World Bank Document

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

World Bank Document View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE A history of the Republicprovided by ofK-Developedia(KDI School) Repository Korea’s industrial structural transformation and spatial development Sam Ock Park The Korean peninsula, which is situated is divided into Yongnam (the southeast at the northeastern rim of the Asian con- region) and Honam (the southwest region). tinent, covers 221,000 square kilometers In general, the western part of Korea con- and includes both the Democratic People’s sists largely of plains, while the eastern part Republic of Korea and the Republic of consists largely of mountains. Korea. Of that total, 99,000 square kilome- Historically, when agriculture was the ters constitute the Republic of Korea, the major economic activity, the western part of 19 focus of this paper. Korea was relatively affl uent, largely due to chapter The Korean peninsula historically served high agricultural productivity in the plains. as a land bridge over which Chinese culture However, since the early 1960s, Korea’s eco- was diffused from China to Japan. Despite nomic geography has changed signifi cantly, the signifi cant infl uence of Chinese culture with rapid industrial development start- and the frequent invasions by foreign pow- ing in the southeastern and capital regions. ers, the Republic of Korea has managed to Construction of the Seoul-Busan express preserve a cultural and ethnic identity that is highway and the industrial development of different from that of either China or Japan, the southeastern region, centered on Busan, with a distinct language, alphabet, arts, and increased the spatial disparity between the customs (Lee and others 1988). axis of Seoul-Busan and the axis of the south- The province (do) is the country’s larg- western and northeastern corners of Korea. est administrative unit. Presently, Korea has Korea has experienced remarkable eco- nine provinces, with names originating in nomic growth for the past fi ve decades. Korea the early Chosun Dynasty. In addition, Korea was among the poorest countries in the world has one special city (Seoul) and six mega following the devastation of the Korean War cities (Busan, Daegu, Daejon, Gwangju, (1950–53). Korea’s per capita gross national Inchon, and Ulsan) that have populations product (GNP) rose from less than US$100 over 1 million and are at the same adminis- (in 1996 US$) in 1960 to US$20,000 in 2007. trative level as provinces (see fi gure 19.1). This remarkable economic achievement, Traditionally, the Korean peninsula known as “compressed economic growth,” was divided into three geographic regions: is closely related to the successful imple- north, central, and south. Due to the politi- mentation of export-oriented, sector-spe- cal division of the Korean peninsula in 1953, cifi c industrial development strategies and some of the northern part of the central the development of human resources since region and the whole of the northern region the launch of the First Five-Year Economic belong to the Democratic People’s Republic Development Plan in 1962. of Korea. In addition, there are cultural and Korea’s compressed economic growth geographic differences between the east and is dynamic, resulting, fi rst, in the concen- west of each region. For example, the south tration of industry and population in the A history of Korea’s industrial structural transformation and spatial development 321 capital region and, subsequently, in the con- Figure 19.1 Administrative divisions of Korea: provinces, mega cities, and provincial cities vergence of regional GDP per capita, as pro- vincial cities and rural areas began to evolve with the development of information and communications technology (ICT). Chunchon Considering the dynamics of the Korean economy and the country’s rapid spatial development, this chapter investigates the Seoul KANGWON following issues: Inchon KYONGGI • The role of government policies in the NORTH transformation of industrial structure CHUNGCHONG Chongju and spatial development; SOUTH CHUNGCHONG • The spatial development of economic NORTH growth in terms of “distance” and “den- Daejon KYONGSANG sity” effects, agglomeration, factor mobil- Daegu ity, and technological development; and Chonju • The lessons and policy implications. NORTH CHOLLA SOUTH Ulsan In Korea, structural dimensions are KYONGSANG closely related to spatial dimensions, and Gwanju Changwon Busan so this chapter examines industrial poli- Mokpo SOUTH cies, spatial transformation, and industrial CHOLLA restructuring. The analyses at the national level are conducted mostly for the period from the 1960s to 2005. However, the analyses at the regional level are conducted mostly for the period from the 1980s to 2005 due to the availability of data Provincial Boundaries by regions and inconsistency of data for Megacities earlier years. CHEJU The basic unit of analysis is the province: 9 provinces and 7 major cities (Seoul and the mega cities), making 16 units. The 16 basic units of provinces and cities are clas- sifi ed into 4 regions: capital, middle, south- 82 percent of the chemical industries, and west, and southeast (see fi gure 19.2). 90 percent of the electronic power–generat- ing facilities were located in the north when Industrial policies, structural Korea was liberated from Japanese occupa- tion in 1945 (Park 1981). To make matters changes of industry, and spatial worse, more than half of the manufacturing transformation facilities were destroyed during the Korean The history of Korean industrialization War, weakening the foundations for indus- is rather short. Manufacturing activities trial development. were mainly in handicrafts created by mid- Industrialization in Korea has progressed dle-class people in the Chosun Kingdom rapidly since the early 1960s, when the First (1392–1910). During the period of Japa- Economic Development Plan (1962–66) nese occupation (1910–45), Japan began was launched. The manufacturing indus- developing heavy and chemical industries try became the major driving force of the in the north (now the Democratic People’s Korean economy for the next two decades. Republic of Korea) to make use of the abun- The share of manufacturing in total national dant hydraulic power and mineral resources production increased rapidly from 12.1 per- there. As a result, 90 percent of the minerals, cent in 1960 to 29.6 percent in 1980, while 322 RESHAPING ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY IN EAST ASIA Figure 19.2 Four regions, nine provinces, and major cities in Korea to the proliferation of industrial cities in the capital region, while the development of a large-scale industrial complex was the major source of growth for industrial cities in the southeast region. Korea’s rural-urban transformation took place through the CAPITAL KANGWON concentration of industry and population REGION in major urban areas, on the one hand, and MIDDLE the decentralization of industry and popu- KYONGGI REGION lation from the large core cities to their NORTH hinterlands within the region, on the other. CHUNGCHONG Both processes are related to distance and density effects. SOUTH CHUNGCHONG Understanding the government’s indus- NORTH KYONGSANG trial policy is a prerequisite to understanding the spatial transformation of Korea. Since SOUTHEAST the First Five-Year Economic Development REGION Plan was launched in 1962, the national NORTH CHOLLA government has sought to promote particu- SOUTH KYONGSANG lar sectors and locations. Export-oriented SOUTHWEST industrialization has been a major strategy REGION since the early 1960s, and the strategy was SOUTH CHOLLA fashioned to promote the most promis- ing industries at a certain stage. These were called “strategic industries.” Labor-intensive industries were the key sectors for the Provincial Boundaries expansion of industrial exports before Regional Boundaries the early 1970s, while heavy and chemical > 500,000 population industries were the strategic industries for < 500,000 population the expansion of exports in the late 1970s CHEJU and early 1980s. The government’s policy of support for heavy and chemical industries contributed to the evolution of the chaebol (business conglomerate) system by allow- the share of agriculture decreased from 39.9 ing chaebols to borrow foreign capital and to 14.6 percent (see table 19.1). granting them incentives to invest in heavy The “density” of a core city and the “dis- industries (Park and Markusen 1995). Since tance” to the core city were important in the the mid-1980s, high-technology industries industrialization phase, as rapid industrial- such as semiconductors have been increas- ization was accompanied by rapid urban- ingly favored. Since the 1990s, especially ization. The urbanization ratio (share of since the fi nancial crisis in November 1997, cities with a population more than 20,000) the Korean government has sought to increased from 35.9 percent in 1960 to 78.6 promote the development of knowledge- percent in 1990. Most of the rapidly growing intensive industries with the intention of cities during the last four decades were in the opening up the country to trade and capi- suburban areas of Seoul and the southeast tal movements, restructuring the economy, region. In addition, most industrial cities including the fi nancial sector, and making grew rapidly, suggesting that agglomeration the labor market more fl exible. Regional or scale economies were important. Most innovation has been the key policy in the of the industrial cities in these regions were twenty-fi rst century (see fi gure 19.3).
Recommended publications
  • Case Study North Rhine-Westphalia
    Contract No. 2008.CE.16.0.AT.020 concerning the ex post evaluation of cohesion policy programmes 2000‐2006 co‐financed by the European Regional Development Fund (Objectives 1 and 2) Work Package 4 “Structural Change and Globalisation” CASE STUDY NORTH RHINE‐WESTPHALIA (DE) Prepared by Christian Hartmann (Joanneum Research) for: European Commission Directorate General Regional Policy Policy Development Evaluation Unit CSIL, Centre for Industrial Studies, Milan, Italy Joanneum Research, Graz, Austria Technopolis Group, Brussels, Belgium In association with Nordregio, the Nordic Centre for Spatial Development, Stockholm, Sweden KITE, Centre for Knowledge, Innovation, Technology and Enterprise, Newcastle, UK Case Study – North Rhine‐Westphalia (DE) Acronyms BERD Business Expenditure on R&D DPMA German Patent and Trade Mark Office ERDF European Regional Development Fund ESF European Social Fund EU European Union GERD Gross Domestic Expenditure on R&D GDP Gross Domestic Product GRP Gross Regional Product GVA Gross Value Added ICT Information and Communication Technology IWR Institute of the Renewable Energy Industry LDS State Office for Statistics and Data Processing NGO Non‐governmental Organisation NPO Non‐profit Organisation NRW North Rhine‐Westphalia NUTS Nomenclature of Territorial Units for Statistics PPS Purchasing Power Standard REN Rational Energy Use and Exploitation of Renewable Resources R&D Research and Development RTDI Research, Technological Development and Innovation SME Small and Medium Enterprise SPD Single Programming Document
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Growth and Structural Change in South Asia: Miracle Or Mirage?
    Economic Growth and Structural Change in South Asia: Miracle or Mirage? Joint Paper: International Growth Centre, Pakistan Programme, and Development Policy Research Center, School of Humanities, Social Sciences and Law, Lahore University of Management Sciences. The Team This monograph has been prepared by Dr Ijaz Nabi with assistance from Abdul Malik, Rabin Working Hattari (World Bank), Turab Husain, Adeel Shafqat, Sana Anwaar, and Ammar Rashid (Lahore University of Management Sciences Paper 10/0859 March, 2010 International Growth Centre London School of Economics and Political Science 4th Floor, Tower Two Houghton Street London WC2A 2AE United Kingdom For media or communications enquiries, please contact Adam Green [email protected] Directed and Organised by www.theigc.org Acknowledgements Special thanks is owed to Praful Patel for making space in the South Asia region, World Bank, work program for this monograph, to Shanta Devarajan, Sadiq Ahmed and John Roome for supporting the work with their timely interventions. The monograph also benefited from excellent comments and suggestions at presentations at Georgetown University, School of Advanced International Studies, Brown University, London School of Economics, Lahore University of Management Sciences, Lahore School of Economics, Applied Economics Research Center, Karachi, Government College University, Lahore, Planning Commission, Government of Pakistan, Islamabad, Center for Policy Dialogue, Bangladesh and Institute of Policy Studies, Sri Lanka. Former colleagues at the World
    [Show full text]
  • Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Developing Countries
    Eastern Illinois University The Keep Masters Theses Student Theses & Publications 2017 Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Developing Countries Ahmed Salim Nuhu Eastern Illinois University This research is a product of the graduate program in Economics at Eastern Illinois University. Find out more about the program. Recommended Citation Nuhu, Ahmed Salim, "Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Developing Countries" (2017). Masters Theses. 2700. https://thekeep.eiu.edu/theses/2700 This is brought to you for free and open access by the Student Theses & Publications at The Keep. It has been accepted for inclusion in Masters Theses by an authorized administrator of The Keep. For more information, please contact [email protected]. The Graduate School � EASTERN ILLINOIS UNIVERSITY Thes is Maintenance andReproduction Certificate FOR: Graduate Candidates Completing Theses in Partial Fulfillment of the Degree Graduate Faculty Advisors Directing the Theses RE: Preservation, Reproduction, and Distribution of Thesis Research Preserving, reproducing, and distributing thesis research is an important part of Booth Library's responsibility to provide access to scholarship. In order to further this goal, Booth Library makes all graduate theses completed as part of a degree program at Eastern Illinois University available for personal study, research, and other not-for-profit educational purposes. Under 17 U.S.C. § 108, the library may reproduce and distribute a copy without infringing on copyright; however, professional courtesy dictates that permission be requested from the author before doing so. Your signatures affirm the following: • The graduate candidate is the author of this thesis. • The graduate candidate retains the copyright and intellectual property rights associated with the original research, creative activity, and intellectual or artistic content of the thesis.
    [Show full text]
  • Experiences from Structural Change in the Ruhr Area ISBN 978-3-946211-21-1
    JUST TRANSITION FOR REGIONS AND GENERATIONS Experiences from structural change in the Ruhr area ISBN 978-3-946211-21-1 JUST TRANSITION FOR REGIONS AND GENERATIONS Experiences from structural change in the Ruhr area Research study conducted on behalf of WWF Germany by Imprint Published by WWF Germany, Berlin Date January 2019 Authors Elke Dahlbeck, Dr. Stefan Gärtner (Institut für Arbeit und Technik) Coordination Juliette de Grandpré ( WWF Germany) Contact [email protected] Editor Thomas Köberich (WWF Germany) Design Anna Risch ([email protected]) The European Climate Initiative (EUKI) is a project financing instrument by the German Federal Ministry for the Environment, Nature Conserva- tion and Nuclear Safety (BMU). Its implementation is supported by the Deutsche Gesellschaft für Internationale Zusammenarbeit (GIZ) GmbH. It is the overarching goal of the EUKI to foster climate cooperation within the European Union (EU) in order to mitigate greenhouse gas emissions. The opinions put forward in this publication are the sole responsibility of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Ministry for the Environment, Nature Conservation and Nuclear Safety. © 2019 WWF Germany · No reprint of the report or extracts thereof without the publisher’s permission. Worldwide, it has become clear that Foreword global warming is the greatest eco- logical and social challenge of our time. Achieving the climate targets are part of a bigger scheme: a global transition in Germany and Europe towards a society that no longer relies on fossil fuels. This transition is the only possible response to the climate crisis, and in its magnitude and significance comparable to such major historical upheavals as industrialisation or digitalisation.
    [Show full text]
  • Structural Change, Industrial Upgrading and Middle Income Trap Preliminary Working Draft Please Do Not Quote Or Cite Without
    Preliminary Working Draft Please do not quote or cite without author’s permission Contact: [email protected] Structural Change, Industrial Upgrading and Middle Income Trap Justin Yifu Liny, Yong Wangz This version: Februrary 2019 Abstract Motivated by several stylized facts about middle-income trap, we develop a simple multi- sector general equilibrium model of structural change and industrial upgrading. The model features the distinction between production service and consumption service and the input- output linkages between di¤erent sectors. We show that the role of production service is asymmetric at di¤erent levels of development. Whereas an underdeveloped sector of production service is not a binding obstacle for development (sometimes even bene…cial) at an early stage of development, it becomes a key bottleneck when the economy reaches a middle-income status. To escape the middle-income trap, government intervention is needed to prevent premature de-industralization and facilitate bene…cial industrial upgrad- ing. Moreover, it also requires a timely reduction of entry barrier to the production service and improvement in its productivity. These theoretical …ndings are shown to be consistent with the stylized facts and also useful to China. The analysis provides a justi…cation for the government’sstrategic use of industrial policies to avoid middle-income trap. Key Words: Structural Change, Industrial Policies, Middle-Income Trap, Chinese Economy, Economic Growth JEL Codes: O11, O14, O33, O41 Institute of New Structural Economics, Peking University, Phone: 86-10-62757375, Fax: 86-10-62751474, Emaily address: [email protected]; Corresponding Author. Institute of New Structural Economics, Peking University, Mailing Address: No.
    [Show full text]
  • War Reparations, Structural Change, and Intergenerational Mobility
    War Reparations, Structural Change, and Intergenerational Mobility Matti Mitrunen* January 2, 2019 Please see the latest version here Abstract This paper presents evidence that government industrial promotion can move labor out of agriculture into manufacturing and have long-term effects via increased human capital accumulation in the next generation. I use variation generated by the Finnish war reparations (1944-1952) that forced the largely agrarian Finland to give 5% of its yearly GDP in industrial products to the Soviet Union. To meet the terms, the Finnish government provided short-term industrial support that persistently raised the employment and production of the treated, skill-intensive industries. I trace the impact of the policy using individual-level registry data and show that the likelihood of leaving agriculture for manufacturing and services increased substantially in municipalities more affected by the war reparations shock. These effects were persistent: 20 years after the intervention, the reallocated workers remained in their new sectors and had higher wages. Younger cohorts affected by the new skill-intensive opportunities obtained higher education and were more likely to work in white-collar occupations by 1970. Finally, I link parents to children to study how the policy affected intergenerational mobility. I show that mobility in both incomes and education increased in the more exposed locations. *[email protected], Institute for International Economic Studies, Stockholm University. I thank my advisors Andreas
    [Show full text]
  • A Comparative Review of Structural Changes in South Korea and South Dakota Agriculture Larry Janssen South Dakota State University
    South Dakota State University Open PRAIRIE: Open Public Research Access Institutional Repository and Information Exchange Department of Economics Staff aP per Series Economics 10-15-2000 A Comparative Review of Structural Changes in South Korea and South Dakota Agriculture Larry Janssen South Dakota State University Yong Kwon Follow this and additional works at: http://openprairie.sdstate.edu/econ_staffpaper Part of the Economics Commons Recommended Citation Janssen, Larry and Kwon, Yong, "A Comparative Review of Structural Changes in South Korea and South Dakota Agriculture" (2000). Department of Economics Staff aP per Series. Paper 149. http://openprairie.sdstate.edu/econ_staffpaper/149 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Economics at Open PRAIRIE: Open Public Research Access Institutional Repository and Information Exchange. It has been accepted for inclusion in Department of Economics Staff aP per Series by an authorized administrator of Open PRAIRIE: Open Public Research Access Institutional Repository and Information Exchange. For more information, please contact [email protected]. A COMPARATIVE REVIEW OF STRUCTURAL CHANGES IN SOUTH KOREA AND SOUTH DAKOTA AGRICULTURE* by Dr. Larry L. Janssen** and Dr. Yong Dae Kwon** Economics Staff Paper No. 2000-12 October 2000 *Paper presented at International Agribusiness Session Seventh Annual South Dakota International Business Conference Rapid City, South Dakota October 5 - 7, 2000 **Dr. Janssen is Professor of Agricultural Economics at South Dakota State University and Dr. Kwon is Professor and Head of Agricultural Economics at Chungnam National University, Taejon, South Korea. Both professors have teaching and research interests in agricultural policy and economic development. Dr. Janssen recently participated in an SDSU faculty teaching exchange program to Chungnam National University, Taejon, South Korea, from March - June (spring semester) 2000.
    [Show full text]
  • World War II Casualties and Structural Change
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Eder, Christoph Working Paper Missing Men: World War II Casualties and Structural Change NRN Working Paper, NRN: The Austrian Center for Labor Economics and the Analysis of the Welfare State, No. 1403 Provided in Cooperation with: NRN: The Austrian Center for Labor Economics and the Analysis of the Welfare State, Johannes Kepler University Linz Suggested Citation: Eder, Christoph (2014) : Missing Men: World War II Casualties and Structural Change, NRN Working Paper, NRN: The Austrian Center for Labor Economics and the Analysis of the Welfare State, No. 1403, Johannes Kepler University Linz, NRN - The Austrian Center for Labor Economics and the Analysis of the Welfare State, Linz This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/115108 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte.
    [Show full text]
  • On the Determinants of Structural Change: an Exploratory Model
    On the determinants of structural change: an exploratory model Francisco Adilson Gabardoa, Gabriel Porcileb, Jo~aoBasilio Pereimac aResearcher at Nucleo of Economics and Complexity (NeX), Federal University of Paran´a(UFPR) bEconomic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (ECLAC), Chile and Department of Economics, Federal University of Paran´a(UFPR) cAssociate Professor of Economics at Federal University of Paran´a(UFPR) Abstract Economists still struggle to understand why some countries are so much richer than others. The shift of labour out of the agricultural sector into other such sectors as manufacturing and services is one important piece of this puzzle. Therefore, understanding not only the driving mechanisms and forces behind the process of structural change but also how these mechanisms interact and reinforce each other is crucial. In the present work we develop a parsimonious computational agent-based model (ABM) where structural change is driven by income and relative-price effects simultaneously. The income effect is generate by the assumption of a simple non-homothetic hierarchical demand structure where consumers spend their income according to a given priority as in Falkinger(1990, 1994) and Andersen(2001). The relative price effect derives from different rates of sectoral productivity growth. Our objective is not to present a full picture of the process of structural change, but to demonstrate that, given certain assumptions regarding agents' behaviour, the two effects proposed by the literature (income and relative-price) are not competing but actually complementary and mutually necessary to replicate the macroeconomic patterns observed in reality. Resumo Economistas ainda lutam para entender por que alguns pa´ısess~aomuito mais ricos do que outros.
    [Show full text]
  • GLOBAL TRENDS in RENEWABLE ENERGY INVESTMENT 2019 Frankfurt School-UNEP Centre/BNEF
    GLOBAL TRENDS IN RENEWABLE ENERGY INVESTMENT 2019 Frankfurt School-UNEP Centre/BNEF. 2019. Global Trends in Renewable Energy Investment 2019, http://www.fs-unep-centre.org (Frankfurt am Main) Copyright © Frankfurt School of Finance & Management gGmbH 2019. This publication may be reproduced in whole or in part in any form for educational or non-profit purposes without special permission from the copyright holder, as long as provided acknowledgement of the source is made. Frankfurt School – UNEP Collaborating Centre for Climate & Sustainable Energy Finance would appreciate receiving a copy of any publication that uses this publication as source. No use of this publication may be made for resale or for any other commercial purpose whatsoever without prior permission in writing from Frankfurt School of Finance & Management gGmbH. Disclaimer Frankfurt School of Finance & Management: The designations employed and the presentation of the material in this publication do not imply the expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of the Frankfurt School of Finance & Management concerning the legal status of any country, territory, city or area or of its authorities, or concerning delimitation of its frontiers or boundaries. Moreover, the views expressed do not necessarily represent the decision or the stated policy of the Frankfurt School of Finance & Management, nor does citing of trade names or commercial processes constitute endorsement. Cover photo courtesy of Bloomberg Mediasource. It shows the floating solar project at the Alto Rabagao dam in Portugal. Photos on pages 17, 18, 19, 25, 27, 33, 38, 39, 41, 47, 48, 55 and 58 courtesy of Bloomberg Mediasource. Photos on other pages reproduced with the permission of: Orsted (pages 14 and 64); Wood Group (page 23); NRG Systems (page 37); BayWa Renewable Energy (page 44); Mott MacDonald (pages 42 and 72); Angus McCrone (page 57); Kyocera (page 66); Orbital Marine Power (page 67); Alcazar Energy (page 69); Bioenergy Infrastructure Group (page 71).
    [Show full text]
  • Globalization, Structural Change, and Productivity Growth, with an Update on Africa
    World Development Vol. 63, pp. 11–32, 2014 Ó 2014 Published by Elsevier Ltd. 0305-750X/$ - see front matter www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2013.10.012 Globalization, Structural Change, and Productivity Growth, with an Update on Africa MARGARET MCMILLAN IFPRI, Washington DC, USA Tufts University, Medford, USA DANI RODRIK Harvard Kennedy School, Cambridge, USA and I´N˜ IGO VERDUZCO-GALLO * IFPRI, Washington DC, USA Summary. — Large gaps in labor productivity between the traditional and modern parts of the economy are a fundamental reality of developing societies. In this paper, we document these gaps, and emphasize that labor flows from low-productivity activities to high- productivity activities are a key driver of development. Our results show that since 1990 structural change has been growth reducing – with labor moving from low – to high- productivity sectors - in both Africa and Latin America, with the most striking changes taking place in Latin America. Our results also show that things seem to be turning around in Africa: after 2000, structural change contributed positively to Africa’s overall productivity growth. For Africa, these results are encouraging. Moreover, the very low levels of produc- tivity and industrialization across most of the continent indicate an enormous potential for growth through structural change. Ó 2014 Published by Elsevier Ltd. Key words — Africa, structural change, productivity growth 1. INTRODUCTION typically those that have experienced substantial growth- enhancing structural change. As we shall see, the bulk of the One of the earliest and most central insights of the literature difference between Asia’s recent growth, on the one hand, on economic development is that development entails struc- and Latin America’s and Africa’s, on the other, can be ex- tural change.
    [Show full text]
  • Structural Change Within the Service Sector and the Future of Baumol Disease∗
    Structural Change within the Service Sector and the Future of Baumol Disease∗ Georg Duernecker (University of Munich, CEPR, and IZA) Berthold Herrendorf (Arizona State University) Akos´ Valentinyi (University of Manchester, MTA KRTK, CEPR) July 30, 2017 Abstract Unbalanced growth slowdown is the reduction in aggregate productivity growth that results from the reallocation of economic activity to industries with low productivity growth. We show that unbalanced growth slowdown has considerably reduced past U.S. productivity growth and we assess by how much it will reduce future U.S. productivity growth. To achieve this, we build a novel model that generates the unbalanced growth slowdown of the postwar period. The model makes the surprising prediction that future reductions in aggregate productivity growth are limited. The reason for this is that the stagnant industries do not take over the model economy. Keywords: Productivity Slowdown; Structural Transformation; Unbalanced Growth. JEL classification: O41; O47; O51. ∗For comments and suggestions, we thank Zsofia´ Bar´ any,´ Marti Mastieri, Rachel Ngai, Richard Rogerson, Michael Sposi, and Gustavo Ventura. We also thank the audiences of presentations at Arizona State University, the Economic Growth and Fluctuations Group of the Barcelona Summer Forum 2017, the Bureau of Economic Anal- ysis, the CEPR European Summer Symposium of International Macroeconomics 2017, the Christmas Meeting of the German Expat Economists 2016, the European Monetary Forum 2016 at the Bank of England, the Federal Reserve Banks of Atlanta and St. Louis, the RIDGE Workshop on Growth and Development 2016, Erasmus Uni- versity Rotterdam, the SED Meeting 2017, Southern Methodist University, the University of Manchester, Western University, and the World Bank.
    [Show full text]