How to Stop Deflation with Fiscal Policy: Past Lessons for the Future

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

How to Stop Deflation with Fiscal Policy: Past Lessons for the Future How to Stop Deflation with Fiscal Policy: Past Lessons for the Future Eric M. Leeper University of Virginia November 2020 Hoover Institution Virtual Series Macro Policies I Can we distinguish monetary from fiscal policy? 1. both issue interest-bearing “safe” liabilities 2. in “dollars” whose supply government controls 3. ultimately backed by primary budget surpluses 4. price level must clear both money & bond markets I Variation in expected surpluses alters rate of exchange between nominal govt liabilities and goods I this is the price level I Price level always determined by both MP & FP I In thinking about P, key distinction between policies is who controls the levers I fiscal authority controls the backing that gives liabilities value I monetary authority controls composition of liabilities public holds Two Examples of Joint Policies 1. Incoherent policies: European efforts to hit inflation targets I MP interest rates negative & large asset purchases I long-term bond yields also negative I inflation chronically below target I FP chronically tight, retiring debt I makes sense only if believe FP irrelevant for inflation 2. Coherent policies: U.S. recovery from Great Depression I abandoned convertibility to gold I created genuinely nominal government debt I MP at ZLB I FP expansionary, financed with new nominal bonds I FDR convinced people debt expansion unbacked European Monetary Policy (pre-Covid) I Negative policy interest rates 1. Euro Area: since June 2014 2. Sweden: since February 2015 3. Switzerland: since December 2014 I Increases in central bank assets since 2006 1. Euro Area: 4.5 × 2. Sweden: 5.1 × 3. Switzerland: 8.3 × I Basic theory: MP can raise inflation only if::: I backed by appropriately expansionary FP I this is what “passive” FP delivers I Europe has been all about fiscal consolidation European Fiscal Policy: Primary Surpluses Germany 2 Switzerland 0 Euro Area Sweden -2 France -4 Spain -6 -8 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 European Inflation 3 2.5 Euro Area Target (upper bound) 2 Germany 1.5 Sweden 1 0.5 0 Switzerland -0.5 -1 -1.5 1/11 7/11 1/12 7/12 1/13 7/13 1/14 7/14 1/15 7/15 1/16 7/16 1/17 7/17 1/18 7/18 1/19 7/19 1/20 7/20 Policies Working Together I Thesis: unbacked fiscal expansion triggered America’s recovery from the Great Depression I Two steps 1. Monetary: reduced gold value of $, abandoned convertibility of gold, abrogated gold clauses 2. Fiscal: expanded government spending financed with nominal bonds and convinced people bonds would not be backed by taxes until economy recovered I Monetary component necessary for fiscal step I under convertibility: bonds are claims to gold I credibility requires bonds be backed fully by taxes I revoking convertibility made bonds genuinely nominal I Policy explicitly state-dependent, lasting until economy & prices recovered I fiscal communication essential to implementation The Policy Problem I Gold standard ) price level mean reverting, but reversion can take decades 180 160 Mean 1921-1929 = 159.9 140 120 Mean 1834-1933 = 100.0 100 80 1840 1850 1860 1870 1880 1890 1900 1910 1920 1930 CPI since 1834 Coinage Act setting 1 oz. gold = $20.67, rescaled to make mean = 100 The Policy Problem I FDR & Congress concerned about debtors who incurred their debts at 1920s prices I deflation raised real costs of debt obligations I household debt-income ratio peaked at 80% in 1933 I farm foreclosures tripled in 1933 I Policy objective called for permanent increase of the price level to level 60% above long-run average I requires substantial permanent revaluation of dollar price of gold I without revaluation, gold cover ratio would fall below legal standard I Cannot permanently raise price level under classical gold standard VAR Evidence from 1930s I Primary surpluses quantitatively important I S most important source of P & Y (17%), aside from own innovations I S most important source of M (39%) I S most important source of G (27%), aside from own innovations I S close to exogenous, explaining 92% of itself I Historical decompositions: S most important contributor to paths of P & Y, aside from own innovations I Estimated output multipliers large—3 to 4—and significant What Is Unbacked Fiscal Expansion? I Definition: Unbacked fiscal expansion (UBFE) 1. increase spending—purchases or transfers, 2. issue nominal bonds to cover the deficit, and 3. convince people surpluses will not rise in future to pay off the bonds I New nominal debt is not expected to be backed by higher primary surpluses I higher nominal debt raises aggregate demand ) higher prices & output I Unbacked fiscal expansion can permanently raise price level, as FDR desired Keynesian Hydraulics + Debt Dynamics I UBFE challenges conventional wisdom: recovery unrelated to fiscal policy I Brown (1956), Romer (1992), Hausman (2016). I fiscal deficits too small to close gap in output I Conventional view: “Keynesian hydraulics” I narrowly construed transmission mechanism I real spending ") real demand ") multiple output " I expansion in nominal demand from higher nominal debt provides no additional stimulus I implicitly, taxes extinguish wealth effects from debt I Broader view: hydraulics + impacts of debt dynamics I unbacked fiscal expansion raises wealth & demand I Multipliers substantially larger when fiscal expansion unbacked FDR’s Triple-Barreled Approach 1. Executive branch—with Congressional blessing—took control of monetary policy I Fed universally regarded as “inept” I Executive reduced gold content of dollar I abandoned convertibility 2. Ran “emergency” deficits financed by nominal bonds I relief through works programs & infrastructure I “emergency” communicated temporary & state-contingent nature of the fiscal policy 3. Political strategy made unprecedented fiscal policy credible I recovery the priority: “more grave” than WWI I feared “agrarian revolution” & “amorphous resentment” of economic institutions I faced “a choice between rise in prices or rise in dictators”; recovery a “war for survival of democracy” Recovery Was Stunning I Recovery coincides with departure from gold I April 1933 the economy turned around I over course of 1933, Treasury & FDR steadily raised dollar price of gold from $20.67 an ounce I FDR was clear there would be no return to gold I Abrogated gold clauses in debts & set price of gold at $35.00 an ounce I a 59% devaluation of the dollar value of gold I Jalil-Rua: inflation expectations rose sharply 1933Q2 I contemporary news accounts & business forecasts I attribute much to FDR’s speeches, fireside chats, press conferences Real Economic Activity Output 130 120 110 100 90 80 Real GNP IP 70 60 1920 1922 1924 1926 1928 1930 1932 1934 1936 1938 1940 Nominal Economic Activity Price Levels 160 GNP Deflator CPI 150 WPI 140 130 120 110 100 90 80 70 1920 1922 1924 1926 1928 1930 1932 1934 1936 1938 1940 Corroborating Evidence I Revaluation of government bond portfolio at heart of UBFE I surprise changes in price level I surprise changes in bond prices (expected inflation) I changes in real discount rates I How do facts about government debt line up with UBFE? Government Debt Facts I Construct detailed government bond portfolio data I Data consistent with UBFE story I nominal debt grew 20% faster than real debt I debt-GNP ratio stabilized at 40% I post-gold standard: real returns more negative I post-GS: surprise devaluations large & negative I post-GS: surprise inflation & lower bond prices important I post-GS: relative price of bonds fell—bonds lost value Government Bond Valuation Indexes of Gross Debt (100 = 32Q2-33Q1) 200 1.3 Nominal 180 Real Real/Nominal (right) Leave Gold 1.2 160 1.1 140 120 1 100 0.9 80 0.8 1920 1922 1924 1926 1928 1930 1932 1934 1936 1938 1940 Debt Stabilized Under UBFE Gross Debt as Percent of GNP 50 45 40 35 30 25 20 Par Value 15 Market Value 10 1920 1922 1924 1926 1928 1930 1932 1934 1936 1938 1940 Lessons for Today 1. Initially FDR was single-minded in pursuit of higher prices & employment; willing to experiment I fiscal policy state contingent I clear deficits would not be offset by surpluses 2. Joint monetary-fiscal behavior triggered recovery I doubling of nominal debt critical I communication about policy goals 3. Policy makers do not understand fiscal inflation I perceive it is a slippery slope: easily leads to runaway inflation Lessons for Today 4. Governments today lack single-mindedness I objectives bounce between stimulus and austerity I fears of sustainability taint policy actions I renders fiscal policy impotent for stimulus 5. Fiscal backstop against deflation (Sims) I no purely monetary cures to serious deflation I commitment to trigger UBFE in face of falling prices 6. Anchoring fiscal expectations I at least as important as monetary expectations.
Recommended publications
  • Fiscal Policy in an Unemployment Crisis∗
    Fiscal Policy in an Unemployment Crisis∗ Pontus Rendahly University of Cambridge, CEPR, and Centre for Macroeconomics (CFM) April 30, 2014 Abstract This paper shows that large fiscal multipliers arise naturally from equilibrium unemploy- ment dynamics. In response to a shock that brings the economy into a liquidity trap, an expansion in government spending increases output and causes a fall in the unemployment rate. Since movements in unemployment are persistent, the effects of current spending linger into the future, leading to an enduring rise in income. As an enduring rise in income boosts private demand, even a temporary increase in government spending sets in motion a virtuous employment-spending spiral with a large associated multiplier. This transmission mechanism contrasts with the conventional view in which fiscal policy may be efficacious only under a prolonged and committed rise in government spending, which engineers a spiral of increasing inflation. Keywords: Fiscal multiplier, liquidity trap, zero lower bound, unemployment inertia. ∗The first version of this paper can be found as Cambridge Working Papers in Economics No. 1211. yThe author would like to thank Andrea Caggese, Giancarlo Corsetti, Wouter den Haan, Jean-Paul L'Huillier, Giammario Impulitti, Karel Mertens, Emi Nakamura, Kristoffer Nimark, Evi Pappa, Franck Portier, Morten Ravn, Jon Steinsson, Silvana Tenreyro, and Mirko Wiederholt for helpful comments and suggestions. I am grateful to seminar participants at LSE, Royal Economic Society, UCL, European Univer- sity Institute, EIEF, ESSIM 2012, SED 2013, Bonn University, Goethe University, UAB, and in particular to James Costain, and Jonathan Heathcote for helpful discussions and conversations. Financial support is gratefully acknowledge from the Centre for Macroeconomics (CFM) and the Institute for New Economic Thinking (INET).
    [Show full text]
  • An Assessment of Modern Monetary Theory
    An assessment of modern monetary theory M. Kasongo Kashama * Introduction Modern monetary theory (MMT) is a so-called heterodox economic school of thought which argues that elected governments should raise funds by issuing money to the maximum extent to implement the policies they deem necessary. While the foundations of MMT were laid in the early 1990s (Mosler, 1993), its tenets have been increasingly echoed in the public arena in recent years. The surge in interest was first reflected by high-profile British and American progressive policy-makers, for whom MMT has provided a rationale for their calls for Green New Deals and other large public spending programmes. In doing so, they have been backed up by new research work and publications from non-mainstream economists in the wake of Mosler’s work (see, for example, Tymoigne et al. (2013), Kelton (2017) or Mitchell et al. (2019)). As the COVID-19 crisis has been hitting the global economy since early this year, the most straightforward application of MMT’s macroeconomic policy agenda – that is, money- financed fiscal expansion or helicopter money – has returned to the forefront on a wider scale. Some consider not only that it is “time for helicopters” (Jourdan, 2020) but also that this global crisis must become a trigger to build on MMT precepts, not least in the euro area context (Bofinger, 2020). The MMT resurgence has been accompanied by lively political discussions and a heated economic debate, bringing fierce criticism from top economists including P. Krugman, G. Mankiw, K. Rogoff or L. Summers. This short article aims at clarifying what is at stake from a macroeconomic stabilisation perspective when considering MMT implementation in advanced economies, paying particular attention to the euro area.
    [Show full text]
  • A Primer on Modern Monetary Theory
    2021 A Primer on Modern Monetary Theory Steven Globerman fraserinstitute.org Contents Executive Summary / i 1. Introducing Modern Monetary Theory / 1 2. Implementing MMT / 4 3. Has Canada Adopted MMT? / 10 4. Proposed Economic and Social Justifications for MMT / 17 5. MMT and Inflation / 23 Concluding Comments / 27 References / 29 About the author / 33 Acknowledgments / 33 Publishing information / 34 Supporting the Fraser Institute / 35 Purpose, funding, and independence / 35 About the Fraser Institute / 36 Editorial Advisory Board / 37 fraserinstitute.org fraserinstitute.org Executive Summary Modern Monetary Theory (MMT) is a policy model for funding govern- ment spending. While MMT is not new, it has recently received wide- spread attention, particularly as government spending has increased dramatically in response to the ongoing COVID-19 crisis and concerns grow about how to pay for this increased spending. The essential message of MMT is that there is no financial constraint on government spending as long as a country is a sovereign issuer of cur- rency and does not tie the value of its currency to another currency. Both Canada and the US are examples of countries that are sovereign issuers of currency. In principle, being a sovereign issuer of currency endows the government with the ability to borrow money from the country’s cen- tral bank. The central bank can effectively credit the government’s bank account at the central bank for an unlimited amount of money without either charging the government interest or, indeed, demanding repayment of the government bonds the central bank has acquired. In 2020, the cen- tral banks in both Canada and the US bought a disproportionately large share of government bonds compared to previous years, which has led some observers to argue that the governments of Canada and the United States are practicing MMT.
    [Show full text]
  • Fiscal Policy in a Monetary Policy Perspective Björn Lagerwall the Author Works in the Riksbank’S Monetary Policy Department1
    NO 5 2019 Economic 27 May Commentaries Fiscal policy in a monetary policy perspective Björn Lagerwall The author works in the Riksbank’s Monetary Policy Department1 In Sweden and many other countries, the framework for stabilisation policy prior to the global financial crisis was aimed at monetary policy playing the lead role and fiscal policy playing a more passive role. But in the wake of the global financial crisis, this view has at least partly been reassessed – towards greater focus on fiscal policy. What are in fact the arguments for this reassessment? We will look Prior to the global financial crisis, more closely at some of them in this Economic Commentary, based on recent the framework for stabilisation research and discussion both internationally and in Sweden. policy, in both Sweden and many One argument has to do with low global interest rates having reduced the other countries, gave monetary scope of monetary policy to, where necessary, provide further stimulus to the policy the lead role. Afterwards, this view has been partly economy. But the low interest rates can also increase the scope of fiscal policy to reassessed – towards a greater stimulate the economy without jeopardising the sustainability of public finances. focus on fiscal policy. Based on Another argument is that many empirical studies have shown that the effects on recent research and discussion, two main reasons for why this household consumption of temporary fiscal policy stimuli may be significantly view has changed can be greater than previously thought. identified, both of which are This Economic Commentary also discusses the interaction between fiscal and discussed in this Economic .
    [Show full text]
  • Fiscal Policy and Inflation Volatility
    WORKING PAPER SERIES NO. 317 / MARCH 2004 FISCAL POLICY AND INFLATION VOLATILITY by Philipp C. Rother WORKING PAPER SERIES NO. 317 / MARCH 2004 FISCAL POLICY AND INFLATION VOLATILITY1 by Philipp C. Rother 2 In 2004 all publications will carry This paper can be downloaded without charge from a motif taken http://www.ecb.int or from the Social Science Research Network from the €100 banknote. electronic library at http://ssrn.com/abstract_id=515081. 1 I thank Silvia Ardagna, Jürgen von Hagen, colleagues at the ECB and an anonymous referee for helpful comments and suggestions. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the European Central Bank. 2 European Central Bank, Kaiserstrasse 29, D-60311 Frankfurt am Main. Fax: +496913446000. Tel: +491613446398. Email: [email protected] . © European Central Bank, 2004 Address Kaiserstrasse 29 60311 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Postal address Postfach 16 03 19 60066 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Telephone +49 69 1344 0 Internet http://www.ecb.int Fax +49 69 1344 6000 Telex 411 144 ecb d All rights reserved. Reproduction for educational and non- commercial purposes is permitted provided that the source is acknowledged. The views expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect those of the European Central Bank. The statement of purpose for the ECB Working Paper Series is available from the ECB website, http://www.ecb.int. ISSN 1561-0810 (print) ISSN 1725-2806 (online) CONTENTS Abstract 4 Non-technical summary 5 1. Introduction 7 2. Literature 8 2.1. Growth effects of inflation volatility 8 2.2.
    [Show full text]
  • Fiscal and Monetary Policy Working Together to Create an Economy That Behaves Reasonably Under All Conditions
    Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Following the 1989 collapse of the Soviet Union, many of the market from becoming dangerously severe. The people cited the United States’ free market as its key government primarily influences the economy through its advantage over the state-controlled economy of the use of the federal monetary and fiscal policies. USSR. Capitalism seemed to have won the day and many Americans reaped the benefits of an unfettered Fiscal Policy market. U.S. fiscal policy is simply how the government uses taxation and spending (i.e. the U.S. budget) to influence But it is a mistake to believe that our “free market” the economy. When the economy is running above or stands completely detached from the government. The below its optimal level, the government can alter the truth is the government uses numerous policies and budget to influence its level of output. plans to influence the economy and keep swings in the market from getting out of hand. If, for instance, the economy is on a powerful upswing and in danger of overheating, the government may Government and the Economy choose to raise taxes or decrease spending to remove The drawback to the fierce competition and effort some money from the market. Or, if the economy is required by capitalism is that the economy can be slow, the government might increase its spending as a subject to boom and bust cycles. When an economy is way to create jobs until consumer demand rises. strong, people tend to spend more and invest in long- term plans.
    [Show full text]
  • Monetary and Fiscal Policy Interactions in a New Keynesian Model with Capital Accumulation and Non-Ricardian Consumers
    WORKING PAPER SERIES NO 649 / JUNE 2006 MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY INTERACTIONS IN A NEW KEYNESIAN MODEL WITH CAPITAL ACCUMULATION AND NON-RICARDIAN CONSUMERS ISSN 1561081-0 by Campbell Leith 9 771561 081005 and Leopold von Thadden WORKING PAPER SERIES NO 649 / JUNE 2006 MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY INTERACTIONS IN A NEW KEYNESIAN MODEL WITH CAPITAL ACCUMULATION AND NON-RICARDIAN CONSUMERS 1 by Campbell Leith 2 and Leopold von Thadden 3 In 2006 all ECB publications will feature This paper can be downloaded without charge from a motif taken http://www.ecb.int or from the Social Science Research Network from the €5 banknote. electronic library at http://ssrn.com/abstract_id=908620 1 Comments on an early version of this paper by Martin Ellison, George von Fuerstenberg, Heinz Herrmann, Leo Kaas, Jana Kremer, Eric Leeper, Massimo Rostagno, Andreas Schabert, Harald Uhlig as well as seminar participants at the European Central Bank, the Deutsche Bundesbank, the University of Konstanz, the CEPR-conference on “The implications of alternative fiscal rules for monetary policy” (Helsinki, 2004), and at the annual meetings of the Econometric Society (Madrid, 2004), the German Economic Association (Dresden, 2004), and the Royal Economic Society (Nottingham, 2005) are gratefully acknowledged. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the European Central Bank. 2 Department of Economics, Adam Smith Building, University of Glasgow, Glasgow G12 8RT, United Kingdom; e-mail: [email protected] 3 European Central Bank, Kaiserstrasse 29, 60311 Frankfurt am Main, Germany; e-mail: [email protected] © European Central Bank, 2006 Address Kaiserstrasse 29 60311 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Postal address Postfach 16 03 19 60066 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Telephone +49 69 1344 0 Internet http://www.ecb.int Fax +49 69 1344 6000 Telex 411 144 ecb d All rights reserved.
    [Show full text]
  • Central Bank Independence and Fiscal Policy: Incentives to Spend and Constraints on the Executive
    Central Bank Independence and Fiscal Policy: Incentives to Spend and Constraints on the Executive Cristina Bodea Michigan State University Masaaki Higashijima Michigan State University Accepted at the British Journal of Political Science Word count: 12146 Abstract Independent central banks prefer balanced budgets due to the long-run connection between deficits and inflation and can enforce their preference through interest rate increases and denial of credit to the government. We argue that legal central bank independence (CBI) deters fiscal deficits predominantly in countries with rule of law and impartial contract enforcement, a free press and constraints on executive power. More, we suggest that CBI may not affect fiscal deficits in a counter-cyclical fashion, but, rather, depending on the electoral calendar and government partisanship. We test our hypotheses with new yearly data on legal CBI for 78 countries from 1970 to 2007. Results show that CBI restrains deficits only in democracies, during non-election years and under left government tenures. 1 1. Introduction In the 1990s countries worldwide started to reform their central bank laws, removing monetary policy from the hands of the government. This means that the newly independent central banks can change interest rates, target the exchange rate or the money supply to ensure price stability or low inflation1, without regard to incumbent approval ratings or re-election prospects. Because central bank independence (CBI) has been designed as an institutional mechanism for keeping a check on inflation, most analyses focus on the effect of such independence on inflation and its potential trade-off with economic growth (Grilli 1991, Cukierman et al.
    [Show full text]
  • What Fiscal Policy Is Effective at Zero Interest Rates?
    Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports What Fiscal Policy Is Effective at Zero Interest Rates? Gauti B. Eggertsson Staff Report no. 402 November 2009 This paper presents preliminary findings and is being distributed to economists and other interested readers solely to stimulate discussion and elicit comments. The views expressed in the paper are those of the author and are not necessarily reflective of views at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the author. What Fiscal Policy Is Effective at Zero Interest Rates? Gauti B. Eggertsson Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports, no. 402 November 2009 JEL classification: E52 Abstract Tax cuts can deepen a recession if the short-term nominal interest rate is zero, according to a standard New Keynesian business cycle model. An example of a contractionary tax cut is a reduction in taxes on wages. This tax cut deepens a recession because it increases deflationary pressures. Another example is a cut in capital taxes. This tax cut deepens a recession because it encourages people to save instead of spend at a time when more spending is needed. Fiscal policies aimed directly at stimulating aggregate demand work better. These policies include 1) a temporary increase in government spending; and 2) tax cuts aimed directly at stimulating aggregate demand rather than aggregate supply, such as an investment tax credit or a cut in sales taxes. The results are specific to an environment in which the interest rate is close to zero, as observed in large parts of the world today.
    [Show full text]
  • FISCAL POLICY and INFLATION Chronic Inflation Has Been The
    FISCAL POLICY AND INFLATION W. Fred Woods Assistant Deputy Director, SEA-Extension, USDA Chronic inflation has been the outstanding feature of the United States economy for more than a decade. It is our foremost economic ill as we approach the 1980s. Inflation has decimated consumer pur- chasing power, inhibited business investment, and weakened our export competitiveness. Since last December, consumer prices have risen at an annual rate of 131/2 percent, a sharp acceleration from the 9 percent of 1978, and almost double the 1977 inflation rate. Earlier this year, a major element in inflation was the rise in food prices. Bad weather and strikes pushed the food component of the Consumer Price Index to a 20 percent annual rate of increase. But increasingly inflation has come from rising energy prices. In January and February of this year, some 30 percent of the in- crease in consumer prices resulted from the rise in food prices. Only 10 percent was attributable to increased energy costs. By May, the proportions were exactly reversed. Since the beginning of 1979, energy product prices at retail have gone up at about a 40 percent annual rate. This is more than three times faster than the rest of the items in the Consumer Price Index. This year's inflation has stemmed in large degree from forces not directly related to current levels of demand, but rather from those forces which were unpredictable and over which we had little if any control. The Development of Chronic Inflation Let's look away from the present situation to the beginnings of our era of chronic inflation.
    [Show full text]
  • Fiscal Policy and Growth
    FISCAL POLICY AND GROWTH Dong Fu Lori L. Taylor Mine K. Yücel Research Department Working Paper 0301 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS Fiscal Policy and Growth* by Dong Fu 214-922-5124 [email protected] Lori L. Taylor 214-922-5158 [email protected] and Mine K. Yücel 214-922-5160 [email protected] Research Department Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas 2200 N. Pearl Street Dallas, TX 75201 January 2003 JEL classification: E62, E66 * The views expressed are those of the authors and are not necessarily the official views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas or the Federal Reserve System. We thank Nathan Balke for helpful comments. Abstract In the literature neither taxes, government spending nor deficits are robustly correlated with economic growth when evaluated individually. The lack of correlation may arise from the inability of any single budgetary component to fully capture the stance of fiscal policy. We use pair-wise combinations of fiscal indicators to assess the relationship between fiscal policy and U.S. growth. We develop a VAR methodology for evaluating simultaneous shocks to more than one variable and use it to examine the impulse responses for simultaneous, unexpected and equivalent structural shocks to pair-wise combinations of fiscal indicators. We also exploit the identity relationship between taxes, spending and deficits and follow Sims and Zha (1998) to evaluate an unexpected structural shock to one included fiscal indicator, holding constant the other included indicator. We find that an increase in the size of federal government leads to slower economic growth, that the deficit is an unreliable indicator of the stance of fiscal policy, and that tax revenues are the most consistent indicator of fiscal policy.
    [Show full text]
  • Is Fiscal Stimulus an Effective Policy Response to a Recession? Reviewing the Existing Research
    FRASER RESEARCH BULLETIN June 2020 Is Fiscal Stimulus an Effective Policy Response to a Recession? Reviewing the Existing Research by Jake Fuss, Alex Whalen, and Tegan Hill Summary This report examines existing academic Research also shows that the Canadian studies that analyze evidence regarding the government’s stimulus in response to the 2009 effectiveness of fiscal stimulus—additional recession contributed little, if anything, to the government spending and/or tax relief—as a economic turnaround. mechanism to mitigate the impact of a reces­ Harvard University professor Alberto Ale­ sion and speed up economic recovery. The re­ sina finds that increases in government spend­ search raises significant doubts about whether ing are associated with lower growth, while fiscal stimulus can achieve this objective. stimulus based on decreases in personal and Evidence from University of California— business taxes are associated with higher rates San Diego professor Valerie Ramey and Har­ of economic growth. In addition, Alesina’s work vard University professor Robert Barro dem­ suggests that reductions to government spend­ onstrates that the fiscal multiplier created by ing are an important part of reducing fiscal increased government spending is below 1.0, deficits following a recession. indicating that stimulus measures actually Before implementing any fiscal stimulus crowd out economic activity that would other­ packages, Canadian policymakers must con­ wise have occurred. sider the potential implications on both the Empirical research from Stanford Univer­ economy and government balance sheets. Past sity professor John Taylor shows that the US history suggests that stimulus will not improve stimulus package during the 2008-09 recession the Canadian economy and may even be a det­ failed to increase consumption and had little to riment to it.
    [Show full text]