Policy Summer 0405.Indd

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Policy Summer 0405.Indd FEATURE Is Economic Growth Given Too High a Priority? Winton Bates finds that Australians see economic growth as one element of overall national and personal well-being ’ve been rich and I’ve been poor; believe me, this extreme view, he is not alone in asking whether honey, rich is better’. Those who agree with people (and governments) give economic growth the singer, Sophie Tucker, do not necessarily higher priority than it deserves in the light of its believe that wealth guarantees happiness. limited contribution to improving their well-being. ‘ Nearly everyone seems to enjoy some of what For example, a prominent British economist, Imoney can buy whilst readily acknowledging that Richard Layard, has suggested marginal tax rates happiness also depends on other things, including of about 60% of additional income to discourage frame of mind, health and relationships with work effort and reduce growth in GDP.3 others. To come to grips with the issue of whether It seems to me that most Australians would not economic growth is given higher priority that it expect further increases in income to make them feel a lot happier than they are already. Survey evidence Winton Bates is an economic consultant confirms that increases in per capita income tend ([email protected]). He has not to be accompanied by corresponding increases in reported happiness, or life satisfaction, in worked for many years on public policy countries with per capita incomes higher than a issues related to economic growth, fairly modest level.1 This raises questions about both in his current role and in his why people seek to earn more and the rationale for previous career working in the New economic growth. Zealand Treasury and the Australian In a recent book, Clive Hamilton argued that Industry Commission (now Productivity economic growth is a fetish and should be stopped.2 Commission). Although Hamilton has received little support for POLICY • Vol. 20 No. 4 • Summer 2004-05 9 Is Economic Growth Given Too High a Priority? warrants, it is useful to consider the following questions: 90 • What priority do people actually give to 80 economic growth relative to other matters in 70 Australia and other countries with different 60 growth experiences? 50 • Is it appropriate to interpret surveys showing 40 that growth has not been accompanied by 30 20 greater life satisfaction as evidence that the 10 benefits of growth are just a mirage? 0 • Should governments be promoting happiness 0 20 40 60 80 100 rather than economic growth? What priority do people give to economic growth? 70 Survey data from the 1999-2002 World Values 60 Survey (WVS) shows us the priority Australians 50 give to economic growth relative to other 40 countries.4 The results of eight relevant questions 30 from the WVS have been plotted against average per capita income levels using scatter diagrams (see 20 Figures 1 to 8).5 The data points in the figures all 10 0 represent countries. For convenience, Australia 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 is shown as a diamond, New Zealand as a dot and the United States as a triangle. Some other countries are also labelled where their results differ markedly from other countries with similar per capita income levels. 90 If economic growth is a fetish it would be 80 70 reasonable to expect that people in high-income 60 countries would be no more satisfied with their 50 financial situation than people in low income 40 countries. The evidence in Figure 1 suggests 30 otherwise. When asked ‘how satisfied are you with 20 the financial situation of your household’, people 10 0 in high-income countries are more likely to respond 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 that they are satisfied. The percentage in Australia is similar to other countries with comparable income levels. People who say that ‘less importance placed on 90 work in our lives’ would be ‘a good thing’ represent 80 a lower proportion of the population in Australia 70 than in many countries with comparable income 60 levels (Figure 2). In general, however, a higher 50 proportion of the population of affluent countries 40 30 favour less emphasis on work. 20 The proportion of Australians who say ‘protecting 10 the environment should be given priority’ over 0 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 ‘economic growth and creating jobs’ is similar 10 Vol. 20 No. 4 • Summer 2004-05 • POLICY Is Economic Growth Given Too High a Priority? to that for other countries with comparable per capita income levels (Figure 3). There is no clear 70 relationship evident between per capita income 60 levels and this indicator of environmental attitudes. 50 This is not surprising in the light of evidence that environmental problems tend to be more severe in 40 low-income countries.6 30 People who say ‘less emphasis on money’ would 20 be a good thing make up a higher proportion 10 of the Australian population than in most 0 other countries with comparable income levels 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 (Figure 4). There does not seem to be a strong relationship between emphasis on money and average income level. As indicated in Figure 5, the proportion of 40 Australians who say that leisure is very important 35 in their lives is relatively high among countries 30 with comparable income levels. Of the countries 25 with the top five rankings on this criterion, four 20 are in South America. It is apparent that for most 15 other countries the importance of leisure depends 10 strongly on income levels. 5 0 For postmaterialist values Australia stands out as 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 having the highest ranking of any of the countries included in the World Values Survey (Figure 6). People are classified as having postmaterialist values if they rank ‘giving people more say in important government decisions’ and ‘protecting freedom of 100 90 speech’ above ‘maintaining order in the nation’ and 80 7 ‘fighting rising prices’. More of the population 70 tend to have postmaterialist values in high-income 60 countries. 50 40 The proportion of Australians who say that 30 good pay is ‘important in a job’ is relatively low by 20 comparison with countries with similar average 10 0 income levels (Figure 7). The percentage viewing 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 good pay as important tends to be lower in high- income countries. Finally, a ‘high level of economic growth’ is given a lower priority by Australians than in some other 100 countries with comparable income levels (Figure 90 8). Respondents were asked which they considered 80 70 most important: ‘a high level of economic growth’, 60 ‘seeing that people have more say about how things 50 are done at their jobs and in their communities’, 40 ‘a strong defence for our country’ and ‘cities and 30 20 countryside more beautiful’. The evidence suggests 10 that people in high-income countries tend to view 0 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 economic growth as having lower priority. POLICY • Vol. 20 No. 4 • Summer 2004-05 11 Is Economic Growth Given Too High a Priority? countries other factors, particularly marriage and 100 unemployment, have a greater impact on SWB than 10 90 does income. But the fact that economic growth 80 in high income countries has been accompanied 70 by little improvement in SWB can only be partly 60 50 explained by the effects of factors such as rising rates 11 40 of separation, divorce and unemployment. 30 20 What does this survey evidence mean? 10 0 Does the SWB evidence imply that economic 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 growth in wealthy countries is not worth having? Those who adopt this interpretation present a variety of arguments: Are the benefits of economic growth just • people are more interested in relative than a mirage? absolute income; What do the surveys show? • as people earn more they adapt to it and their Three main findings emerge from the survey aspirations rise—so the growth process is like evidence about the relationship between income being on a treadmill going nowhere; and subjective well-being (SWB)8: • economic growth occurs as a result of manipulation of consumer preferences. • People on high incomes tend to be happier than those with low incomes. There is no doubt that relative income has an • Cross-country comparisons show a strong important influence on SWB. This is evident, for positive relationship between per capita GDP example, in the results of a US survey in which and average life satisfaction up to a modest per students were asked whether they would prefer to capita GDP level (of about $US15,000) and no live in a world where they had high relative income clear relationship at higher income levels (See and low absolute income or in a world where they Figure 9). had high absolute income and low relative income. • In recent decades, economic growth in high Half of the students chose high relative income in income countries has been accompanied by little preference to high absolute income.12 At the same improvement in SWB. time, there is no shortage of people who have high relative incomes who are seeking to migrate from poor countries to rich countries to obtain higher In wealthy countries other absolute incomes. factors, particularly marriage and What are the practical implications if, say, unemployment, have a greater every additional dollar increase in your income is impact on subjective well-being associated with a decline in happiness for everyone than does income.
Recommended publications
  • Canadian Politics of the Economy and the Environment 1867-2017
    The paradox of growth and the promise of unsettled times: Canadian politics of the economy and the environment 1867-2017 Christopher James Orr Department of Natural Resource Sciences McGill University, Montreal August 2020 A thesis submitted to McGill University in partial fulfillment of the requirements of the degree of Doctor of Philosophy © Christopher James Orr 2020 Abstract Why does economic growth persist as a primary policy objective of nation states that is pursued and overwhelmingly supported? Accumulating evidence indicates that after a certain point economic growth does not contribute to social wellbeing, and undermines global ecological integrity. The persistence of economic growth as a primary policy objective is a paradox. This paradox is an important research gap that demands explanation. Explaining this paradox is important because, unless we are able to explain why growth persists, policies cannot enable humanity to live in harmony with this finite Earth. The overarching purpose of this thesis is to explain the paradox of growth in Canadian federal politics. The study has four specific objectives: (1) to map the dominant belief system in Canadian federal politics 1867-2017, and show how the persistence of economic growth as part of that system is a paradox; (2) to develop a conceptual framework to understand how society and nature coevolve, and the role of belief systems in that coevolving relationship; (3) to use this framework to explain the persistence of economic growth in Canadian federal politics; and (4) to identify barriers and opportunities for how Canada can move towards an ecologically sustainable economy and ways of life. First, I use Canadian political manifestos (party platforms) to map the dominant belief system in Canadian federal politics 1867-2017, and to show how the evolution of ideas about economic growth and the environment is a paradox.
    [Show full text]
  • Digital Authoritarianism and the Global Threat to Free Speech Hearing
    DIGITAL AUTHORITARIANISM AND THE GLOBAL THREAT TO FREE SPEECH HEARING BEFORE THE CONGRESSIONAL-EXECUTIVE COMMISSION ON CHINA ONE HUNDRED FIFTEENTH CONGRESS SECOND SESSION APRIL 26, 2018 Printed for the use of the Congressional-Executive Commission on China ( Available at www.cecc.gov or www.govinfo.gov U.S. GOVERNMENT PUBLISHING OFFICE 30–233 PDF WASHINGTON : 2018 VerDate Nov 24 2008 12:25 Dec 16, 2018 Jkt 081003 PO 00000 Frm 00001 Fmt 5011 Sfmt 5011 C:\USERS\DSHERMAN1\DESKTOP\VONITA TEST.TXT DAVID CONGRESSIONAL-EXECUTIVE COMMISSION ON CHINA LEGISLATIVE BRANCH COMMISSIONERS Senate House MARCO RUBIO, Florida, Chairman CHRIS SMITH, New Jersey, Cochairman TOM COTTON, Arkansas ROBERT PITTENGER, North Carolina STEVE DAINES, Montana RANDY HULTGREN, Illinois JAMES LANKFORD, Oklahoma MARCY KAPTUR, Ohio TODD YOUNG, Indiana TIM WALZ, Minnesota DIANNE FEINSTEIN, California TED LIEU, California JEFF MERKLEY, Oregon GARY PETERS, Michigan ANGUS KING, Maine EXECUTIVE BRANCH COMMISSIONERS Not yet appointed ELYSE B. ANDERSON, Staff Director PAUL B. PROTIC, Deputy Staff Director (ii) VerDate Nov 24 2008 12:25 Dec 16, 2018 Jkt 081003 PO 00000 Frm 00002 Fmt 0486 Sfmt 0486 C:\USERS\DSHERMAN1\DESKTOP\VONITA TEST.TXT DAVID C O N T E N T S STATEMENTS Page Opening Statement of Hon. Marco Rubio, a U.S. Senator from Florida; Chair- man, Congressional-Executive Commission on China ...................................... 1 Statement of Hon. Christopher Smith, a U.S. Representative from New Jer- sey; Cochairman, Congressional-Executive Commission on China .................. 4 Cook, Sarah, Senior Research Analyst for East Asia and Editor, China Media Bulletin, Freedom House ..................................................................................... 6 Hamilton, Clive, Professor of Public Ethics, Charles Sturt University (Aus- tralia) and author, ‘‘Silent Invasion: China’s Influence in Australia’’ ............
    [Show full text]
  • The Post-Growth Challenge — Secular Stagnation, Inequality and the Limits to Growth
    The Jus Semper Global Alliance In Pursuit of the People and Planet Paradigm Sustainable Human Development January 2021 ESSAYS ON TRUE DEMOCRACY AND CAPITALISM The Post-Growth Challenge: Secular Stagnation, Inequality and the Limits to Growth Tim Jackson Abstract ritics have long questioned the C feasibility (and desirability) of exponential growth on a finite planet. More recently, mainstream economists have begun to suggest some ‘secular’ limits to growth. Sluggish recovery in the wake of the financial crisis has revived discussion of a ‘secular stagnation’ in advanced economies, in particular. Declining growth rates have in their turn been identified as instrumental in increased inequality and the rise of political populism. This paper explores these emerging arguments paying a particular attention to the dynamics of secular stagnation. It explores the underlying phenomenon of declining labour productivity growth and unpacks the close relationships between productivity growth, the wage rate and social inequality. It also points to the historical congruence (and potential causal links) between declining productivity growth and resource bottlenecks. Contrary to some mainstream views, this paper finds no inevitability in the rising inequality that has haunted advanced economies in recent decades, suggesting instead that it lies in the pursuit of growth at all costs, even in the face of challenging fundamentals. This strategy has hindered technological innovation, reinforced inequality and exacerbated financial instability. At the very
    [Show full text]
  • Critiques of Growth in Classical Political Economy: Mill's Stationary
    Critiques of growth in classical political economy: Mill’s stationary state and a Marxian response GARETH DALE ABSTRACT In recent political-economic theories of ‘nature,’ Mill and Marx/Engels form important reference points. Ecological economists see Mill’s ‘stationary state’ as seminal, while Marxists have ‘brought capitalism back in’ to debates on growth and climate change, sparking a Marxological renaissance that has overturned our understanding of Marx/Engels’ opus. This essay explores aspects of Mill’s and Marx/Engels’ work and contemporary reception. It identifies a resemblance between their historical dialectics. Marx’s communism is driven by logics of ‘agency’ and ‘structure’ (including the ‘tendency of profit rates to fall’). In Mill’s dialectic a ‘thesis,’ material progress, calls forth its ‘antithesis,’ diminishing returns. The inevitable ‘Aufhebung’ is a stationary state of wealth and population; Mill mentions countervailing tendencies but fails to consider their capacity to postpone utopia’s arrival. Today, Mill’s schema lives on in ecological economics, shorn of determinism but with its market advocacy intact. It appears to contrast with the ‘productive forces expansion’ espoused by Marx/Engels. They stand accused of ‘Promethean arrogance,’ ignoring ‘natural limits’ and ‘gambling on abundance.’ But I find these criticisms to be ill-judged, and propose an alternative reading, arguing that their work contains a critique of the ‘growth paradigm,’ and that their ‘cornucopian’ ends do not sanction ‘promethean’ means. That Karl Marx and John Stuart Mill inhabited the same city for over twenty years without encountering one another has prompted some of their admirers to compensate for the frustration of this event’s unfortunate non-occurrence by means of fantasy.
    [Show full text]
  • A Political Science Manifesto for the Age of Populism
    “Every engaged citizen, every political activist living in our times, which are bad times, needs to read this book.” Michael Walzer A POLITICAL SCIENCE MANIFESTO FOR THE AGE OF POPULISM Downloaded fromDAVID https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: M. 170.106.34.90 , on RICCI03 Oct 2021 at 04:40:29, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://www.cambridge.org/core/product/8FA8474DA61700F0A5BB4EB1A9A8D84F ii Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 170.106.34.90, on 03 Oct 2021 at 04:40:29, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://www.cambridge.org/core/product/8FA8474DA61700F0A5BB4EB1A9A8D84F i A POLITICAL SCIENCE MANIFESTO FOR THE AGE OF POPULISM Populism and authoritarian-populist parties have surged throughout the world in the twenty- fi rst century. In the United States, it’s diffi - cult to pinpoint the cause, yet Donald Trump appears to have become the poster president. David Ricci, in this call to arms, thinks Trump is symptomatic of a myriad of changes that have caused a crisis among Americans – namely, mass economic and creative destruction: automation, outsourcing, deindustrialization, globalization, priva- tization, fi nancialization, digitalization, and the rise of temporary jobs – all breeding resentment, which then breeds populism. Rather than dwelling on symptoms, Ricci focuses on the root of our nation’s problems. Thus, creative destruction, aiming at perpetual economic growth, encouraged by neoliberalism, creates the economic inequality that fuels resentment and leads to increased populism, putting democracy at risk.
    [Show full text]
  • Growth Isn't Possible: Why We Need a New Economic Direction
    Schumacher College Transformative learning for sustainable living Growth isn’t possible Why we need a new economic direction Contents Foreword 2 Introduction 4 Greenhouse gas emissions and current climate change 24 Scenarios of growth and emission reductions 52 Peak Oil, Gas and Coal? 69 Carbon capture and storage – 85 the nuclear fusion of the 2010s? The limits to nuclear 91 The hydrogen economy 93 Biofuels 95 Geoengineering – technological saviour 98 or damaging distraction? How much can energy efficiency really improve? 102 Equity considerations 117 If not the economics of global growth, then what? 118 Getting an economy the right size for the planet Endnotes 125 Foreword If you spend your time thinking that the most important objective of public policy is to get growth up from 1.9 per cent to 2 per cent and even better 2.1 per cent we’re pursuing a sort of false god there. We’re pursuing it first of all because if we accept that, we will do things to the climate that will be harmful, but also because all the evidence shows that beyond the sort of standard of living which Britain has now achieved, extra growth does not automatically translate into human welfare and happiness. Lord Adair Turner1 Chair of the UK Financial Services Authority Anyone who believes exponential growth can go on forever in a finite world is either a madman or an economist. Kenneth E. Boulding Economist and co-founder of General Systems Theory n January 2006, nef (the new economics foundation) published the report Growth isn’t working.2 It highlighted a flaw at the heart of the general economic strategy Ithat relies upon global economic growth to reduce poverty.
    [Show full text]
  • Debt As Power 25.Pdf
    Debt as Power THEORY FOR A GLOBAL AGE Series Editor: Gurminder K. Bhambra Globalization is widely viewed as a current condition of the world, but there is little engagement with how this changes the way we understand it. The Theory for a Global Age series addresses the impact of globalization on the social sciences and humanities. Each title will focus on a particular theoretical issue or topic of empirical controversy and debate, addressing theory in a more global and interconnected manner. With contributions from scholars across the globe, the series will explore different perspectives to examine globalization from a global viewpoint. True to its global character, the Theory for a Global Age series will be available for online access worldwide via Creative Commons licensing, aiming to stimulate wide debate within academia and beyond. Previously published by Bloomsbury: Published by Manchester Connected Sociologies University Press: Gurminder K. Bhambra John Dewey: The Global Public and Its Problems Eurafrica: The Untold History of John Narayan European Integration and Colonialism Peo Hansen and Stefan Jonsson On Sovereignty and Other Political Delusions Joan Cocks Postcolonial Piracy: Media Distribution and Cultural Production in the Global South Edited by Lars Eckstein and Anja Schwarz The Black Pacific: Anti-Colonial Struggles and Oceanic Connections Robbie Shilliam Democracy and Revolutionary Politics Neera Chandhoke Debt as Power Tim Di Muzio and Richard H. Robbins Manchester University Press Copyright © Tim Di Muzio and Richard H. Robbins 2016 The right of Tim Di Muzio and Richard H. Robbins to be identified as the authors of this work has been asserted by them in accordance with the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988.
    [Show full text]
  • Ideology and Politics: Essential Factors in the Path Toward Sustainability
    Ideology and Politics: Essential Factors in the Path toward Sustainability John Coates St. Thomas University, New Brunswick, Canada Terry Leahy University of Newcastle, Australia ..................................... With the Kyoto protocol coming into force we can expect media attention to focus on governments’ efforts to reduce global warming. While some have questioned how effective such efforts will be due to the number of countries who have not signed on (notably the USA), the potential effectiveness of efforts to combat climate change, and more generally to achieve a sustainable society, can better be understood in the light of ideological and socio-political contexts. This paper argues that ideology and socio-political structure are essential considerations in the path toward a sustainable society. Four models are discussed in terms of their potential to achieve sustainability. The review of ecological devastation, much of it occurring in the past 100 years, exposes our economy to be an “extractive economy” (Berry, 1997). An extractive economy depletes non-renewable resources, exploits renewable resources beyond their capacity to survive, and causes irreparable damage to land, sea and air (see Coates, 2003a; Foster, 1999; McLaughlin, 1993; Trainer, 1985). Further, the production of toxins along with industrial and domestic effluent greatly exceeds the healing and regenerating capacities of the Earth (see Colborn, Dumanoski & Myers, 1997). The Earth cannot cope with such excesses as human activity has changed the chemistry of the planet and altered the eco-systems upon which modern civilization depends. In fact, no eco-system on Earth is free from the pervasive influence of chemical discharges (Vitousek, Mooney, Lubchenko, & Melillo, 1997).
    [Show full text]
  • Consumer Capitalism Is This As Good As It Gets?
    Consumer capitalism Is this as good as it gets? 15th Maurice Blackburn Oration Coburg Town Hall 25th February 2004 Clive Hamilton Executive Director, The Australia Institute Until recently, there has never been a time in human history when each of us could hope to live a truly fulfilling life. From the earliest days, the hopes of ordinary men and women were severely constrained by their cultural and material circumstances. For ordinary people the binding constraint was economic and the most they could reasonably hope for was to achieve a modest but secure existence in the company of their families. For almost all, cultural and social limits imposed at birth were also binding; one’s life course was conditioned by one’s class, gender and race. There were two dreams of liberation. Religious ecstasy in another life seemed attainable for everyone. Political authority was comfortable with this opium of the masses. The second dream, a society of equals, was much more threatening. Socialism promised prosperity in a classless society; by means of revolution it would abolish both the material and the social constraints on the full realisation of ordinary men and women. In the end, it was not socialism that broke down the barriers of poverty and class, it was capitalism itself. In recent decades, in the rich countries of the world, the forces that held in check the hopes of the masses have for the most part fallen away. Despite pervasive money-hunger, most people in rich countries live lives of abundance in conditions that their grandparents would have regarded as luxurious.
    [Show full text]
  • James Gustave Speth © As Delivered. a New American Environmentalism
    James Gustave Speth © As delivered. A New American Environmentalism and the New Economy James Gustave Speth Senior Fellow, Demos and Professor of Law, Vermont Law School (7/2010) The 10th Annual John H. Chafee Memorial Lecture National Council for Science and the Environment Washington, D.C. January 21, 2010 I’m both pleased and honored to have been asked by NCSE to give this 10th Annual John H. Chafee Memorial Lecture. I knew John personally and had the opportunity to work with him during his long and distinguished service on the Senate Environment Committee. He was a wonderful person and a great Senator. I wish we had a dozen John Chafees in the Senate today. And I want also to acknowledge the ever-more important role NCSE has played in our national life. Many of you are familiar with its contributions, including this blockbuster conference, but you may not know of its leadership in creating and supporting a council of deans and directors of America’s environmental schools. I know that that initiative meant a lot to us at Yale. And let me especially join in celebrating the achievements of the remarkable Herman Daly, a profound thinker, a generous soul, and a great wit. Herman launched us into considering the steady state economy and led in the creation of the now highly-productive field of ecological economics. We owe him a great debt for all he has done. To begin, I would like to invite you to join me in a journey of the imagination. I want you to join me in visiting a world very different from the one we have today.
    [Show full text]
  • Is There a Future for Social Democracy After the Financial Crisis?
    Is There a Future for Social Democracy After the Financial Crisis? Plenary paper to the Congress of the Foundation for European Progressive Studies organised by the Kalevi Sorsa Foundation, Helsinki, 6 th November 2009 Clive Hamilton 1 1. Social democracy and the GFC There are two lessons from the global financial crisis. The first is that capitalism always moves in cycles. The second is that we are destined always to forget the first. Social democrats will always be gainfully employed trying to protect capitalism from its own excesses. They will be proven right about the need to regulate financial markets to dampen the speculative urge, but they will be proven right over and over again because they fight a losing battle. After all, the window of opportunity to impose effective restraints on secondary financial markets after the crash has now closed; the tough talk has led to very little. Of course, the neoliberal model has been discredited by the crash of 2008. For critics of the free market model there was more than a pang of schadenfreude to be had from Alan Greenspan’s astonishingly frank testimony to Congress: ‘Those of us who have looked to the self-interest of lending institutions to protect shareholder’s equity— myself especially—are in a state of shocked disbelief’. We shook our heads in dismay as he owned up to being ‘very distressed’ at finding a ‘flaw’ in his free market philosophy. Of course, clever people had been pointing to the flaw for years, but good advice is always drowned out by ideological conviction as long as the economy is growing.
    [Show full text]
  • The Disappointment of Liberalism and the Quest for Inner Freedom
    THE AUSTRALIA INSTITUTE The Disappointment of Liberalism and the quest for inner freedom Clive Hamilton Discussion Paper Number 70 August 2004 ISSN 1322-5421 ii © The Australia Institute This work is copyright. It may be reproduced in whole or in part for study or training purposes only with the written permission of the Australia Institute. Such use must not be for the purposes of sale or commercial exploitation. Subject to the Copyright Act 1968, reproduction, storage in a retrieval system or transmission in any form by any means of any part of the work other than for the purposes above is not permitted without written permission. Requests and inquiries should be directed to The Australia Institute. The Australia Institute iii Table of Contents Acknowledgements iv Summary v 1. The disappointment of liberalism 1 2. Liberty, individualism and happiness 7 Freedom and happiness 10 3. Types of liberty 14 4. Inner freedom 19 Self-deception 21 Akrasia 25 5. A digression on the ethic of consent 28 6. Exercising inner freedom 32 7. Coercion and inner freedom 36 8. The decline of free will 40 9. From political philosophy to metaphysics 45 The disappointment of liberalism iv Acknowledgements This paper was mostly written while I was a visiting fellow at Clare Hall, Cambridge, in late 2003. The development of the ideas benefited from seminars at Clare Hall and, especially, the Cambridge Realist Economics Workshop organised by Tony Lawson. The paper has also been improved as a result of comments from and discussions with Charles Weijer (Dalhousie University), Geoff Harcourt (University of Cambridge), Brian Ellis (University of Melbourne), Richard Eckersley (Australian National University) and Richard Denniss (The Australia Institute).
    [Show full text]