. Unless the policies of the current Egyptian government shift, the United States can only seek to manage, not repair, this rift. The next U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • The Grain Economy of Mamluk Egypt by Ira M. Lapidus
    THE GRAIN ECONOMY OF MAMLUK EGYPT BY IRA M. LAPIDUS (University of California, Berkeley) Scholarly studies of the economy of Egypt in the Middle Ages, from the Fatimid through the Mamluk periods, have stressed two seemingly contradictory themes. On the one hand, the extraordinary involvement of the state in economic affairs is manifest. At different times, and in various ways, the ruling regimes of Egypt monopolized or strictly controlled certain primary or strategic products. Wood and metals, both domestic and imported, were strictly controlled to assure the availability of military supplies. Certain export products like natron were sometimes made state monopolies. So too products of unusual commercial importance were exploited, especially by the Mamluk Sultans, to gain monetary advantages. Sugar production, often in the hands of rulers and oflicials, was also, on occasion, a state monopoly. At another level, the state participated in economic activity it did not monopolize. Either the governing bureaus themselves, or elite members of the regime, were responsible for irrigation and other investments essential to agricultural productivity. In the trading sphere, though state-sponsored trading expeditions are unknown, state support for trade by treaty arrangements, by military and diplomatic protection, and direct participation in the form of investments placed with mer- chants were characteristic activities. How much of the capital of trade was "booty" or political capital we shall never know. In other spheres, state participation gave way to state controls for the purposes of taxation. Regulation of the movements of merchants, or the distribution of goods, facilitated taxation. For religious or moral reasons state controls also extended to the supervision, regulation, or prohibition of certain illicit trades.
    [Show full text]
  • Rethinking Islamist Politics February 11, 2014 Contents
    POMEPS STUDIES 6 islam in a changing middle east Rethinking Islamist Politics February 11, 2014 Contents The Debacle of Orthodox Islamism . 7 Khalil al-Anani, Middle East Institute Understanding the Ideological Drivers Pushing Youth Toward Violence in Post-Coup Egypt . 9 Mokhtar Awad, Center for American Progress Why do Islamists Provide Social Services? . 13 Steven Brooke, University of Texas at Austin Rethinking Post-Islamism and the Study of Changes in Islamist Ideology . 16 By Michaelle Browers, Wake Forest University The Brotherhood Withdraws Into Itself . 19 Nathan J. Brown, George Washington University Were the Islamists Wrong-Footed by the Arab Spring? . 24 François Burgat, CNRS, Institut de recherches et d’études sur le monde arabe et musulman (translated by Patrick Hutchinson) Jihadism: Seven Assumptions Shaken by the Arab Spring . 28 Thomas Hegghammer, Norwegian Defence Research Establishment (FFI) The Islamist Appeal to Quranic Authority . 31 Bruce B. Lawrence, Duke University Is the Post-Islamism Thesis Still Valid? . 33 Peter Mandaville, George Mason University Did We Get the Muslim Brotherhood Wrong? . 37 Marc Lynch, George Washington University Rethinking Political Islam? Think Again . 40 Tarek Masoud, Harvard University Islamist Movements and the Political After the Arab Uprisings . 44 Roel Meijer, Radboud University Nijmegen, The Netherlands, and Ghent University, Belgium Beyond Islamist Groups . 47 Jillian Schwedler, Hunter College, City University of New York The Shifting Legitimization of Democracy and Elections: . 50 Joas Wagemakers, Radboud University Nijmegen, the Netherlands Rethinking Islamist Politics . 52 Carrie Rosefsky Wickham, Emory University Progressive Problemshift or Paradigmatic Degeneration? . 56 Stacey Philbrick Yadav, Hobart and William Smith Colleges Online Article Index Please see http://pomeps.org/2014/01/rethinking-islamist-politics-conference/ for online versions of all of the articles in this briefing .
    [Show full text]
  • Fault Lines: Sinai Peninsula 20 OCT 2017 the Sinai Peninsula Is a Complicated Operational Environment (OE)
    Fault Lines: Sinai Peninsula 20 OCT 2017 The Sinai Peninsula is a complicated operational environment (OE). At present, there are a number of interconnected conditions creating instability and fostering a favorable environment for the growth of Islamic extremist groups. Egypt is battling this situation with large-scale security operations, yet militant activity is not diminishing. The Egyptian government, in coordination with the Israeli government, is placing renewed interest on countering insurgent actors in the region and establishing a lasting security. Despite its best effort, Egypt has been largely unsuccessful. A variety of factors have contributed to the continued rise of the insurgents. We submit there are four key fault lines contributing to instability. These fault lines are neither mutually exclusive nor are they isolated to the Sinai. In fact, they are inexorably intertwined, in ways between Egypt, Israel, and the Sinai Peninsula. Issues related to faults create stability complications, legitimacy concerns, and disidentification problems that can be easily exploited by interested actors. It is essential to understand the conditions creating the faults, the escalation that results from them operating at the same time, and the potential effects for continued insecurity and ultimately instability in the region. FAULT LINES Egypt-Israel Relations - Enduring geopolitical tension between Egypt and Israel, and complex coordination needs between are “exploitable dissimilar and traditionally untrusting cultures, has potential for explosive effects on regional stability. sources of Political Instability - Continued political instability, generated from leadership turmoil, mounting security concerns, and insufficient efforts for economic development may lead to an exponentially dire security situation and direct and violent instability in the challenges to the government.
    [Show full text]
  • ANALYSIS and MAJOR FINDINGS Analysis and Major Findings
    Preface PART3 ANALYSIS AND MAJOR FINDINGS Analysis and Major Findings 3.1 OVERVIEW (AFCEs), individual government consumption expenditures Purchasing power parities are used to contrast estimates of the size (IGCEs), collective government consumption expenditures of a country’s economy, its aggregate welfare, the well-being of its (CGCEs) and investment. Africa regional values include only the residents and how its prices compare with those in other countries. 48 African countries that participated in 2005 ICP-Africa. The main results are presented in tables and figures. The main indi- The results of 2005 ICP-Africa are presented below. The descrip- cators used are price level indices (PLIs) and per capita GDP, its tive analysis covers gross domestic product (GDP) and some of expenditure components and their expenditure shares in terms its main components: actual final consumption expenditures of the total Africa region. Figure 1: Real GDP By Country in Billion AFRIC, 2005 180 160 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 e r os de r r oon ogo Mali e r T occo Niger Chad unisia Benin r V Egypt Kenya Sudan Liberia Ghana T Congo Gabon Malawi Nigeria Angola Guinea Djibouti Zambia anzania Gambia Uganda Ethiopia Senegal Lesotho Namibia Rwanda T Mo Mauritius Como Botswana Swaziland Mauritania Zimbabwe Came Cape South Africa Madagascar Sierra Leone Côte d'Ivoi Mozambique Burkina Faso Guinea-Bissau ome and Principe Equatorial Guinea T Sao Central African Republic Congo, Democratic Republic Note: For more details, see Table T10 in part 6. Burundi is not shown because it did not supply national account data.
    [Show full text]
  • 'Bread, Dignity and Social Justice': the Political
    briefing paper page 1 ‘Bread, Dignity and Social Justice’: The Political Economy of Egypt’s Transition Jane Kinninmont Middle East and North Africa Programme | April 2012 | MENAP BP 2012/01 Summary points zz In Egypt’s 2011 uprising, political and economic grievances were closely linked in attempts to address complex problems of corruption and injustice. But the cross- class, cross-ideology coalition that united behind the uprising has predictably fragmented, and different groups now have divergent views on the applicability of liberal economic policies to Egypt. zz The Islamist parties which between them won a majority in the 2011–12 parliamentary election appear to favour the continuation of a broadly pro-market policy, although, like all parties, they have emphasized the need for greater ‘social justice’ and less corruption. Leftist groups and trade unions remain largely unrepresented in parliament and tensions may be brewing between labour and Islamist forces over economic policy. zz Uncertainty over future economic policy is currently deterring investment. Although economic policy was not the main focus in the parliamentary election campaign, there is a pressing need for all parties to develop their economic blueprints further. zz Debates over the role of the state, the free market and the nature of globalization are part of democratic self-determination. Rather than repeating old mantras about the intrinsic desirability of a smaller public sector, external actors need to remember that economic policy advice on the role of the state is not purely technical but value-laden. www.chathamhouse.org ‘Bread, Dignity and Social Justice’: The Political Economy of Egypt’s Transition page 2 Introduction and revealed the transformative potential of street protest, When a popular uprising overthrew President Hosni bottom-up coalition-building and mass campaigning.
    [Show full text]
  • Republican Egypt Interpreted: Revolution and Beyond
    14 Republican Egypt interpreted: revolution and beyond ALAIN ROUSSILLON Egypt is one of a restricted group of developing countries whose politics have assumed a special significance as test cases of opposing models of development. Egypt shares with India, China, Algeria, Yugoslavia and Cuba the analytical interest of partisan and aca- demic observers for the light its experience may shed upon the competing theories of development and for the possibility that its history may reveal a unique and unanticipated model Leonard Binder, In a Moment of Enthusiasm, p.. i. Introduction Towards the end of the 1970s, as the opening up (infitah) toward the west and the liberalization of the economy were sharply criticized as "betrayal" of the 1952 revolution's goals, as return of the exploitative bourgeoisie, and as abandonment of the Palestinian cause, certain observers, Egyptian and foreign, began to lay out a new "model" for the reading of contemporary Egyptian history. This model attempted to view Egypt's various "experi- ments," before and after the revolution, from a common perspective; it also made it possible to explain the "cycles" through which Egypt has ultimately failed to "modernize" and regain the place among nations that its millenia of history allows it to demand. Muhammad 'Ali and Nasir, breaking with a past of national humiliation, both incarnated Egypt's "will to power" by basing restoration of its regional and international role on a state economy heavily reliant on industry and the construction of a national armed force: the failure of both projects was brought about by conjunction of the "perverse" consequences of their own options and methods, and by the hostility from coalitions of external interests, alarmed by the regional role to which Egypt aspired.
    [Show full text]
  • CHP2.Pdf.Pdf (69.15Kb)
    Chapter Two The Etatist system in Egypt, 1952-1991 Introduction To understand the historical development of the economic and political transformations caused by Egypt’s structural adjustment program at the beginning of the 1990s, it is necessary to analyze the development of the Egyptian economy from the 1950s to today. Hansen (1991: 10) divides Egypt’s economic and political transformations in the twentieth century into five periods. The first period, from 1929 to 1955, was characterized by a dependence upon private enterprise and free trade. This yielded a moderate-sized public sector. At this time, Egypt’s development strategy depended upon agricultural exports, which it supported through public investment. In terms of industry, Egypt primarily focused upon import substitution, which supported Egypt’s industry through tariffs and other trade restrictions. The second period, from 1955 to 1960, which was a period of transition, witnessed no essential changes. However, the third period, from 1960 to 1965, witnessed the rise of etatism, a peacetime economy, an increased public sector, and Egypt’s first five-year plan. Like the first period, Egypt’s economy still depended upon agriculture, export promotion and import substitution. In industry, however, import substitution began to be supplanted by a growing military-production agenda. The fourth period, from 1965 to 1973, merged etatism with a wartime economy, an enlarged public sector, and military-based economic growth. Finally, the fifth period, 17 from 1973 to1991 continued Egypt’s involvement with etatism and a large public sector, but moved back to a peacetime economy, and witnessed the development of the infitah, or partial economic liberalization.
    [Show full text]
  • The Success of Macroeconomic Policies of Selected Countries of North Africa
    Journal of Economics, Business and Management, Vol. 3, No. 1, January 2015 The Success of Macroeconomic Policies of Selected Countries of North Africa Ingrid Majerová country a wide range of different variables and indicators Abstract—The aim of the article was to analyze the success of might be used. The best predicative ability is attributed to economic policies of selected countries of North Africa - Egypt, four groups of indicators that measure the size of product, Sudan and Morocco. The success was compared using the price level, unemployment and external economic position method of comparison in selected macroeconomic indicators such as gross domestic product growth rate, the share of [2]. Another approach for measuring the macroeconomic current account deficit to gross domestic product, inflation rate performance is used in [3], [4]. and the unemployment rate from 2007 to 2012. For this Magical polygons are used as a standard tool for comparison graphical form of magic quadrangle was chosen. evaluation of success of economy and economic policy. From the resulting data magical quadrangle has shown that the Deviations from the optimum are represented using the four most successful economic policy is implemented by Morocco, indicators of external and internal economic policies of the followed by Egypt and Sudan occupies last place. country. The optimum is defined by OECD and has the Index Terms—Comparison, economic policy, magic following amounts: quadrangle, North African countries. GDP growth rate – 3%, Unemployment rate – 5%, Inflation rate – 2.5%, I. INTRODUCTION Share of current account balance to GDP – 0%. Africa as a whole is undoubtedly one of the most A.
    [Show full text]
  • Evolving Approaches to Nile Waters Management
    THE NILE BASIN: EVOLVING APPROACHES TO NILE WATERS MANAGEMENT J. Anthony Allan, SOAS, University of London UK, [email protected] Occasional Paper 20 SOAS Water Issues Group June 1999 Abstract The paper will review briefly to hydraulic engineering history and the hydropolitical contexts of such development. After a century of activity inspired by an ambitious hydraulic mission the numerous stakeholders in the Nile system are currently influenced by a new water resources mission inspired by environmental and economic principles. The decade of the 1990s, in the post-Cold War era, has witnessed considerable positive progress towards a co- operative international relations regime over Nile waters. This progress has been made despite the numerous armed conflicts in the Horn of Africa, in the south of Sudan and in Rwanda and neighbouring territories. None of these conflicts has been water related; nor has there been any attempt to date to link Nile waters to other conflictual issues as is usual in other MENA (Middle East and North Africa) river basins. The analysis will be informed by international relations theory and illustrated by observation of the contribution of the upstream and downstream riparians to the very important discourse on an as yet very partially developed river basin. Introduction At the end of the twentieth century the Nile hydrological system is of major economic significance to two of its riparians, Egypt and the Sudan; its waters could be of economic significance to at least four of its other riparians. A number of forces external to the Nile Basin have shaped the history of water resource development in the Basin in the past century.
    [Show full text]
  • The Impact of Economic Globalization on the Shadow Economy in Egypt
    Joint Discussion Paper Series in Economics by the Universities of Aachen ∙ Gießen ∙ Göttingen Kassel ∙ Marburg ∙ Siegen ISSN 1867-3678 No. 18-2017 Mohammad Reza Farzanegan and Mai Hassan The Impact of economic globalization on the shadow economy in Egypt This paper can be downloaded from http://www.uni-marburg.de/fb02/makro/forschung/magkspapers Coordination: Bernd Hayo • Philipps-University Marburg School of Business and Economics • Universitätsstraße 24, D-35032 Marburg Tel: +49-6421-2823091, Fax: +49-6421-2823088, e-mail: [email protected] Nr. 2017/06 The impact of economic globalization on the shadow economy in Egypt Mohammad Reza Farzanegan and Mai Hassan MACIE, Philipps-Universität Marburg Marburg Centre for Institutional Economics • Coordination: Prof. Dr. Elisabeth Schulte c/o Research Group Institutional Economics • Barfuessertor 2 • D-35037 Marburg Phone: +49 (0) 6421-28-23196 • Fax: +49 (0) 6421-28-24858 • www.uni-marburg.de/fb02/MACIE • [email protected] This version: 24.03.2017 The impact of economic globalization on the shadow economy in Egypt Mohammad Reza Farzaneganabc and Mai Hassana a Philipps-Universität Marburg, CNMS, Economics of the Middle East Research Group, Marburg b CESifo, Munich c ERF, Cairo d MACIE, Marburg Abstract This study examines the economic globalization and the shadow economy nexus in Egypt. Using time series data from 1976 to 2013, the impulse response analysis shows that the response of the shadow economy in Egypt to positive shocks in economic globalization is negative and statistically significant for the first three years following the shock. This finding is obtained by controlling for several intermediary channels in globalization-shadow economy nexus such as education, government spending, industrial production, and labor force participation.
    [Show full text]
  • Sectoral Transformations in Neo-Patrimonial Rentier States: Tourism Development and State Policy in Egypt
    GIGA Research Unit: Institute of Middle East Studies ___________________________ Sectoral Transformations in Neo-Patrimonial Rentier States: Tourism Development and State Policy in Egypt Thomas Richter / Christian Steiner N° 61 November 2007 www.giga-hamburg.de/workingpapers GIGA WP 61/2007 GIGA Working Papers Edited by GIGA German Institute of Global and Area Studies / Leibniz-Institut für Globale und Regionale Studien. The Working Paper Series serves to disseminate the research results of work in progress prior to publication to encourage the exchange of ideas and academic debate. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. Inclusion of a paper in the Working Paper Series does not constitute publication and should not limit publication in any other venue. Copyright remains with the authors. When Working Papers are eventually accepted by or published in a journal or book, the correct citation reference and, if possible, the corresponding link will then be included in the Working Papers website at: www.giga-hamburg.de/workingpapers. GIGA research unit responsible for this issue: Institute of Middle East Studies Editor of the GIGA Working Paper Series: Anja Zorob <[email protected]> Copyright for this issue: © Thomas Richter and Christian Steiner Editorial assistant and production: Vera Rathje All GIGA Working Papers are available online and free of charge at the website: www.giga-hamburg.de/workingpapers. Working Papers can also be ordered in print. For production
    [Show full text]