A) the Economic Rationale for Trade Net Effect on the Terms-Of-Trade, but Lead to a Agreements Contraction of Trade Volumes Which Reduces Overall Welfare (See Box 1

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

A) the Economic Rationale for Trade Net Effect on the Terms-Of-Trade, but Lead to a Agreements Contraction of Trade Volumes Which Reduces Overall Welfare (See Box 1 II – B FLEXIBILITY IN TRADE AGREEMENTS B FLEXIBILITY IN TRADE AGREEMENTS The aim of this section is to: (a) clarify what Economists have identified several rationales for justifies the inclusion of contingency measures in the existence of trade agreements, such as those trade agreements; (b) provide an account of all embodied in the WTO, and its antecedent, the circumstances when a suspension of commitments General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). may make economic sense; and (c) identify the Two main approaches can be distinguished.1 The flexibility measures built into WTO agreements. first states that in the absence of a trade agreement, The section provides a framework for the discussion a country may be tempted to manipulate the of specific contingency measures in the subsequent terms-of-trade (i.e. the price of its exports relative sections of the Report. to its imports) in order to increase its national income at the expense of its trading partners. The 1. ECONOMIC THEORIES OF second approach stresses the economic and political TRADE AGREEMENTS AND THE difficulties that governments face in setting trade policy. As discussed below, trade agreements allow ROLE OF FLEXIBILITIES governments to escape terms-of-trade conflicts and/ or to resist pressures from the private sector and Trade agreements aim to strike a balance between special-interest groups urging the government to flexibility and commitments. If there is too deviate from a liberal trade policy. much flexibility, the value of the commitment is undermined. If there is too little flexibility, countries i) The traditional approach to trade agreements may refuse to make deep commitments or may easily renege on such commitments. This section explores The main logic of the terms-of-trade (or traditional) how this trade-off works. It reviews the economic approach is that countries that have market power rationale for international trade cooperation and (i.e. that can influence their terms-of-trade) cannot explains the reason for the inclusion of flexibilities resist the temptation to act in their own interests. in a trade agreement. It is important to highlight Johnson (1954) analyzes a situation where each the distinction between the initial motivations for country sets trade policy in an attempt to improve introducing flexibilities and the consequences of its terms-of-trade and increase national income. The using such flexibilities. This section focuses on the resulting “non-cooperative equilibrium” (known as reasons for including flexibilities while the effects Nash equilibrium) is inefficient as the unilateral of specific measures are examined in Sections C actions of countries cancel out one another. More and D. restrictive trade policies by all countries have little (a) The economic rationale for trade net effect on the terms-of-trade, but lead to a agreements contraction of trade volumes which reduces overall welfare (see Box 1). There has long been a solid argument in favour of free trade based on economic efficiency. Based on this premise, there is no need for trade agreements since governments intent on maximizing national welfare would consider any deviation from free trade as a self-defeating choice. Notwithstanding this well-known argument, unilateral trade policies that inefficiently restrict trade flows do occur and trade agreements that aim to limit such unilateral actions are in place. 21 WORLD TRADE REPORT 2009 Box 1 Terms-of-trade and the international cost-shifting problem This box examines why countries may be Importantly, however, terms-of-trade manipulation tempted to exploit terms-of-trade effects and why is a “beggar-thy-neighbour” type of policy. The such unilateral behaviour leads to an inefficient benefit to Country A comes at the expense outcome, i.e. a reduction in global welfare. of welfare in Country B. This is because the Consider two large trading partners, Country A tariff can be seen as a tax partly paid by foreign and Country B. Each government can choose free producers who cannot fully pass it on to domestic trade or impose a tariff on imported goods. What consumers and, therefore, end up bearing part of will be the welfare effect if Country A imposes a the burden. As the government in Country A does tariff on imports from Country B? How will the nothing to offset the negative effect that the tariff tariff affect the welfare of Country B? imposes on foreign producers, it has adopted a policy which is inefficient from the point of view When the government of a large country imposes of global welfare. This is the beggar-thy-neighbour a tariff on an imported good, it reduces the that the terms-of-trade theory identifies. demand for that good in the international market as domestic residents will buy less of it at the The last step is to understand what would be higher domestic price. Because the consumers the optimal trade policy in Country B given the in Country A represent such a large proportion strategy of the government in Country A. If the of the market, this fall in demand for the good government in Country B chooses free trade, produced in Country B depresses its price in it is hurt by the tariff imposed by its trading the international market, which in turn implies partner. If, on the other hand, the government that Country A obtains its imports at a lower in Country B imposes its own tariff on goods international price than before. This positive effect produced in Country A, it will also benefit from of a tariff on the country’s welfare is the terms- an improvement in its terms-of-trade. This is why of-trade effect.2 Country A will set this benefit unilateral policy setting leads trading partners to against the costs of trade restrictions, which arise retaliate against each other. Both governments because of the expansion of inefficient domestic impose trade restrictions, creating a situation often production and the reduction in consumer choice called “trade war”. In this situation, the benefits that the tariff introduces. of the terms-of-trade are generally cancelled out (with neither country gaining from it) while the imposition of the tariffs reduces global welfare. This situation, which is often referred to as a It is important to note that an agreement facilitates “Prisoners’ Dilemma” driven by terms-of-trade, trade cooperation, but does not eliminate the can be avoided through a trade agreement between signatories’ beggar-thy-neighbour temptations. In countries allowing them to cooperate rather than act the absence of external punishment mechanisms, unilaterally.3 By cooperating in binding agreements a trade agreement needs to be “self-enforcing”: to reduce their trade restrictions, countries overcome signatories will abide as long as respecting the this inefficiency (Mayer, 1981). Interestingly, the agreement is in their own interest. This implies purpose of a trade agreement in this situation is that the short-term gains from deviating from the not tied to the assumption that governments choose commitment must be balanced by the long-term trade policy to maximize national income. Even loss from retaliation. when governments are concerned about the political consequences of their tariff choices, Bagwell and ii) The commitment approach to trade Staiger (1999; 2002) show that the two main agreements features of the GATT/WTO system, the principles of reciprocity and non-discrimination, are simple While the traditional approach to trade agreements rules that allow countries to escape the terms-of- emphasizes an international source of inefficiency trade driven Prisoners’ Dilemma.4 in trade policy (i.e. the temptation of countries to act in a non-cooperative manner), commitment 22 II – B FLEXIBILITY IN TRADE AGREEMENTS theory focuses on a domestic source of inefficiency. through which time-inconsistent trade policy may When setting trade policy, a government may be lead to inefficiencies (a partial list includes Staiger unable to make credible economic and/or political and Tabellini, 1987; Matsuyama, 1990 and Amin, commitments to the private sector or the parliament. 2003). In these models, the government wishes to use discretionary trade policy to increase social The lack of economic commitment leads to a welfare (for example, in response to unexpected so-called time-inconsistency problem. This is a events, or to allow temporary protection to an situation where the decision of the government to infant industry, etc.). However, the use of trade implement a certain policy at some future time policy changes the behaviour of participants in the is not optimal when the future period arrives. economy. If agents anticipate the policy that the Therefore, the statement that the policy will be government will implement, they can react to it in a implemented in the future is not credible (see Box way that will reduce the impact that it has on them. 2). The notion of time inconsistency has been This implies that the government will not be able to applied to trade policy in a large number of studies use discretionary trade policy as intended, and this which highlight several different mechanisms results in a socially inefficient trade policy. Box 2 Time-inconsistency The following example illustrates the time- In both situations, the problem becomes one inconsistency problem. A teacher informs her of finding a means of credibly committing to class that there will be an algebra test next week. carrying out the originally stated action – that This is the “optimal” action – the threat of the is, to hold the exam or maintain low inflationary test encourages the students to work hard which policies. For example, the teacher might promise is good for both the teacher and the students. to report the students’ results to a higher body, However, when next week arrives, the teacher and the government might delegate responsibility has the opportunity to rethink whether or not to for monetary policy to a Central Bank which is actually hold the test.
Recommended publications
  • The Effects of ASEAN Free Trade Are to Its Members
    Asia-Pacific Research and Training Network on Trade Working Paper Series, No. 21, November 2006 Determinants of AFTA Members’ Trade Flows and Potential for Trade Diversion By Indira M. Hapsari and Carlos Mangunsong* *Indira M. Hapsari and Carlos Mangunsong are Research Assistant at the Department of Economics Centre for Strategic and International Studies (CSIS) and Teaching Assistant at the Faculty of Economics, University of Indonesia, The views presented in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of CSIS, ARTNeT members, partners and the United Nations. This study was conducted as part of the Asia-Pacific Research and Training Network on Trade (ARTNeT) initiative, aimed at building regional trade policy and facilitation research capacity in developing countries. This work was carried out with the aid of a grant from the International Development Research Centre, Ottawa, Canada. The technical support of the United Nations Economic and Social Commission for Asia and the Pacific is gratefully acknowledged. Any remaining errors are the responsibility of the authors. The authors may be contacted at [email protected] and [email protected] The Asia-Pacific Research and Training Network on Trade (ARTNeT) aims at building regional trade policy and facilitation research capacity in developing countries. The ARTNeT Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about trade issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. ARTNeT working papers are available online at: www.artnetontrade.org.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 2 New Challenges to the Export Oriented Growth Model
    Chapter 2 New Challenges to the Export Oriented Growth Model Song Hong Institute of World Economics and Politics (IWEP), Chinese Academy of Social Sciences (CASS) December 2012 This chapter should be cited as Song, H. (2012), ‘New Challenges to the Export Oriented Growth Model’, in Zhang, Y., F. Kimura and S. Oum (eds.), Moving Toward a New Development Model for East Asia- The Role of Domestic Policy and Regional Cooperation . ERIA Research Project Report 2011-10, Jakarta: ERIA. pp.27-54. CHAPTER 2 New Challenges to the Export Oriented Growth Model SONG HONG Institute of World Economics and Politics (IWEP), Chinese Academy of Social Sciences (CASS) The export-oriented strategy played a crucial role for the successful development of East Asian economies after the World War II. They first exported low-technology manufactured goods, then gradually upgraded and transformed their export goods packages and finally caught up with the developed countries. Export oriented strategy in East Asia has been based on a series of internal and external conditions. Those conditions includes an open international environment, the existence of a certain size of external market, a stable supply of raw materials, as well as good and convenient navigation, and some internal conditions. Global financial crisis badly changed some of these conditions. For example, the external market was very unstable and was growing very slow; after the financial crisis, international raw material and energy prices experienced sharp volatility, which caused great challenges to the countries and enterprises seeking to implement an export oriented strategy. However, after the financial crisis the changes in international and domestic environments did not change the nature and trends of globalization, only temporarily slowed the pace of this process.
    [Show full text]
  • Structural Change in the World Economy and Forms of Protectionism
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Altvater, Elmar Article — Digitized Version Structural change in the world economy and forms of protectionism Intereconomics Suggested Citation: Altvater, Elmar (1988) : Structural change in the world economy and forms of protectionism, Intereconomics, ISSN 0020-5346, Verlag Weltarchiv, Hamburg, Vol. 23, Iss. 6, pp. 286-296, http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/BF02925126 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/140159 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu PROTECTIONISM Elmar Altvater* Structural Change in the World Economy and Forms of Protectionism Warnings about the dangers of protectionism are being heard from a// sides at present. However, rehearsing the advantages of free trade and the drawbacks of protectionism is to/itt/e avai/ if it fai/s to take account of the/imitations that the internationa/ context imposes on nationa/ economic po/icy.
    [Show full text]
  • A. the GATT and the BWI
    International Organizations Law Review 3: 267–315, 2006 ©2006 Koninklijke Brill NV, Leiden, The Netherlands. INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC POLICY-MAKING: EXPLORING THE LEGAL LINKAGES BETWEEN THE WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION AND THE BRETTON WOODS INSTITUTIONS JAN WOUTERS1 AND DOMINIC COPPENS2 This contribution aims to shed some light upon the legal relationship between the three main pillars of the international economic architecture: the World Trade Organization (WTO), and its predecessor the GATT 1947, focusing on trade; the International Monetary Fund (IMF or Fund), guarding international monetary and financial stability; and the World Bank, specializing in the field of development. We will examine various aspects of the legal interactions between, on the one hand, the GATT/WTO, and, on the other hand, the IMF and the World Bank, labeled as the Bretton Woods Institutions (BWI). The general legal linkages between the three institutions are first of all explored from a historical perspec- tive (Section I). Section II elaborates upon the different levels of consultation between the WTO and BWI, whereas Section III discusses the involvement of the WTO and BWI in the deliverance of Aid for Trade, which by definition raises interesting questions of collaboration between aid and trade institutions. Finally, various aspects of the legal interactions between the WTO and the BWI are analysed more in depth (Section IV), namely, (i) the relationship between BWI programmes and WTO rules (the substantive level), and (ii) the role of the BWI in the dispute settlement
    [Show full text]
  • International Trade
    International Trade or centuries, people of the world have traded. From the ancient silk routes and spice trade to modern F shipping containers and satellite data transfers, nations have tied their economies to the rest of the world by complex flows of products and services. Free trade, which allows traders to interact without barriers imposed by government, can improve the living standards of people because it reduces prices and increases the variety of goods and services for consumers. It can also create new jobs and opportunities, and it encourages innovative uses of resources. However, even though free trade can benefit an economy as a whole, specific groups may be hurt. While certain sectors will experience job gains, others will face job losses. Still, societies throughout history have found that the benefits of international trade outweigh the costs. Why Trade? As consumers, all of us have an interest in trading they live, is because they believe they will be better with other countries. We often are unaware of trade’s off by trading. When we consider the alternative— influence on product prices and the quality and each of us producing everything for ourselves—trade availability of the goods we buy. But we all benefit simply makes more sense. from the greater abundance and variety of products and the lower prices that trading with others makes Trade is beneficial because it allows people to possible. Without trade, countries become isolated. specialize, or concentrate their work in the type of The quality of their goods and services lags behind production that they do best.
    [Show full text]
  • Sustainable Growth Based on Export-Oriented Economic Strategy : the Bulgarian Case in an International Comparison
    ECONOMIC POLICY ANALYSES Sustainable Growth Based on Export-Oriented Economic Strategy The Bulgarian Case in an International Comparison Prof. András Inotai This paper aims at identifying the strengths and weaknesses of the Bulgarian economy’s transformation to a more dynamic and export-oriented growth model. By referring to two groups of countries – Central European EU member states as well as the Western Balkans, the study puts an emphasis on the impact the EU membership and the 2009 crisis year have on the Bulgarian foreign trade and export performance in particular. The first chapter gathers arguments in favour of the export-oriented growth model but also addresses potential risk factors of such long-term policy. Despite some drawbacks as increasing vulnerability and de- pendence on external factors, this development path is justified as the better way for achieving sustainable economic growth of small economies like Bulgaria. The second chapter deals with the global financial crisis and its influence on the exports and foreign trade in general. Then, the author focuses on Bulgaria’s export performance in the EU and on a regional compari- son by stressing on the role of foreign direct investments in the export orientation of the country. Finally, the paper concludes by summarizing measures and instruments for catching-up export-driven economic development and by formulating policy recommendations supporting the successful implementa- tion of such an export-led growth model. April 2013 Imprint Orders All texts are available online Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung Economic www.fes.bg Office Bulgaria Policy Institute 97, Knjaz Boris I St. Yasen Georgiev The views expressed in this publication 1000 Sofia, Bulgaria are not necessarily those of the Responsible: e-mail: [email protected] Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung or of the Regine Schubert, Director Fax: (+359 2) 9522693 organization for which the author works.
    [Show full text]
  • International Trade: Who Is Left Behind and What to Do About It”
    Department of Economic & Social Affairs CDP Background Paper No. 45 ST/ESA/2018/CDP/45 Rev.1 December 2018 International trade or technology? Who is left behind and what to do about it* Ann Harrison** ABSTRACT We examine globalization’s effects on those left behind in both industrial and emerging mar- kets. While access to global markets has lifted billions out of poverty in emerging markets, the benefits have not been equally shared. Increased competition through globalization as well as skill-biased technical change has hurt less educated workers in rich and poor countries. While much of the rising inequality is often attributed to globalization alone, a brief review of the literature suggests that labor-saving technology has likely played an even more important role. The backlash has focused on the negative consequences of globalization in developed countries, and now threatens the global trading system and access to that system for emerging markets. We conclude by proposing some solutions to compensate losers from the twin forces of techni- cal change and globalization. Keywords: trade, “leaving no one behind”, globalization, inequality JEL Classification: F02, F16, D63 * This paper replaces a previous version entitled “International Trade: Who is left behind and what to do about it”. ** Member of the Committee for Development Policy (CDP); University of California, Berkeley Haas; research associate at the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER). All errors remain those of the author. CONTENTS 1 Countries left behind by globalization ....................................................................... 3 2 Individuals left behind by globalization in emerging markets ................................................ 9 3 Individuals left behind in industrial countries: disentangling globalization and technology ..................
    [Show full text]
  • United Arab Emirates (Uae)
    Library of Congress – Federal Research Division Country Profile: United Arab Emirates, July 2007 COUNTRY PROFILE: UNITED ARAB EMIRATES (UAE) July 2007 COUNTRY اﻟﻌﺮﺑﻴّﺔ اﻟﻤﺘّﺤﺪة (Formal Name: United Arab Emirates (Al Imarat al Arabiyah al Muttahidah Dubai , أﺑﻮ ﻇﺒﻲ (The seven emirates, in order of size, are: Abu Dhabi (Abu Zaby .اﻹﻣﺎرات Al ,ﻋﺠﻤﺎن Ajman , أ مّ اﻟﻘﻴﻮﻳﻦ Umm al Qaywayn , اﻟﺸﺎرﻗﺔ (Sharjah (Ash Shariqah ,دﺑﻲّ (Dubayy) .رأس اﻟﺨﻴﻤﺔ and Ras al Khaymah ,اﻟﻔﺠﻴﺮة Fajayrah Short Form: UAE. اﻣﺮاﺗﻰ .(Term for Citizen(s): Emirati(s أﺑﻮ ﻇﺒﻲ .Capital: Abu Dhabi City Major Cities: Al Ayn, capital of the Eastern Region, and Madinat Zayid, capital of the Western Region, are located in Abu Dhabi Emirate, the largest and most populous emirate. Dubai City is located in Dubai Emirate, the second largest emirate. Sharjah City and Khawr Fakkan are the major cities of the third largest emirate—Sharjah. Independence: The United Kingdom announced in 1968 and reaffirmed in 1971 that it would end its treaty relationships with the seven Trucial Coast states, which had been under British protection since 1892. Following the termination of all existing treaties with Britain, on December 2, 1971, six of the seven sheikhdoms formed the United Arab Emirates (UAE). The seventh sheikhdom, Ras al Khaymah, joined the UAE in 1972. Public holidays: Public holidays other than New Year’s Day and UAE National Day are dependent on the Islamic calendar and vary from year to year. For 2007, the holidays are: New Year’s Day (January 1); Muharram, Islamic New Year (January 20); Mouloud, Birth of Muhammad (March 31); Accession of the Ruler of Abu Dhabi—observed only in Abu Dhabi (August 6); Leilat al Meiraj, Ascension of Muhammad (August 10); first day of Ramadan (September 13); Eid al Fitr, end of Ramadan (October 13); UAE National Day (December 2); Eid al Adha, Feast of the Sacrifice (December 20); and Christmas Day (December 25).
    [Show full text]
  • A Patchwork Planet 29
    patchwork A planet beneficial co-operation of governance. If so, you are likely find- The Covid-19 crisis has exposed the ing the coronavirus crisis even more depressing. From Donald arbitrary way in which we have stitched Trump’s branding of the disease as a specifically “Chinese virus” and his defunding of the World Health Organisation (WHO), to globalisation together. It’s time to go the violation of rules about sharing medical data and an unseemly back to first principles, and tailor a new scramble to secure masks and ventilators amid unilateral export restrictions, there is scant sign of global harmony just now. set of international rules around them The irony, of course, is that at the same time the virus risks setting globalisation (as we have conventionally understood it) spinning into reverse, it is also affirming anew our shared fate dani rodrik as human beings. That might seem like a paradox, but in fact our present-day globalisation is not and never has been the only way—or the best way—of meshing together our economies and other interests. And it is not only scholars in ivory towers who are wondering if this is a moment for a reset. hat do you think of when you hear the word “glo- President Macron of France is both a determined economic balisation?” It might well be the usual newspa- liberal and former investment banker, and yet he used a major per illustration—the container ship that moves interview with the Financial Times in April to concede that amid merchandise round the world.
    [Show full text]
  • Djibouti Health Expenditure Profile
    Djibouti Health expenditure profile HEALTH SPENDING IN BRIEF WHO PAYS FOR HEALTH? 0.6% Health spending (% of GDP) 3.5 27.8% Health expenditure per capita (US$) 70 Public Out-of-pocket 45.8% Public spending on health per capita (US$) 32 Voluntary prepayment External Other GDP per capita (US$) 2,004 25.8% Life expectancy, both sexes (years) 62 RICHER COUNTRIES SPEND MORE ON HEALTH… …BUT NOT NECESSARILY AS A SHARE OF GDP 10,000 25 20 1,000 15 10 100 Health spending % of GDP 5 Health spending per capita (US$, log scale) 10 0 100 1,000 10,000 100,000 100 1,000 10,000 100,000 GDP per capita (US$, log scale) GDP per capita (US$, log scale) MORE GOVERNMENT SPENDING ON HEALTH IS ASSOCIATED WITH LOWER OUT-OF-POCKET SPENDING DOES GOVERNMENT SPEND ENOUGH ON HEALTH? 100 100 10 80 80 8 60 60 6 % US$ 40 40 4 20 20 2 Out-of-pocket spending % of health 0 0 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 Public spending on health % of GDP Health spending per capita (US$, bars) Government health spending % of total government spending (line) Djibouti PRIORITY OF HEALTH IN BUDGET ALLOCATION IS A POLITICAL CHOICE 25 20 15 10 5 Government health spending % of total government spending 0 India Egypt Kenya Congo Nigeria Angola Kiribati Ghana Bhutan SudanBoliviaJordan Tunisia Djibouti Vanuatu Armenia Ukraine Zambia Morocco Georgia Eswatini Lao PDRPakistan Myanmar TajikistanMongolia IndonesiaSri LankaViet Nam Honduras Cameroon MauritaniaMicronesia Cambodia Philippines Uzbekistan GuatemalaNicaraguaEl Salvador Timor-LesteBangladesh Côte d'Ivoire Cabo Verde Solomon
    [Show full text]
  • Trends Gross and Net Spending Non-Cash Benefits
    8. PUBLIC EXPENDITURE ON PENSIONS Key Results Public spending on cash old-age pensions and survivors’ benefits in the OECD increased from an average of 6.6% of gross domestic product (GDP) to 8.0% between 2000 and 2015. Public pensions are often the largest single item of social expenditure, accounting for 18.4% of total government spending on average in 2015. Greece spent the largest proportion of national income Trends on public pensions among OECD countries in 2015: 16.9% of Public pension spending was fairly stable as a GDP. Other countries with high gross public pension proportion of GDP over the period 1990-2015 in spending are in continental Europe, with Italy at 16.2% and ten countries: Australia, Germany, Iceland, Israel, Lithuania, Austria, France and Portugal at between 13% and 14% of New Zealand, Poland, Slovenia, Sweden and Switzerland. GDP. Public pensions generally account for between one- fourth and one-third of total public expenditure in these Public pension expenditure increased by more than 4 countries. points of GDP between 2000 and 2015 in Finland, Greece, Portugal and Turkey, and between 2 and 3 percentage points Iceland and Mexico spent 2.1% and 2.2% of GDP on in France, Italy, Japan and Spain. public pensions, respectively. Korea is also a low spender at 2.9% of GDP. Mexico has a relative young population, which Gross and net spending is also the case but to a lesser extent in Iceland, where much of retirement income is provided by compulsory The penultimate column of the table shows public occupational schemes (see the next indicator of “Pension- spending in net terms: after taxes and contributions paid on benefit expenditures: Public and private”), leaving a lesser benefits.
    [Show full text]
  • English Geneva, 19 May 1998
    WORLD TRADE WT/FIFTY/H/ST/1 19 May 1998 ORGANIZATION (98-2004) 50th ANNIVERSARY Original: English Geneva, 19 May 1998 SINGAPORE Statement circulated by H.E. Mr. Goh Chok Tong Prime Minister The Multilateral Trading System: Challenges and opportunities 1. This is an important occasion to toast the success as well as ponder over the future of the multilateral trading system. 2. Together with the Bretton Woods Institutions, the GATT has provided the foundation for post-war global prosperity. Through a non-discriminatory system of rules governing international trade, it has underpinned the robust post-war growth in trade and output. Without the multilateral trading system, the world would not be as prosperous as it is today, nor as peaceful. 3. The benefits of multilateral trade cannot be evenly spread by decree. Each country has to compete for its share of the benefits through its own hard work, efficiency and competitiveness. Competition is tough, but every country can find some areas where they can do well. 4. Developing countries have shown this to be true. Over the past decade, their share of world trade has increased from 20 per cent to 25 per cent, while their share of trade in manufactured goods has doubled from 10 per cent to 20 per cent. 5. The remarkable success of the GATT, however, is rather recent history. The “beggar-thy-neighbour” policies that were pursued duringthe inter-war period broughtdisaster to world trade and the global economy and contributed to the 2nd World War. The most-favoured-nation principle is very much a post-war phenomenon.
    [Show full text]