<<

Environmental , Political Economy and Change: Frameworks and Tools for Research and Analysis • Ronnie D. Lipschutz*

RonnieEnvironmental D. Lipschutz History, Political Economy and Change What kinds of insights can environmental history provide that would enhance understanding of the political economy and sociology of human-nature rela- tionships?1 And what tools can such political economy and sociology offer in the search for environmental policies and strategies leading to sustainable, rather than destructive, relationships between human societies and nature? These two questions motivate this article, although they only begin to address what is clearly a complex undertaking:crafting environmental policies that are just and democratic, as well as sustainable and effective. Behind these questions lie others:Why engage in such an effort? Who beneªts? From whose standpoint is the activity to be undertaken? What is an appropriate analytical framework? What approaches to the study of the of some places will best inform at- tempts to describe what is happening today and what might occur in the future in other places? This article represents the cumulation of several years of thought and writ- ing focused on all of these questions.2 The substance of my argument is as fol- lows:While most environmental history is seen as having to do with landscapes past and how they got that way, environmental history can also have practical contemporary applications. By coming to understand the sources and origins of environmental degradation, and the patterns of social organization that led to them, we may be better positioned to foster environmental protection and conservation in ways that may resolve and/or support local efforts around

* This article was originally prepared for presentation in an APSA , and Envi- ronmental Politics Workshop on “New Frontiers in Environmental Research,” Northeastern University, Boston, Mass., September 2, 1998. Parts of the article are drawn from a number of earlier memorandums, thinkpieces and proposals. Zsuzsanna Gille was an original co-author of earlier versions of several parts of this paper, while Carolyn Merchant, Margaret FitzSimmons, Carolyn Pomeroy, and two anonymous readers, among others, made substantive and editorial contributions along the way. 1. I use the lower-case term “nature” to refer to the biogeophysical world, and the upper-case term “Nature” to refer to the ideological/ideational concept. 2. Lipschutz 1996.

Global 1:3, August 2001 © 2001 by the Massachusetts Institute of Technology

72

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/152638001316881412 by guest on 30 September 2021 Ronnie D. Lipschutz • 73

the world. Such studies can help to address conºicts that arise over conservation policies, especially when these studies illuminate the origins and historical trajectories of places, and provide insights into ways of working with, rather than against, local , knowledges, and social arrangements. In other words, to understand, imagine, and shape landscapes in the future, we need to know how they were created in the past. As Donald Worster, one of the best- known contemporary American historians of the environment, wrote some years ago: We [environmental historians] are not concerned merely with the history of literary reactions to nature or of conservation policies, as important as those are. We are, in the largest sense, interested in all the ways people organize themselves into patterns of power, production, and ideology in the presence of what we conventionally call nature—the nonhuman world. Our goal is to discover, through the study of the past, some general ideas about how to make those patterns work better in the future for both ourselves and the rest of the world.3 I begin this paper with a discussion of the relationship between environ- mental history, political economy, sociology and policy and then turn more ex- plicitly to practices of environmental history and matters of scale. In the ªnal section, I address some questions of method and research strategy.

The Transformation of Nature and the Nature of Transformations From the perspective of the social and humanities, one of the things generally absent from analysis and practice is an adequate understanding of the relationship between human societies and nature. Debates over causality, and the practical and ethical implications of competing analyti- cal approaches, are much too complex to summarize here;4 sufªce it to say that two of the best-known approaches point either toward continuing human ma- nipulation of nature in order to “improve” it or “living lightly on the earth” and returning to some, largely mythical, “natural” relationship characteristic of an imagined earlier time. While both offer guidelines for policy-making, they are also seriously ºawed. The former is widely-agreed to not be viable over the lon- ger-term and, in any event, would require an impossible degree of centralized management, while the latter dictates a substantial change in both the material and cognitive realms of human activity and even massive reductions in human numbers (and, as I discuss below, there are serious contradictions in assuming that such an Edenic “state of Nature” ever actually existed). This does not mean, however, that we cannot change or develop sustainable practices. Rather, it indi- cates that we need to better understand how social change in more environmen- tally friendly directions has taken place in the past and how it could come about

3. Worster 1987, 251. 4. See, for example, Redclift and Benton 1994.

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/152638001316881412 by guest on 30 September 2021 74 • Environmental History, Political Economy and Change

in the future.5 But making policy without any deep awareness of history and po- litical economy virtually ensures that we will not be able to devise sustainable practices. Several methodological and conceptual shortcomings stand as obstacles to realistic and effective environmental policy analysis. One has to do with its economistic assumptions, a second with questions of scale, a third with the problem of social change, and a fourth with meaning. Taken together, these shortcomings suggest that we ought not to view environmental damage in terms of a limited and deterministic causal explanation (although such explana- tions can be useful) to which straighforward policy tools can be applied; rather, we must pursue a deeper focus on hermeneutic/descriptive analyses (similar to “thick description”) that combine history and political economy with structure and agency. In particular, policy analysis tends toward reiªed assumptions about the economic motivations of actions6 and, as a result, policy analysts dis- place environmental problems from the sphere of social practice and politics to that of economics.7 In this same context, environmental policy analysts usually avoid questions of meaning when they address the relationship of various social actors to nature. I address each of these points below.

Errors of Economism Much environmental policy analysis is focused at the macro-level, formulated in a very generalized form, and based on a set of assumptions regarding the be- havior of economically “rational” actors. In the language of rational choice, preferences are assumed to be exogenously determined and additive, and this permits generalization about the joint preferences of entire groups or commu- nities. These assumptions do not hold up well on closer inspection, although not for the reasons usually adduced within the critical of rational choice theory.8 Not only are these assumptions applied in similar fashion across cultures, they are also assumed to apply uniformly within industrial societies, which can also exhibit a high degree of diversity at relevant scales of political economy, such as the landscape or community. To be more precise, not only are many preferences endogenously determined, they are also the outgrowth of long-term processes and relationships—social, economic, cultural—that have developed within bounded areas and regions.

Space and Place This points, therefore, to the ever-present dilemma of scale:Over what space ought environmental damage and change be studied, environmental analysis performed, and policies implemented? As I have argued elsewhere, although

5. Lipschutz 1996, ch. 7–8. 6. Stone 1997. 7. Hay 1994. 8. Green and Shapiro 1994.

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/152638001316881412 by guest on 30 September 2021 Ronnie D. Lipschutz • 75

many environmental problems are conventionally framed in supra-regional, national, and global terms, due to the transboundary or global nature of struc- tural forces and physical processes, the immediate causes and consequences of such problems are generally quite localized.9 All fossil fueled plants emit carbon dioxide, but each plant has a somewhat different social organization and is lo- cated in a socially-unique place. Such “local” diversity among societies is recog- nized by anthropologists and rural sociologists, of course, although researchers in these disciplines work infrequently in industrialized countries.10

Changing Places Another major lacuna in environmental policy analysis has to do with an in- complete understanding of how individuals and societies initiate changes in their environments and how they, in turn, respond to these changes. We also face the question of how to study change. Do we focus on, for example, the ways in which changes in the external systems (within which, of course, a study site is implicated) are played out within speciªed regions? Or do we address processes of social change and adaptation within a region to environmental changes that might originate within or without? Responses to change are generally inter- preted in instrumental terms, as actions intended to reduce vulnerability and costs. But people often have extensive repertoires for responding to changes in their environments, and these may be quite place speciªc. Furthermore, changes in environments can become accepted as the “normal” state of things, rather than a dislocation from some idealized baseline.

What do you Mean by That? Finally, environmental analysts and policy-makers tend to focus on only one of the many types of meanings attached to natural resources, the valuation of re- sources as commodities to be exchanged in markets, that is, price. This is in keeping with the economism of the rational actor approach that, more often than not, assumes preferences and measures values in monetary terms. But a singular focus on economic valuation overlooks other meanings that, in partic- ular contexts, may often be of much greater signiªcance. How can we determine what these meanings might be? and sociology have the tools necessary to uncover non-monetary meanings based on criteria other than economic, but similar kinds of questions have been raised by environmental historians, as well.11 Nature is a source of livelihood—farm- ing, ªshing, eco-tourism, wilderness treks—around which some people and groups structure their individual and collective identities. Certain elements of nature—rivers, watersheds, mountains, bays, forests—are focal points for collec- tive identity, organization and activity. The historical modiªcation of nature

9. Lipschutz 1996, ch. 2. 10. But, see Walton 1992. 11. Schama 1995.

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/152638001316881412 by guest on 30 September 2021 76 • Environmental History, Political Economy and Change

into certain kinds of landscapes of production and —the “Rust Belt,” the Paciªc Northwest, the Great Plains—leave their indelible marks on people’s consciousness of Nature as well as long-term constraints on the possi- bilities of and opportunities for change in nature. This leads us to ask what, ex- actly, is “Nature?”

The nature of Nature It is commonplace to observe that human activities have impacts on the “natu- ral world,” a term that is generally taken to mean those parts of the biological and physical environment around us that are not, obviously, a product of hu- man origin. Yet, there is a great deal of archeological and historical evidence— and it is growing in volume and substance—showing that many locales often assumed to be primevally “natural” are not. Rather, they have been altered over time through collective human error, or managed through deliberate human ac- tivity.12 With a few notable exceptions,13 political scientists and scholars of pub- lic policy have rarely looked closely at the speciªc and contextualized historical patterns of Nature transformation that have created, altered and, at times, de- stroyed the biological environments in which human beings live. In many ways, the concept of a “genealogy of landscape” stands in opposi- tion to the still-widespread notion that there are some antediluvian or idealized conditions against which contemporary ecosystems can be compared and mea- sured, and which stand as baselines for restoration. But as mentioned earlier, in recent centuries Nature has not been a blank slate waiting to be written on by human action, even in “less-developed” parts of the world. Nature is more akin to a palimpsest on which new modiªcations have been inscribed over earlier ones. Indeed, in many instances the changes in the environment that seem so noticeable and alarming to the present generation are taking place in land- scapes already greatly transformed by earlier human action. To be sure, the mag- nitude of more recent changes often greatly exceeds those of earlier times, but forests have nonetheless been transformed into pastures and deserts many times in human history (while the reverse has almost never been the case, so far as I am aware). Hence, for example, the Great Plain of Hungary is only several hundred years old, notwithstanding the widely-held that it has “always” been there. The apparently wild tropical rainforests of Indonesia bear unmistakable evidence of having been managed for many centuries.14 And, in imitation of the of ignition of forests and grasslands by lightning and their periodic burning, the Native Americans of California intentionally and regularly set their own ªres as a tool of game and woodland management.15 There is one impor- tant difference between these cases and our contemporary situation, however:

12. See, for example, Peluso 1992. 13. See, for example, Walton 1992. 14. Peluso 1992. 15. Davis 1998, ch. 3.

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/152638001316881412 by guest on 30 September 2021 Ronnie D. Lipschutz • 77

while such human transformations of landscapes were deliberate, they were also part of the production and reproduction of relatively small-scale social units, and not enormous world-girdling ones.

What Basis for Baselines? While ecologists and anthropologists, among others, have been exploring the physical parameters of what appears to be a contradiction between the natural and the social, the methodological and policy implications of the palimpsest nature of landscapes have not been given much thought, especially not from the perspective of environmental protection and “nature” conservation.16 At least two important consequences emerge from the failure to recognize this point. First, environmental “damage” becomes something of a relative term. Some species thrive on disturbance and some ecosystems require it on a regular basis. While one might wish to interfere with the normal functioning of ecosystems as little as possible, how do we treat ecosystems that have been modiªed by hu- man action in one way or another? And, at what point does “damage” or change to such ecosystems exceed acceptable limits? For that matter, how do we deªne “acceptable?”17 The second consequence follows from the ªrst:The choice of a “baseline” toward which policy, protection and conservation would aim is primarily a po- litical decision rather than a scientiªc or economic one, involving the perennial question of what constitutes the “good” life. This is not to suggest that natural science or economics cannot play a role in the process of analysis and protec- tion; scientiªc research is necessary to tell us what is there and what has been there in the past, and to indicate what might or might not happen if we take a given action or fail to act. Economics can, at least, suggest what particular poli- cies might cost. But neither can tell societies what they should or how they should accomplish their desired ends. For example, given the phenomenon of global warming, there are many ways to respond (or to not respond) to it, each of which could accomplish the same end. Or, if a community wishes to restore a local watershed (a political matter), there are different forms of organization that can be applied to the task. Such choices are themselves matters of politics. To put this in different language, is relative, and “how safe is safe enough” is not a question that can (or should) be answered except by way of politics.

Social Constructions have Real Consequences These arguments demonstrate that the nature and environments we analyze and seek to protect are not so much the biological and geophysical world

16. See Cronon 1993; as well as Soulé and Lease 1995. 17. This is a point that is made by some postmodernists, such as Tim Luke (Luke 1997), and ªercely attacked by ecologists such as Michael Soule and humanists such as Gary Lease (Soule and Lease 1995), who worry that it will give license to rape and pillage the natural world.

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/152638001316881412 by guest on 30 September 2021 78 • Environmental History, Political Economy and Change

that we perceive as the products of human social action, both material and mental, over time. Nature, in other words, is a product not only of human methods of production, which is what we generally address, but also repro- duction, which we rarely consider. The original biological and geophysical world (“First nature”) offers opportunities and imposes constraints on what changes we can make (or errors we can repair), but so does the transformed world (“Second nature”) and the ways in which we have molded it to our needs and desires. In other words, the transformation of nature involves not only the physical process of modiªcation (and degradation), but also imagination:how it could, or will, appear once an action is taken and com - pleted, and how that transformed nature might, in turn, transform the trans- former. As Marx put it, “we erect our structure in imagination before we erect in reality.”18 What are the origins of such “imagined landscapes?” Or, rather, how do people (re)construct nature and Nature? There are at least three important forms of action. First, people tend to reproduce the familiar and customary. New arrivals often try to recreate old abodes and material practices in their new homes. These practices do not always succeed—consider the fate of 19th and early 20th century farmers in the Great American Desert. Nature imposes physi- cal constraints; people already established in such places often resist new arriv- als. But the traces of “old countries” are visible everywhere. Second, the physical environment and people’s conceptions of it are mo- bilized as elements in project development and capital accumulation. Under these circumstances, the objective of those who wish to transform landscapes is to convince people that nature is hostile, useless, or inefªcient as it is and must be turned into commodities and mobile money that can be used to foster grow- ing incomes and to seek out other opportunities for mobilization and accumu- lation. Such conversions might involve the draining of wetlands, the paving of farmland, or the felling of trees, all in the pursuit of increasing wealth and achieving “.” A ªnal form of action might be called environmental “idealism,” the at- tempt to construct an “appropriate” nature (or a Nature appropriate to a partic- ular place and time) through restoration or transformation into something ap- proximating an historical nature. Nature, in these schemes, becomes not only something to be manipulated in the pursuit of material goals but also a reºec- tion of who we are or whom we would like to become. It is in this context that a hermeneutic approach to history and political economy can be fruitful, as a ba- sis for crafting policies that are more “in tune” with their environments, so to speak. In order to understand why landscapes have undergone change, in other words, we cannot simply invoke environmental determinism or generalized ra- tional choice theories of human behavior. Rather, we must recreate on paper

18. Marx 1967, 178, quoted in Harvey 1989, 345.

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/152638001316881412 by guest on 30 September 2021 Ronnie D. Lipschutz • 79

and in our minds the speciªc social, historical, and material conditions faced by speciªc human communities and societies and, to the extent possible, try to un- derstand what those people believed they were doing in altering their Nature. Because these actions in the past created both the physical and mental land- scapes of today, they still exert considerable inºuence over today’s practices and beliefs. Only by engaging in such an exercise can we also explain, in speciªc places today, what is happening to nature as well as account for changes cen- tered around environments within and among human societies. Because we do not understand very well how changes in social practices do or can come about in contemporary settings—and our social sciences are much better at studying social stability than social change—our best recourse is to look to history for explanations, more speciªcally, for a contextual history of the social development of Nature. In order to formulate effective, sustainable, and just environmental policies, it is important to understand, in an historical and sociological sense, how landscapes and environments in particular places came to be as they are today. Environmental history can be extremely useful in developing such understandings.

Space: The Final Frontier? Arguing on behalf of an historical approach to understanding environmental change leaves unanswered one question:At what scale should the study of envi- ronmental history for policy purposes be focused? The best known works in en- vironmental history have tended to be broad in scale. Among the spaces covered have been the world or great parts of it,19 continents,20 and sub-continental ex- panses.21 More recently, there has been a growing recognition of the relationship between nature and more delimited spaces, and many working in the ªeld have begun to narrow the spatial breadth of their studies to regional and local scales. This narrowing of scope permits both greater resolution in terms of details and a better understanding of the social, spatial, and temporal dynamics through which environmental transformation takes place. Thus, for example, McEvoy’s exploration of the history of ªshery law and policy is restricted to California;22 Cronon takes Chicago and its agricultural hinterland as an appropriate unit of historical analysis;23 Walton focuses largely on a single river valley in eastern California and its relationship to Los An- geles;24 White deals with the environmental past of the area around the Great Lakes.25 Such a regional orientation has also spilled over into the social sciences,

19. Crosby 1986; and Grove 1995. 20. Jones 1981. 21. Worster 1985; Cronon 1983; and Merchant 1989. 22. McEvoy 1986. 23. Cronon 1991. 24. Walton 1992. 25. White 1991.

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/152638001316881412 by guest on 30 September 2021 80 • Environmental History, Political Economy and Change

as seen in research into the relationships among space, place and identity. This is most evident in the burgeoning literature on ethnicity and “imagined com- munities”26 and in work by geographers,27 but it is also seen in work on environ- mental politics and policy.28

Thinking about the Region Despite this trend, the “region” remains an essentially-contested concept. It is common to refer to both subnational and supranational spaces, and their lim- its, both physical and institutional, are rarely well-speciªed. Out of the many possible boundaries offered by the history, ecology, geography and political economy of a place, which do we choose and for what reason? For the most part, the historian’s region is usually deªned more by her/his proclivities and re- search agenda, reºective of historical constructs and local knowledge, than boundary markers or a coherent epistemology of space. The “West” is thus construed to be a region, although examination of envi- ronmental histories of the western United States shows that there are many dif- ferent “Wests.” Flores, among others, has proposed using the “bioregion”—a somewhat ill-deªned concept, but more in keeping with nature and ecology— as a unit of analysis,29 but there are serious ºaws in this approach. While the bioregion might be more “natural” and less “cultural” than other imagined re- gions, speciªcation still requires the scholar to choose among complex bound- aries. In many cases, furthermore, bioregional boundaries have little correspon- dence with those areas that are organized around resource exploitation. We must, therefore, make what are essentially political and social choices about space in selecting a region of study.30 At the same time as regions have gained prominence, the development of nature and transformation of landscapes takes place in a fashion that links local and global, although rarely in a conscious fashion. On the one hand, as users (and abusers) of nature, people are linked into networks of economy, politics and that extend in many directions, both spatially and temporally. On the other hand, people continue to act as though landscapes were composed of discrete and historically important parts:a river here, a mountain there, a forest, a bay, a species. But it is out of some sense of the relationship of these parts and the mental and social location of the local in the global that the “region” is con- ceptualized and materialized. In order to transcend such analytical difªculties, it is helpful to conceptu- alize “region” in at least three different, albeit related, ways. Regionalism origi- nates in culture, history and people’s believed and experienced connections to

26. Anderson 1991. 27. Bird et al. 1993; Entrikin 1991; Gilbert 1988; Olwig 1984; and Soja 1989. 28. Lipschutz 1996; and Press 1994. 29. Flores 1994. 30. Lipschutz 1996, ch. 7.

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/152638001316881412 by guest on 30 September 2021 Ronnie D. Lipschutz • 81

Nature and place. Regionalization is produced by the locational, linking and ag- gregating effects of internal and external economic development and political relations. Regionality carries forward, into the present, previous constructions of geography including the accumulation of situated patterns of experience, politi- cal boundaries and physical infrastructure over time.31 Each of these aspects of region formation is critical to understanding change in landscapes at a tractable scale, and each helps to explain why some “regions” become or remain cultur- ally resonant while others do not. As a rule of thumb, I would suggest that it is the interaction of political economy, social action, and nature over time that produces landscapes and their cultures and histories, a dynamic that generates borders which rarely correspond exactly to either natural or political bound- aries.

Boundary Conditions While there are any number of questions that might be asked and studied in re- sponse to the discussion above, there is one that remains of particular impor- tance and interest:How do we determine the scale and scope of the environ- mental transformation we wish to examine and explain? While this might seem to be mostly a question of physical parameters, I would argue that it is not. Transformations of nature take place at a variety of different scales and scopes, and these are not a simple function of geography, economy, history or politics. Since the social forces and structures that drive the transformation of nature are not bound to speciªc places or limited in time—which is one reason why the transcription of practices takes place (see below)—it might seem too constrain- ing to put boundaries around our studies. Still, boundaries exist and they are as much a function of the social formation embedded in the transformative pro- cess of environmental change as they are of anything else. This social formation is, in turn, partly generated by a speciªc history and political economy in a par- ticular place. And because the combination of historical, political and economic inºuences of concern is likely to be different over relatively small distances and times, it is important to understand the context-speciªc nature of each place or formation being studied. Here, I will argue that the most appropriate space or scale is the landscape-scale social ecology, which can be envisioned as the spatialization of an historical political economy based on place or region, as deªned earlier.32 Such landscapes are circumscribed geographically, socially and economi- cally, although their boundaries are ºuid and not always coterminous in terms of these three factors. Histories are circumscribed, too, but as with landscapes, they are linked to other places by virtue of the movements of people and re-

31. FitzSimmons 1990. 32. Although “social ecology” usually refers to one type of philosophical-political perspective on ecology, I use the term here in the same sense as “social ecosystem,” that is, a political-economic organizational spatial unit in which production and reproduction take place.

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/152638001316881412 by guest on 30 September 2021 82 • Environmental History, Political Economy and Change

sources, capital and goods, cultures and social structures. Moreover, these histo- ries demonstrate that landscapes and their human inhabitants are not static or pristine; social and ecological “succession” are dynamic processes in all places. Each successive period of interaction between humans and nature has its con- tingent and contextual cultural and material logics, sometimes generated locally but, more often, brought from elsewhere and adapted to the material possibili- ties of a particular place. Each logic, whether sustainable or not, is eventually followed by another, as resources are played out or environmental conditions change (whatever the cause), as technology and social organization change, as internal and external demands generate markets for new resources and goods, and as incentives to behave in particular ways shift. Each successive logic is, nonetheless, linked to its predecessor as the past is transformed into present and the present sets the stage for the future.33 The reasoning behind this argument is as follows. Speciªc landscapes are produced over time in a contingent and contextual fashion by the cumula- tive acts of people. At the same time, social action, both present and future, is constrained by the material and social possibilities of those places and land- scapes. Geography and nature, in particular, both impose constraints on and of- fer opportunities for social action in three ways (my speciªc examples are drawn from California, but they are equally applicable anywhere). First, geographic features do much to give deªnition to regions, offering centers and boundaries, in the way that mountain ranges limit development along many parts of the California Coast or in the ways that river valleys channel transportation, agricul- ture practices, and patterns of development. Second, biogeophysical factors— climate, soil, supply—inºuence or direct what can be done in speciªc places with a given set of skills and tools, as in the practices and institutions of agriculture in California’s Central Valley compared to the Southern United States (and changes in skills and tools also change what is constraining, not al- ways for the better). Finally, people migrating from one particular culture and place to another often seek out geographies familiar to them, where they can utilize the skills and reproduce the cultural practices and social forms of their prior everyday lives. Such patterns can be seen in the ªshing communities of Eu- ropean and Asian origin that developed along Central Coast of California and were subsequently absorbed by industrialized ªshing.34

Thinking through Social What we ªnd in these delimited regions, then, are patterns in which the biogeophysical and the social, interacting with exogenous factors, lead to a kind of “social ecological” succession. New “regions” do not displace the old but, rather, are overlain on them (reminiscent of the tels composed of ruins and gar-

33. Cronon 1993, 12–16; Worster 1994; and O’Connor 1995. 34. Orbach and Beckwith 1980; Orbach 1983; and Lydon 1985.

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/152638001316881412 by guest on 30 September 2021 Ronnie D. Lipschutz • 83

bage that one ªnds in Asia Minor, the Middle East, and North Africa). As ac- counts of patterns of both social and ecological succession, environmental his- tories for policy purposes ought therefore be more than mere “facts of nature,” and those who document the history of places and landscapes should be also aware of the “cultural constructions so deeply embedded in our language.”35 This last point also reminds us that speciªc environmental histories (as op- posed to the histories of environments) emerge from the perspectives and epistemologies of the scholar and the questions that the scholar asks.36 As Hajer argues, we can agree that forests are dead or dying, but we may differ radically in our explanations of the phenomenon.37 To draw on a California example again:Trees are logged and turned into houses and proªt—that is one constant in the stories of forests and their exploi- tation—but an environmental history told from the perspective of labor will differ from one told from the perspective of capital. And because the histories of speciªc places are contextual and contingent, even though different locations are exposed to the same external forces and processes, a of red- woods in Santa Cruz County will differ from one about redwoods in Mendocino County, of land in the Central Valley from one in Marin county, about water in the Sacramento River from one focused on the San Joaquin. This does not mean that one history is somehow more “true” than another; rather, it shows that by beginning in different places, adopting different standpoints, and asking different questions, even two environmental histories of the same place or the same resource may offer very different narratives and insights. In other words, social formations and institutions are only partly deter- mined by the First nature around them; human beings transform nature through the operations of their social formations and institutions and these, in turn, are acted upon by this transformed (Second) nature. Although the land- scapes that result from this may be viewed as “managed,” “wild,” or “restored,” what is important is that they differ from what preceded them. As Arthur McEvoy has put it, “[J]ust as people develop their views of the world through in- teractions with their social and material environments, so, too, do those views change as people continually make the world over in response to changing ways of understanding it.”38 Only through an environmental history that is sensitive to this dialectical process can we comprehend how these changes come about and, to return to Worster’s point above, “make those patterns work better in the future for both ourselves and the rest of the world.”39 It can be argued that the spatial scales I have proposed here are too artiªcial and leave out too much information. For example, would it be possible to analyze the extinguishing of the salmon run on the Columbia River by exam-

35. Cronon 1992, 1352. 36. Leibhardt 1988. 37. Hajer 1993. 38. McEvoy 1988, 214. 39. Worster 1987, 251.

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/152638001316881412 by guest on 30 September 2021 84 • Environmental History, Political Economy and Change

ining only one small portion of the river’s watershed? No—the fate of the salmon is as much a function of political economy and history as it is of geogra- phy and nature. What is important is the juxtaposition of the macro with the micro, in this case, a description of the larger forces at work on the Columbia combined with a place- and formation-centered analysis of how these processes were played out in a limited arena.

Other Dimensions What constitutes an appropriate temporal span for such studies? After all, the histories of transformed landscapes can be extended backward for centuries if not millennia. Our choice depends on whether we wish to understand the prac- tices of contemporary “everyday life” as opposed to the “life-cycle” of a transfor- mation. The former is open-ended, in that it does not consider either the begin- ning or the ending of the process; the latter, although longer and more complex an undertaking, is better placed within history. It permits us to assess how par- ticular transformations in the landscape begin as part of an earlier transforma- tion, and end as part of a later one (without presuming closure). Again, within reason and the limits of tractability, both can be rewarding. How do we select an appropriate unit of analysis? I suggested above that boundaries of scale and scope are inherent in particular social formations; the question posed here refers more to cultural boundaries. To return to the Monterey Bay example cited earlier, are the communities engaged in the exploi- tation of particular ªsheries also characterized by a shared cultural and class character? What are the social relations and relations of production that charac- terized the community? To what extent do these characteristics close the practice to others, that is, what are the social and cultural barriers to entry? Finally, what other activities are such communities engaged in that may also be having a transformative impact on the landscape (and seascape)? One ªnal (fourth) important element of environmental policy analysis is that it tends to focus on speciªc resources or forms of degradation (e.g., number of members of a species rather than damage to habitat), strictly separating inte- gral elements of nature from one another. Most environmentally-focused social take a more holistic approach, focusing on social ecology rather than on natural resources, but this has its shortcomings, as well. A regional ap- proach usually implies, ªrst, downplaying those social inequalities that are the best observed relative to one natural resource (see, for example Peluso’s notion of the structure of access control vis a vis forests) and, second, limiting explora- tion of connections between local and global and the unintended consequences of locally-devised measures. This suggests that, for the purposes of making envi- ronmental policy, we need to be more sensitive to the ways in which resources, and their exploitation, are embedded not only within physical regions, but within social and economic domains, as well.

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/152638001316881412 by guest on 30 September 2021 Ronnie D. Lipschutz • 85

Methodological Approaches and Alternatives

Historical and Determinism One common characteristic of environmental history works against a consistent hermeneutic analysis over time, and that is the fact that environmental history ordinarily deals with “closed cases,” that is, those that are no longer “in prog- ress.”40 In such cases, the consequences of particular patterns of human political economy and, perhaps, the causal relations that have lead to those outcomes, are clearly visible and can be analyzed retrospectively. From a more theoretical perspective, histories can be used to develop and reªne methodologies appro- priate for the sociological study of contemporary environmental contexts. But unless we begin with ready-made assumptions about the character of particular societies, localities and problems, and the continuity of these characteristics, a purely historical angle will not sufªce in studying such contexts. The ºaws inherent in working from such assumptions can be seen in one historian’s work, where it might not be expected:the holistic materialist ap- proach, more-or-less represented by Donald Worster’s Rivers of Empire.41 The ho- listic materialist approach tends to treat the exploitation of resources and dam- age to nature as driven by forces beyond the control of local agency. As with world systems theory, the imperatives behind such forces are to be found in the geographies, histories, and political economies of whole societies and civiliza- tions, if not the entire world. This approach tends, as a result, to be rather deter- ministic in its analyses. The very presence of certain types of environmental con- texts dictates both speciªc political and social forms as well as largely predictable outcomes.42 Thus, in Rivers of Empire, Worster deduces that the relative scarcity of water in the American West, combined with the expansionist tendencies of the United States and the domination of society by capital, could only have led, in- evitably, to the creation of a highly-centralized, environmentally-destructive “hydraulic society,” along the lines of the type theorized by Karl Wittfogel.43 The “democratic East” was, consequently, not reproduced in the resource scarce West. There are a number of problems with Worster’s argument, not the least of which is that large-scale water storage and distribution systems never emerge ex

40. By deªnition, “history” excludes the present and some portion of the recent past. Nonetheless, to invoke Marx once again, institutions, relations, and roles constituted in historical times un- der particular conditions provide the contexts within which people ªnd themselves today, and with which they will have to work tomorrow. Also, see again Walton 1992. 41. Worster 1985. 42. The movement of the late 1970s, and work by energy analysts such as Amory Lovins, who pioneered the concept of “hard” and “soft” , were also charac- terized by such determinism. 43. Wittfogel 1957.

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/152638001316881412 by guest on 30 September 2021 86 • Environmental History, Political Economy and Change

nihilo from the deductive abilities of the engineers who, seeing water disappear into the desert and knowing it to be inherently “scarce” (scarce for what pur- poses?), immediately imagine how water management systems should be de- signed, built, and controlled. Such engineers had (and have) ideas, knowledge, and aspirations that originated in particular societies and cultures, in particular places and times. It was the immediate social conditions that underpinned their evaluation of the landscape and gave them a particular vision about how to transform nature in that place and time. Their imagined landscapes were not, moreover, simply a product of re- gional or national context, either; extensive communication took place between American and British hydraulic designers and engineers, the former working in the American West, the latter in the Indian Raj. These same people also pos- sessed some awareness of the larger features of ancient Middle Eastern irrigation systems (without much sense of the controlling institutions), whose outlines had already been rediscovered and described in the late 19th and early 20th centuries. Kate Showers has demonstrated similar “technology transfers” be- tween the United States and Great Britain with respect to the problem of soil in Lesotho.44 This phenomenon of “environmental transcription,” as it were, the whole- sale transference of human transformations of nature from one part of the world to another, is all too common; indeed, it is no more than one form of dis- cursive learning (although the prevalent impression is that such knowledge moves mostly from industrialized to developing societies). The possibility that environmental transformations are as much a product of discourses as of agency or structure, as discussed earlier, does go hand-in-hand with the tran- scription of landscapes from one place to another. Only by seeing two widely- separated places as sufªciently similar to think of them as interchangeable does it becomes possible to reproduce whole systems in a new locale. Were this not so, a transcription would not have occurred. But lessons are not always learned, either. Even when something has not “worked” in one location, for whatever reason, there frequently remains the abiding belief, not always borne out in practice, that those ºaws which caused failure in one place can be redressed or engineered out in another. Whether such wholesale transcription from one location to another makes ecological sense—especially if the practice has failed in its original site— is something that can only be determined by a careful comparative assess- ment of physical conditions at the two sites. And, even the presence of ostensi- bly-appropriate “natural” conditions says nothing about the social and cultural context into which the practice is to be transcribed. Wittfogel and Worster notwithstanding, such human contexts are almost certainly not the same in both places, and outcomes are almost certainly going to be differ- ent.

44. Showers 1994.

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/152638001316881412 by guest on 30 September 2021 Ronnie D. Lipschutz • 87

Materialism, Agency, and Discourse A somewhat different approach to environmental history and analysis takes less for granted and recognizes the role of human agency and constructed meanings in the transformation of the landscape. This is, more or less, the strategy adopted by William Cronon in Nature’s Metropolis45 (although he might not ad- mit to it). Such a method recognizes that the environmental “context” facing human agents in any given location is not, a priori, determining, although it can be constraining and offer opportunities that push in one direction as opposed to another.46 Take, for example, Cronon’s description of the site on which Chicago was founded. He indicates that it had few, if any, natural advantages, such as a good port, which were often instrumental in locational decisions. Wiser people might have built the city in another, more attractive location with better lake access, perhaps farther up the shores of Lake Michigan where Waukegan now stands. (Had this happened, would Chicago have been more inºuential in the history of the West than Waukegan?). Somewhat paradoxically, in this instance, and quite contrary to what environmental determinism might have us predict, it was the very absence of a deep port that worked in favor of Chicago’s expansion. This lacuna prevented the city from becoming a major shipping center and forced the city’s elites to look to other ways of fostering its expansion. Cronon’s contrast of Chicago’s success with that of St. Louis’ fate illustrates this point. The leaders of the St. Louis, which had excellent access to the Mississippi, were less enamored of the possibilities of rail transporta- tion than were the leaders of Chicago. As a consequence, St. Louis lost out when the holders of capital had to choose between the two sites and rail vs. river, even though it was more centrally-located with respect to the West than was Chicago. More to the point, the growth of Chicago also had reverberating effects on the political economy, history, and ecology of points West, North and South, as the visions of economic and social transformation informed expansion, and ex- pansion opened up new material (farms) and social ªelds (catalogue sales) to hoe. In a way, Cronon argues that these transformations, and their environmen- tal consequences, were almost incidental to the economic pull of Chicago. Given the dominant capitalist ideology of then (and now), however, the opti- mal choice for an individual farmer or businessman was self-evident:Deal with and through Chicago, or do no business at all. That from our perspective there were no other “obvious” paths by which to do business in the late 19th century Midwest is a form of Whiggish history. Our perceptions do not mean that there were no other paths that could have

45. Cronon 1991. 46. For example, water can be made to ºow uphill, but only at considerable cost (as in California). Water supply in any given context is, ultimately, limited, although the purposes for which it is used are almost inªnite. Varying the mix of uses—that is, demand—can have as much effect on supply as the building of new storage facilities.

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/152638001316881412 by guest on 30 September 2021 88 • Environmental History, Political Economy and Change

been chosen; only that roles and relationships to the land and people were strongly conditioned by what frontier society regarded as its founding and the ways in which Chicago’s growth helped to elaborate on these original myths. (A companion volume to Cronon’s, entitled Nature’s Hamlet, document- ing some other Midwestern town’s failure to grow, might be instructive in illus- trating these points.) Thus, Cronon not only describes the white settlers’ pre- sumptions concerning “real” agriculture, “real” ownership and trade, valuable goods, women’s appropriate roles, and the vision Chicago’s founders cherished. He also reveals the social origins of these presumptions and visions and shows how such factors helped to materially transform and produce the landscape we see today. What this materialist, agency, and discourse-centered approach makes possible, then, is the following. On the one hand, it helps us to understand the origins of the social transformation of nature while, on the other hand, offering an awareness of the physical setting in which the transformation is taking place (which imposes constraints and permits choices). This means that we do need to have some idea of what the landscape in a place looked like prior to a partic- ular change in the land even if it does not mean that we know how it appeared at some originary time. Having these two pieces—physical setting and social transformation—may permit us to work through the puzzle of why changes in the land took one form as opposed to another, although it is equally likely that, without extensive research into the social history and conditions of a speciªc lo- cation, we will not be able to tell anything at all from the landscape and long- term environmental changes there.

Data Sources This last point raises some ªnal methodological questions about research strate- gies:Where do we search for such clues? Government are limited in this regard. Although they may provide a paper trail of policy discussions and im- plementation, they are not always a good indicator of the emergence of or changes in particular discourses. An approach somewhat akin to a social history (or genealogy, as suggested above) of nature may be more useful in this respect: Reading of not only ofªcial documents, but public, popular and personal ones, as well, and, where possible, interviewing individuals who may have been wit- ness to the changes of interest. This is roughly the approach adopted by Showers,47 applied in what she calls “historical environmental impact assess- ment,” although she has been less concerned with the discourse/agency ques- tions addressed here. In addition to these sources, the documents and literature of “expert knowledge”—the mostly technical- and management-oriented trade and pro- fessional journals of the times—can act as important sources of discursive infor-

47. Showers 1994.

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/152638001316881412 by guest on 30 September 2021 Ronnie D. Lipschutz • 89

mation because these bodies of knowledge accomplish the delicate translation of vision and into reality. The researcher must, nevertheless, always be cognizant of the social and political restrictions on full realization of imagined landscapes. At the same time, there is also a limit to such techniques. For peri- ods much beyond 150 or 200 years ago, and more recently in some parts of the world, such sources are simply not available. Because our primary interest in en- vironmental policy-making centers on landscapes transformed during the past 200 years (and in many places, more recently), such limits do not pose insuper- able obstacles to research.

Conclusion What I have offered here is not, I should note, “environmental history” as the discipline is commonly understood and practiced, whose practitioners usually seek to describe the progression through which nature has been exploited by humanity. What I am describing here is, rather, the social history of things, for- mations, and processes and, in this case, a social history of nature integral to so- cial ecologies of people. Although human beings the world over once con- fronted some sort of “original” Nature, they now act to transform a nature already-changed—in some instances, many times—through the operations of their social formations and institutions. These are then, in turn, acted upon by this transformed nature although not, as some environmental determinists might have it, constrained and deter- mined by the nature around them. More than this, the transformation of nature is not simply something that “happens.” Often as not, it is a project with clearly- deªned objectives and means, some economic, some political, some cultural. This is not to suggest, however, a competing form of . Nature, in turn, imposes constraints on and limits to what is humanly possible. To paraphrase Marx (badly):Women and men transform Nature, but they do so to Nature transformed by the earlier actions of other women and men, which set limits to what they who follow can do. There may, of course, be “lim- its to growth,” both relative and absolute, that put an end to human projects, but neither these limits nor the original “state of Nature” can determine our “correct” social response to the changes or the limits. Science can tell us what might happen if we carry on as usual, and policy analysis can suggest how we might change. What they cannot tell us is what to do if we wish to change our ways or see an imminent need to do so. That is the province of politics.

References Anderson, Benedict. 1991. Imagined Communities—Reºections on the Origins and Spread of Nationalism. London: Verso, 2nd ed. Bird, Jon, Barry Curtis, Tim Putnam, George Robertson and Lisa Tickner, eds. 1993. Map- ping the Futures—Local Cultures, Global Change. London: Routledge .

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/152638001316881412 by guest on 30 September 2021 90 • Environmental History, Political Economy and Change

Cronon, William. 1983. Changes in the Land: Indians, Colonists and the Ecology of New Eng- land. New York: Hill & Wang. ______. 1991. Nature’s Metropolis—Chicago and the Great West. New York: Norton. ______. 1992. A Place for Stories:Nature, History, and Narrative. Journal of American History 78: 1347–76. ______. 1993. The Uses of Environmental History. Environmental History Review 17 (4): 1–22. Crosby, Alfred. 1986. Ecological —The Biological Expansion of Europe, 900– 1900. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press . Davis, Mike. 1998. The Ecology of Fear—Los Angeles and the Imagination of Disaster. New York: Metropolitan/Henry Holt. Entrikin, J. Nicholas. 1991. The Betweenness of Place: Towards a Geography of Modernity. Bal- timore: Johns Hopkins University Press. FitzSimmons, Margaret. 1990. The Social and Environmental Relations of United States Agricultural Regions. In Technological Change and the Rural Environment, edited by Philip Lowe, Terry Marsden and Sarah Whatmore, 8–32. London: David Fulton. Flores, Dan. 1994. Place:An Argument for Bioregional History. Environmental History Re- view 18, (4):1–18. Gilbert, Anne. 1988. The New Regional Geography in English and French-Speaking Countries. Progress In , 208–228. Green, Donald P. and Ian Shapiro. 1994. Pathologies of Rational Choice Theory. New Ha- ven: Yale University Press. Grove, Richard H. 1995. Green Imperialism—Colonial Expansion, Tropical Island Edens and the Origins of , 1600–1860. Cambridge:Cambridge University Press. Hajer, Maarten A. 1993. Discourse Coalitions and the Institutionalization of Practice: The Case of Acid Rain in Great Britain. In The Argumentative Turn in Policy Analysis and Planning, edited by Frank Fischer and John Forester, 43–76. Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press. Harvey, David. 1989. The Condition of Postmodernity. Cambridge, Mass.: Blackwell. Hay, Colin. 1994. Environmental Security and State Legitimacy. Capitalism, Nature, So- cialism 5 (17): 83–97. Jones, E.L. 1981. The European Miracle—Environments, Economics and Geopolitics in the His- tory of Europe and Asia. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Leibhardt, Barbara. 1988. Interpretation and Causal Analysis:Theories in Environmental History. Environmental Review 12 (1): 3–36. Lipschutz, Ronnie D., with Judith Mayer. 1996. Global Civil Society and Global Environmen- tal Governance—The Politics of Nature from Place to Planet. Albany, N.Y.:State Uni - versity of New York Press. Luke, Timothy W. 1997. Ecocritique: Contesting the Politics of Nature, Economy, and Culture. Minneapolis, Minn.: University of Minnesota Press. Lydon, Sandy. 1985. Chinese Gold: The Chinese in the Monterey Bay Region. Capitola, CA.: Capitola Book Company. McEvoy, Arthur F. 1986. The Fisherman’s Problem: Ecology and Law in the California Fish- eries. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ______. 1988. Toward an Interactive Theory of Nature and Culture:Ecology, Produc - tion, and Cognition in the California Fishing Industry. In The Ends of the Earth: Per- spectives on Modern Environmental History, edited by Donald Worster, 211–29. Cam- bridge: Cambridge University Press.

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/152638001316881412 by guest on 30 September 2021 Ronnie D. Lipschutz • 91

Marx, Karl. 1967. Capital, vol 3, New York. Merchant, Carolyn. 1989. Ecological Revolutions: Nature, Gender, and Science in New Eng- land. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press. O’Connor, James. 1995. What is Environmental History? Why Environmental History? Capitalism, Nature, Socialism 6 (4):1–27. Olwig, Kenneth. 1984. Nature’s Ideological Landscape. London: G. Allen & Unwin. Orbach, Michael K. 1983. The ‘Success in Failure’ of the Vietnamese ªshermen in Monterey Bay. Coastal Zone Management Journal 10: 331–45. Orbach, Michael K. and Janese Beckwith. 1980. A Report on the Adaptation of Indochinese Refugees to the Fishing Industry and Community of Monterey Bay. Santa Cruz, Calif.: Center for Coastal Marine Studies, University of California, Santa Cruz. Peluso, Nancy L. 1992. Rich Forests, Poor People. Berkeley: University of California Press. Press, Daniel. 1994. Democratic Dilemmas in the Age of Ecology—Trees and Toxics in the American West. Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press. Redclift, Michael and Ted Benton. 1994. Social Theory and the Global Environment. Lon- don: Routledge. Schama, Simon. 1995. Landscape and Memory. New York: Vintage. Showers, Kate B. 1994. Historical Environmental Impact Assessment:Connecting Land Use History to Environmental Impact Assessment. Boston, Mass.:Boston Univer- sity, African Studies Center Working Paper No. 174. Soja, Edward. 1989. Postmodern Geographies: The Reassertion of Space in Critical Social The- ory. London: Verso. Soule, Michael and Gary Lease. 1995. Reinventing Nature? Responses to Postmodern Decons- truction. Washington, D.C.: . Stone, Deborah. 1997. Policy Paradox: The Art of Political Decision Making. New York:W.W. Norton. Walton, John. 1992. Western Times and Water Wars—State, Culture, and Rebellion in Cali- fornia. Berkeley: University of California Press. White, Richard. 1991. The Middle Ground: Indians, Empires and Republics in the Great Lakes Region, 1650–1815. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Wittfogel, Karl. 1957. Oriental Despotism—A Comparative Study of Total Power. New Haven: Yale University Press. Worster, Donald. 1985. Rivers of Empire: Water, Aridity, and the Growth of the American West. New York: Pantheon. ______. 1987. Introduction to Theories of Environmental History. Environmental Review 11 (4): 251–53. ______. 1994. Nature and the Disorder of History. Environmental History Review 18 (2): 1–15.

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/152638001316881412 by guest on 30 September 2021