<<

University of Tennessee, Knoxville TRACE: Tennessee Research and Creative Exchange

Doctoral Dissertations Graduate School

8-2013

RELIGION AND CONFLICT: WHAT EXPLAINS THE PUZZLING CASE OF “ISLAMIC VIOLENCE” AND ISLAMIST PARTY MODERATION?

Suveyda Karakaya [email protected]

Follow this and additional works at: https://trace.tennessee.edu/utk_graddiss

Part of the Comparative Commons, and the International Relations Commons

Recommended Citation Karakaya, Suveyda, " AND CONFLICT: WHAT EXPLAINS THE PUZZLING CASE OF “ISLAMIC VIOLENCE” AND ISLAMIST PARTY MODERATION?. " PhD diss., University of Tennessee, 2013. https://trace.tennessee.edu/utk_graddiss/2441

This Dissertation is brought to you for free and open access by the Graduate School at TRACE: Tennessee Research and Creative Exchange. It has been accepted for inclusion in Doctoral Dissertations by an authorized administrator of TRACE: Tennessee Research and Creative Exchange. For more information, please contact [email protected]. To the Graduate Council:

I am submitting herewith a dissertation written by Suveyda Karakaya entitled "RELIGION AND CONFLICT: WHAT EXPLAINS THE PUZZLING CASE OF “ISLAMIC VIOLENCE” AND ISLAMIST PARTY MODERATION?." I have examined the final electronic copy of this dissertation for form and content and recommend that it be accepted in partial fulfillment of the equirr ements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy, with a major in .

Brandon Prins, Major Professor

We have read this dissertation and recommend its acceptance:

Wonjae Hwang, Ian Down, Youshaa Patel

Accepted for the Council:

Carolyn R. Hodges

Vice Provost and Dean of the Graduate School

(Original signatures are on file with official studentecor r ds.)

RELIGION AND CONFLICT:

WHAT EXPLAINS THE PUZZLING CASE OF “ISLAMIC VIOLENCE” AND

ISLAMIST PARTY MODERATION?

ADissertationPresentedforthe

DoctorofPhilosophy

Degree

TheUniversityofTennessee,Knoxville

SuveydaKarakaya

August2013

©bySuveydaKarakaya,2013

Allrightsreserved

ii

This dissertation is dedicated to my husband Mahmut

and my beautiful daughter Zeynep Neda.

iii Acknowledgements

Iamgratefultomanypeoplethatmadethisworkpossible.ThoughIcannotthankallofthe numerouspeoplewhohavecontributedtothisexperience,afewdeserveselectmention.First,I wouldliketothankmyadvisor,Dr.BrandonPrins. Healwaysenlightenedmypathwithhis patient guidance, encouragement and careful assessment. Also, I would like to thank my committeemembersDr.IanDown,Dr.WonjaeHwang,andDr.YoushaaPatel.Theiradviceand counsel have been of equal importance. I greatly appreciate their time and input to this dissertation.

Furthermore I would also like to acknowledge with much appreciation the crucial role of Dr

Ahmet Kuru, Dr Kadir Yildirim, and Dr Renat Shaykutdinov, who patiently reviewed initial drafts of this dissertation and provided very useful suggestions. Within the Political Science

Department,Iowemanythankstomyfellowgraduatestudents,AmandaSanfordandNurgul

Aitalieva,whowerealwayswillingtohelpme.

Lastbutnotleast,IwouldliketoexpressmygreatestgratitudetomyhusbandMahmut,whohad beenthroughthesamechallengingprocess,andearnedhisPhDdegreejusttwoyearsago.You taught me so much about sacrifice, selfdiscipline, patience, and compromise. Finishing this dissertationwouldbeadreamwithoutyourneverendinglove,encouragement,andsupport.I feelveryluckyandprivilegedtohaveyou.

iv Abstract

Despiteconsiderableinterestintherelationshipbetween and political violence, there is little systematic empirical research that explores the intra conflict proneness of Muslim majority states. Existing studies either offer inconclusive evidence of a relationship or suffer from methodological flaws. If we analyze the proportion of countries with large Muslim populationsthatexperiencedomesticarmedconflicts,Muslimmajority statesdoinfactstand out.WhatexplainstheprevalenceofpoliticalviolenceintheMuslimworldandtowhatextent does religion play a role in promoting violence? Under which conditions ethnopolitical organizationsoptforviolentstrategiestoachievetheirpoliticalgoals?Underwhichconditions

Islamist parties denounce violence and shift from radical to moderate, pragmatist positions?

Thesequestionsareyettobefullyaddressed.Inanattempttofillagapintheextantliterature, this dissertation investigates the empirical nexus between Islam and political violence/nonviolence by specifically focusing on the incidence of domestic armed conflict, grouplevel political violence (such as insurgency, , and ), and party moderation.IexploretheroleofreligionandIslamistideologyindrivingpoliticalviolencein the first two quantitative chapters whereas the qualitative chapter focuses on Islamist party moderation.Iarguethatreligionalonedoesnotnecessarilymakecountriesmoreorlessconflict prone. Socioeconomic and political conditions usually determine the decision to resort to violenceoralternativelytorenounceviolenceandtomoderate.Higherprevalenceofrepressive regimes,poverty,andyouthbulgesmakeMuslimpluralitycountriesveryvulnerabletodomestic conflict.Theoverallfindingsindicatethat,contrarytosuggestionsandclaimsintheliterature, neitherreligiousfractionalizationnorIslampromotespoliticalviolenceoncesocioeconomicand political factors are taken into account. Muslimplurality states are indeed disproportionately

v involvedindomesticarmedconflict,butthesestatesarealsocharacterizedbylowerGDPper capita, oil dependency, state repression, , and youth bulges, all of which correlate stronglywithdomestic armed conflict.Moreover,the analysisof Islamistpartiessuggestthat

Islamist parties respond to societal changes, renounce violence and moderate their radical ideologieswhentheyaregivenachancetoparticipateinthepoliticalsystem.

vi Table of Contents

I. Chapter1 a. Introduction………………………………………………………….……………1 b. ReferenceList……………………………………………………………………11 II. Chapter2 a. ThePuzzlingCaseof“IslamicViolence”:WhatExplainsPrevalenceof DomesticArmedConflictintheMuslimWorld?...... 13

b. ReferenceList……………………………………………………………………44

c. Appendix1:ListofTables………...……………………………………….……51 d. Appendix2:ListofFigures……………………………………………………...60 III. Chapter3: a. EthnopoliticalOrganizationsintheMiddleEast:WhenDoTheyOptfor Violence?...... 61

b. ReferenceList……………………………………………………………………86

c. Appendix1:ListofTables………...……………………………………….……89 d. Appendix2:ListofFigures………………………………………………….…..94 e. Appendix3:DescriptionofVariables…………………………………………...96 IV. Chapter4 a. DeradicalizationandModerationofIslamistParties…….………………..….101

b. ReferenceList……………………………………...…………………………...136 c. Appendix1:ListofTables………...…………………..…………………….…142

d. Appendix2:ListofInterviewees………………………………………………144 V. Chapter5 a. Conclusion…………………………………………………….....……………..145

b. ReferenceList…………………………………………………………………..158

VI. Vita………………………………………………………………………………….159

vii List of Tables

Table Page

2.1SummaryofVariables……………………………………………………………………….51

2.2SummaryofDescriptiveStatisticsinMuslimpluralityandothercountries…………...... 52

2.3BivariateRegressions………………………………………………………….……………..53

2.4RiskofDomesticArmedConflict(19812009………………………………………………54

2.5CorrelationofIndependentVariables………………………………………………………..55

2.6RandomEffectsModel………………………………………………………………………56

2.7RelogitModel………………………………………………………………………………..57

2.8RegressionswithMuslimProportion……………………………………………………….58

2.9ListofDomesticArmedConflict……………………………………………...…………….59

3.1CorrelationofIndependentVariables……………………………………………………….89

3.2SummaryofVariables……………………………………………………………………….90

3.3SummaryofDescriptiveStatistics…………………………………………………………...91

3.4LogisticRegressiononUseofViolencebyEthnopoliticalOrganizations(19802004)…..92

3.5AlternativeModelSpecifications……………………………………………………………93

4.1ArgumentsonIslamistModerationintheLiterature………………………………………142

4.2SummaryofCases………………………………………………………………………….143

viii List of Figures

Figure Page

2.1RepressionandthePredictedProbabilityofIntrastateConflict…………………………....60

3.1ProbabilityofViolenceinAutocraticandNonAutocraticCountries………………………94

3.2YouthBulgesandPredictedProbabilityofUseofViolence………………………………..95

ix CHAPTER 1

Introduction

1 InDecember2010,aTunisianvegetablepeddlerburnedhimselftodeathasaprotestafterhis cartistakenawaybypolice.Thisincidentcreatedaspillovereffectofviolentandnonviolent protestsinmanyMiddleEasterncountries,andinitiatedtheArabSpring.Sofar,theArabSpring successfully toppled dictators in Tunisia, , and while the protests in Syria transformedintoabloodycivilwar.Bothacademiciansandpolicymakersarewonderingabout thecausesoftheseongoingprotestsandthecycleofviolenceintheMiddleEast.Infact,itisnot uncommontoseepoliticallyorientedviolenceintheMiddleEast,aswellasinotherpartsofthe

Muslimworld.

Whilesomescholarsarguethatunfavorablesocioeconomicandpoliticalconditionssuch

asstaterepression,incomeinequality,andunemploymentare driving violenceintheMuslim

world,othersemphasizetheinfluenceofreligioninfosteringviolence(Dalacoura2011;Fishet

al.2010;Hafez2003;Huntington1996;Toft2007;Zaidiseetal2007).Notsurprisingly,since

9/11, Islam is used as an explanatory concept for many issues involving . More

specifically,evenamongscholars,thereisthetendencyto referto Islamicculturetoexplain

manyfailuresintheMuslimworldwithoutproperresearch(Roy2004).Yet,theMuslimworld

is very diverse; there is no unique Islam and the understanding/practice of Islam differs

considerablyfromoneregiontoanother.Forexample,whilemanymainstreamreligiousleaders

andMuslimscontendthatthosewhokillciviliansinthenameofIslamarenotMuslims,some

militant groups with an “Islamist” ideology argue the opposite; they believe that those who

denounce the physical struggle against nonbelievers are not Muslims (Vertigans 2009). What

explainstheprevalenceofpoliticalviolenceintheMuslimworld?Towhatextentdoesreligion play a role in promoting violence? Even though public interest in this subject significantly

2 increased especially after 9/11 terrorist attacks, these questions remain underexplored and existingstudiessufferfromoversimplificationormethodologicalflaws.

Somescholarsarguethatreligiousfundamentalismand/orpoliticalIslamisareactionto modernity;thegoalisprotectionofreligiousidentityfrommodernity and(Ayoob

2005;Fox2004).ModernsocialscientistssuchasKarlMarx,JohnStuartMill,andMaxWeber, predicted that modernity would lead to the institutional separation of religious and secular spheresaswellasthemarginalizationanddeclineofreligion(Appleby2000).Contrarytothe expectations of modernization and secularization theory, the portion of the world population adheringtoChristianity,IslamandHinduismincreasedfromfiftypercentin1900tosixtyfour percentin2000(Toftetal2011:2).Inlinewiththistrend,theinfluenceofreligiononpolitics hasalsoincreased(Armstrong2009;Berger1999;Fox2007;Philpott2007).Toftetal.notethat

“Once passive, religion is now assertive and engaged. Once local, it is now global. Once subservienttothepowersthatbe,religionhasoftenbecomepropheticandresistanttopoliticians ateverylevel”(2011:3).Ironically,theresurgenceofreligionisfacilitatedbythedynamicsof modernization (which predicted the demise of religion) such as , technological improvements in communication, and globalization. The crises in secular ideologies also contributedtothisreligiousresurgence(Toftetal2011). 1

Thereligiousresurgencethatwehavewitnessedsincethe1960shasledtotheincreasing impactofreligioninpolitics.Inmanypartsoftheworld,religiousinstitutionshaveprominent public roles and the publicprivate distinction is blurred (Appleby 2000). The increasing influence of religion on politics is also manifested in wars. Civil wars driven by religious differenceshaveincreasedovertimeastheyareoftencitedtobemoredestructive,morelikelyto

1Manysecularhavefailedtoprovideprosperityandstabilityinthedevelopingcountries.Asaresult, secularideologieslostpopularitywhereasideologiesinspiredbyreligionbecamemoreprominent. 3 recur,andlongerlastingcomparedwithnonreligiouscivilwars(Toft2007).In2010,50%of sixteenongoing civilwarshadareligiousbasis(Toftetal.2011).

Religion has the potential to promote conflict by influencing the identity, loyalty and political goals of people. However, religious goalsandidentitiesoftenmixwithnonreligious goalsinmanyconflicts(Philpott2007).Religiouscleavagesarenotclearlydistinguishablefrom ethnicgrievancesinsomecasesand,therefore,maynotbetherootcauseofmanysupposedly religiousdomesticarmedconflicts(Appleby2000;Philpott2007).Forexample,Applebypoints out that the exact roleof religion in the Bosnian war (19921995) is not clear. Even though religioussymbolswereclearlyutilized,someanalystspointoutthatthemostBosnianMuslims weresecularizedandonlyafewSerborCroatnationalistleaderswerepracticingCatholicismor

Orthodoxy.Forinstance,accordingtoPaulMojzes,areligioushistorian,theBosnianwarwas primarilyethnonational,notreligious(Appleby2000:6768).Similarly,itisnotexactlyclear whethertheChechenfightersinandthePalestinians(e.g.,inGaza)aremotivated byreligionor.

Some scholars (Fox 2007; Toft et al. 2011) criticize the tendency on the part of internationalrelationsscholarshiptounderestimatetheimpactofreligionbyemphasizingsocial andeconomiccauses,whereasotherscholars(Canettietal.2010;Fishetal.2010;Sorlietal.

2005)aremoreskepticalabouttheimpactofreligion.Toftetal.arguethat‘religionisabasic driver of politics in its own right’ (2011:219). On the other hand, Canetti et al. (2010) and

Zaidise et al. (2007) argue that socioeconomic deprivation plays a mediating role between political violence and religion. As Coward and Smith (2004) point out, religious texts and practicesareopentointerpretation.Therefore,theinterpretationormanipulationofreligionby socialactorsexplainshowthesamereligioussourcescouldbeusedtopromotebothviolence

4 and peace. Moreover, improvements in crosscultural communication caused religious polycentrism. Therefore, seemingly religious behaviors cannot be explained by religious affiliationalone.

Extremists,whoarguethattheyupholdthefundamentalsofreligion,arehighlyselective in choosing religious doctrines to justify violence. Thus, they convince uneducated ordinary believers by using selective religious scriptures, which seemingly endorse violence (Appleby

2000). While there are instances when Islamic groups tend to shift from radical to moderate positions,orviceversa,thereislittleevidencethattheseshiftsinstrategiesstemfromreligious teachings.Forexample,theconceptof“”canbeusedbothtojustifyviolenceandpeaceful activitiessinceitisinterpreteddifferentlybydifferentMuslims.ClassicalIslamicscholarspoint outtwoprimarytypesofjihad:thegreaterjihadandthelesserjihad.Thefirstonereferstothe spiritualstruggletobeamorallybetterpersonbyfightingoffimmoraldesires,whereasthelatter one,whichisonlyameanstoachievethegreaterjihad,referstoaphysicalstrugglepermitted undercertainconditionssuchasselfdefenseoroppression.Yet,contemporaryradicalIslamist groupsredefinedjihadasanindividualdutyforallMuslimstofightagainstnonMuslimsaswell as some seemingly “Muslim” leaders. So, any person who does not follow Islam and who prevents“therealizationofIslam”becomesalegitimatetargetofjihad(Mandaville2006).

Amongall,Islamisthemostcommonlyassociatedwithpoliticalviolence.2Itis arguedthatIslamisintoleranttowardsnonbelieversandhence,itisinherentlyconflictprone.

The scholars who refer to Islamic culture to explain prevalence of domestic and interstate conflictintheMuslimworldrelyontheconceptofjihad,someselectivehistoricalcases,and selectiveversesfromtheKoran(Laquer2003;Pipes2003;Toft2007).Forinstance,Huntington

(1996)arguesthat“Islamhasbloodybordersandbloodyinnards”.Yet,numerousquantitative 2Indeed,manyscholarsarguethatIslamisparticularlypronetoviolence.SeeZaidiseetal.(2007:502)fordetails 5 studieshavetestedHuntington’s(1996)famous“clashofcivilizations”thesisandfoundlittleor noempiricalsupport.3Similarly,somescholarsclaimthatIslamencouragestheuseofviolence againstnonMuslimssincetheobligationofjihadcallsforafightagainstnonbelievers(Laquer

2003).Allinall,eventhoughthesescholarsdonotnecessarilyexplorethecausalfactorsthat leadtoMuslimmajoritystates’disproportionateinvolvementinintrastateconflicts,theystill characterizeMuslimmajoritycountriesasmoreviolence/conflictproneingeneral.

However,Muslimshistoricallyhavebeenmostlypeacefulandtolerant.Justtwodecades ago,religiousideologiesintheMiddleEastwerenotpopularatallandsuicideterrorinthename ofjihadwasveryrare(Mousseau2011).Moreover,socioeconomicandpoliticalgrievancesmay be the root cause of seemingly religiously oriented violence. For example, public opinion

surveysshowthatthosewhothink9/11terroristattacksarejustifiedarenotIslamistsatalland

mostradicalMuslimshaveaWesterneducation,notareligiousone(Kurzman2011;Roy2004).

Accordingtoasurveyconductedin2001,seventyfivepercentofMuslimsbelievethattheUS

foreign policy was partly responsible for the 9/11 attacks (Kurzman 2011). Similarly, Roy

(2004:46) notes that “Al Qaeda did not attackSaint Peter’s Basilica in Rome but the World

TradeCenter;ittargetedmodernimperialism”.

Tosumup,whiletheoreticaldebatesabouttheroleofIslaminpromotingconflictare

abundant, there are only a handful of empirical studies. The existing studies provide mixed

evidenceregardingIslam’sroleinpromotingconflict(Fishetal2010;Fox2007;Sorlietal2005;

Tofteal2011).Thereisnoscholarlyconsensusabouttheextenttowhichreligioningeneraland

theIslamicfaithinparticular,mayfosterviolence.Doesreligionhaveanindependenteffecton

conflicts regardless of socioeconomic conditions or does it act as a catalyst under certain

3ManystudieshavechallengedHuntington’sthesis.Foracomprehensivelistofquantitativestudiestesting Huntington’sthesis,seeFox(2007:366). 6 circumstances?Underwhatconditionsdoethnopoliticalorganizationsresorttoviolence?Are religious organizations more violenceprone than others? Under what conditions do Islamist partiesrenouncetheuseofviolentmeansandideologicallyandbehaviorallymoderate?These questionsareyettobeaddressedsystematically.

Thepurposeofthisdissertationistocontributetotheseliteraturesbyinvestigatingthe empirical nexus between Islam and political violence/nonviolence. This dissertation will specifically focus on the incidence of domestic armed conflict, grouplevel political violence

(such as insurgency, terrorism, and genocide), and party moderation. The benefits of this research are threefold. First, it sheds light on the complex relationship between Islam and politicalviolencethroughamoresystematic,theoreticallyorientedandempiricalanalysisthat better controls for alternative explanations for political violence. Second, understanding the factorsthatmakeethnopoliticalorganizationspreferviolentstrategiesovernonviolentoneshas significantpolicyimplications.Thefindingsofthisresearcharelikelytoinformpolicymakers andassistthemindevelopingstrategiesthathelp toreducethethreatofreligious radicalism.

Third, understanding the evolution of radical Islamist parties (the moderation process) is necessaryforbetterpolicymakingespeciallyinthewakeofthe“ArabSpring.”Islamistparties arekeypoliticalactorsintheMiddleEastandtheirdegreeofcommitmenttoliberaldemocratic principles as well as the moderation process will be very influential during the democratic transitionsintheregion.

Chapter Outline

In chapter 2, I examine factors that increase a country’s riskofexperiencingdomestic armed conflicts and I empirically test competing arguments proposed by scholars to explain domesticconflictintheMuslimworld.Muslimmajoritystates’domesticconflictpronenessis

7 explained by a number of competing arguments that rely on either case studies or mere descriptivestatistics.Inthischapter,IfirstreviewtheliteratureonIslamandpoliticalviolence, anddomesticarmedconflict,respectively.Second,Icomparetheprevalenceofdomesticarmed conflictsandsomesocioeconomicindicatorsinMuslimpluralitycountriestoothercountriesby usingdescriptivestatistics.Then,Idevelopageneraldomesticarmedconflictonsetmodeland conductlogisticregressionanalysistotestmyhypotheses.Iarguethatthehigherprevalenceof repressive regimes, poverty, and youth bulges in the Islamic world make Muslimplurality countries very vulnerable to domestic armed conflict. I utilize the Uppsala Conflict Data

Program’srecentdataforthe19812009periodtotestmyhypotheses.Theempiricalfindings show that Muslimplurality states are indeed disproportionally involved in domestic armed conflicts,butthesestatesarealsocharacterizedbylowerGDPpercapita,oildependency,state repression, autocracy, and youth bulges, all of which correlate strongly with domestic armed conflict.ThesignificanceofIslamdisappearswhencontrolsforsuchfactorsareincludedinthe statisticalmodel.

Inchapter3,Iconductagrouplevelanalysisandexploreconditionsunderwhichethno politicalorganizationspreferviolentstrategiestoachievetheirgoals.Thischapterbuildsonthe previouschapterbyfocusingonfactorsthatincreasetheprobabilityoftheuseofviolenceatthe grouplevelratherthancountrylevel.Thereviewoftheliteraturesuggeststhatethnopolitical organizations’ decision to use violence is influenced by the existence of grievances, political opportunitystructures,resourcemobilization,organizationalstructure,andtheideologyofthe organization.Inadditiontothesecommonlycitedfactors, I argue that the existence of youth bulgesinasocietyalsoincreasetheprobabilityofadoptingviolentstrategiesbyethnopolitical organizations. Frustrated young males under repressive and authoritarian regimes tend to be

8 likely recruits for violent organizations. I use the Minorities at Risk Organizational Behavior

(MAROB) dataset, which includes 118 organizations in 16 countries of the Middle East and

North to test my hypotheses. Even though the level of analysis and also degree of violencediffersfromthepreviouschapter,thefindingssuggestthatsimilarcausalfactorsthat promote domestic armed conflict such as socioeconomic grievances, existence of repressive states, and youth bulges also increase the probability of use of violent strategies by ethno politicalorganizations.Ethnopoliticalorganizationsthathaveareligious/Islamistideologyare nomoreconflictpronethanotherorganizations.Thesefindingsareconsistentwiththefindings ofthepreviouschapter;socioeconomicfactorsandpoliticalopportunities/constraintsratherthan religiondrivesthedecisiontoresorttoviolence.Somescholarsarguethatyouthhaveplayeda significantroleduringtherecentuprisingsintheMiddleEast.Thoseyoungpeople,dissatisfied with their oppressive regimes and frustrated with unemployment, rebelled against their governments(HoffmanandJamal2012;Mohammed2011).Thefindingsofthischaptersupport theargumentthattheexistenceofyouthbulgesintheMiddleEastincreasestheprobabilityof resortingtoviolence.

Inchapter4,IexaminecausalfactorsthatcontributetomoderationofIslamistparties.

Whileexploringtheconditionswhichfosterpolitical violence and radicalism is an interesting and important research question, the process of deradicalization and moderation of Islamist parties is equally important, which remains underexplored. In this respect, exploring the evolution of radical Islamist parties (moderation process) will yield important clues to better understandintheMuslimworldand formulatemore cohesivepoliciesinthe wakeofthe“ArabAwakening.”Shiftingfromradicaltomoderatepositionshasbeenacommon trend for many Islamist parties. However, there exists great variation—both among Islamists

9 andothers—astowhatthenotionofmoderationrefers.Moderation,hence,hasbecomeacatch allterm.WhatformsdoesIslamistmoderationtake,andwhichfactorsunderlieeachformof moderation?Althoughaprevalentquestioninrecentyears,lessisknownaboutthecausesand forms of Islamist moderation in a systematic fashion. By building on the findings of the

Communist moderation literature, I introduce a twostage framework to explain variation in

Islamist moderation over time and across space: tactical vs. ideological moderation. Tactical moderation refers to the kind of moderation where radical parties leave armed struggle and decide to accept electoral democracy as a means to achieve ideological goals without compromising their platforms. Structural factors such as political liberalization, international factorsandstaterepressionarecausesoftacticalmoderation.Ideologicalmoderationpertainsto shiftsinplatformfromaradicalnichetomoremoderate lines to respond to societal changes

(economic liberalization, economic growth, electoral loss and changing voter preferences) to gaingreaterpopularsupport.Empirically,theItalianCommunistPartyandthePartyfor andDevelopmentinMoroccoareanalyzedinacomparativeperspective.

Finally,chapter5summarizesthekeyfindingsandcontributionsofthisdissertationto thesocialscienceliterature.Ialsodiscusspotentialpolicyimplicationsandprovidefinalremarks forfutureresearchinthisconcludingchapter.

10 Reference List

Appleby,R.Scott.2000. The Ambivalence of the Sacred: Religion, Violence, and Reconciliation, NewYork:RowmanandLittlefield Armstrong, Karen. Think Again: . Foreign Policy, November/December 2009, Retrieved from http://www.foreignpolicy.com/articles/2009/10/19/god_0?page=full Ayoob,Mohammed.2005.TheFutureofPoliticalIslam:TheImportanceofExternalVariables. International Affairs 81(5):951961 Berger, Peter L. 1999. The Desecularization of the World: Resurgent Religion and World Politics.NewYork:RandomHouse Canetti,Daphna;StevanEHobfoll,AmiPedahzurandEranZaidise.2010.MuchAdoAbout Religion: Religiosity, Resource Loss, and Support for Political Violence. Journal of Peace Research 47(5):575587. Coward, Harold G. and Gordon S. Smith. 2004. Religion and Peacebuilding . Albany: State UniversityofNewYorkPress. Dalacoura,Katerina.2011 . Islamist Terrorism and Democracy in the Middle East .Cambridge: CambridgeUniversityPress. Fish,StevenM.,Jensenius,FrancescaR.,andKatherineE.Michel2010.IslamandLargeScale PoliticalViolence:IsThereaConnection? Comparative Political Studies 43(11):13271362 Fox,Jonathan.2004.ReligionandStateFailure:AnExaminationoftheExtentandMagnitudeof ReligiousConflictfrom1950to1996. International Political Science Review 25(1):5576 Hafez, Mohammed M. 2003. Why Muslims Rebel: Repression and Resistance in the Islamic World .RiennerPublishersInc:Colorado. Hoffman, Michael and Jamal Amaney. 2012. The Youth and the Arab Spring: Cohort DifferencesandSimilarities. Middle East Law and Governance 4:168–188 Huntington,Samuel.1996. The clash of civilizations and the remaking of world order .NewYork: Simon&Schuster. Kurzman, Charles. 2011. The Missing Martyrs: Why There Are so few Muslim Terrorists . USA:OxfordUniversityPress. Laquer,Walter.2003. No End to War: Terrorism in the Twenty-First Century .NewYork:The ContinuumInternationalPublishingInc.

11 Mandaville,Peter.2007.GlobalPoliticalIslam.NewYork:Routledge

Mohammad,AlMomani.2011.TheArab“YouthQuake“:ImplicationsonDemocratizationand Stability. Middle East Law and Governance ,3(12):159170 Mousseau, Michael. 2011. Urban poverty and support for Islamist terror Survey results of Muslimsinfourteencountries.Journal of Peace Research 48(1):3547. Philpott,Daniel.2007.ExplainingthePoliticalAmbivalenceofReligion.American Political Science Review ,101(3):505525 Roy,Olivier.2004. Globalised Islam: The Search for a New .London:Hurst Sørli,Mirjam,GleditschNillsPetter,andHavardStrand.2005.WhyIsThereSoMuchConflict intheMiddleEast? Journal of Conflict Resolution 49(1):141165. Toft, Monica Duffy. 2007. Getting Religion? The Puzzling Case of Islam and Civil War. International Security .31(4):97131. Toft,MonicaD.,DanielPhilpott,&TimothyS.Shah.2011. God ‟s Century: Resurgent Religion and Global Politics ,NewYork,NY:W.W.Norton&Company. Vertigans,Stephen.2009.MilitantIslam:ASociologyofCharacteristics,Causes,and Consequences.NewYork:Routledge. Zaidise,Eran;DaphnaCanettiNisim&AmiPedahzur.2007.PoliticsofGodorpoliticsofman? TheroleofreligionanddeprivationinpredictingsupportforpoliticalviolenceinIsrael. Political Studies 55(3):499–521

12

CHAPTER 2

The Puzzling Case of “Islamic Violence”: What Explains Prevalence of

Domestic Armed Conflicts in the ?

13 A. Abstract

Despiteconsiderableinterestintherelationshipbetween Islamandpoliticalviolence, there is little systematic empirical research that explores the intrastate conflict pronenessofcountrieswithlargeMuslimpopulations.Thestudiesthatdoexisteither offerinconclusiveevidenceofarelationshiporsufferfrommethodologicalflawsthat bringintoquestiontheirveryfindings.Ifweanalyzetheproportionofcountrieswith largeMuslimpopulationsthatexperiencedomesticarmed conflicts, Muslimmajority statesdoinfactstandout.Howcanweexplainthishighhazardofintrastateconflict amongcountrieswithlargeMuslimpopulations?Towhatextent,ifatall,Islamicfaith is a contributing factor to this phenomenon? Indeed, might there be potentially overlooked socioeconomic or political characteristics that explain the seeming associationbetweenIslamandintrastateconflict?Thesequestionshaveyettobefully addressed.Inanattempttofillagapintheextantliterature,thischapterinvestigatesthe empirical nexus between Islam and domestic armed conflict through the conditional factorsofrelativedeprivationandopportunitystructures.Iarguethathigherprevalence ofrepressiveregimes,poverty,andyouthbulgesmakeMuslimpluralitycountriesvery vulnerabletodomesticarmedconflicts.Further,theroleofstaterepressionisexamined inrelationtodomesticarmedconflictonset,whichhaslargelybeenignoredinexisting research. Utilizing Uppsala Conflict Data Program’s recent data for the 19812009 period,thefindingsindicatethatMuslimpluralitystatesareindeeddisproportionately involvedindomesticarmedconflicts,butthesestatesarealsocharacterizedbylower GDPpercapita,oildependency,staterepression,autocracy, and youthbulges,allof whichcorrelatestronglywithdomesticarmedconflictonset.ThesignificanceofIslam disappearswhencontrolsforsuchfactorsareincludedinthestatisticalmodel.Among thefactorsthatincreasetheriskofdomesticarmed conflict, the presence of a youth bulgehasthegreatestimpactinMuslimpluralitycountries.

14 B. Introduction

Notsurprisingly,thetragiceventsof9/11ledtogrowinginterestinthetopicofreligionand

violenceforthecommonaudienceandforscholarsalike. As the terrorists were selfdeclared jihadists,itwasalsonosurprisethatIslambecameverycloselyassociatedwithpoliticalviolence.

While it is true that a large proportion of terrorist attacks during recent decades have been

committedbyMuslimsinthenameofIslam(Fishetal2010),somescholarsblametheWestern

mediaforanexaggeratedandundueassociationofIslamandviolence(Ahmed2011;Said1997).

AprominentinstanceisthebombingoftheFederalOfficebuildinginOklahomaCityin1995

anditsinitialattributiontoMuslims(Ahmed2011). Similarly, when Anders Behring Breivik killed76civiliansinNorwayin2011,somemediaoutletsintheUSrushedtoblameMuslims.

The New York Times featured a headline: “Powerful Explosions Hit Oslo; Jihadis Claim

Responsibility.” Interestingly, the killer was initially labeled a terrorist; once the media discovered that the attack was committed by a right wing Norwegian, he was described as a

“madman”orsimplyas“insane.” 4

Besidesthemedia,many scholarseitherimplicitly or explicitlyarguethatthe Islamic

faithisparticularlyconflictprone(BenDorandPedahzur2003;Huntington1993;1996;Lewis

2001; 2003; Pipes 2003; Toft 2007). For example, Huntington (1996) argues that “Islam has bloodybordersandbloodyinnards”.Huntingtoncontendsthatfutureconflictsintheworldwill be between different civilizations, especially between the Islamic and Western civilizations.

However, Huntington’s thesis relies on a selective reading of history. Numerous quantitative

studieshavetestedHuntington’sconjecturesandfoundlittleornoempiricalsupport. 5Historian

BernardLewis(1990:8)statesthat“Itshouldbynowbeclearthatwearefacingamoodanda 4“WhenitiseasytoblameMuslims”,Today’sZaman,July272011;Dr.AbdullahiSheikhRashid. 5ManystudieshavechallengedHuntington’sthesis.Foracomprehensivelistofquantitativestudiestesting Huntington’sthesis,seeFox(2007:366). 15 movementfartranscendingthelevelofissuesandpoliciesandthegovernmentsthatpursuethem.

Thisisnolessthanaclashofcivilizations—theperhapsirrationalbutsurelyhistoricreactionof an ancient rival against our JudeoChristian heritage, our secular present, and the worldwide expansionofboth.”ThereisalsosomeevidencethatMuslimmajoritystatesaremorelikelyto engageindomesticconflictsthanotherstates(Fox2007;Toft2007).Ontheotherhand,some scholarscriticizethetendencytotheIslamicfaithasviolenceproneandrefertothe diversity within the Muslim world and suggest that other socioeconomic factors explain the seeming conflictproneness of Muslim countries (Ahmad 2011; Esposito 1992; Hafez 2003;

Zaidiseetal2007).

WhiletheoreticaldebatesabouttheroleofIslaminpromotingconflictareabundant,as

Fishetal.(2010)andFox(2004)note,thereareonlyahandfulofsystematicempiricalstudies.

TheextantresearchontherelationshipbetweenIslamandviolencelargelyreliesoncasestudies, whichpreventsmakingbroadgeneralizations(Fish2011).Further,theexistingstudiesprovide mixedevidenceregardingIslam’sroleinpromotingdomesticconflict(Fishetal2010;Fox2007;

Sorlietal2005;Toftetal2011).Whilereligioncaninciteconflictbyinfluencingtheidentity, loyalty,andpoliticalgoalsofpeople,religiousendsandidentitiesmixwithnonreligiousgoals inmanyconflicts(Philpott2007).ThischapterarguesthatIslamalonedoesnotnecessarilymake countries more or less conflictprone. Indeed, existing studies that conclude that Muslim majority countries are characterized by a higher rate of domestic armed conflict and political violence fail to control for factors that increase the risk of conflict, such as socioeconomic development,staterepression,andoildependence,andconfoundmanyvariablesunder“Islam”.

Withoutcontrollingforconfoundingfactors,wecannotevaluatetheimpactofIslamonconflict properly.

16 This chapter focuses on the onset of domestic armed conflict and contributes to the researchonIslamandpoliticalviolencebyexaminingthecausalfactorsthatexplainvariationin the prevalence of domestic armed conflict in Muslimplurality states 6 . I argue that higher prevalenceofrepressiveregimes,youthbulge,andoildependenteconomies,allofwhichhighly

correlate with domestic armed conflict onset, make Muslimplurality countries particularly

vulnerable to intrastate conflicts. In other words, Muslimplurality states should be no more

conflictpronethanothersoncewecontrolforthecorrelatesofdomesticarmedconflict.This

chapteralsocontributestotheliteratureondomesticarmedconflictbyexploringtheroleofstate

repression(whichhaslargelybeenoverlooked)inincreasingtheriskofdomesticarmedconflict.

Thischapterisorganizedintofivesections.First,IreviewtheliteratureonIslamand politicalviolence,anddomesticarmedconflictonsetrespectively.Next,Idiscussmytheoryand hypotheses.Then,Isummarizedata,methods,andmyresearchdesign,whichwillbeusedtotest thederivedhypotheses.Idiscussempiricalfindingsinthefourthsection.Lastly,implicationsof thesefindingsandsomesuggestionsforfutureresearchareprovidedintheconcludingsection.

C. Islam and Political Violence

Despite historical evidence to the contrary, Islam is commonly associated with violence and terrorismbytheUSmediaandsomescholars.Muslimshave historicallybeenmostlypeaceful andtolerant.Justtwodecadesago,secularandnationalistideologieswerefarmorepopularthan religiousonesintheMiddleEastandsuicideterrorinthenameofjihadwasveryrare(Mousseau

2011).Yet,somescholarsarguethatthecoreprinciplesofIslamincludeintolerantviewstoward nonbelievers andthat Islamisinherently violenceprone. The scholars who attribute conflict pronenessofMuslimstoIslamlargelyrelyontheconceptofjihadandsomeselectiveverses fromtheKorantosupporttheirarguments(Laquer2003;Pipes2003;Toft2007).Forinstance, 6MuslimpluralitystatesaredefinedascountriesinwhichIslamisthemostcommonlypracticedreligion. 17 Laquer (2003) argues that violence is blessed in Islam if it is carried out against infidels

(nonbelievers)andthereisnoroomforthemintheIslamicfaith.Similarly,Pipes(2003)claims thattheviolencepronenessofMuslimsstemsfromtheverynatureofIslam:theobligationof jihad.Jihadisanwordwhichliterallymeans“struggle”anditistranslatedas“holywar” byPipes.

However, this highly controversial concept of “Jihad” can be interpreted in different ways;asmallminorityoffundamentalistMuslimsthinkjihadjustifiesphysicalviolenceagainst

“infidels”whereasthevastmajorityregarditasaninternalstruggletobeamorallybetterperson

(e.g., by fighting off immoral desires). Roy (2004) notes that jihadist Islam is a product of sociological changes. Traditionally, jihad was understood as a collective, defensive duty, but modernradicalsviewitasanindividualpermanentdutytofightagainsttheWest.Islamisalso portrayedasatotalitarianandpoliticallyorientedreligion(Zaidiseetal2007). Islamhasnot undergoneareformationlikeChristianity,whichseparatedthereligiousandpoliticalspheres; religiouslyorientedviolenceisattributedtothelackofsecularstatesystemsintheMuslimworld

(Appleby2000;Toft2007).

Toft (2007) argues that in Abrahamic traditions violent conflict is regarded as a manifestationofGod’swill.Thesetraditionstendtobeuncompromisingandencouragepeople to sacrifice in this world (for eternal reward in the afterlife) to defend their faith. Thus, the indivisibility of religious doctrines and the promise of martyrdom render bargaining and deterrenceuseless.RadicalIslamicgroupspromisespiritualincentives(paradise)toindividuals; therefore,highcostactivitiesinthepresentlifebecomerationalsincethefuturebenefitsexceed thecosts(WiktorowiczandKaltenthaler2006).Allinall,eventhoughthesescholarsdonot necessarilydifferentiateMuslimmajoritystates’tendencytoengageininterstateorintrastate

18 conflicts,theygenerallycharacterizeMuslimmajoritycountriesasmoreviolence/conflictprone andattributethistoIslam.However,theMuslimworldisverydiverse;thereisnouniqueIslam practicedbyallMuslimsintheworld.ThesecleavageswithinIslampreventtotreatIslamasa single monolithic entity and draw a conclusion regarding Islam’s role in promoting conflict.

Extremists,whorefertosomeselectivereligiousdoctrinestojustifyuseofviolence,existinall religions.

Asmentionedabove,thereareonlyafewempiricalstudiesthatexaminethelinkbetween

Islam anddomestic armedconflict.Sorliet. al (2005) observe that Islam is not a significant factor in driving civil war once they control for other explanatory factors such as economic development,oildependency,ethnicdiversityetc.Similarly,Fishetal.(2010)examineIslam’s conflictpronenessbyanalyzingepisodesoflargescale political violence that occurred during

19462007.TheyobservethatthereisnosignificantcorrelationbetweentheMuslimproportion livinginacountryandthenumberofdeathsinpolitical violence episodes. The authors also examinewhetherradicalasanideology,ratherthantheIslamicfaith,isassociatedwith politicalviolence.Theyrelyonpressreportsandsecondarysourcestocodeconflictsinstigated byIslamists.ThefindingsindicatethatIslamistideologyisinvolvedinelevenpercentoftotal episodesandaccountedforsixteenpercentoftotaldeaths.Eventhoughonemayconcludethat theepisodesinvolvingIslamistsseemtoaccountforadisproportionateamountofdeaths,Fishet al. note that some episodes were instigated by both Islamist and other actors who bear joint responsibility.

Ontheotherhand,Toft(2007)findsthatinfortytworeligiouscivilwarsfrom1940to

2000,eightyonepercenthadeitherincumbentgovernmentsorrebelsidentifiedwithIslam.In

fiftyeightpercentofreligiouscivilwars,Islamwasthedominantreligion.ToftexplainsIslam’s

19 overrepresentation in civil wars with historical (lack of Thirty Years’ War and the Peace of

WestphaliainIslam),geographic(proximityofIsrael,oilreserves,andIslam’sholiestsites),and particularlyideological(jihad)factors.ToftnotesthatthedestructivenessoftheThirtyYears’

WarandthefollowingEnlightenmentperioddecreased the power of religious authorities and resultedinthedevelopmentofthemodernsecularstatesysteminEurope.Incontrast,theIslamic worldhasnotexperienceditsownThirtyYears’War,whichmayhaveenabledacontinuedrole ofreligioninpolitics.ThegeographicproximityofoilreservesandIslam’sholiestsites,Western industrialstates’interestintheMiddleEast,andcolonialexperiencealsocontributedtotherise ofIslamicidentityandradicalization.Lastly,Toftemphasizestheconceptofjihadtoexplainthe prevalenceofcivilwarsintheMuslimworldandarguesthatviolenceisjustifiedinIslamto defend the faith from unbelievers. Toft provides some historical examples to support her argument,suchasMuslimfighterswhoarrivedfrom,,andSaudiArabiatohelpthe

AfghanmujahedeencombatSovietinvasionin1979.

However,Toft’s(2007)findingssufferfromseveralmethodologicalweaknesses.First,

Toftbasesherconclusionsonmeredescriptivestatistics,whichpreventsdrawinganyinferences aboutthedriversofcivilwar.Second,theauthordoesnotattempttoaddressthepossibilityof spuriousrelationshipsthroughtheuseofamultivariatestatisticalmodel.Toftonlylooksatmere percentagesofcivilwarsinwhichIslamissomehowinvolved.Also,Toftprovidesinsufficient informationaboutthecodingofreligiouscivilwars,particularlythosethatareassociatedwith

Islam.Toft(2007:112113)providesdetailedinformationaboutthecriteriatobecodedasacivil warbutdoesnotprovideanyexplanationaboutthecodingof“religiouscivilwars”orcivilwars inwhichIslamisinvolved.Forexample,Toftstatesthat“ofthefortytworeligiouscivilwars foughtfrom1940to2000,oneorbothpartiesadheredtoIslaminastrikingthirtyfourcasesand

20 thirtyfourofthecivilwarshadanIslamiccomponent”(2007:113).Toftdoesnotexplainwhat exactly“adherencetoIslam”or“Islamiccomponent”means.

Inarecentstudy,Fox(2007)testsHuntington’s“clashofcivilizations”thesisandfinds partialsupportforHuntington’sargumentaboutIslam’sconflictproneness.FoxusestheState

Failuredatasettooperationalizedomesticconflictsbetween1960and2004.Foxexaminesboth intrareligious and interreligious conflicts in which at least one party invokes religion. Fox

(2007)findsthat,whiletheIslamiccivilizationisfoundtobemoreconflictprone,themajority of conflicts involving Islamic countries is with other Muslimmajority states (not with other civilizations).Foxalsoobservesthatbeginningin2002,religiousconflictsbecameamajorityof allconflicts.However,Fox’sstudysuffersfromoversimplificationandfailuretocontrolforwar onset factors. Fox relies on comparative analysis of proportion of state failures in Muslim majorityandothercountries.

Insum,thereissomeevidencethatdomesticarmedconflictsaremorecommonamong

Muslimmajority states compared to other countries. Yet, it is not possible to draw a causal relationshipbetweenIslamandtheriskofdomesticconflictwithoutcontrollingforthecorrelates ofdomesticarmedconflict.Muslimmajoritystates’domesticconflictpronenessisexplainedby anumberofcompetingargumentsthatrelyoneithercasestudiesormeredescriptivestatistics.I argue that a more systematic analysis is necessary to investigate other potential explanatory factorsthataccountfor Muslimmajoritystates’involvement in intrastate conflicts. Below, I review the literature on domestic armed conflict onset which may help to explain the disproportionalinvolvementofMuslimmajoritycountriesindomesticconflicts.

21 Correlates of Domestic Armed Conflict

Therearenumerousquantitativestudiesthatexaminefactorsthatincreasetheriskofdomestic

armed conflict. Even though different scholars use different sets of variables and sometimes

disagreeonhowtooperationalizesimilarconceptsorprovidedifferentinterpretationsofsimilar

findings,atleastsomefactorsarefoundtoberobustlycorrelatedwithdomesticarmedconflict

onset.Economicfactors,theresourcecurse,demography,geographicandenvironmentalfactors,

ethnicandreligiousdiversity,conflicthistory,typeandregimechangeareamong

the commonly tested concepts which are deemed to impact risk of domestic conflict (Dixon

2009). Among hundreds of variables used to proxy some of the concepts mentioned above, population, GDP per capita, economic growth, democracy, political instability, small military

capacity,roughterrain, warproneneighbors, andoildependence are foundtobesignificantly

correlatedtodomesticarmedconflictandrobusttosensitivitychecks(Dixon2009;Hegreand

Sambanis2006).

Economicfactors,whicharegenerallyoperationalizedbyGDPpercapitaorannualGDP percapitagrowthrate,areamongthefewvariableswhicharerobustlycorrelatedwithdomestic armedconflictonset.Yet,GDPpercapitaisaverybroadconceptwhichcanbeinterpretedin different ways. For example, Collier and Hoeffler (2004)useGDPpercapitatomeasurethe opportunitycostofrebellion,whereasFearonandLaitin(2003)usethesamevariabletomeasure statecapacity.Indeed,itisreasonabletoassumethatcountrieswithlowGDPpercapitawould becharacterizedbylowstatecapacitiesorlowopportunitycostofrebellion.Regardlessofthe wayeconomicfactorsareinterpreted,itissafetoconcludethatpoorcountriesaremoreproneto intrastateconflicts.

22 Oildependence, or natural resource dependence, is another economic factor which increases the risk of domestic armed conflict. Oil rents make leaders less dependent on tax revenues,whichcreateweakstateinstitutions.Weakinstitutionsinturnincreasethefeasibility of rebellion (Fjelde 2009). Fearon (2005) argues that oil producers generally have low state capabilities,andthereforearemorepronetoconflict,whereasRoss(2006)claimsthatoiland othermineralsincreasetheriskofconflictbecausetheymakeindependencemoredesirablefor resourcerichregions.CollierandHoeffler(2004)confirmthattheexistenceofnaturalresources createsopportunitiestorebel.Naturalresourcedependenteconomiesmayalsomakecountries more conflict prone by increasing the probability of trade shocks (Humphreys 2005). On the otherhand,oilmoneycanalsobeusedtocooptpotentialdissidents,especiallyinpolitically corruptregimes,thusreducingtheriskofdomesticconflict(Fjelde2009).HegreandSambanis

(2006)’ssensitivityanalysissuggeststhatoildependenceismarginally robustwhereasnatural resourcedependenceisnotrobust.Therelativerobustnessofoildependencecomparedtonatural resourcedependenceisatheoreticalpuzzlethatcanbeexploredbyfuturestudies.Onepotential reasoncouldbemissingdataandmeasurementerrors.Ross(2006:265)notesthatthestudiesthat examinethelinkbetweennaturalresourcewealthandcivilwarsufferfrommeasurementerror, endogeneity problems, lack of robustness, shortage of data, and uncertainty about causal mechanisms.

Thedemographicandgeographiccharacteristicsofacountryalsoaffectthelikelihoodof domesticarmedconflict;conditionsthatfavorinsurgency,suchastotalpopulation,youthbulges, andmountainousterrainmakecountriesmoreconflictprone. Itishard tocontrolpeopleand deterinsurgencyinhighlypopulatedcountries.Indeed,populationisoneofthevariablesthat robustly and positively correlates with domestic armed conflict. Similarly, the existence of

23 mountainousterrainmakesiteasierforrebelgroupstohidefromgovernmentanditisrobustto sensitivityanalyses(HegreandSambanis2006).Theexistenceofayouthbulgealsoincreases theriskofdomesticconflict.Thereishistoricalevidence that violent outbreaks are correlated with the proportion of a society’s young male population. Young people tend to be more violencepronecomparedwithadults,becausetheytendtobemoreriskacceptantandtheyare notfullyawareoftheconsequencesoftheiractionsand(Fuller2003).Theexistenceofayouth bulge increases both grievances (especially when coupled with poverty, unemployment, and repressiveregimes)andthesupplyofpotentialrebelrecruits(Urdal2006).

The role of ethnic or religious diversity in promoting domestic conflict is debated by many scholars. Theoretically, ethnic and religious differences are likely to be sources of grievances and therefore increase the risk of intrastate conflict. Empirically, existing studies provide contradictory findings. Collier and Hoeffler (2004) find that greater social fractionalization (both ethnic and religious) actually reduces the risk of conflict. Hegre and

Sambanis (2006) show that ethnic fractionalization is robustly associated with the risk of domesticconflicts,inwhich25battledeathsisusedasathresholdtocodeconflicts,whereasitis insignificantincivilwarswhichhasatleast1.000battledeaths.Asfarasreligiousdiversityis concerned,thefindingsareagaininconclusive.DeSoysa(2002)findsthatreligioushomogeneity increasestheriskofcivilwarwhereasreligiousheterogeneitydecreasesit.Ontheotherhand,

ReynalQuerol’s (2002) analysis of ethnic civil wars indicates that religious polarization increases the risk of ethnic conflicts. Lastly, Fearon and Latin (2003) find no significant relationshipbetweencivilwarandreligiousfractionalizationbetween1945and1999.

Regimetypeisanotherimportantfactorwhichaffectstheriskofdomesticarmedconflict.

Semi are deemed to be more conflictprone since they are characterized by

24 insufficientrepressivenesstodeterviolenceandinsufficientopennesstoinducesubstitutionto nonviolent tactics (Hegre at al 2001). Both Hegre and Sambanis (2006) and Dixon’s (2009) analysesconfirmthatanocracyandinstitutionalinconsistency(changeinpolityscorepriortothe civilwar)arerobustlyassociatedwiththeriskofcivilwar.

Finally, more recent studies explore some new concepts which are ignored in the previousresearch,suchasstaterepression(JakobsenandDeSoysa2009;Young2012),different dimensionsofstatecapacity(FjeldeandSoysa2009; Gleditsch and Ruggeri 2010), political corruption(Fjelde2009)orfocusondevelopingbettermeasuresofexistingconcepts.Gleditsch and Ruggeri (2010) argue that Polity scores or GDP per capita are poor indicators of state strength and offer an alternative variable: irregular leader changes, which occur through a militarycouporviolenttakeoverofthegovernment,tomeasurestateweakness.Theauthorsfind thatirregularregimetransitionsindeedincreasetheriskofdomesticconflict.FjeldeandSoysa

(2009)examineimpactofstatecapacityandcategorizestatecapacityintothreetypes:coercion, cooptation,andcooperation.Theirfindingsindicatethathighgovernmentspending(cooptation) and trustworthy institutions (cooperation) can better reduce the risk of conflict than coercive state capacities. Jakobsen and De Soysa (2009) find that state repression in ethnically fractionalizedstatesnegativelyaffectsthelikelihoodofcivilwar,whereasitincreasestheriskof domesticconflictinethnicallyhomogenousstates.Young(2012)findsthatpoorandrepressive regimes are particularly more prone to conflict. Fjelde (2009) finds that while both oil and corruption alone increase the risk of civil war, the interaction of oil and political corruption actuallydecreasestheriskofcivilwar,whichsuggeststhatoildependencycanplayapacifying roleinpoliticallycorruptregimesthroughcooptingpotentialdissidents.

25 Insum,theliteratureondomesticarmedconflictonsetsuggeststhattherearenumerous factorswhichhavethepotentialtoincreasetheriskofdomesticconflictsandthereisno“right” setofvariableswhichshouldbeincludedinadomesticarmedconflictonsetmodel.Nevertheless, thanks to the development of more sophisticated statistical models and new data collection, considerable progress has been made in understanding the causes and correlates of domestic armedconflict.

Returning to the relationship between Islam and intrastate conflict, how do these potentialfactorsthatincreasetheriskofdomesticconflictoperateintheMuslimworldandto whatextentarethesefactorsseenamongMuslimpluralitycountries?Also,canweexplainthe prevalenceofdomesticconflictwiththesecommonlycitedcorrelatesofdomesticarmedconflict oristhereanothercausalmechanismthatmightbedrivinginsurgencyintheMuslimworld?In otherwords,istherean“Islamicexceptionalism”?Thesequestionsstillremainunderexplored.A more systematic and empirical analysis is required to examine the relationship between Islam andtheriskofintrastateconflict.Todoso,Irelyonanotherbodyofliteraturethatfocuseson theunderlyingcausesofradicalizationandviolenceintheMuslimworld.Inthenextsection,I reviewtheliteratureonradicalizationandviolenceintheMuslimworldandsynthesizeitwith thedomesticarmedconflictonsetliteraturefromwhichIderivemytestablehypotheses.

D. Theory and Hypothesis

Most of the research about Islamic is either descriptive or focuses on the unique ideological orientation of Islam and thus perpetuates “Islamic exceptionalism” (Wiktorowicz

2004).Since9/11,emphasizingIslamiccultureinexplainingmanyfailuresintheMuslimworld withoutproperresearchandevidencehasbecomeacommontrendinmanyfields(Roy2004).In thischapter,Iempiricallytestcompetingargumentsproposedbyscholarstoexplaindomestic

26 violenceintheMuslimworld.Accordingtotheliteratureonradicalizationandviolenceinthe

Muslimworld,theprevalentcausalfactorsofreligiousviolencecanbecategorizedintocultural explanations,relativedeprivation,politicalopportunitystructures,existenceofrentierstatesand youthbulges.

According to culturalidentity based explanations, Islamists adhere to radical religious identitiesasaresponsetoculturalimperialism,colonialhistory,andthegrowinginfluenceof

Western culture. These cultural arguments frame Islamic identity as violenceprone and emphasizethesalienceofreligiousculturalnormsamongMuslims(Ashour2009).Itisargued thatthefailureofsecularandliberalideologiesintheMuslimworldalsocontributestotherise ofIslamicfundamentalism(Appleby2000;Toft2007).Yet,identitydoesnotalwaysdetermine politicalbehavior.Surveysshowthatthereisnosignificantcorrelationbetweenpersonalpiety andpoliticalattitudes(Tessler2003).TesslerandRobbins(2007)findthatreligiousorientations do not seem to affect approval of terrorism among people living in and Algeria.

Unfortunately, it is hard to operationalize concepts such as radical Islamic identity. Due to limitations in data availability, I proxy Islamic identity with the most commonly practiced religion practiced in a country and the proportion of Muslims living in a country. I test the politicalcultureapproachwiththefollowinghypothesis:

Hypothesis 1a :Muslimpluralitystatesaremorelikelytohavedomesticarmedconflict

thannonMuslimstates,ceterisparibus.

Hypothesis 1b :Theriskofdomesticarmedconflictincreaseswithanincreaseinthe

proportionofMuslimswithinastate,ceterisparibus.

Social,economic,andpoliticalgrievancesandagrowing sense of relative deprivation arecommonly citedreasonsforreligiousviolence(Ansari 1984; Appleby 2000; Canetti et al

27 2010;Hafez2003) 7.TherelativedeprivationhypothesiswasoriginallyproposedbyTeddGurr’s

(1970) theory of conflict behavior. The role of grievances in increasing the risk of domestic armedconflictsisalsomuchdebatedintheliteratureoncivilwar.Further,somescholarsargue thatgrievancessuchashighinequality,lackofpoliticalrights,ethnicandreligiousdivisionsare therootcausesofcivilwar,whereasotherscontendthatgreed−theexistenceofanopportunity torebel(e.g.,naturalresources)−playsamoreimportantroleincivilwaronset(Collierand

Hoeffler2004;Collieretal2009;DeSoysa2002;FearonandLaitin2003).

Ansari(1984)arguesthatIslamistmilitancyisaproductofrapidurbanizationandrural migration. Studies show that militant Islamists tend to come from common backgrounds: educatedstudentsandprofessionalsintheirtwentiesandthirties,membersofthelowermiddle class,recentmigrantstocities,unemployedorunderemployed.Canettietal.(2010)alsoobserve therelationshipbetweenrelativedeprivationandpoliticalviolence.Theauthorsuseindividual surveysconductedamongMuslimsandJewslivinginIsraeltoexploretherelationshipbetween supportforpoliticalviolenceandreligiousaffiliation.Muslimsarefoundtobemoresupportive of political violence in general. However, Jews become more supportive of political violence oncetheycontrolforobjectiveandsubjectivedeprivationbyusingastructuralequationmodel.

Although limited in scope, the findings indicate that objective and perceived deprivation mediatesbetweenreligiousaffiliationandsupportforpoliticalviolence.Mousseau(2011)finds thatapprovalofIslamistterrorisnotassociatedwithreligiosity,lackof education,povertyor incomedissatisfaction,butratherwithurbanpoverty. Iftherelativedeprivationhypothesisis correct, then, socioeconomic grievances should be more prevalent among Muslimplurality statesandtheriskofdomesticconflictshouldincreasewithincreasing grievances.The above discussionleadstoonemoretestableconjecture. 7Massmediaincreasedawarenessofinequalitiesandgrievances 28 Hypothesis 2 :Theriskofdomesticarmedconflictinastateincreaseswithincreasing

socioeconomicgrievances.

Hafez (2003) contends that nonmilitant movements also emerged under unfavorable

socioeconomicconditionsandnotallMuslimsocietiesexperienceMuslimrebellion.Heargues

that the Muslim rebel is not the result of economic deprivation or psychological alienation produced by failed modernization but a response to indiscriminate state repression and

institutional exclusion. Hafez criticizes socioeconomic and psychological approaches for

ignoringtheresourcesrequiredtomobilizeandforsimplisticassumptionthatacertainlevelof

discontent almost automatically generates rebellion. Moreover, the relative deprivation

hypothesisignoresthepossibilitythatdeprivedindividualscouldalsoseekreformsbylobbying, petitioning,andformingpoliticalparties.Torebel,deprivedgroupsshouldbelievethatviolent

actionistheonlyoption.Therefore,politicalopportunitiesplayasignificantroleintransforming

grievances into militant action. Hafez (2003:19) proposes a “political process approach” to

Islamistrebellions.ThisapproachconsidersthepoliticalenvironmentinwhichIslamistsoperate,

themobilizationstructuresbywhichresourcesareacquiredandallocated,andideologicalframes

withwhich Islamistsjustifycollectiveaction. It isarguedthat whileexclusiveandrepressive

regimes promote violence, inclusive regimes decrease the probability of Islamist violence.

Hafez’s (2003) political process approach resemblesthefeasibilityhypothesisinthecivilwar

onsetliterature,whichfocusesonfactorsthatincreasethefeasibilityofrebellion(Collieretal

2009).

Staterepression,whichisanimportantfactorindeterminingthechoiceofviolentornon

violentstrategiesbydissidents,haslargelybeenignoredinthecivilwaronsetliterature(Young

2012).Repressionhasthepotentialbothtoincreaseanddecreasetheriskofdomesticconflict.

29 Ontheonehand,repressioncanincreasethecostofcollectiveactionanddeterrebellion.Onthe otherhand,repressioncanalsoincreasegrievancesandtheriskofconflict.Hafez(2003)argues thatthetimingandnatureofrepressionmatters;selectiveandpreemptiverepressionislikelyto deter rebellion, whereas indiscriminate repression and institutional exclusion breeds more violence.Guptaetal(1993)findthatrepressionbreedsbothviolentandnonviolentprotestsin democracies, whereas there is a curvilinear relationship between repression and violent/nonviolent protests in nondemocracies. Gurr (1970) also argues that there is a curvilinearrelationshipbetweenrepressionandrebellion.IexpecttofindaninvertedUshaped relationship between repression and domestic armed conflict. Repression initially increases domestic violence since grievances increase with more repression. However, extremely high levelsofrepressionshoulddecreasetheriskofconflictsincethecostsofcollectiveactionwillbe greaterinhighlyrepressivestates.

Hypothesis 3 :ThereisaninvertedUshapedrelationshipbetweenstaterepressionand

theprobabilityofdomesticarmedconflict.

GoingbacktothepoliticalprocessapproachproposedbyHafez(2003),thereareother political opportunities and constraints (in addition to state repression) which also affect the likelihoodofdomesticconflict.Ahigherproportionofyoungmales,whichincreasesthenumber ofpotentialdissidentsaswellasgrievanceswhencoupledwithunemploymentandpoverty,also makecountriesmorevulnerabletodomesticconflict (Urdal 2006). Finally, rebel groups need bothfinancialandhumanresourcestomobilizeandtorebelagainstagovernment.Oildependent or natural resourcedependent economies are also associated with a higher risk of domestic armedconflict.Indeed,themajorityofMuslimstateshaverepressiveauthoritariangovernments, oildependenteconomies,andanincreasingyouthpopulationthatisplaguedwithhighratesof

30 unemployment.Forexample,theMiddleEast,whichispredominantlyMuslim,hasthehighest rate of unemployment in the world: 15 million as of 2011. According to a report by the

International Finance Corporation and Islamic Development Bank, youth (ages 1524) unemploymentrateintheMiddleEastis25.1%comparedto12.6%intheworld asof2010 8.

MiddleEasterncountrieshaverichoilsuppliesaswell.SixGulfcountries−Bahrain,,

Oman, , Saudi Arabia and UAE− sit on nearly 500billionbarrelsofcrudeoiland41.5

trillioncubicmetersofnaturalgasreserves(HarriganandElSaid2011).Thecoexistenceofall

ofthesefactorscreatesapoliticalenvironmentthatisveryvulnerabletodomesticconflict.The

followinghypothesiswilltestthepoliticalprocessapproach:

Hypothesis 4: Theriskofdomesticarmedconflictincreasesifthereisarentierstateand agrowingyouthpopulationinastate.

E. Data, Methods, and Research Design

Thissectiondescribesthedata,methods,andresearchdesignthatIusetotestthehypotheses derivedintheprevioussection.Iexaminecausalfactorsthatincreaseacountry’sprobabilityof experiencingdomesticarmedconflict.Atimeseriescrosssectionaldataset,whichincludesall thestatesintheinternationalsystem,isusedtotestthehypothesesabove.First,Icomparethe prevalenceofdomesticarmedconflictsandsomesocioeconomicindicatorsinMuslimplurality countriestoothercountriesbyusingdescriptivestatistics.Then,Idevelopageneraldomestic armedconflictonsetmodelandconductlogisticregressionanalysis.

Thedependentvariableisdomesticarmedconflictonsetandtheunitofanalysisisthe countryyear.Sincereliabledataarerarelyavailableduringongoingwars,usingconflictonset rather than conflict prevalence is preferred. Following Collier and Hoeffler (2004), ongoing conflictyearsaredroppedforthepurposeofnotconflatingdomesticarmedconflictinitiation 8http://www.e4earabyouth.com/downloads/IFCBook_A4_Online_Complete.pdf 31 and duration. I utilize Uppsala Conflict Data Program (UCDP)’s recent data collected by

HarbomandWallensteen(2010)andGleditschetal(2002)whichcoversalldomestic armed conflictsthatoccurredbetween1945and2009.Theonsetdatasetcontainsannualobservations of172statesintheinternationalsystem,asdefinedbyGleditschandWard(1999).Eventhough thedataondomesticarmedconflictonset areavailablestartingfrom1945,itishardtofind reliabledataaboutsocioeconomicindicatorsbefore1980.Dataonoilproductionstartsfrom

1970whereasCIRIintegritydata,whichmeasurestaterepression,beginin1981.Giventhese datalimitations,Ianalyzetheperiodfrom1981to2009.

TheUCDP/PRIOconflictdatadefinesanarmedconflictas“acontestedincompatibility whichconcernsgovernmentand/orterritorywheretheuseofarmedforcebetweentwoparties, ofwhichatleastoneisthegovernmentofastate,resultsinatleast25battlerelateddeaths”

(Gledistchetal.2002:618).Intotal,thereare163domesticarmedconflictonsetsoutof4,079 countryyearobservations,or4%ofallcountryyearobservations.Theworkingsampleconsists ofonlyabout3.000countryyearobservationsduetothemissingdataonseveralexplanatory variables.All172countriesintheinternationalsystemareincludedintheanalysis.

Independent Variables

The main explanatory variables included in the analyses below include: Muslimplurality country,Muslimproportionofthetotalpopulation, GDP per capita, The CingranelliRichards

(CIRI)integrityscore,oilrents,naturalresourcerents,andtheproportionofyoungmales(ages between1524)inasociety.TheMuslimpluralityvariableisadummyvariablewhichtakesthe value1forcountriesinwhichIslamicfaithispracticedbyapluralityofthepopulation.This variable comes from Jonathan Fox’s (2004) Religion and State (RAS) project. I also use the proportionofMuslimslivinginacountrytoassesstherobustnessoftherelationshipbetween

32 Islamandpoliticalviolence.DataontheproportionofMuslimslivinginacountryaretaken from Kuru (2011). Kuru (2011) collected these demographic data from the International

ReligiousFreedomReports,theCIAWorldFactbook,andtheUSDepartmentofState'scountry analysisreports.GDPpercapitaintendstoproxyeconomic grievance (lower values indicates less development and hence more grievances). Purchasing power parity converted GDP per capita (constant in 2005 international dollars) data come from The Penn World Tables.

Unemployment rates and education data may better capture the existence of economic grievances,butthesedatahavemanymoremissingobservations.Infact,morethan50%ofthe observationsofthesetwovariablesaremissingintheWorldBankdata.IutilizetheCingranelli

Richards (CIRI) data to measure state repression. The Physical Integrity Rights Index is an additive index constructed from torture, extrajudicial killing, political imprisonment, and disappearanceindicators.Itrangesfrom0(nogovernmentrespectforthesefourrights)to8(full governmentrespectforthesefourrights).IrescaletheCIRIscoresfrom1to9inwhichhigher values indicate less government respect of human rights and more repression to make interpretation easier. I also include a squared term of repression to capture the hypothesized curvilinear relationship between state repression and conflict onset. Natural resource and oil dependencedatacomefromtheWorldBank’sWorldDevelopmentIndicators.Naturalresource dependencemeasuresthesumofoilrents,naturalgasrents,coalrents(hardandsoft),mineral rents,andforestrentsasapercentageofGDP.Oilrentsarethedifferencebetweenthevalueof crude oil production at world prices and total costs of production as a percentage of GDP.

Finally,thedataontheproportionofyoungmalesbetweentheageof15and24tototaladult malepopulation(15+)comefromtheUN’sWorldPopulationProspectsdata.

33 Ialsoincludethefollowingcontrolvariables,whichareexpectedtoincreasetheriskof domestic conflict (based on the findings of previous studies): ethnic fractionalization and religious fractionalization, a dummy for transitionary regimes, percentage of mountainous terrain,andtotalpopulation.Iusethepolity2score from the Polity IV project to control for regimetype.PreviousresearchsuggeststhatthereisaninvertedUshapedrelationshipbetween regimetypeanddomesticarmedconflictonsetandtransitionaryregimesaremoreconflictprone

(Hegre et al. 2001) I create a dummy variable to operationalize transitionary regimes; the countries that have polity 2 score between 5 and +5 are coded as anocracies. Ethnic and religiousfractionalizationdatacomefromFearonandLaitin(2003).Iextrapolatethedatafor yearsafter2000.Bothethnicandreligiousfractionalizationinasocietyhardlychangeovertime.

Theethnicfractionalizationindexgivestheprobabilitythattworandomlyselectedindividualsin a country are from different ethnolinguistic groups. Similarly, the religious fractionalization index measures the probability that two randomly selected individuals in a country are from differentreligions.Lastly,IusethenaturallogofGDPpercapita,percentageofmountainous terrain,andthepopulation.ThevariablesGDPpercapitaandrepressionarelaggedoneyearto avoidproblemsininferringcausaldirection.Table2.1summarizesthelistofvariablesusedin theempiricalanalysisandhowtheconceptsareoperationalized.

Table 2.1 about here

Since the dependent variable is dichotomous, I use a logistic regression statistical estimator to test my hypotheses, with robust standard errors clustered by country. Domestic armedconflictisarareevent;KingandZeng(2001)pointoutthatstandardlogisticregression modelsmightproducebiasedcoefficientestimateswhentheproportionofzeroestoonesisvery lowinthedependentvariable.IuseKingandZeng’sRelogitmethodtotestwhethertherare

34 event issue can generate any significantly different outcomes in the analysis. To control for unobserved heterogeneity which typically exists in a timeseriescrosssectional data set, I employarandomeffectmodelaswell.Toaddresstheproblemoftemporaldependence—the factthatforagivencountry,manyobservationsovertimearestatisticallyrelated—Ifollowthe adviceofCarterandSignorino(2010)byaddingnumberofpeaceyearssincethelastconflict, peace years squared, and a cubic term of peace years to each model. Carter and Signorino

(2010)arguethatpolynomialapproximationislesscomplexandeasiertointerpretthanusing

naturalcubicsplinessuggestedbyBecketal(1998).Finally,Ireportthepairwisecorrelationsof

theindependentvariablestoassessmulticollinearity.Thecorrelationmatricesareincludedin

Table2.5intheAppendix1 9.

F. Findings

If we only look at theproportion of Muslimplurality countries and the proportion of

domesticarmedconflicts,Islampluralitystatesareindeedmoreconflictprone.Sixtytwoof163

intrastateconflicts(38%)occurredinMuslimpluralitystates,whereas26.5%ofallstateshave

Muslimplurality population. Six percent of Muslimplurality states and 4% of all countries

experienced intrastate conflict respectively. Yet, a closer look at some of the explanatory

variablesthatincreasetheriskofdomesticconflictsuggestthatMuslimpluralitycountriesare

also associated with lower levels of life expectancy, lower GDP per capita, oildependent

economies,higherproportionofyoungmales,morestaterepressionandautocraticgovernments. 9ThereisahighcorrelationbetweenGDPpercapitaandyouthbulges(.76)whichleadstosomeconcernabout multicollinearityinthemodel.Unfortunately,thereisnostatisticalmethodtoovercomethemulticollineaity problem.AsArceneauxandHuber(2007)notes,droppingoneofthecollinearvariablesfromthemodelcanbias coefficientestimateswhereasmulticollinearityonlymakesestimateslessprecise.Moreover,theyouthbulge variableremainsinsignificantwhenIdropGDPpercapitafromModels4,5,and6.Similarly,theimpactofGDP percapitadoesnotchangewhenyouthbulgeisdroppedfromModels4,5,and6.Thefindingsdonotchangewhen GDPpercapitaisdroppedfromModel7whereasIslamyouthinteractionlosessignificancewhenGDPpercapitais droppedfromModel8.IdecidedtokeepbothGDPpercapitaandyouthbulgesintheregressionmodelssince droppingoneofthecollinearvariablesmightleadtoommittedvariablebiaswhichisdeemedtobemoreseverethan imprecisioninthestandarderrorofacoefficient. 35 ThemedianGDPpercapitainMuslimplurality statesis$2,761,whereasitisanaverageof

$7,011 for other countries and an average of $5,537 for the world. Similarly, median life expectancyinMuslimpluralitystatesis65.6comparedtoanaverageof70.1inothercountries.

ThemedianpolityscoreinMuslimpluralitystatesisonly6comparedto+7inothercountries.

Onaverage,oilrentsconstitute14.9%ofGDPinMuslimpluralitystateswhereasonly0.025% ofGDPcomesfromoilrentsinothercountries.Theproportionofyoungmalesis21%higherin

Muslimplurality states compared to other countries whereas the CIRI integrity score is 20% lower(whichindicatesthatMuslimpluralitystatesmoreoftenhaverepressiveregimes).Table

2.2comparesdescriptivestatisticsofMuslimpluralitycountriestononIslamiccountries.Given thelowerlevelsofGDPpercapita,lowerlifeexpectancy,alackofdemocracy,morerepressive regimes,higherproportionofyoungmales,andoilornaturalresourcedependenteconomies,itis not surprising to find higher rates of domestic conflict in Muslimplurality countries. The comparison of main explanatory variables in Muslimplurality states and other states provide suggests that both grievances−which motivate rebellion−, and natural resources, and human resources−whichprovideopportunitytorebel−aremoreprevalentintheMuslimworld.

Table 2.2 about here

Inordertobetterexploreroleofreligionindomesticarmedconflictonset,Ifirstestimate severalbivariateregressions.Then,Ispecifyamore complete theoretical model and examine severalinteractions.InModel1,IregressdomesticarmedconflictonsetonIslamandinclude onlypeaceyears,anditspolynomialcombinationstocontrolfortemporaldependence.Islamis positiveandsignificantwhichprovidessupportforHypothesis1ifweoverlookotherfactorsthat

makecountriesmoreconflictprone.However,thestatisticalsignificanceoftheIslamdummy

disappears when repression and its squared term are added to the regression in Model 2.

36 Repressionispositiveandsignificantwhereasthesquaredtermisnegativeandsignificantwhich confirmsthecurvilinearrelationshipbetweenrepressionanddomesticarmedconflictonset.In

Model3,Idroptherepressionandaddoildependencetotheregression.Similarly,theIslam dummybecomesinsignificantwhenoildependenceiscontrolledforeventhoughoildependence aloneisnotsignificanteither.ThebivariateregressionresultssuggestthattheIslamicfaithalone doesnotmakecountriesmoreconflictproneoncewecontrolforevenjustoneothervariablethat increasestheriskofconflict.Table2.3showstheresultsoftheseregressions.

Table 2.3 about here

InModel4,Idevelopageneraldomesticarmedconflictonsetmodeltoexploretherole

ofIslaminpromotingconflictonceonecontrolsforthecorrelatesofdomesticarmedconflict.I

include ethnic fractionalization, oil rents, logged GDP per capita, repression and its squared

term,proportionofyoungmales,adummyforanocracies,aMuslimpluralitydummy,andthe percentageofmountainousterrain.Ethnicfractionalization,population,anocracy,andoilrents

significantlyincreasetheriskofdomesticarmedconflictwhereasreligiousfractionalizationand

Muslimpluralityarenegativebutinsignificant.Repressionispositiveandsignificantwhereasits

squared term is negative and significant, which confirms the curvilinear relationship between

state repression and domestic armed conflict. The graph in Figure 2.1 shows the relationship between the predicted probability of domestic armed conflict and repression 10 . This finding supportsHypothesis3;repressioninitiallyincreasestheriskofdomesticarmedconflictdueto increasing grievances but extreme levels of repression decreases the risk of conflict since collectiveactionbecomesverycostlyandhencerebelgroupsaredeterred.Onepotentialcritique oftheimpactofrepressioncouldbethepotential endogeneity problem; increasing repressive 10 Iusedtheclarifyprogramtocalculatethepredictedprobabilities 37 measuresbyastatemaybepartoftheconflictratherthanacauseoftheconflictwhichlater escalatesintodomesticarmedconflict.Yetsimilarargumentscouldbemadeforothercorrelates of domestic armed conflict such as GDP per capita and regime type, which are commonly includedindomesticarmedconflictonsetmodels.Ilaggedthemeasureofrepressiononeyearto mitigatethisproblem.Asarobustnesscheck,Ialsolaggedthemeasureofrepressionfortwo yearsanditremainedstatisticallysignificant.Moreover,Idropongoingconflictyearsanduse onset of domestic armed conflict as my dependent variable, which mitigates endogeneity problems.

Figure 2.1 about here

Unlikepreviousstudies,GDPpercapitaandyouthbulgedonotseemtoaffecttheriskof domestic armed conflict. States characterized by oildependent economies, repressive regimes, transitionarypoliticalinstitutions,andethnicdiversityaremoreconflictprone,whereasneither

Islamnorreligiousdiversityhasanysignificanteffect.Forarobustnesstest,IusedbothKing andZeng(2001)’sRelogitprocedureandarandomeffectsmodel.Theresultsdidnotchange.I alsoreplacedtheMuslimpluralitydummywithMuslimproportionandtheresultsagaindidnot change 11 .OnecanreasonablyconcludethatthereislittlesupportforHypothesis1.

Inmodel5,Idropoilrentsandreplaceitwithnaturalresourcerents. Likeoilrents, naturalresourcerentsalsopositivelyandsignificantlyaffectthelikelihoodofdomesticarmed conflict onset. The anocracy variable loses significance whereas GDP per capita becomes negativeandsignificant.Thenumberofobservationsincreasesbyabout500inthismodel(since thevariableoilrentshasmoremissingdata),which might be the reason for slightly different

11 ThesealternativemodelspecificationsarereportedintheAppendix1,Table2.6,2.7,and2.8 38 findings.Alternatively,inclusionofoilrentsmightbethereasonfortheinsignificanceofGDP percapitainModel4.Eventhoughwealthiercountriesareexpectedtobelessconflictprone, those countries with both high GDP per capita and highly oildependent economies might actuallystillbevulnerabletodomesticconflict.Islamisstillinsignificantandagain,replacing theMuslimpluralitydummywithMuslimproportiondoesnotchangetheresults.Inmodel6,I add a dummy variable for countries in which Christianity is the most commonly practiced religion.LikeIslam,Christianityisalsoinsignificant.

Overall, these findings suggest that religious denomination alone does not necessarily make countries more or less conflictprone. State repression, which is previously ignored in many studies, significantly affects the likelihood of domestic conflict, whereas the impact of other variables is similar to previous studies. Even though Muslimplurality countries are no moreconflictpronethanothersonceonecontrolsforthecorrelatesofdomesticarmedconflict, onemaywonderwhatmayaccountforthehigherproportionofdomesticarmedconflictsinthe

Muslim world. In other words, what explains the variation in conflictproneness of Muslim pluralitycountriesspecifically?Toanswerthisquestion,Iinteractvariousexplanatoryvariables with Islam. The interactions of Islam dummy with all of the explanatory variables were all insignificant except youth bulgesIslam interaction. In Model 7, I interact the proportion of youngmaleswiththeMuslimpluralitydummy.Muslimpluralitydummybecomesnegativeand significant whereas the interaction of Muslimplurality and young male proportion is positive andsignificant.Interestingly,religiousfractionalizationisnegativeandsignificantinModel7.

Unliketheoreticalexpectations,increasingreligiousheterogeneityseemstodecreasetheriskof domestic armed conflict. Islamyouth interaction remains significant when I replace oil rents withnaturalresourcerentsinModel8.Whileyouthbulgesingeneraldonotmakecountries

39 moreconflictprone,theydoincreasetheriskofdomestic armed conflict in Muslimplurality countries. Yet, it is important to note that this finding is not robust to alternative model specifications;IslamyouthinteractionlosessignificancewhenIusearandomeffectsmodelor when the Islam dummy is replaced with proportion of Muslims living in a country. 12 These

findingsaresummarizedinTable2.4

Table 2.4 about here

ThesignificanceofIslamyouthinteractionisatheoreticalpuzzle,whichcanbeexplored byfutureresearch.Theoretically,youthbulgesalonedonotcreateproblemsinasociety.Young people usually become more prone to use of violence when they face unfavorable socio

economicandpoliticalconditionssuchasunemployment,poverty,incomeinequality,repressive,

andautocraticregimes.IcontrolforeconomicdevelopmentwithGDPpercapita,whichisavery

crude proxy variable. The existing crossnational data about unemployment or other socio

economicindicatorssuchasincomeinequalityoreducationhavemanymissingobservations.In

additiontothesepotentialexplanations,youngpeoplearemoreexposedtotheexternalworld,

which increase grievances and perceptions of relative deprivation. Moreover, social media

networkssuchasFacebookandmakeiteasierforyoungpeopletocommunicatewith

each other, to spread their ideas, to mobilize and rebel against governments. Indeed, young peopleplayedacrucialroleduringArabSpring.

IalsoestimatetheanalysisbyaddingtheinteractionsofIslamandGDPpercapita,Islam andoil,Islamandrepression,Islamandanocracy,andIslamandethnicfractionalizationoneata timetothemodel.Noneoftheinteractionswerestatisticallysignificant.When Iconductthe

12 ThesealternativemodelspecificationsarereportedinAppendix,Table2.6,Table2.7andTable2.8 40 analysisforonlyMuslimpluralitycountries,ethnicfractionalization,repressionandyouthbulge arepositiveandsignificantwhereasthesquaredtermofrepressionisnegativeandsignificant.

Surprisingly,oildependencedoesnotseemtomakeMuslimcountriesmoreconflictproneeven though there is a high correlation between Muslimplurality and oil rents (0.44), and oil in generalincreasestheriskofconflict.

Finally, I calculatepredictedprobabilitiesfordomesticarmed conflictonsettoexplore thesubstantiveeffectofotherexplanatoryvariablesusingModel8 13 .Domesticarmedconflictis arareevent;thepredictedprobabilityofdomesticarmedconflictisonlyonepercentwhenall explanatoryvariablesareheldattheirmeanvaluesanddummyvariablesaresetto0.Theriskof domesticarmedconflictincreasesby240%(from0.004to0.014)whenrepressionshiftsfrom

10thpercentileto90thpercentilevaluewhileall explanatory variables are held at their mean valuesanddummyvariablesaresetto0.Similarly,ashiftinethnicfractionalizationfrom10thto

90thpercentileleadsto208%increaseintheriskofdomesticarmedconflict.Thesubstantive impact of GDP per capita and natural resource dependence are relatively small; the risk of domesticarmedconflictdecreasesby72%whenloggedGDPpercapitashiftsfrom10thto90th percentile value whereas a shift from 10th to 90th percentile in natural resource dependence leads to only a 34% increase in the risk of war. The probability of domestic armed conflict increasesby224%whenloggedtotalpopulationshiftsfrom10thpercentileto90thpercentile whereasashiftoflogofpercentageofmountainousterrainfrom10thto90thpercentileleadsto

90%increaseintheprobabilityofdomesticarmedconflict.

13 Iuseclarifyprogramtocalculatepredictedprobabilities. 41 G. Conclusion

WhatexplainsvariationintheprevalenceofdomesticarmedconflictsintheMuslimworldand

towhichextentcouldreligionplayaroleinfosteringviolence?Inthischapter,Iconductatime

series and crossnational analysis to find answers to preceding research questions. Several

conclusions can be drawn from the analysis. Most importantly, contrary to suggestions and

claimsintheliterature,religionbyitselfdoesnotpromoteconflict;religiousdiversityisnegative

andinsignificantinalloftheregressions.Second,intrastateconflictsareindeedmoreprevalent

inMuslimpluralitystates,butsocial,economic,andpoliticalconditionsinthesestatescreatean

environmentwhichisverysusceptibletodomesticarmedconflicts.Muslimpluralitystatesare

characterizedbyahigherproportionof youthbulges, more repressive regimes, oil dependent

economies,andlowerGDPpercapita.Religiousdenominationdoesnotseemtomakecountries

moreorlessconflictproneonceonecontrolsforthesesocioeconomicandpoliticalconditions.

BothMuslimpluralityandinteractionsofMuslimplurality with various explanatory variables

remaininsignificantinmostoftheregressionsevenaftertryingdifferentoperationalizationof

Islam –use of Muslimplurality or Muslim proportion−, and alternative model specifications

(Randomeffects model, logit and relogit). Third, state repression, which is overlooked in previousstudies,issignificantinallofthemodels.Repressioninitiallyincreasesriskofconflict

due to increasing grievances, but extreme levels of repression actually decreases the risk of

conflictsincerebelgroupsaredeterred.Fourth,theinsignificanceofIslam*oilinteractionoroil

rentswhentheanalysisisrunforonlyMuslimcountriesispuzzling;previousstudiesaboutthe

causes of domestic armed conflict suggest that oil dependence increases the risk of conflict

(Fearon2005;Ross2012).Yet,oildependencedoesnotseemtoincreasetheriskofconflictin

Muslimplurality countries. Future research may focus on solving this puzzle. One potential

42 explanationcouldbethatleadersmayuseoilmoneytocooptorcontainpotentialdissidentsand thus prevent domestic conflicts as suggested by Fjelde (2009). Gause (2011) argues that autocraticleadersintheArabworldsuccessfullycooptedandcontainedmobilizationsagainst the governments until very recently. Finally, even though interactions of Islam with many explanatoryvariablesareinsignificant, Islamyouthbulgeinteractionpositivelyaffectsriskof domesticconflict.Futurestudiesmayfocusonexploringthecausalmechanismsbywhichyouth bulgesincreasesriskofdomesticarmedconflictintheMuslimworld.Somescholarsarguethat youthbulgeshaveplayedasignificantroleduringtherecentuprisingsintheMiddleEast;those young people, dissatisfied with their oppressive regimes and frustrated with unemployment, rebelled against their governments (Hoffman and Jamal 2012; Mohammed 2011). Future research can test conditional impact of youth bulges by interacting youth bulge with unemployment rate, and education. All in all, this chapter contributes to the literature by exploringcausalfactorsthatincreaseriskofdomesticconflictinMuslimpluralitystatesaswell asinotherstates.

43 Reference List

Arceneaux,KevinandGregoryA.Huber.WhattoDo(AndNotDo)withMulticollinearityin StatePoliticsResearch. State Politics and Policy Quarterly ,7(1):81101. Ahmad,IshamPawan.2011.WesternMisperceptionsAgainstIslamandtheMuslims AnAnalysis. Journal of Islam in Asia ,4:433451. AlanHeston,RobertSummersandBettinaAten,PennWorldTableVersion7.0,Centerfor InternationalComparisonsofProduction,IncomeandPricesattheUniversityofPennsylvania, May2011.

Appleby,R.Scott.2000. The Ambivalence of the Sacred: Religion, Violence, and Reconciliation, NewYork:RowmanandLittlefield Ansari,HamiedN.1984.The IslamicMilitantsinEgyptian Politics. International Journal of Middle East Studies 16(1):123144. Armstrong, Karen. Think Again: God. Foreign Policy, November/December 2009, Retrieved from http://www.foreignpolicy.com/articles/2009/10/19/god_0?page=full Argo, Nichole. 2006. The Role of Social Context in Terrorist Attacks. Chronicle of Higher Education. Ashour, Omer 2009. The De-Radicalization of Jihadists: Transforming Armed Islamist Movements .NewYork:Routledge Ayoob,Mohammed.2005.TheFutureofPoliticalIslam:TheImportanceofExternalVariables. International Affairs, 81(5):951961 Beck,Nathaniel,JonathanN.Katz,andRichardTucker.1998.TakingTimeSeriously:Time SeriesCrossSectionAnalysiswithaBinaryDependentVariable. American Journal of Political Science 42(4):12601288. BenDor,andAmiPedahzur.2003.TheUniquenessofIslamicFundamentalismandthe FourthWaveofInternationalTerrorism. Totalitarian Movements and Political Religions ,4(3): 7190

Berger, Peter L. 1999. The Desecularization of the World: Resurgent Religion and World Politics .NewYork:RandomHouse Canetti,Daphna;StevanEHobfoll,AmiPedahzurandEranZaidise.2010.MuchAdoAbout Religion: Religiosity, Resource Loss, and Support for Political Violence. Journal of Peace Research, 47(5):575587.

44 Carter,DavidB.,andCurtisS.Signorino.2010.BacktotheFuture:ModelingTimeDependence inBinaryData. Political Analysis 18(3):271292. Cingranelli,DavidL.andDavidL.Richards.2008.TheCingranelliRichards(CIRI) HumanRightsDataProject.Retrievedfrom: http://www.humanrightsdata.org/index.asp Collier, Paul and Anke Hoeffler.2004. Greed and Grievance in Civil War. Oxford Economic Papers ,50:56373. Collier,Paul,AnkeHoeffler,and DominicRohner.Beyond Greed and Grievance: Feasibility andCivilWar. Oxford Economic Papers 61(1):127. Coward,HaroldG.andGordonS.Smith.2004. Religion and Peace Building . Albany: State UniversityofNewYorkPress. Dekmejian,R.Hrair.1995. Islam in Revolution: Fundamentalism in the Arab World ,2 nd edition rev.Syracuse:SyracuseUniversityPress. DeSoysa,Indra.2002.ParadiseisaBazaar?Greed,Creed,andGovernanceinCivilWar,1989 99. Journal of Peace Research 39(4):395416. Dixon, Jeffrey. 2009. What causes civil wars? Integrating quantitative research findings. International Studies Review 11(4):707735. Eickelman,DaleF.2003.“InsidetheIslamicReformation,”in Revolutionaries and Reformers: Contemporary Islamist Movements in the Middle East ,ed.BarryRubinAlbany:StateUniversity ofNewYorkPress,pp.20306. ElSaid,HamedandRichardBarrett.2011.RadicalisationandExtremismthatLeadtoViolent ExtremismintheArabWorld.In Globalisation, Democratisation and Radicalisation in the Arab World, ElSaidandHarrington,eds.NewYork:PalgraveMacmillan. Esposito,JohnL.1992. The Islamic Threat: Myth or Reality ,NewYork : OxfordUniversity Press.

.2002. Unholy war: Terror in the name of Islam .NewYork:OxfordUniversityPress. Faksh,MahmudA.1997. The Future of Islam in the Middle East .Westport:Praeger. Fearon,JamesD.,andDavidD.Laitin.2003.Ethnicity,Insurgency,andCivilWar. American Political Science Review 97(1)7590. Fearon, James. D. 2005. Primary Commodity Exports and Civil War. Journal of Conflict Resolution 49(4):483507.

45 Fish,StevenM.,Jensenius,FrancescaR.,andKatherineE.Michel.2010.IslamandLargeScale PoliticalViolence:IsThereaConnection? Comparative Political Studies 43(11):13271362 Fjelde,Hanne.2009.BuyingPeace?OilWealth,CorruptionandCivilWar,1985—99. Journal of Peace Research 46(2):199218. Fox,Jonathan.2004.ReligionandStateFailure:AnExaminationoftheExtentandMagnitudeof ReligiousConflictfrom1950to1996. International Political Science Review 25(1):5576 .2007.TheRiseofReligionandtheFalloftheCivilizationParadigmasExplanations forIntrastateConflict. Cambridge Review of International Affairs 20(3):361382 Fox,Jonathan.(2004).TheReligionandStateProject.Retrievedfrom: http://www.thearda.com/ras/ Fuller,GrahamE.2003.Theyouthfactor:thenewdemographicsoftheMiddleEastand theimplicationsforUSpolicy.Draft,18Jan2003.Retrievedfrom: http://www.brookings.edu/fp/projects/islam/fuller2003.pdf Fuller,GrahamE.2004.TheFutureofPoliticalIslam. Foreign Affairs 81(2):4860 Gause,F.GregoryIII.2011.WhyMiddleEastStudiesMissedtheArabSpring:theMythof AuthoritarianStability. Foreign Affairs 90(4):81 Gleditsch,NilsPetter,PeterWallensteen,MikaelEriksson, Margareta Sollenberg, and Håvard Strand.2002.ArmedConflict19462001:ANewDataset. Journal of Peace Research 39(5). Gupta,DipakK.,HarinderSingh,andTomSprague.1993.GovernmentCoercionofDissidents DeterrenceorProvocation?Journal of Conflict Resolution 37(2):301339. Gurr,TedRobert.1970. Why Men Rebel .Princeton,NJ:PrincetonUP. ———.1988.War,Revolution,andtheGrowthoftheCoerciveState. Comparative Political Studies 21:4565. ———.1993.WhyMinoritiesRebel:AGlobalAnalysisofCommunal MobilizationandConflictsince1945. International Political Science Review , 14:161201. ———.1996.“Minorities,Nationalists,andEthnopoliticalConflict.”In Managing Global Chaos: Sources of and Responses to International Conflict ,ed. ChesterA.CrockerandFenOslerHampson.Washington,DC:UnitedStates InstituteofPeacePress,pp.5378.

46 ———.1999. Minorities at Risk Dataset. College Park, MD: Center for International DevelopmentandConflictManagement. ———.2000. Peoples versus States: Minorities at Risk in the New Century . Washington,DC:UnitedStatesInstituteofPeacePress. Gurr,TedRobertandWillH.Moore1997.EthnopoliticalRebellion:ACrossSectionalAnalysis ofthe1980swithRiskAssessmentsforthe1990s. American Journal of Political Science ,41: 10791103. Hafez, Mohammed M. 2003. Why Muslims Rebel: Repression and Resistance in the Islamic World .Colorado:RiennerPublishersInc. Harbom, Lotta and Peter Wallensteen, 2010. Armed Conflict, 19462009. Journal of Peace Research, 47(4) Harrigan,JaneandHamedelSaid.2011. Globalization, Democratization, and Radicalization in the Arab World .NewYork:PalgraveMacmillan Hegre, Havard, Tanja Ellingsen, Scott Gates and Nils Petter Gleditsch.2001. Toward a Civil Democratic Peace? Democracy, Political Change, and Civil War. American Political Science Review, 95:3348. Hegre,Håvard,andNicholasSambanis.2006.Sensitivityanalysisofempiricalresultsoncivil waronset. Journal of Conflict Resolution 50(4):508535. Hofheinz,Albrecht.2005.TheInternetintheArabworld:Playgroundforpoliticalliberalization. International Politics and Society, (3):7896.

Hoffman,ValerieJ.1995.MuslimFundamentalists:PsychosocialProfiles.In Fundamentalisms Comprehended , edited by Martin E. Marty and R. Scott Appleby. Chicago: University of ChicagoPress. Hoffman, Michael and Jamal Amaney. 2012. The Youth and the Arab Spring: Cohort DifferencesandSimilarities. Middle East Law and Governance 4:168–188. Horowitz, Michael C. 2009. Long Time Going Religion and the Duration of Crusading. International Security ,34(2):162193. Humphreys,Macartan.2005.NaturalResources,Conflict,andConflictResolution: UncoveringtheMechanisms, Journal of Conflict Resolution 49:50837. Huntington,Samuel.1993.Theclashofcivilizations? Foreign Affairs 72(Summer):2249. ———.1996. The clash of civilizations and the remaking of world order .NewYork:Simon& Schuster.

47 Jakobsen, Tor G., and Indra De Soysa. 2009. Give me Liberty, or Give me Death! State Repression,EthnicGrievanceandCivilWar,1981–2004. Civil Wars 11(2):137157. Karagiannis, Emmanuel & Clark McCauley. Hizb utTahrir alIslami: Evaluating the Threat PosedbyaRadicalIslamicGroupThatRemainsNonviolent. Terrorism and Political Violence 18(2) King, Gary, and Langche Zeng. 2001. Logistic Regression in Rare Events Data. Political Analysis 9(2):137163. Krueger, Alan B., and Jitka Malečková. 2003. Education, Poverty and Terrorism: Is There a CausalConnection? Journal of Economic Perspectives ,17(4):119–144.

Kuru, Ahmet T. “Rentier States and Regional Effects: in Muslimmajority Countries,”PaperPresentedatAPSAConference,September14,2011. Laquer,Walter.2003. No End to War: Terrorism in the Twenty-First Century .NewYork:The ContinuumInternationalPublishingInc. Lewis,Bernard.1990.TheRootsofMuslimRage.TheAtlanticOnline,September1990 ———.2001.Whatwentwrong?TheclashbetweenIslamandmodernityintheMiddleEast. NewYork:Perennial ———.2003.TheCrisisofIslam:HolyWarandUnholyTerror.NewYork:ModernLibrary Lichbach,MarkIrving.1987.DeterrenceorEscalation?ThePuzzleofAggregateStudiesof RepressionandDissent.TheJournalofConflictResolution,31(2):266297. Marshall,MontyG.,KeithJaggersandTedRobertGurr.2011.PolityIVProject: PoliticalRegimeCharacteristicsandTransitions,18002010.Retrievedfrom: http://www.systemicpeace.org/polity/polity4.htm McAdam,Doug(1982). Political Process and the Development of Black Insurgency, 1930-1970 .Chicago,IL:UniversityofChicagoPress. McCarthy,JohnD.andZald,MayerN.1977.ResourceMobilizationandSocialMovements:A PartialTheory. American Journal of Sociology 82(6):12121241.

Mohammad,AlMomani.2011.TheArab“YouthQuake“:ImplicationsonDemocratizationand Stability. Middle East Law and Governance ,3(12):159170.

48 Mousseau, Michael. 2011. Urban poverty and support for Islamist terror Survey results of Muslimsinfourteencountries. Journal of Peace Research 48(1):3547. Philpott,Daniel.2007.ExplainingthePoliticalAmbivalenceofReligion. American Political Science Review ,101(3):505525 Pipes,Daniel.2003. Militant Islam Reaches America .NewYork:W.W.Norton&CompanyInc. Piscatori,James.1994.“AccountingforIslamicFundamentalism”in Accounting for Fundamentalisms ,eds.MartinE.MartyandR.ScottAppleby,pp.36173.Londonand Chicago:UniversityofChicagoPress ReynalQuerol, Marta. 2002. Ethnicity, Political Systems and Civil War, Journal of Conflict Resolution .Vol.46(1):2954 Ross, Michael. 2006. A Closer Look at Oil, Diamonds, and Civil War. Annual Review of Political Science .9:265300. Roy,Olivier.2004. Globalised Islam: The Search for a New Ummah .London:Hurst. Russell,CharlesandBowmanMiller.1983.“ProfileofaTerrorist,”reprintedin PerspectivesonTerrorism,Wilmington,Delaware:ScholarlyResourcesInc.,pp.4560. Said,Edward.1997. Covering Islam: How The Media And The Experts Determine How We See The Rest Of The World .NewYork:VintageBooks. Sampson, Cynthia. 2007. Religion and Conflict: 273326, in Peacemaking in International Conflict: Methods & Techniques ed.byI.WilliamZartman.Washington,D.C.:UnitedStates InstituteofPeacePress Sørli,Mirjam,GleditschNillsPetter,andHavardStrand.2005.WhyIsThereSoMuchConflict intheMiddleEast? Journal of Conflict Resolution 49(1):141165. Soysa,DeIndra.2002.ParadiseIsaBazaar?Greed,Creed,andGovernanceinCivilWar,1989 99.JournalofPeaceResearch.39(4):395416. Schwedler, Jillian. 2007. Democratization, Inclusion and the Moderation of Islamist Parties.” Development 50(1):5661. Stephan,MarianandChenoweth,Erica.2008.WhyCivilResistanceWorks?TheStrategicLogic ofNonviolentConflict. International Security 33(1):744. Stephan,Marian2009. Civilian jihad: nonviolent struggle, democratization, and governance in the Middle East NewYork:PalgraveMacmillan

49 Svensson, Isak and Emily Harding. 2011. How Holy Wars End: Exploring the Termination PatternsofConflictwithReligiousDimensionsinAsia.TerrorismandPoliticalViolence23(2): 133149 Tarrow,Sydney.1998. Power in Movements (2nded.).Cambridge:CambridgeUniversityPress. Tessler, Mark. 2003. Arab and Muslim Political Attitudes: and Evidence from SurveyResearch. International Studies Perspectives ,4:175–181. Tessler,MarkandMichaelD.H.Robbins.2007.WhatLeadsSomeOrdinaryArabMenand WomentoApproveofTerroristActsAgainsttheUnitedStates?51(2):305328 TheUnitedNations.2010. World Population Prospects: The 2010 Revision. Retrievedfrom: http://esa.un.org/wpp/ Toft, Monica Duffy. 2007. Getting Religion? The Puzzling Case of Islam and Civil War. International Security .31(4):97131. Toft,MonicaD.,DanielPhilpott,&TimothyS.Shah.2011. God ’s Century: Resurgent Religion and Global Politics ,NewYork,NY:W.W.Norton&Company. Urdal, Henrik. 2006. A Clash of Generations? Youth Bulges and Political Violence. International Studies Quarterly 50(3):607629 Waltz,Susan.1986.IslamistAppealinTunisia. Middle East Journal 40(4):651670. Wiktorowicz, Quintan. 2004. Islamic Activism: A Social Movement Theory Approach. Bloomington&Indianapolis:IndianaUniversityPress Wiktorowicz,Quintan,andKarlKaltenthaler.2006. The rationality of radical Islam. Political Science Quarterly. 121(2):295319. WorldBank.2012. World Development Indicators .Retrievedfrom: http://data.worldbank.org/datacatalog/worlddevelopmentindicators Young, Joseph K. 2012. Repression, Dissent, and the Onset of Civil War. Political Research Quarterly.August:117. Zaidise,Eran;DaphnaCanettiNisim&AmiPedahzur.2007.PoliticsofGodorpoliticsofman? TheroleofreligionanddeprivationinpredictingsupportforpoliticalviolenceinIsrael. Political Studies 55(3):499–521.

50 Appendix 1: List of Tables

Table 2.1: Summary of Variables

Variable Name Concept

Islam Dummy for countries in which Islam is the most commonly practiced religion Log of GDP per capita Economic grievances Repression (rescaled CIRI score) Political constraints (repression) Oil rents (% of GDP) Rentier state status Natural resource rents (% of GDP) Rentier state status Muslim proportion Religion Anocracy Political opportunity structure (control variable ) Youth bulge Human resources Ethnic fractionalization Ethnic diversity (control variable) Religious fractionalization Religious diversity(control variable) Log of total population Population(control variable) % of mountainous terrain Geographic factors(control variable)

51 Table 2.2: Summary of Descriptive Statistics in Muslim-plurality and Other Countries

Muslim- Median St.dev. Min Max Other Median St. Min Max plurality countries dev. Countries GDP per 2761 .7 16852 .4 454.2 159144. GDP per 7011 .4 11814 136 89814 capita 5 capita Life 65 .6 10 .3 38.1 77.9 Life exp. 70 .09 10 .5 30.4 82.9 expectancy CIRI integrity 5 1.96 0 888 CIRI 6 2.01 0 8 integrity Polity −6 5.4 -10 9 Polity 7 7.02 -10 10 Prop. of 0.34 0.06 0.14 0.42 Prop. of 0.28 0.08 0.11 0.47 young males young males Oil rents 14 .9 18 .3 0 103.2 Oil rents 0.025 10 .05 0 79.5 (%of GDP) (%of GDP) Natural 9.8 25 .3 0 214.4 Natural 2.2 10 .9 0 80.6 resource resource rents (% of rents (% of GDP) GDP) Number of 62 Number of 101 domestic (38%) domestic (62%) armed armed conflicts conflicts Proportion 26.5% Proportion 73.5% of Muslim- of other plurality countries countries

52 Table 2.3 Bivariate Regressions

Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Islam .463* .0456 .292 (.250) (.290) (.306) Repression 1.12*** (.281) Repression square -0.081*** (.029) Oil rents .01 (.006) Peace years -.72*** -.44*** -.741*** (.160) (.174) (.178) Peace years 2 .066*** .036** .062*** (.018) (.017) (.019) Peace years 3 -.0014*** -.001** -.002*** (.000) (.000) (.000) N 4079 3443 3071

Note: Logit regressions, dependent variable: war onset. Standard errors are in parentheses. Asterisks (*, **, ***) indicate significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively. All regressions include an intercept (not reported).

53 Table 2.4: Risk of Domestic Armed Conflict (1981-2009)

Variables Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 Model 7 Model 8 Repression a .832** .586* .807** .895** .641** (.377) (.302) (.372) (.379) (.298) Repression squared a -.07* -.049 -.068* -.0771** -.054* (.038) (.031) (.038) (.039) (.031) GDP per capita a b -.129 -.353* -.182 -.209 -.390** (.215) (.184) (.214) (.220) (.192) Ethnic fractionalization 2.27*** 1.545** 2.30*** 2.36*** 1.606*** (.671) (.645) (.674) (.688) (.666) Religious fractionalization -1.049 -.663 -1.122 -1.183* -.689 (.732) (.702) (.736) (.730) (.681) Oil rents (% of GDP) .021** .0212** .020** (.008) (.009) (.009) Natural resource rents (% .009* .010* of GDP) (.005) (.006) Youth bulge(15 -24/15+) -4.084 -1.792 -4.232 -5.451* -3.735 (3.247) (3.128) (3.184) (3.282) (3.239) Islam -.413 -.024 -.234 -4.65** -3.983** (.344) (.317) (.434) (2.099) (1.995) Islam*Youth bulge 13.205** 11.598** (6.109) (5.595) Christian .307 .297 (.351) (.354) Anocracy .632** .415 .656** .605* .394 (.320) (.279) (.322) (.321) (.274) Population b .373*** .276** .399*** .397*** .274** (.128) (.110) (.126) (.130) (.111) % of Mountainous terrain b .165* .155* .167 .176* .191** (.103) (.092) (.104) (.102) (.095) Peace years -.229 -.259* -.231 -.228 -.248* (.149) (.137) (.147) (.145) (.138) Peace years 2 .011 .019 .011 .010 .018 (.014) (.013) (.013) (.013) (.013) Peace years 3 -.000 -.000 -.000 -.000 -.000 (.000) (.000) (.000) (.000) (.000)

N 2497 3007 2497 2497 3007

Note: Logit regressions, dependent variable: war onset. Standard errors are in parentheses. Asterisks (*, **, ***) indicate significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively. All regressions include an intercept (not reported). a: Lagged one year b: Logged

54 Table 2.5: Correlation of Independent Variables

Ethnic fr. Population GDP capita Youth bulge Polity Natural res. Relig. Fr. Muslim prop. Mount. Ter. CIRI Oil rents

Ethnic fr. 1.00 Population 0.02 1.00 GDP capita 0.38 0.08 1.00 Youth bulge 0.45 0.02 0.77 1.00 Polity 0.21 0.08 0.32 0.44 1.00 Natural res. 0.15 0.05 0.07 0.24 0.44 1.00 Relig. Fr. 0.38 0.08 0.06 0.01 0.04 0.03 1.00 Muslim prop. 0.10 0.05 0.14 0.29 0.58 0.41 0.12 1.00 Mount. Ter. 0.01 0.16 0.14 0.10 0.07 0.03 0.20 0.04 1.00 CIRI 0.24 0.27 0.54 0.53 0.46 0.23 0.07 0.29 0.24 1.00 Oil rents 0.10 0.04 0.01 0.19 0.45 0.82 0.04 0.40 0.08 0.22 1.00 Islam 0.02 0.04 0.10 0.25 0.52 0.42 0.14 0.95 0.03 0.27 0.42 Christian 0.15 0.18 0.21 0.34 0.56 0.26 0.03 0.70 0.00 0.33 0.25

55

Table 2.6: Random-Effects Model

Variables Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 Model 7 Model 8 Islam -.412 -.012 -.234 -4.795 -4.25 (.353) (.364) (.434) (3.5) (2.938) Islam*Youth bulge 13.139 12.44 (10.33) (8.464) Repression a .832** .704** .808** .922** .746** (.391) (.331) (.392) (.398) (.33) Repression squared a -.07* -.06* -.068* -.079** -.064** (.036) (.032) (.036) (.037) (.032) GDP per capita a b -.129 -.316 -.181 -.157 -.365* (.2) (.199) (.214) (.206) (.2) Ethnic fractionalization 2.266*** 1.753** 2.3*** 2.325*** 1.757*** (.675) (.675) (.683) (.676) (661) Religious fractionalization -1.105 -.48 -1.122 -1.113 -.509 (.825) (.855) (.84) (.826) (.84) Oil rents (% of GDP) .021** .021** .020** (.009) (.009) (.009) Natural res. rents (% of GDP) .009 .011 (.007) (.006) Youth bulge(15 -24/15+) -4.082 -.132 -4.232 -5.374 -2.4 (3.57) (3.75) (3.184) (3.654) (3.86) Christian .307 .296 (.41) .(415) Anocracy .631** .416 .656** .582* .401 (.314) (.281) (.316) (.315) (.28) Population b .373*** .35*** .399*** .370*** .338*** (.112) (.123) (.117) (.112) (.12) % of Mountainous terrain b .165 .192* .168 .172 .224* (.118) (.116) (.12) (.117) (.116) Peace years -.229 -.15 -.231 -.227 -.151 (.149) (.148) (.149) (.149) (.146) Peace years 2 .01 .012 .011 .01 .011 (.015) (.015) (.015) (.015) (.0145) Peace years 3 -.000 -.000 -.000 -.000 -.000 (.000) (.000) (.000) (.000) (.000) N 2497 3007 2497 2497 3007

56 Table 2.7: Relogit Model

Variables Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 Model 7 Model 8 Islam -.397 -.024 -.244 -4.325 -3.873 (.341) (.316) (.431) (1.98) (1.984) Islam*Youth bulge 11.877** 11.324** (5.859) (5.565) Repression a .762** .542* .739** .849** .599** (.376) (.3) (.37) (.383) (.297) Repression squared a -.063* -.044 -.062* -.072* -.049* (.037) (.03) (.037) (.038) (.03) GDP per capita a b -.134 -.352* -.182 -.159 -.386** (.213) (.183) (.212) (.219) (.19) Ethnic fractionalization 2.162*** 1.489** 2.197*** 2.2*** 1.542** (.666) (.642) (.666) (.68) (663) Religious fractionalization -1.001 -.655 -1.055 -1.061 -.672 (.727) (.698) (.73) (.723) (.677) Oil rents (% of GDP) .021** .021** .020** (.008) (.008) (.009) Natural res. rents (% of GDP) .009* .011* (.005) (.005) Youth bulge(15 -24/15+) -4.05 -.1.868 -4.157 -5.255 -3.765 (3.227) (3.11) (3.163) (3.32) (3.222) Christian .274 .254 (.348) (.351) Anocracy .624** .414 .645** .596* .392 (.318) (.277) (.32) (.318) (.273) Population b .362*** .271** .385*** .378*** .268** (.127) (.109) (.125) (.129) (.111) % of Mountainous terrain b .161 .153* .162 .168* .188** (.102) (.09) (.1) (.1) (.094) Peace years -.204 -.237* -.2 -.202 -.226* (.147) (.136) (.146) (.144) (.136) Peace years 2 .07 .016 .07 .07 .015 (.014) (.013) (.013) (.013) (.013) Peace years 3 -.000 -.000 -.000 -.000 -.000 (.000) (.000) (.000) (.000) (.000) N 2497 3007 2497 2497 3007

57 Table 2.8: Regressions with Muslim Proportion

Variables Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 Model 7 Model 8 Muslim prop. -.003 .000 .000 -.027 -.032 (.003) (.003) (.005) (.024) (.021) Muslim*Youth bulge .085 .097 (.073) (.063) Repression a .831** .587* .793** .858** .638** (.384) (.302) (.377) (.396) (.31) Repression squared a -.07* -.049 -.067* -.074* -.053* (.039) (.031) (.038) (.04) (.031) GDP per capita a b -.127 -.349* -.203 -.217 -.373** (.215) (.182) (.214) (.217) (.186) Ethnic fractionalization 2.245*** 1.524** 2.277*** 2.325*** 1.575** (.675) (.652) (.679) (.685) (.671) Religious fractionalization -.954 -.613 -1.072 -1.067 -.558 (.772) (.694) (.732) (.723) (.681) Oil rents (% of GDP) .019** .019** .02** (.009) (.008) (.009) Natural res. rents (% of GDP) .008 .009* (.005) (.005) Youth bulge(15 -24/15+) -4.288 -.1.838 -4.451 -5.88* -3.931 (3.258) (3.107) (3.178) (3.52) (3.436) Christian .483 .454 (.395) (.398) Anocracy .64** .415 .682** .661** .404 (.323) (.278) (.327) (.326) (.277) Population b .353*** .273*** .402*** .394*** .266** (.125) (.105) (.124) (.126) (.107) % of Mountainous terrain b .172* .156* .165 .175* .185** (.103) (.09) (.104) (.103) (.093) Peace years -.235 -.259* -.235 -.234 -.252* (.149) (.137) (.148) (.147) (.137) Peace years 2 .011 .019 .011 .011 .018 (.014) (.013) (.013) (.013) (.013) Peace years 3 -.000 -.000 -.000 -.000 -.000 (.000) (.000) (.000) (.000) (.000) N 2497 3007 2497 2497 3007

58 Table 2.9: List of Domestic Armed Conflicts

Algeria 1991-2009 1981 Lesotho 1998 Russia (Soviet Union) 1990-1991 Angola 1991-1993 Guinea 2000-2001 Liberia 1989-1990 Russia (Soviet Union) 1993 Angola 1994-1997 Guinea-Bissau 1998-1999 Liberia 2000-2003 Russia (Soviet Union) 1994-1996 Angola 1998-2001 Haiti 1989 Macedonia 2001 Russia (Soviet Union) 1999-2006 Angola 2002 Haiti 2004 Malaysia 1981 Russia (Soviet Union) 2007-2009 Angola 2007 India 1982 Mali 1990 Rwanda 1990-1994 Azerbaijan 1991 India 1983-1988 Mali 1994 Rwanda 1997-2002 Azerbaijan 1993-1995 India 1989 Mali 2007-2009 Rwanda 2009 Azerbaijan 2005 India 1990-1991 1994 Senegal 1990 Bosnia-Herzegovina 1992 India 1992 Moldova 1992 Sierra Leone 1991-2000 Bosnia-Herzegovina 1993-1995 India 1993 (Burma) 1987-1989 1982-1984 Burkina Faso 1987 India 1994 Myanmar (Burma) 1990 Somalia 2001-2002 Burundi 1991-1992 India 1997-1999 Myanmar (Burma) 1991 Somalia 2006-2009 Cameroon 1984 India 2000-2002 Myanmar (Burma) 1992 South Africa 1981-1988 Central African 2001-2002 India 2003-2004 Myanmar (Burma) 1993-1994 1985-1987 Central African Republic 2006 India 2005-2007 Myanmar (Burma) 1995 Spain 1991-1992 Central African Republic 2009 India 2008 Myanmar (Burma) 1996 Sri Lanka 1984-1988 Chad 1997-2002 India 2009 Myanmar (Burma) 1997-2003 Sri Lanka 1989-2001 Chad 2005-2009 1981-1989 Myanmar (Burma) 2005-2008 1983-2009 Comoros 1989 Indonesia 1990-1991 Myanmar (Burma) 2009 Surinam 1987 Comoros 1997 Indonesia 1992 Nepal 1996-2006 Tajikistan 1992-1996 Congo 1993-1994 Indonesia 1997 Nicaragua 1982 2003-2009 Congo 1997-1999 Indonesia 1999 Niger 1991-1992 The US 2001 Congo 2002 Iran 1986-1988 Niger 1994 Togo 1986 Cote D'ivoire 2002-2004 Iran 1991-1992 Niger 1995 Trinidad and Tobago 1990 Croatia 1992-1993 Iran 1993 Niger 1997 1984-1990 Djibouti 1991-1994 Iran 1996 Niger 2007-2008 Turkey 1991-2004 Djibouti 1999 Iran 1997 2004 Turkey 2005-2009 Egypt 1993-1998 Iran 2005-2009 Nigeria 2009 United Kingdom 1998 1997 1982-1986 Pakistan 1990 Uzbekistan 1999-2000 Eritrea 2003 Iraq 1987-1990 Pakistan 1995-1996 Uzbekistan 2004 Ethiopia 1983-1992 Iraq 1991-1994 Pakistan 2004-2006 Venezuela 1982 Ethiopia 1994-1995 Iraq 1995-1996 Pakistan 2007-2009 Venezuela 1992 Ethiopia 1996 Iraq 2004-2009 Panama 1989 1986 Ethiopia 1998 Israel 1990-1999 Papua New Guinea 1989-1990 Yemen 1994 Ethiopia 1999-2009 Israel 2000-2005 Paraguay 1989 Yemen 2009 Gambia 1981 Israel 2006-2009 Peru 1982-1999 Yugoslavia (Serbia) 1991 Georgia 1991 Kenya 1982 Peru 2007-2009 Yugoslavia (Serbia) 1998-1999 Georgia 1992 Laos 1989-1990 Philippines 1993-2009 Zaire 1996-2001 Georgia 2004 1982-1986 Rumania 1989 Zaire 2006 Georgia 2008 Lebanon 1989-1990 Zaire 2007

59 Appendix 2: List of Figures

.03 .02 .01 ProbabilityIntra-stateConflict of 0

0 2 4 6 8 10 Repression

Figure 2.1: Repression and the Predicted Probability of Intra-state Conflict

60 CHAPTER 3

Ethno-political Organizations in the Middle East: When Do They Opt for Violence?

61 A. Abstract

Whydosomeethnopoliticalorganizationsresorttoviolencewhileothersabstainfromit? Are ethnopolitical organizations with a religious/Islamist ideology more violenceprone comparedtononreligiousones?Thischapterattemptstofindanswerstothesequestions byanalyzingethnopoliticalorganizationsintheMiddleEast.Thefactorsthatincreasea country’s risk of experiencing domestic armed conflicts are examined in the previous chapter. In this chapter, I conduct a grouplevel analysis and explore conditions under whichethnopoliticalorganizationspreferviolentstrategiestoachievetheirgoals.Iusethe Minorities at Risk Organizational Behavior (MAROB) dataset, which includes 118 organizationsin16countriesoftheMiddleEastandNorthAfricatotestmyhypotheses. Eventhoughthelevelofanalysisandalsodegreeofviolencediffersfromtheprevious chapter, the findings suggest that similar causal factors that promote domestic armed conflict such as socioeconomic grievances, existence of repressive states, and youth bulges also increase the probability of use of violent strategies by ethnopolitical organizations.Youthbulgesfosterviolenceespeciallyinautocraticcountries.

62 B. Introduction

“Youth have played a prominent role in political violence throughout recorded history and the existence of a “youth bulge” has historically been associated with times of political crises” (Goldstone 2001:95)

“The Middle East is facing a demographic bulge in which youth aged fifteen to twenty-nine comprise the largest proportion of the population. These young people, frustrated with the lack of jobs, have been at the forefront of anti-government protests” (Assaad 2011, cited in Hoffman and Jamal 2012:169)

Inthepreviouschapter,Iexaminedcausalfactorsthatincreaseacountry’sriskofexperiencing domestic armed conflict. This chapter builds on those analyses by focusing on factors that increase the probability of violence at the grouplevel rather than countrylevel. I explore conditions under which ethnopolitical organizations prefer violent strategies to achieve their goals.Kalyvas(2006)callsforstudiesthatincorporatemicro,mesoandmacroleveldataintoa coherentpictureofviolencewithindomesticarmedconflictsandotherirregularconflicts.This dissertationaimstodosobybuildingabridgebetweentheresearchondomesticarmedconflicts, contentiouspolitics,socialmovements,andradicalization,andtestingsimilarhypothesesatthe stateandgrouplevels.Eventhoughthelevelofanalysisandalsodegreeofviolencediffersfrom thepreviouschapter,similarcausalfactorsthatpromotedomesticarmedconflictsuchassocio economicgrievancesandtheexistenceofrepressivestatesarealsousedtoexplaintheadoption ofviolentstrategiesbyethnopoliticalorganizations.Therefore,Itestsimilarhypothesestothe onesexaminedinthepreviouschapter.

Ethnopolitical organizations are politically active communal groups. Gurr (1993:161) definescommunalgroupsas“culturalandreligiousidentitygroupsthatdonothaverecognized states or institutionalized political status”. The review of the literature suggests that ethno political organizations’ decision to use violence is influenced by the existence of grievances,

63 politicalopportunitystructures,resourcemobilization,organizationalstructure,andtheideology oftheorganization.Inadditiontothesecommonlycited factors, I argue that the existence of youthbulgesinasocietyalsoincreasetheprobabilityofadoptingviolentstrategiesbyethno politicalorganizations.Frustratedyoungmalesunderrepressiveandauthoritarianregimestend to be likely recruits for violent organizations. I utilize the Minorities at Risk Organizational

Behavior(MAROB)datasettotestmyhypotheses.Thedatasetincludes118organizationsin16 countriesoftheMiddleEastandNorthAfrica,operatingbetween1980and2004.Theempirical findings confirm that youth bulges, state repression, organizational fractionalization, external support for the organization, and economic grievances positively affect adoption of violent strategies by ethnopolitical organizations, whereas an increasing GDP growth rate has a pacifying impact. Ethnopolitical organizations thathaveareligious/ Islamistideology areno moreconflictpronethanotherorganizations.Thesefindingsareconsistentwiththefindingsof thepreviouschapter;socioeconomicfactorsandpoliticalopportunities/constraintsratherthan religiondrivesthedecisiontoresorttoviolence.

Thischapterisorganizedasfollows.FirstIreviewtheliteratureoncontentiouspolitics, socialmovements,andradicalizationandderivetestablehypothesis.Next, Idescribethedata, methods,andtheresearchdesign.Then, Idiscussthe empirical findings. Finally, I provide a briefconclusioninwhichIdiscussimplicationsofthesefindingsaswellasthelimitationsofthis research.

C. Literature Review

While some ethnopolitical organizations prefer to use conventional means to advance their interestssuchasparticipationinelections,othersengageineithernonviolentprotestorviolent resistance.TillyandTarrow(2007)usetheconcept‘contentiouspolitics’torefertobothviolent

64 and nonviolent strategies used by organizations such as protest and rebellion. They define contentious politics as “interactions in which actors make claims bearing on someone else’s interests, leading to coordinated efforts on behalf of shared interests or programs in which governments are involved as targets, initiators of claims, or third parties” (Tilly and Tarrow

2007:4). Stephan and Chenoweth (2008) find that nonviolent campaigns are actually more successful than violent campaigns in achieving political goals. Yet, violence is regarded as a viable option and used by many ethnopolitical organizations. Why do some ethnopolitical organizationschooseviolenceratherthanconventionalpoliticsorprotest,whichislessrisky, lesscostly,andtendstobemoresuccessfulinachievingpoliticalgoals?Whatfactorsinfluence ethnopoliticalgroups’choiceofviolentvsnonviolent strategies? The review of the literature suggeststhattherearefivebroadconcepts,whichaffectdecisionstouseviolentornonviolent strategies by ethnopolitical organizations: grievances, resource mobilization, political opportunitystructures,organizationalstructure,andtheideologyoftheorganization.Inaddition tothesefactors,Iarguethatethnopoliticalorganizations,whichareactiveinsocietieswitha largeyouthpopulation,tendtobemoreviolenceprone.Below,Ifirstreviewtheseconceptsand pointouttheweaknessesofexistingliterature.Then,Iexplainhowyouthbulgesmayfosterthe use of violence by ethnopolitical organizations and conclude this section with my testable hypothesis.

Grievances

According to Gurr (1970)’s relative deprivation hypothesis, grievances, which stem from inequalities−eithersubjectiveorobjective−,leadtofrustrationandmotivatecollectiveviolence.

Inotherwords,thedifferencebetweentheexpectationsofanindividualandwhattheindividual actuallypossesses,leadstodiscontentandeventuallyincitesviolence.Globalizationandready

65 access to information have increased awareness of inequalities, increased expectations, and consequently deepened the feelings of frustration. Regan (2009) confirms that grievances that stem from poverty, inequality, and discrimination lead to violence. Gurr (1993) argues that grievances are especially critical in early stages of group mobilization but become less significantoncepeoplearecommittedtocollectiveaction.Inotherwords,leadersinitiallyuse grievances to mobilize people for collective action and recruit potential rebels but once the conflictprocessbegins,itbecomesaselfsustainingdynamic.

The literature on social movements also focuses on grievances and structural and psychological causes of mass mobilization. It is argued that structural factors such as modernization (rapid economic liberalization and industrialization) or economic crises disrupt social life and create a sense of despair and anxiety which in turn makes joining social movementsattractive.Likewise,Islamicactivismisexplainedbysociopsychologicalfactorsas wellasgrievances;thepopularityofIslamistmovementsisexplainedbyapowervacuum,which emergedduetothefailureofautocraticregimesandsecularmodernizationprojectstopromote economicdevelopment(Ayoob2005;Fox2004;Moghadam2009;Wiktorowicz2004).

Whilethecorrupt,authoritarianregimesinmanyMuslimcountriesfailtoprovidesocial services,Islamistsfillthisvacuumthroughcharityorganizations.Islamistparties,whicharevery popularinmanyMuslimcountries,areregardedasbeinglesscorruptthanotherparties. Itis argued that rapid structural and demographic dislocations during the postcolonial period also contributedtoasenseofrelativedeprivationandalienation.Whileliteracyratesandeducation increased,theseeducatednewelitescouldnotfindemploymentortheywereunderemployed.

Moreover,themodernizationprocessincreasedexpectationsamongpeople(Hafez2003).Ansari

(1984) argues that Islamist militancy is a product of rapid urbanization and rural migration.

66 StudiesshowthatmilitantIslamisttendtocomefromfamiliarbackgrounds;educatedstudents and professionals in their twenties and thirties, members of the lower middle class, recent migrants to cities, unemployed or underemployed. In addition to these domestic grievances, globally,surveysshowthatMuslimsaredissatisfiedwiththeinternationalstatusquo,especially withtheUSforeignpolicy.TheUSsupportofIsraelandthe Iraqwarin2003areamongthe commonlycitedpoliticalgrievances(Ayoob2005;HarriganandElSaid2011).

Whilesocialmovementtheory focuseson groupsasthe unit of analysis and provides grouplevelexplanationofpoliticalviolence,theliteratureonterrorismisinsightfulinproviding individual level explanations for radicalization andthedecisiontouseviolence.Eventhough unfavorable socioeconomic conditions, such as poverty and low levels of education, are sometimes associated with terrorism, Krueger and Maleckova (2003) and Russel’s (1983) findingssuggestthatpovertyandlackofeducationdonotnecessarilyleadtohigherratesof terrorism. Russel and Miller (1983) examine the profile of 350 terrorists from revolutionary groupsandfindthatthemajorityoftheseterroristswereinfactwelleducatedandcomefrom middle or uppermiddle classes. Therefore, inequalitiesandinjustices aredeemedtobemore influentialthanpovertyindrivingviolentextremism(ElSaidandBarret2011).

Still,somescholarsareskepticalabouttheimpact of grievances in fostering violence; theyarguethatsuchdiscontentexistsinallsocieties(Hafez2003; Wiktorowicz2004). Existing studiesprovidemixedevidenceregardingtheimpactofgrievancesinpromotingviolence.Gurr

(1993)observesthatpoliticalgrievancessuchasthehistoricallossofautonomyanddifferential politicalstatusincreasetheprobabilityofrebellionwhereasseverepoliticaldiscriminationand culturalgrievancesdecreaseit.GurrandMoore(1997)findthatgrievancesdon’thaveadirect impactonrebellionbutincreasemobilizationcapacityofethnopoliticalorganizationswhichin

67 turnincreasestheriskofrebellion.ReganandNorton(2005)findthatpoliticaldiscrimination increases the risk of rebellion and civil war. Similarly, Cederman et al (2010) find that the probabilityofethnicconflictincreasesifleadersofanethnicgroupareexcludedfromcentral

executivepoweroriftheyareunderrepresented.

Resource Mobilization Theory

Resource mobilization theory, which is based on rational choice perspective, rose as a major

challengetotherelativedeprivationapproach(Brush1996). Theresourcemobilizationtheory

emphasizestheabilityofsocialmovementstogainresourcesofpower,toorganize,torecruit

members,andtoprovideindividualincentivesorcoercioninmotivatingparticipationinsocial

movement activities. According to resource mobilization theory, movements are rational,

organizationalmanifestationsofcollectiveaction.Collectiveactiondependsonmembers’shared

interests as well as organization and opportunities (Tilly 1978:55). The relative deprivation

approachiscriticizedforignoringtheresources requiredtomobilizeandmaintaininsurgency

(Muller1985).

Tilly (1969) argues that collective violence occurs when individuals believe that

collectiveactionwillbesuccessfulandtheexpectedbenefitsexceedthecostsratherthanwhen

individualshavegrievances.Inotherwords,frustrationisnotsufficientformobilization;groups

needresourcestotranslateindividualfrustrationintogroupmobilization.Grievancesexistinall

societiesandcaneasilybemanufacturedbythemobilizingeffortsofmovemententrepreneurs

(McCarthy and Zald 1977). Hafez (2003) criticizes the relative deprivation hypothesis for

ignoring the possibility that deprived individuals could also seek to advance their interests

throughtheuseofnonviolentstrategies.

68 Weinstein(2006)findsthatrebelgroupsthatemergeinnaturalresourcerichregionsor thosethathaveexternalsupportusehigherlevelsofviolencewhereasmovementsthatemergein poornationsuseviolenceselectively.Daltonetal(2010)usetheWorldValueSurveytotestthe influenceof relativedeprivationandtheavailabilityofresourcesindrivingprotest.Theyfind that protest increases not because of increasing grievances such as dissatisfaction with government,butbecauseoftheavailabilityofresources.Similarly,Muller(1985)examinesthe relationship between income inequality−which is used to measure grievances− and collective political violence for the 19581977 periods and finds only a weak correlation between inequalityandthenumberofdeathstemmingfrompoliticalviolence.Muller(1985)concludes thatdiscontentingeneralisweaklyrelatedtopoliticalviolencewhereasresourcesplayamore significantrole.Insum,itisarguedthatbothexternalandinternalresources,whichfacilitate mobilization,aremorecrucialthangrievancesindrivingcollectiveviolence(McCarthyandZald

1977).

Political Process Approach

Thepoliticalprocessapproach,originallydevelopedbyMcAdam(1982),couldberegardedasa modified version of resource mobilization theory. According to a political process approach, collectiveactionislimitedbyexternalopportunitiesandconstraints.Therefore,thedecisionto useviolencebyagroupisinfluencedbythebroader political context (Hafez 2003; McAdam

1982;Tarrow1998;Wiktorowicz2004).McAdam(1982)pointsoutthreeimportantfactorsthat influence the organizations’ collective action: the level of organization within the group, the group’sbeliefintheprobabilityofsuccessofcollectiveaction,andthepoliticalopportunities availabletoachievethegoals.While“politicalprocess”isaverybroadconcept,whichcanbea

69 catchall term, the characteristics of the state and regime type are two key factors in shaping opportunitiesandconstraintsfororganizationsorsocialmovements.

In democratic and inclusive regimes, organizations have the option of participating in electionsorprotestratherthanrebelliontosearchfortheirrights.Therefore,theywillbeless likelytoadoptunconventional,riskyandviolentstrategies.Ontheotherhand,exclusiveand repressiveregimeslegitimizetheuseofviolencesinceconventionalpoliticalparticipationisnot available(Hafez2003;Wiktorowicz2004).TillyandTarrow(2007)arguethatviolentrebellion ismorelikelytooccurinlowcapacityandnondemocraticregimes.Similarly,Goodwin(2001) examines revolutionary movements between 1945 and 1991 and concludes that revolutionary movements do not occur just because of economic inequality but rather due to political oppression.Goodwinarguesthatrevolutionsaremostlikelytooccurinauthoritarian,exclusive, repressive, organizationally incoherent and militarily weak states. In other words, revolutions occurwhen“thereisnootherwayout”(Trotsky1961;citedinGoodwin2001:26).

Staterepressionisanotherimportantfactorindeterminingthechoiceofviolentornon violentstrategiesbydissidents.Yet,thereisnoconsensusamongscholarsregardingtheimpact ofrepressioninmotivatingviolence.ReganandNorton (2005) find that repression decreases protestbutincreasesbothrebellionandcivilwar.Lichbach(1987)arguesthatdissidentsswitch between violent and nonviolent protest depending on the government response. If the governmentrespondstoonetypeofprotestwithviolence,thedissidentswillswitchtoanother type. Lichbach also argues that consistent government accommodative or repressive policies reduce dissent; inconsistent policies increase dissent. Gupta et al (1993) find that repression breeds both violent and nonviolent protests in democracies whereas there is a curvilinear relationshipbetweenrepressionandviolent/nonviolentprotestsinnondemocracies.Gurr(1970)

70 andMuller(1985)confirmthatthereisa curvilinear relationship between repression and the probabilityofrebellion.

Organizational Factors

While external factors such as state institutions, resources, and grievances are influential in motivating adoption of violent strategies, internal factors such as organizational structure and ideologyarealsoimportantinpromotingviolence.Intergrouporintragroupcompetitionand groupfractionalizationfosterviolence(Borum2011;Dalacoura2011).Accordingtothetheory of outbidding, competing groups tend to radicalize and resort to violence to increase their support and to outbid other groups (Bloom 2004; Lawrence 2010). Similarly, group fractionalization and intragroup competition lead lessmotivated members to leave the group andthusincreasegroupradicalization(Borum2011).

Finally, the ideology of an organization has the potential to influence the decision to resort to violence. Juergensmeyer (2003) argues that religious organizations tend to be more violentsincetheybelievethatGodistheirprimaryaudienceandtheyseetheenemyasevil. Toft

(2007) notes that violent conflict is regarded as a manifestation of God’s will in religious traditions.Amongallreligions,Islamisthemostcommonlyassociatedwithpoliticalviolenceas discussedinthepreviouschapter.IfIslamisinherentlypronetoviolenceasarguedbysome scholars,ethnopoliticalorganizationswithanIslamistideologyshouldbemorelikelytobehave violentlythanothers.

Insum,thereviewoftheliteraturesuggeststhat alloftheconceptsdiscussedabove− grievances,resources,politicalopportunitiesandconstraints,ideologyoftheorganization,and organizationalstructure−havethepotentialtopromoteviolence.Numerousstudieshavetested theimpactofthesefactors.Yet,thereisnoconsensusamongscholarsaboutwhethergrievances

71 orresourcesaswellaspoliticalopportunitiesplay amoreimportantroleindrivingviolence.

Thischapterintendstoshedlightonthesegrievancesversusresourcesdebatesbyexaminingthe impact of grievances, resources, and political opportunities in motivating violence by ethno politicalorganizationsintheMiddleEast.Moreover,thischapterexaminestheroleof youth bulgesindrivinggrouplevelviolence,whichhasbeenignoredbyexistingstudies.Iarguethat the existence of large youth cohorts also increasestheprobabilityofadoptionofviolenceby ethnopoliticalorganizationssinceyoungpeoplearemorelikelytobepronetoviolence. 14

Youthbulgesleadtocompetitionandscarcityinlabormarketsandeducationalsystems, which in turn increases grievances and the potential for violence (Urdal 2004). Furthermore, large youth cohorts provide an excellent human resource for violent organizations. The opportunitycostofjoininginsurgencymovementsisusuallylowerforyoungpeoplesincethey havelesstolose(Collier2000).Thus,ayouthbulgehasthepotentialtoincreasebothgrievances and available resources. Goldstone (2001) claims that youth population has historically been associated with political violence. Goldstone (2001) contends that welleducated youth are specificallymorepronetopoliticalviolencesincetheywillhavehighereconomicandpolitical expectations.Resortingtoviolencebecomesverylikelyiftheseeducatedyouthareunemployed orunderemployedandliveinauthoritariancountriesinwhichconventionalmeansofexpressing frustration and political demands are usually unavailable. Moller (1968) points out that the youthpopulationplayedanimportantroleduringtheFrenchRevolutionandtheriseofNazism inGermanyinthe1930s(citedinUrdal2004).

14 Thebrain’sprefrontallobe,whichisdeemedtoplayanimportantroleinpreventinginappropriatebehavior,does notreachfulldevelopmentuntiltheageof20(Fuller2003). 72 Youthbulgescreateinstabilityinasocietyespeciallywhensocialinfrastructureisweak anddemandsoftheseyoutharenotmet.Fuller(2003)arguesthat youngpeoplewillbemore pronetoradicalideologiesiftheyfeeldesperateandseefewopportunitiesinthefuture(Fuller

2003). Some evidence shows that rising youth population increases support for Islamist movements(Moghadam2009;Urdal2004).Forexample,violentIslamistmovementssuchas the Armed Islamic Group (GIA) in Algeria and Gamaa Islamiyya in Egypt rely on young, uneducated, urban poor people (Dalacoura 2011). Indeed, youth population has played a significantroleduringtherecentuprisingsintheMiddleEast.Arguably,thelargenumberof unemployedyouthinArabnations,frustratedunderrepressive,autocratic,andcorruptregimes, drove the Arab Spring (Mohammed 2011). For these young people who have a low socio economicstatus,participationinviolentorganizationsbecomesatoolforpowerandprestige, mitigatesfeelingofinsecurityandhelplessnessandoffersasenseofidentity(Dalacoura2011;

Fuller2003).

TheMiddleEasternregion,whichisanalyzedinthischapter,hasthehighestproportion ofyouthpopulationintheworld:theaveragepercentageofyouthpopulation−thoseunderageof thirty−isaroundsixtypercentcomparedtoonlythirtypercentinNorthAmerica(Hoffmanand

Jamal2012).Inadditiontohavingahigherproportionofyouthpopulation,theunemployment rate is also highest in the Middle East. According to a report by the International Finance

CorporationandIslamicDevelopmentBank,theaverageyouth(ages1524)unemploymentrate intheMiddleEastistwentyfivepercentcomparedtotwelvepercentintheworld asof2010. 15

Insum,eventhough youthbulgesisatheoreticallysignificantconcept,whichhasthe potential to increase political violence, none of the existing studies quantitatively tested the

15 http://www.e4earabyouth.com/downloads/IFCBook_A4_Online_Complete.pdf 73 impactofyouthbulgesinfosteringviolenceatthegrouplevel.Thischapterfillsthisgapinthe literaturebyexaminingtheroleofyouthbulgesinmotivatingtheadoptionofviolentstrategies byethnopoliticalorganizations.Ihypothesizethat:

Hypothesis: Ethnopolitical organizations that are active in countries in which there are

largeyouthcohortswillbemorelikelytoresorttoviolence.

D. Data, Methods, and Research Design

I examine the causal factors that increase ethnopolitical organizations’ probability of use of violence. A timeseries crosssectional dataset, which includes all active ethnopolitical organizationsintheMiddleEastandNorthAfrica,isusedtoempiricallytestthehypothesis.The

MinoritiesatRiskOrganizationalBehavior(MAROB)projectisasubsidiaryoftheMinoritiesat

Risk(MAR)project.Thedatasetincludes118organizationsrepresentingtheinterestsofall22 ethnopoliticalgroupsin16countriesoftheMiddleEastandNorthAfrica,operatingbetween

1980and2004.Thedataareunbalancedpaneldatainanorganizationyearformatwith1,789 observations. The MAROB data provides information about ideology, motivations, and strategies(bothviolentandnonviolent)oforganizationsaswellasthestatebehavior(repressive or tolerant towards the organization). Inordertobeincludedinthedataset,anorganization shouldmeetthefollowingcriteria:

1. The organization makes explicit claims to represent the interests of one or more

ethnic groups and/or the organization’s members are primarily members of a specific

ethnic minority.

2. The organization is political in its goals and activities.

3. The organization is active at a regional and/or national level.

4. The organization was not created by a government.

74 5. The organization is active for at least three consecutive years between 1980 and

2006.

6. Umbrella organizations (coalitions/alliances) are NOT coded. Instead, member

organizations are coded (MAROB codebook 2008).

The dependent variable is dichotomous; coded as 1 for the years during which the

organizationusedviolenceasastrategyandcodedas0otherwise.Thedependentvariableisa

dummyvariable,soIusealogisticregressionstatisticalestimatortotestmyhypothesis,with

robuststandarderrorsclusteredbycountryandorganization.Iusetwoordinalvariablesfrom

MAROBdatatocreatethedependentvariable. 16 Thesevariablescodethefrequencyofuseof violencebyorganizationsasastrategy.SinceIaminterestedinwhethertheorganizationadopts aviolentstrategyornotratherthanfrequencyofuseofviolence,Irecodedthesevariables.Thus, organizationsthatuseviolenceeithertotargetdomestic or transnationalentitiesarecodedas1.

In total, organizations used violence in 30.3 % of all organization years. I also include the correlation matrices in Table 3.1 to document multicollinearity; there is no multicollinearity problem.

Table 3.1 about here

Independent Variable and Control Variables

Myprimaryindependentvariableistheexistenceofyouthbulgesinasociety. Thedataonthe proportionofyoungmalesbetweentheageof15and24tototaladultmalepopulation(15+)

comefromtheUnitedNationsWorldPopulationProspectsdata.Ialsocontrolforthefollowing

variablesintheempiricalanalysissincethereviewoftheliteraturesuggestthatthesevariables

16 Thesevariablesarecalled“domorgviolence”and“transvioltarg”intheMAROBdata,thedescriptionofvariables areintheAppendix1. 75 havethepotentialtoaffectthelikelihoodofresortingtoviolencebyorganizations:democracy, staterepression,political,economic,andculturalgrievances,externalsupportfororganization, organizational popularity, organizational split, leadership type, religious/Islamist ideology, a dichotomousvariablefororganizationsthatoperateinIsrael,andGDPgrowthrate.

Regime type and state repression intend to test the impact of political opportunity structure on the probability of violence by ethnopolitical organizations. Ethnopolitical organizationsthatareactiveindemocraticcountriesareexpectedtobelessviolencepronesince othernonviolentstrategiesavailablecouldbelessrisky,lesscostlyandhencemoreattractive.I use the polity 2 score from the Polity IV project to control for regime type. I create a dichotomousvariablefordemocraciesbycodingcountrieswithPolityscoresgreaterthanfiveas one. Repression is like a doubleedged sword; it can either deter or foster rebellion. Some scholars suggest that there is a curvilinear relationship between repression and dissidents’ probability of use of violence. While lower levels of repression may foster violence by increasinggrievances,extremerepressioncandeterinsurgencysincecollectiveactionbecomes verycostly(Muller1985).Unfortunately,itisnotpossibletotestthe curvilinearrelationship betweenstaterepressionanduseofviolencewithMAROBdatasincethevariablethatmeasures staterepressionisanordinalvariablewithonlythreecategories.Therefore,Isimplyexpectto find a positive correlation between state repression and political violence. The state violence measureswhetherthestateuseslethalviolenceagainsttheorganizationandrangesfrom1(no repression)to3(highrepression).Icreateadummyvariablebycombiningthesecond(periodic lethal violence against the organization) and third (consistently high lethal repression of the organization)categories.Therepressionislaggedoneyeartoavoidproblemsininferringcausal direction.

76 Eventhoughtheempiricalevidenceismixed,grievanceshavethepotentialtomotivate violence. Therefore, I control for grievances in the empirical analysis. Economic grievance, cultural grievance, and political grievance data are taken from the MAROB data. Economic grievanceisanordinalmeasureforthedominanteconomicgrievance;zerodenotesthatthereis no expressed economic grievance; one means that eliminating economic discrimination is a majorgoal,andtwomeansthattheorganizationfocusesoncreatingorstrengtheningremedial policies.Culturalgrievancesarealsomeasuredbyanordinalvariablewiththreecategories.All oftheethnopoliticalorganizationsincludedintheMAROBdatasethavesomesortofpolitical grievances,whichmakeithardtotesttheimpactofpoliticalgrievances.Thedominantpolitical grievanceoftheorganizationintheoriginalMAROBdataiscodedasthefollowing:

1. Major organizational goals focused on eliminating discrimination

2. Major organizational goals focused on creating or increasing remedial policies

3. Major organizational goals focused on creating or strengthening autonomous status for

group

4. Major organizational goals focused on creating a separate state for the group or

revanchist change in border of state

5. -88 Other

Thereare703(outof1775)observationsintheothercategorywithtextdescriptionof

these grievancessuch as“Palestinianindependence”,“EstablishinganIslamiststate”,“regime

change”etc.Toavoiddropping703observationsintheothercategory,aclosereadingofeach

casedescriptionwasdonebytheauthorandeachoftheindependencemovementswascodedas

afour.Inotherwords,adichotomousvariable,whichtakesthevalueofoneforindependenceor

separationistmovements,called“highpoliticalgrievance”iscreated.Organizationsthatfocuson

77 gaining independence and/or establishing a separate state are expected to be more violence prone. Alternatively, I create another dummy for only separationist organizations by coding categorynumberfouraboveasone(itiscalledautonomyintheregressionsbelow).

The variables that measure external support for organization and organizational popularity are included to test the resource mobilization theory. An organization’s ability to mobilizepeopleandengageincollectiveactiondepends on existence of external and internal support for the organization. To measure external support for the organization, four dummy variables from the MAROB data are used. The organizations that received support (financial support, human support, or political support) from diasporas, from foreign states, from internationalgovernmentalorganizations,frominternationalnongovernmentalorganizations,or fromothernonstateactorsarecodedasone.Thereisanordinalvariable(rangesfrom1to3) that measures organizational popularity among the group that the organization represents. I createadichotomousvariableforhighlypopular,dominantorganizations 17 totesttheimpactof

domesticsupport.

I use two dichotomous variables from MAROB data, which measure intragroup

competition,inordertotesttheimpactoforganizationalstructure(thetheoryofoutbidding).

Thereisadichotomousvariablecodedasoneifthereisanorganizationalsplitduringtheyearof

observation. I alsocreateadummyfororganizations with factionalized/competing leaders by

using the leadership type variable in MAROB data. Ethnopolitical organizations that are

fractionalizedand/orhaveaweak/competingleadershipareexpectedtobemoreviolenceprone.

Iusetwovariablestocontrolforreligion.Thereisadichotomousvariablewhichiscodedasone

for organizations that have a religious ideology. For robustness, and to test the impact of 17 Adummyvariableispreferredsincetheuseofanordinalvariableleadstomulticollinearityproblem.Also,87.9% ofallobservationsareinthemiddlecategory(number2)whichsuggeststhatmostoftheorganizationshavesome sortofpopularity.Therefore,controllingfordominantorganizationsisempiricallymorevalid. 78 Islamist ideology specifically, I create a dummy variable for organizations that focus on establishinganIslamiststatebyusingthetextdescriptionfoundintheotherpoliticalgrievances category.

Finally,IcontrolforeconomicdevelopmentandorganizationsthatareactiveinIsrael.

IsraelisanoutlierintheMiddleEast;itisademocratic,wealthycountrywithalonghistoryof conflictwiththePalestinians.IuseannualGDPpercapitagrowthratetocontrolforeconomic development.PurchasingpowerparityconvertedGDPpercapita(constantin2005international dollars)datacomefromThePennWorldTables.Table3.2summarizesthelistofvariablesused in the empirical analysis and how the concepts are operationalized whereas Table 3.3 summarizesdescriptivestatisticsofvariables.

Table 3.2 and 3.3 about here

E. Findings

InModel1,IincludeannualGDPpercapitagrowthrate,adummyfordemocracy,youthbulges, staterepression,organizationalpopularity,externalsupport,highpoliticalgrievances,economic grievances,culturalgrievances,adummyfororganizationsthathaveareligiousideology,anda dummy for organizations located in Israel. Youth bulge is positive and significant, which supports my hypothesis. State repression positively affects the likelihood of adopting violent strategies by ethnopolitical organizations, whereas democracy is insignificant; these findings indicate that there is partial support for political opportunity structure argument. However, cautioniswarrantedininterpretingtheinsignificanceofregimetype;theanalysisislimitedto theMiddleEast,whichispredominantlynondemocratic.Thereisnotenoughvariationinthis explanatoryvariable,whichmaybethereasonfortheinsignificantresults.

79 Economicgrievancesincreasetheprobabilityofuseofviolentstrategies. Interestingly,

the high political grievance dummy is insignificant; organizations that focus on gaining

independenceorestablishingaseparatestatearenomoreviolencepronethanothers.Therefore,

therelativedeprivationargumentispartiallysupported.Likewise,thereispartialsupportforthe

resourcemobilizationargument;externalsupportispositiveandsignificantbutorganizational popularity−whichintendstoproxydomesticsupportfororganization−isinsignificant.TheIsraeli

dummy is positive and significant; ethnopolitical organizations that are active in Israel are

indeedmoreviolenceprone.Religiousideologyisnotstatisticallysignificantwhereasincreasing

GDPgrowthratehasapacifyingeffect.

Inmodel2,Idropthehighpoliticalgrievancedummyandreplaceitwithanautonomy dummy which is coded as one for separationist organizations (4th category of the dominant political grievance variable in the original data). While autonomy is insignificant, like high politicalgrievance,impactofallothervariablesissimilartothepreviousmodel.InModel3,I dropthereligiousideologydummyandreplaceitwithadummyfororganizationsthatfocuson creatinganIslamiststateasarobustnesscheck.Likereligiousideology,anIslamiststatedummy isinsignificant;thereisnosupportfortheargumentthatreligiousorIslamistorganizationsare moreviolencepronethannonreligiousones.

IaddorganizationalsplitandweakleadershipdummiesinModels4and5respectively 18 toexaminetheimpactoforganizationalstructure.Accordingtothetheoryofoutbidding,both intergroupandintragroupcompetitioncausemoreradicalization,thusincreasetheprobability ofviolentstrategies.Icanonlyexaminetheimpactofintragroupcompetitionsincethereisno

18 Iaddedthesetwovariablesseparatelysincetheyintendtomeasurethesameconcepts:intragroupcompetition andorganizationalcoherence. 80 variable that measures intergroup competition in the MAROB dataset. 19 I use organizational splitandleadershiptype(weak/competingleadersindicateexistenceofintragroupcompetition) to proxy intragroup competition. The findings indicate that fractionalized organizations and organizationswithcompeting/weakleadershipareindeedmoreviolencepronethanotherethno politicalorganizations.YouthbulgeispositiveandsignificantinModel4andModel5,likein previousmodels;onecanconcludethatthesignificanceofyouthbulgeisrobusttoalternative modelspecifications.

Whiletheempiricalanalysisaboveconfirmsthatyouthbulgesfosterviolence,exploring the underlying causal mechanisms of youthviolence relationship and mediating variables is another interesting research question. Those scholars who argue that youth bulges are more prone to violence generally argue that such violenceproneness is conditional on other socio economic and political factors. High unemployment rate, state repression and autocracy are amongthecommonlycitedfactorsthatactlikeacatalystbetweenviolenceandyouthbulges.I interactautocracyandyouthbulgesanddemocracyandyouthbulgesinModel6andModel7, respectivelytoseeiftheexistenceofyouthbulgescreatesmoreproblemsin.The interaction of youth bulge and autocracy is positive and significant, whereas the youth democracy interaction is insignificant. This finding suggests that youth bulges in autocratic regimestendtobemoreviolencepronethanyouthbulgesindemocraticregimes.Youngpeople indemocracies canexpresstheir frustration/dissatisfactionthroughnonviolentmeans,whereas such conventional strategies usually do not exist in autocracies, which makes resorting to violence the only viable option. The graph in Figure 3.1 show the predicted probability of violenceforchangingvaluesofyouthbulgesinautocraticandother(nonautocratic)countries. 19 Thedatasetincludesadichotomousvariablewhichiscoded1ifthereisaninterorganizationalconflict.Ididnot usethisvariablesinceitmeasuresconflictratherthancompetition.Interorganizationalconflictiscorrelatedwith thedependentvariable(0.56);itmaybetautologicaltousethisvariableasanexplanatoryfactor. 81 Whilethepredictedprobabilityofviolenceishigherinnonautocraticcountriesforlowvaluesof youthbulges,autocraticcountriesfaceagreaterriskofviolencewhentheproportionofyoung males exceeds about 38%. The higher risk of violence in nonautocratic countries may be becauseofinclusionofbothdemocraciesandanocraciesinthiscategory.Asvisuallyseeninthe graph,thesubstantiveimpactofyouthbulgesinincreasingriskofviolenceishigherinautocratic countriescomparedtoothercountries.

Figure 3.1 about here

Ialsointeractyouthbulgeswithstaterepression,negativeGDPgrowthrate, 20 economic grievances,andIslamistideologyinordertofindoutwhetheryouthbulgesfosterviolencewhen coupledwithanyofthesefactors.Iaddtheseinteractedvariablesone atatimetothemodel.

None of the interactions was significant. 21 I suspect that the insignificance of the interaction termsmightbeduetotheuseofcrudeproxiestomeasurethetheoreticallyrelevantconceptsor alternatively limitations in the structure of the data. For example, economic grievance is an ordinal variable with only three categories whereas repression is a dichotomous variable.

Overall,whiletheempiricalanalysisabovesuggeststhattheexistenceofyouthbulgesingeneral increases likelihood of political violence at grouplevel, the insignificance of most of the interactiontermsisatheoreticalpuzzlethatrequiresfurtherresearch.Table3.4summarizesthe regressionanalysis.

Table 3.4 about here

Finally,Icalculatethepredictedprobabilitiestoshowthesubstantiveimportanceofthe explanatoryvariablesbyusingModels4,5,and6.Thepredictedprobabilityofanorganizations’ useofviolenceis5.7%whenallcontinuousvariablesareheldattheirmeanvaluesanddummy 20 Idonothavetheunemploymentdata.Therefore,negativeGDPgrowthrateisusedtotestwhetherimpactof youthbulgesisconditionaloneconomicdevelopment. 21 Thesealternativemodelspecificationsarereportedintable3.5,inAppendix.. 82 variablesaresetto0.ThegraphinFigure3.2showsthechangesinpredictedprobabilityofuse of violence by ethnopolitical organizations as the proportion of youth bulges shifts from its minimumvaluetomaximumvalue.Theprobabilityofuseofviolenceincreasesfrom2%to10% astheproportionofyoungmalesshiftsfrom21%toabout40%.Inotherwords,theprobability ofuseofviolencebyethnopoliticalorganizationsincreasesby400%.

Figure 3.2 about here

Theprobabilityofuseofviolenceincreasesfrom5.7%to13%whenrepressionshifts

from0to1 whileallcontinuousvariablesareheldattheirmeanvaluesanddummyvariablesare

set to 0. In other words, the predicted probability of use of violence increases by 131%.

Similarly,theprobabilityofviolenceincreases100%whentheweakleadershipdummyshifts

from0to1.Shiftingexternalsupportfrom0to1alsoleadstoa115%increaseintheprobability

ofviolence.Ashiftineconomicgrievancefromthelowesttohighestvalue(0to2)leadstoa

191%increaseintheprobabilityofviolence.TheimpactofGDPgrowthrateisrelativelysmall;

shifting GDP growth rate from 10 th to 90 th percentile leads to only a 20% decline in the probabilityofviolence.Shiftingorganizationalsplitdummyfrom0to1leadsto188%increase in the dependent variable. Lastly, a shift in youth*autocracy interaction from 0 to 0.39 (90 th percentileofyouthbulge)leadstoa78%increaseintheprobabilityofviolence.

All in all, these findings indicate that youth bulges, economic grievances, external

supportfororganization,staterepression,organizationalsplit,andfractionalizedleadershipall

increase probability of use of violent strategies by ethnopolitical organizations whereas

increasing GDP growth ratehas anegativeimpact.Youthbulgesespeciallyfosterviolencein

autocraticregimes.

83 F. Conclusion

In December 2010, a Tunisian vegetable peddler burned himself to death after his cart is confiscated by a policewoman. This incident created a spillover effect of protests in many

Middle Eastern countries, and initiated the Arab Spring. 22 Some scholars describe the recent

uprisingsintheMiddle Eastas youth revolutions; those young people, dissatisfied with their

oppressive regimes and frustrated with unemployment, rebelled against their governments

(Hoffman and Jamal 2012; Mohammed 2011). The findings of this chapter supports the

argument that existence of youth bulges in the Middle East increase the risk of resorting to

violencebyethnopoliticalorganizations.

Inadditiontoyouthbulges,otherinternalandexternalfactorsalsoinfluencedecisionto

resort to violence by organizations. Economic grievances and state repression foster violence

whereasincreasingGDPgrowthratehasanegativeimpact.Whilepoliticalgrievancesarefound

to be insignificant; one needs to be cautious while interpreting this finding. All of the

organizationsincludedintheMAROBdatasethavepoliticalgrievances,whichmakesithardto

explore role of political grievances. Organizational factors such as fractionalization and

competingleadershipincreaselikelihoodofresortingtoviolence,whichconfirmsthetheoryof

outbidding. External support for the organization has a positive impact, whereas domestic

support (measured by organizational popularity) is insignificant; there is partial support for

resourcemobilizationtheory.Religious/Islamist ideologyisinsignificantinallofthemodels;

thereisnosupportfortheargumentthatreligiousorganizationsaremoreviolencepronethan

others.

22 http://www.telegraph.co.uk/news/worldnews/africaandindianocean/libya/8839143/ArabSpringtimelineofthe AfricanandMiddleEastrebellions.html 84 In conclusion, two observations stand out. First, socioeconomic and political factors suchasyouthbulge,economicdevelopment,andstaterepression,aswellasinternalfactorssuch as organizational structure are crucial in the decision to resort to violence whereas religious ideologydoesnotseemtobeadrivingforce.Second,thesefindingsareconsistentwiththe findingsofthepreviouschapter;religiousideologydoesnotseemtomakecountriesmoreorless conflictproneoncewecontrolforsocioeconomicandpoliticalconditionsthatincreaseriskof domesticarmedconflict.Amongallofthevariablestestedinthischapterandintheprevious chapter, state repression and economic grievances are significant in most of the regressions, whichsuggeststhatviolenceislargelydrivenbysocioeconomicandpoliticalconditions.

Finally,itisimportanttonotesomeofthelimitationsofthisresearch.Theanalysisis limitedtoonlysixteencountriesthatarelocatedinMENAregion,whichintroducesaselection biasproblemandpreventsmakingbroadergeneralizations.TheanalysisislimitedtoMENAdue tolimitationsindataavailability.Futureresearchmaytestthegeneralizabilityofthesefindings ifcrossnationaldatabecomeavailable.

85 Reference List

Ayoob,Mohammed.2005.TheFutureofPoliticalIslam:TheImportanceofExternalVariables. International Affairs 81(5):951961 Bloom, Mia M. 2004. Palestinian Suicide Bombing: Public Support, Market Share, and Outbidding . Political Science Quarterly 119(1):6188. Borum, Randy. 2011. Radicalization into Violent Extremism: A Review of Social Science Theories. Journal of Strategic Security .4(4):736. Collier, Paul, 2000. ‘Doing Well Out of War: An Economic Perspective’, In Greed and Grievance: Economic Agendas in Civil Wars eds. Mats Berdal and David M. Malone, Boulder, CO and London: Lynne Rienner, 91–111. Dalacoura,Katerina.2011 . Islamist Terrorism and Democracy in the Middle East .Cambridge: CambridgeUniversityPress. RussellDalton,AlixVanSickleandStevenWeldon.2010.TheIndividual–InstitutionalNexus ofProtestBehaviour. British Journal of Political Science ,40:5173 Fox,Jonathan.2000.TheEffectsofReligiousDiscriminationonEthnoReligiousProtestand Rebellion. Journal of Conflict Studies 20(1). ———. 2004. Religion and State Failure: An Examination of the Extent and Magnitude of ReligiousConflictfrom1950to1996. International Political Science Review 25(1):5576 Fox,JonathanandShmuelSandler.2004. Bringing Religion into International Relations .New York:PalgraveMacmillan Fuller,GrahamE.2003.Theyouthfactor:thenewdemographicsoftheMiddleEastand theimplicationsforUSpolicy.Draft,18Jan2003.Retrievedfrom: http://www.brookings.edu/fp/projects/islam/fuller2003.pdf Golstone,JackA.2001.Demography,Environment,and Security. In Environmental Conflict. Eds.PaulF.DiehlandNilsPetterGleditsch,Boulder,CO:Westview,84108 Gupta,DipakK.,HarinderSingh,andTomSprague.1993.GovernmentCoercionofDissidents: DeterrenceorProvocation? Journal of Conflict Resolution .37:30139. Gurr,TedRobert.1970. Why Men Rebel .Princeton,NJ:PrincetonUP. ———.1993.WhyMinoritiesRebel:AGlobalAnalysisofCommunal MobilizationandConflictsince1945.” International Political Science Review , 14:161201.

86 Gurr,TedRobertandWillH.Moore1997.EthnopoliticalRebellion:ACrossSectionalAnalysis ofthe1980swithRiskAssessmentsforthe1990s. American Journal of Political Science ,41: 10791103. Hafez, Mohammed M. 2003. Why Muslims Rebel: Repression and Resistance in the Islamic World .RiennerPublishersInc:Colorado. Hoffman, Michael and Jamal Amaney. 2012. The Youth and the Arab Spring: Cohort DifferencesandSimilarities. Middle East Law and Governance 4:168–188 Juergensmeyer, Mark. 2003. Global Religions: An Introduction . Oxford: Oxford University Press. Karagiannis, Emmanuel & Clark McCauley. Hizb utTahrir alIslami: Evaluating the Threat PosedbyaRadicalIslamicGroupThatRemainsNonviolent. Terrorism and Political Violence 18(2) Krueger, Alan B., and Jitka Malečková. 2003. Education, Poverty and Terrorism: Is There a CausalConnection? Journal of Economic Perspectives ,17(4):119–144. Lawrence,Adria.2010.“TriggeringNationalistViolence:CompetitionandConflictinUprisings againstColonialRule.” International Security 35(2):88122. Lichbach, Mark Irving. 1987. Deterrence or Escalation?ThePuzzleofAggregateStudiesof RepressionandDissent. Journal of Conflict Resolution 31:26697 McCarthy,JohnD.andZald,MayerN.1977.ResourceMobilizationandSocialMovements:A PartialTheory. American Journal of Sociology 82(6):12121241. McAdam,Doug,1982. Political Process and the Development of Black Insurgency. Chicago: UniversityofChicagoPress. Moghadam,ValentineM.2009. Globalization and Social Movements: Islamism, Feminism, and the Global Justice Movement .UnitedKingdom:RowmanandLittlefieldPublishers. Muller, Edward N. 1985. Income Inequality, Regime Repressiveness, and Political Violence. American Sociological Review 50(1):4761. Regan, Patrick, and Daniel Norton. 2005. Greed, Grievance, and Mobilization in Civil Wars. Journal of Conflict Resolution 49(3):319–36 Regan,PatrickM.2009. Sixteen Million One ,ParadigmPublishers. Russell,CharlesandBowmanMiller.1983.“ Profile of a Terrorist ,”reprintedin PerspectivesonTerrorism,Wilmington,Delaware:ScholarlyResourcesInc.,pp.4560.

87 Saxton,GregoryD.2005.Repression,Grievances,Mobilization,andRebellion:ANewTestof Gurr’sModelofEthnopoliticalRebellion. International Interactions .31(1):87116

Stephan,MariaJ.andEricaChenoweth.2008.WhyCivilResistanceWorks:TheStrategicLogic ofNonviolentConflict. International Security .33(1):744.

Schwedler,Jillian.2007.Democratization,InclusionandtheModerationofIslamistParties. Development 50(1):5661. Tarrow,Sydney.1998. Power in Movements (2nded.).Cambridge:CambridgeUniversity Press.

Tilly,CharlesandSidneyTarrow.2007. Contentious Politics .London:ParadigmPublishers.

Tilly,Charles.1978. From mobilization to revolution .RandomHouse

Urdal,Henrik.2004.TheDevilinDemographics:TheEffectofYouthBulgesonDomestic ArmedConflict,19502000. Social Development Papers, The World Bank .No:14.

––––––.2006. A Clash of Generations? Youth Bulges and Political Violence. International Studies Quarterly 50(3):607629 Wiktorowicz, Quintan. 2004. Islamic Activism: A Social Movement Theory Approach. Bloomington&Indianapolis:IndianaUniversityPres

88 Appendix 1: List of Tables Table 3.1: Correlation of Variables

organizational economic cultural religious youth external Islamist repression Israel democracy GDP split grievance grievance ideology bulge support ideology growth organizational split 1 economic grievance 0.0192 1 cultural grievance 0.0383 0.3631 1 religious ideology 0.0283 -0.0792 0.418 1 youth bulge 0.0542 0.0779 0.313 0.0322 1 external support 0.0012 0.0514 -0.002 0.068 -0.081 1 Islamist ideology 0.0244 -0.0527 0.4417 0.4848 0.1183 -0.0843 1 repression 0.0187 0.3888 0.2748 0.032 0.145 0.201 0.0486 1 Israel -0.0027 -0.0357 -0.228 -0.0179 -0.4689 -0.0975 -0.1131 0.053 1 democracy -0.0339 -0.1182 -0.3391 -0.1216 -0.6788 0.0485 -0.0137 -0.0687 0.4375 1 GDP growth 0.0338 -0.0056 -0.0109 -0.0147 0.0008 0.0241 -0.0118 0.0487 0.0055 0.0055 1

weaklead 0.4696 -0.0126 0.0443 0.0929 0.0435 0.0678 0.0036 0.0179 0.0053 0.0238 0.0335

89 Table 3.2: Summary of Variables

Variable Name Concept Youth bulge Demographic character Annual GDP per capita growth rate (%) Economic development Repression Political Opportunity Structure Organizational popularity Domestic support (resource mobilization) External support External support (resource mobilization) Religious ideology Religion Islamist ideology Organizations that aim to create an Islamist state High political grievance Organizations that focus on creating a separate state/ gaining independence Economic grievances Economic grievances Cultural grievances Cultural grievances Democracy Political Opportunity Structure Organizational split Organizational structure (resource mobilization) Weak leadership Organizational structure (resource mobilization) Israel Dummy for organizations that operate in Israel

90 Table 3.3: Descriptive Statistics

Variables Mean Standard Min Max deviation AnnualGDPgrowthrate(%) 0.012 0.181 0.648 0.605 Youthbulges . 31 0.057 0.20 0.41 Repression 0.131 0.337 0 881 Polity2 −0.49 7.91 10 10 Prop.ofyoungmales 0.31 0.057 0.206 0.411 Organizationalpopularity 2.02 0.461 1 3 Externalsupport 0.411 0.492 0 1 LeadershipType 3.1 0.754 1 4 Religiousideology 0.233 0.423 0 1 Islamistideology .072 0.259 0 1 HighPoliticalGrievance 0.386 0.487 0 1 EconomicGrievance 0.258 0.617 0 2 CulturalGrievance 0.562 0.857 0 2 Autonomy 0.186 0.389 0 1 Autocracy 0.325 0.468 0 1 Democracy 0.485 0.499 0 1 Organizationalsplit 0.029 0.168 0 1 Israel 0.163 0.37 0 1

91 Table 3.4: Logistic Regression on Use of Violence by Ethno-political Organizations (1980-2004)

Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 Model 7 Repression .886*** .885*** .865*** .903*** .897*** .934*** .897*** (.268) (.267) (.269) (.262) (.262) (.27) (.262) Youth bulge 7.474*** 7.497*** 7.554*** 7.126*** 7.306*** 3.46 7.628*** (2.461) (2.466) (2.465) (2.549) (2.5) (3.17) (2.75) GDP growth -.980*** -.967** -.973** -.991*** -1.026*** -1.059*** -1.028*** (.378) (.379) (.382) (.382) (.385) (.385) (.384) Religious ideology .324 .335 .328 .335 .349 .334 (.334) (.341) (.343) (.340) (.358) (.34) Islamist ideology .175 (.456) Economic grievance .570*** .585*** .518** .591*** .579*** .609*** .579*** (.208) (.209) (.209) (.208) (.21) (.214) (.21) Cultural grievance -.137 -.117 -.03 -.03 -.119 -.095 -.118 (.163) (.163) (.15) (.164) (.161) (.163) (.161) High political grievance -.146 (.271) Autonomy -.053 -.083 -.082 -.069 -.033 -.072 (.280) (.281) (.292) (.278) (.269) (.28) External support .906*** .877*** .936*** .854*** .883*** .854*** .882*** (.233) (.207) (.216) (.208) (.204) (.2) (.204) Organizational popularity .360 .359 .335 .369 .375 .41 .38 (.289) (.291) (.282) (.282) (.283) (.272) (.283) Democracy .207 .194 .198 .155 .186 .474 (.256) (.259) (.262) (.26) (.259) (1.486) Autocracy -4.413** (1.72) Organizational split 1.171*** 1.217*** 1.173*** (.37) (.371) (.371) Weak leadership .722* (.369) Youth*autocracy 11.584** (4.6) Youth*democracy -.891 (4.679) Israel .670** .685* .772** .704** .721** .461 .696* (.331) (.358) (.349) (.361) (.359) (.381) (.379) Peace years -1.560*** -1.560*** -1.573*** -1.557*** -1.558*** -1.546*** -1.558*** (.182) (.183) (.186) (.185) (.183) (.183) (.183) Peace years 2 .199*** .199*** .201*** .2*** .199*** .197*** .197*** (.045) (.045) (.046) (.046) (.045) (.045) (.045) Peace years 3 -.007*** -.007*** -.007*** -.007*** -.007*** -.007*** -.007*** (.003) (.002) (.002) (.003) (.003) (.003) (.003) N 1649 1649 1649 1649 1644 1644 1644

Note: Standard errors are in parentheses. Asterisks (*, **, ***) indicate significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively. All regressions include an intercept (not reported).

92 Table 3.5: Alternative Model Specifications Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Repression 3.587** .854*** .895*** .876*** (1.814) (.272) (.261) (.262) Youth bulge 8.092*** 6.514** 7.4*** 7.521*** (2.447) (2.55) (2.5) (2.6) GDP growth .995*** 1.032*** 1.032*** (.374) (.388) (.389) Negative GDP growth 2.362 (4.23) Religious ideology .318 .440 .332 (.346) (.346) (.34) Islamist ideology .741 (3.292) Economic grievance .606*** 1.31 .579*** .507** (.215) (1.589) (.209) (.209) Cultural grievance .109 .165 .118 .031 (.161) (.171) (.161) (.152) Autonomy .089 .159 .076 .101 (.271) (.275) (.279) (.28) External support .892*** .886*** .883*** .943*** (.207) (.206) (.205) (.215) Organizational popularity .360 .359 .371 .349 (.287) (.285) (.282) (.274) Democracy .178 .207 .184 .183 (.258) (.259) (.258) (.261) Organizational split 1.173*** 1.228*** 1.168*** (.367) (.372) (.371) Youth*Repression 8.034 (5.33) Youth* Negative GDP growth 9.244 (11.66) Youth* Economic grievance 5.8 (4.663) Youth*Islamist ideology 1.668 (8.751) Israel .677* .758** .722** .826** (.361) (.346) (.359) (.353) Peace years 1.565*** 1.543*** 1.559*** 1.571*** (.184) (.182) (.186) (.186) Peace years2 .198*** .196*** .198*** .2*** (.045) (.045) (.045) (.046) Peace years3 .007*** .008*** .007*** .007*** (.003) (.003) (.002) (.002) N 1644 1644 1644 1644

93 Appendix 2: List of Figures

Probability of Violence in Autocratic and Non-Autocratic Countries .2 .15 .1 ProbabilityViolence of .05 0

.2 .25 .3 .35 .4 Proportion of Young Males

Autocracy=1 Autocracy=0

Figure 3.1: Probability of Violence in Autocratic and Non-Autocratic Countries

94 .25 .2 .15 .1 ProbabilityUseof of Violence .05 0

.2 .25 .3 .35 .4 Proportion of Young Males

Figure 3.2: Youth Bulges and Predicted Probability of Use of Violence

95 Appendix 3: Description of Variables (From MAROB codebook)

Dependent Variable:

DOMORGVIOLENCE :Towhatdegreeistheorganizationusingviolencedomesticallyasa strategy?

0Organizationisnotusingviolenceasastrategy

1Organizationisusingviolenceasoccasionalstrategybutisnotspecificallytargetingpersons.

2Organizationisusingviolenceregularlyasastrategybutistargetingsecuritypersonnel

(includingstatesecuritypersonnelandnonstatearmedmilitias)andnotgovernmentnonsecurity personnelorcivilians

3Organizationisusingviolenceregularlyasastrategybutistargetingsecuritypersonnel

(includingstatesecuritypersonnelandnonstatearmedmilitias)and/orgovernmentnonsecurity personnel,butnotcivilians

4Organizationisoccasionallytargetingciviliansbutmostofitsviolentactstargetsecurity

5Organizationistargetingciviliansregularly

TRANSVIOLTARG :Towhatdegreeistheorganizationusingviolencetotargettransnational entitiesasastrategy?(Theclassificationisthesameasdomorgviolence,rangesfrom0to5)

Independent Variables:

ORGPOLGR Dominantpoliticalgrievanceoftheorganization

ValueLabel

1Majororganizationalgoalsfocusedoneliminatingdiscrimination

2Majororganizationalgoalsfocusedoncreatingorincreasingremedialpolicies

3Majororganizationalgoalsfocusedoncreatingorstrengtheningautonomousstatusforgroup

96 4Majororganizationalgoalsfocusedoncreatingaseparatestateforthegrouporrevanchist changeinborderofstate

88Other:goaldescribedinORGPOLGRDES

99MissingValue/Nobasisforjudgment

ORGECGR Dominanteconomicgrievanceoftheorganization

ValueLabel

0Noexpressedeconomicgrievances

1Economicgrievancesfocusedoneliminationofdiscrimination

2Economicgrievancesfocusedoncreatingorstrengtheningeconomicremedialpolicies

99MissingValue/Nobasisforjudgment

ORGCULTGR Codethedominantculturalgrievanceoftheorganization

ValueLabel

0Noexpressedculturalgrievances

1Culturalgrievancesfocusedoneliminationofdiscrimination

2Culturalgrievancesfocusedoncreatingorstrengtheningeconomicremedialpolicies(i.e., establishingorincreasingstatefundingforculturalprotectionand/orpromotion)

99MissingValue/Nobasisforjudgment

ORGSPLIT Didtheorganizationsplitthisyear?

ValueLabel

0Nosplit

1Split

99Unclear

97 LEAD Typeofleadershipfororganization

ValueLabel

1Factionalized/competingleaders

2Weakordecentralizedleadership

3Strongrulingcouncil

4Strongsingleleader

99MissingValue/Nobasisforjudgment

ORGPOP Popularityoforganization

ValueLabel

1Fringenoevidenceofsupportfromgroup

2Oneofseveralorganizationswithsupportfromgroup

3Dominantorganization

99MissingValue/Nobasisforjudgment

RELORG Doestheorganizationadvocatepoliciesthatincorporatereligioninto publiclife?

ValueLabel

0No(nonreligious)

1Yes

99MissingValue/Nobasisforjudgment

DIASUP Hasorg.receivedsupportfromdiasporainyearbeingcoded?

ValueLabel

0No

98 1Yes

99MissingValue/Nobasisforjudgment

FORSTSUP Hasorg.receivedsupportfromforeignstateinyearbeingcoded?

ValueLabel

0No

1Yes

99MissingValue/Nobasisforjudgment

IGOSUP Hasorg.receivedsupportfrominternationalgovernmentalorganizationinyearbeing coded?

ValueLabel

0No

1Yes

99MissingValue/Nobasisforjudgment

INGOSUP Hasorg.receivedsupportfrominternationalnongovernmentalorganizationorother nonstateactor?

ValueLabel

0No

1Yes

99MissingValue/Nobasisforjudgment

STATEVIOLENCE

Doesthestateuseviolenceagainsttheorganization?

ValueLabel

99 1Stateisnotusinglethalviolenceagainsttheorganization

2Stateisusingperiodiclethalviolenceagainsttheorganization

3Stateisusingconsistentlethalviolenceagainsttheorganization

100 CHAPTER 4

De-Radicalization and Moderation of Islamist Parties 23

23 SomeportionsofthisarticlehavepreviouslybeenpublishedinJuly2012issueof Democratization withmyco authorA.KadirYildirim. 101 A. Abstract Whileexploringtheconditionswhichfosterpoliticalviolenceandradicalismisaninteresting and important research question, the process of deradicalization and moderation of Islamist parties is also equally important which remains underexplored. In this respect, exploring the evolution of radical Islamist parties (moderation process) will yield important clues to better understanddemocratizationintheMuslimworldand formulatemore cohesivepoliciesinthe wakeofthe“ArabSpring.”WhatformsdoIslamistmoderationtake,andwhichfactorsunderlie eachformofmoderation?BybuildingonthefindingsofCommunistmoderationliterature,this chapterintroducesatwostageframeworktoexplainvariationinIslamistpartymoderationover timeandacrossspace:tacticalvs.ideologicalmoderation. Tactical moderation referstothekind ofmoderationwhereradicalpartiesmakeadecisiononwhethertoacceptelectoraldemocracy (rather than violent strategies) as a means to achieve ideological goals without compromising theirplatforms.Structuralfactorssuchaspoliticalliberalization,internationalfactorsandstate repression are causes of tactical moderation. Ideological moderation pertains to shifts in a platformfromaradicalnichetomoremoderatelinestorespondtosocietalchanges(economic liberalization, economic growth, generational changes, electoral loss and changing voter preferences)togaingreaterpopularsupport.Empirically,IanalyzetheItalianCommunistParty, the Party for Justice and Development in Morocco, the Welfare Party, The Justice and DevelopmentParty,theFelicityPartyinTurkey,theMuslimBrotherhoodandtheWasatPartyin Egypt,theHamasinGazastrip,andtheIslamicActionFrontinJordan.Inprovidingevidence throughstructuredcomparisonsandfieldinterviews,thischapterdevelopsageneralizabletheory ofradicalpartymoderation.

102 B. Introduction

Whileexploringtheconditionswhichfosterpolitical violence and radicalism is an interesting

and important research question, the process of deradicalization and moderation of Islamist parties is also equally important, which remains underexplored. The militant Islamist groups

receivedisproportionalmediacoverage,whereasthevoicesofthosenonviolentormainstream

organizationssuchasmoderatepoliticalparties are hardly heard. When Islamist parties issue

statements,whichemphasizecommitmenttodemocracyorrespectforruleoflaw,their‘true’

intentionsareusuallyquestioned.Morespecifically,therearetheoreticaldebatesaboutwhether

Islamanddemocracycancoexistornot,andwhetherpoliticalpartieswithanIslamistideology

cancontributetodemocratizationornot,whichissomehowsimilartothedebatesaboutwhether

Islam promotes violence or not. I explored driving forces of violence and radicalism in the previouschapters.Thischapterbuildsonthepreviouschaptersbyexaminingareversetrend:de

radicalizationandthemoderationofIslamistparties.

While the debates about whether Islam and democracy can coexist or not continue,

support for Islamicoriented political parties has increased considerably since the 1980s.

Attempts by Islamic parties to participate in political systems in semidemocratic Muslim

societiesarecrucialinunderstandingthedemocraticconsolidationofthesecountries.Ontheone

hand, some scholars and policy makers contend that Islamist parties’ participation should be

viewed with caution since they might have the hidden agenda of changing the regime and

establishinganIslamicstateoncetheycometopower.Schwedler(1998)callsthispossibility

‘theparadoxofdemocracy’;theideathatdemocraticprocessesmightempowernondemocratic

actors.Yet,thereisnohistoricalcasesupportingahiddenagendaargument.Ontheotherhand,

otherscontendthattheinclusionoftheseIslamicpartiesleadstomoderationandhencehelps

103 democratic consolidation (Nasr 2005; Schwedler, 2006; Wickham 2004). Indeed, there is a growingtrendofshiftingfromideologyorientedpoliciestomoderatepragmaticpoliciesamong

IslamicorientedpartiesandgrowingsupportforthesemoderateIslamicparties(Nasr,2005).

ModerationappearstohaveemergedasakeytermindiscussionsaboutIslamistsand

Islamist political participation in the Muslim world, as Schwedler (2007) duly notes. That

violence,radicalism,andoppositiontodemocracyareincreasinglyviewedasillegitimatemeans

for political participation led many Islamists to reframe their political discourse accordingly.

This trend has been most visible within the context of the Arab Spring in the Middle East.

However,thereexistsgreatvariation—bothamongIslamistsandothers—astowhatthenotion

ofmoderationrefers.Moderation,hence,hasbecomeacatchallterm.

Inpopulardiscourse,virtuallyeveryIslamistgroupeitherhasaclaimonmoderation,or

is being cast as an example of moderation. Examples include the Party for Justice and

Development in Morocco (PJD), 24 the Islamic Action Front in Jordan, 25 the Yemeni Islah

Party, 26 the Algerian Islah Party, 27 the Turkish Justice and Development Party (AKP), 28 the

EgyptianMuslimBrotherhood, 29 AlNahdainTunisia, 30 theSyrianMuslimBrotherhood, 31 and

24 “Don'tHangtheBarber,” Economist ,July24,2003;KhadijaFinan,“WesternSaharaImpasse,” Le Monde Diplomatique, January11,2006;“IslamistsSlipinMoroccanElections,” Christian Science Monitor ,September10, 2007;“Morocco:IslamistsDivided,JihadistsContained,Secure,” Stratfor Report ,September7,2007. 25 “JordanQuestionsDozensOverAmmanBombings,” ABC News Online ,November12,2005 (http://www.abc.net.au/news/newsitems/200511/s1505087.htmaccessedJanuary30,2011);Clark2006. 26 “YemenPursuingTerrorItsOwnWay;Tactics,ResultsVary,ButTargetIsAlQaeda,” , October17,2002. 27 “AlgerianLeaderEyesPollVictory,” BBC ,April7,2004(http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/africa/3607603.stm accessedJanuary30,2011). 28 “Turkey:PostIslamistsinPower,” Le Monde Diplomatique ,March6,2003. 29 JoshuaStacherandSamerShehata,“HearoutMuslimBrotherhood,” Boston Globe ,March25,2007;“Egypt's BannedMuslimBrotherhoodWins29MoreSeatsinRunoffPolls,” USA Today ,November27,2005;Matthew Kaminski,“AmongtheMuslimBrothers:TheContradictoryFacesofPoliticalIslaminPostMubarakEgypt,” The Wall Street Journal ,April9,2011. 30 MahanAbedin,“IslamistLeaderReturnsFromExile–AnInterviewwithRashidAlGhannoushi,” Le Monde Diplomatique ,31January2011;Gearon,Eamonn,2011.“The‘RealDeal’Revolutions.”Middle East 421:1821; OlivierRoy,“TheTunisianRevolt:WhereHaveAlltheIslamistsGone?” Christian Science Monitor ,January21, 2011 31 “SyriaMuslimBrotherhoodLeaderUrgesWesttoBoycottAssad,” Lebanon Wire ,March18,2006. 104 HamasinthePalestinianTerritories. 32 WhengroupsasdiverseastheTurkishAKPandHamas arebrandedas“moderate,”thetermislikelytolosemuchofitsdistinctiveness.Thisapparent lackofconsensusonmoderationisnotlimitedtopopular discourse. Scholarly literature also showsgreatvarianceastothemeaningandcausesofIslamistmoderation.Suchvariationmight beasymptomofthedifferenttypesofIslamistmoderation. Hence, the question guiding this researchisasfollows:WhatformsdoIslamistmoderationtake,andwhichfactorsunderlieeach formofmoderation?

Fromasocialscienceperspective,theinconsistentuseofthetermmoderationamountsto

“conceptualstretching”implyingthatsomeattributesoftheconceptareeliminatedinfavorof broader applicability, which ultimately decreases the usefulness of the concept (Sartori 1970;

Goertz2006).Thissuggestsalackofprogresstoward a coherent and systematic approach to explaining Islamist moderation. A more systematic approach is thus likely to contribute to a betterunderstandingofIslamistmoderationinacrossnationalperspective.

Another implication is that moderation can become an instrument in ideological struggles; different factions may utilize the concept to gain legitimacy and sympathy from a broaderdomesticandinternationalaudience.Wheremoderationanddemocracyhavebecomethe currencyofpoliticaldiscourse,itiscrucialtounderstand what kind of moderation each party claims and the conditions under which such moderation comes about. 33 Finally, a better understandingofmoderationisnecessaryforbetterpolicymakingespeciallyinthewakeofthe

“ArabAwakening.”ThatIslamistpartiesarekeypoliticalactorsintheMiddleEastandwhether

32 “HamasRepresentsIslamic“CurrentofModeration,” Al-Arabiya TV ,September9,2007. 33 Moderationcanalsobeadoubleedgedsword;hence,partiesneedtomaintainadelicatebalancebetweenactual moderationandretainingideologicalpurityofthepartytopreventcredibilityproblemsandnottoalienatecore supporters(D’Alimonte1999;SánchezCuenca2004;Kitschelt1994,ascitedinAdamsetal.2006). 105 Islamistpartiesmoderateornot—or,towhatextent they moderate—may shape the course of transitionsintheregion.

Inthischapter,IanalyzeIslamistmoderationtoidentifythedifferentformsittakesand to explain how each kind of moderation comes about. To this end, I present a preliminary systematicframework,arguingthatmoderationofIslamistpartiestakesontwocomplementary forms.Thefirstformofmoderationismarkedbyachangeinstrategy.Islamistpartieschooseto participateintheformalpoliticalstructure(ratherthanuseofviolenttactics)byrenouncingtheir originalstance,i.e.,thattheformalpoliticalstructureisirrelevanttotheirultimategoalofan

Islamic state. All of this is done, however, without compromising their core ideology. Such limitedengagementimpliesthatIslamistswillworkwithintheproceduralrulesofanelectoral game,yettheendgoalremainsthesame—replacementoftheexistingsystemwithanIslamic one. Hence, Islamist parties shift from use of violent strategies to nonviolent electoral participation and have a strong conviction that they can attain the ultimate goal via popular support,whichleadstheideologicalplatformtoremainlargelyunchanged,andIslamistparties toremainpolicyseekingparties.Icallthisprocess tactical moderation .34

SomeIslamistparties,however,gofurtherandoverhaulmajorelementsoftheirideology infavorofmorecentristpositions.Specifically,thesepartieschangetheirideologicalpositions on democracy, the economic system, and the political role of Islam. This shift is a clear indicationthatthepartyhasmovedtowardbecomingavoteseekingpartyratherthanapolicy seekingone.Icallthissecondkindofmoderationideological moderation . The causal factors thatmotivateeachtypeofmoderationdifferfromeachother.Whilethetacticalmoderationis largelydrivenbystructuralfactors(e.g.,politicalliberalization,internationalfactors,failureof 34 Theterm“tacticalmoderation”ispreviouslyusedindifferentcontextssuchasSpanishCommunistParty,PSOE, (Share1985)andtheBritishLaborParty(Barker1973).TheuseofthetermforIslamistgroupsdidnotoccuruntil veryrecently(Matesan2009). 106 nondemocraticpathstoachieveideologicalgoalsandregimerepression),societalfactors,such associoeconomicchanges,electoralparticipation,andintrapartydynamics,motivateideological moderation.

The theory developed in this chapter rests in part on the findings of the Communist moderation literature, and more broadly on party moderation. The motivation for reliance on

Western Communist party moderation literature is twofold. Theoretically, the literature on

Communist moderation presents a coherent conceptual framework with which to analyze

Islamistmoderation.Secondly,andmoreconceptually,acrossoverfromCommunistmoderation toIslamistmoderationpointstoakeycategoricalsimilaritybetweenCommunistand Islamist parties.Bothkindsofpartiesareantisystemparties;thatistosayboth,ideally,wanttoreplace thecurrentpolitical,economicandsocialsystemwithonethatisinlinewiththeirideological commitments.

Empirically, I analyze The Italian Communist Party (PCI) and the Moroccan Party for

JusticeandDevelopment(PJD)inacomparativeperspective.Ialsoexamineseveralothercases ofmoderationintheMiddleEastandIapplythetheoreticalframeworkdevelopedinthischapter tothesecases.ThePCIhasbeenoneofthemostradical,yetsimultaneouslyoneofthemost influentialandsuccessfulworkingclasspartiesinWesternEuropeinthe20 th century.Hencethe

PCIcaseoffersinsightsintothemoderationofWesternCommunistparties.Foritspart,thePCI helpstosubstantiatethetheoreticalargumentasIbuildontheCommunistmoderationliterature toanalyzeIslamistmoderation.Theanalysisreliesonsecondaryliterature,andaimstooffera comparativeperspectiveon Islamistmoderation.TheanalysisofthePJDreliesoninterviews with party officials in Morocco, and primary sources, i.e., party publications. The PJD’s selectionoffersauniqueopportunity.ThepartyisoneofthefewIslamicpartiesthathastraveled

107 thewholespectrumofmoderationfromextremeradicalisminthe1970stoamainstreamMuslim democratic platform in the 21 st century, and allows observing both kinds of moderation in a

singlecase.

This chapter is organized into five sections. First, I review the literature on Islamist

moderationandidentifydistincthypothesesofIslamistmoderation.Then,Ipresentasuccinct

review of the Western Communist party moderation literature, and introduce the theoretical

framework for analyzing Islamist moderation based on this literature. In this, I utilize the

moderationoftheItalianPCItodemonstratetheframework.InthethirdsectionIanalyzethe

Moroccan PJD. The fourth section briefly reviews various cases of Islamist moderation in

differentcountriesandexamineshowwelleachcaseofmoderationfitstothetheoryofIslamist

moderationdevelopedinthischapter.Thefinalsectionsummarizesthefindingsanddiscusses

theimplicationsoftheanalysis.

C. Islamist Moderation in the Literature

ThereexistsawiderangeofargumentsonwhatconstitutesIslamistmoderationandthecausal

factorsleadingtomoderation.Theinclusionmoderationhypothesisisoneofthemostimportant

argumentsonIslamistmoderation(Brooks2002;Brumberg2002;Willis2004;Schwedler2006,

2007and2011;Wickham2004;Tezcur2010),andonparty moderation more broadly (Tilly

1978; Kitschelt 1986; Przeworski and Sprague 1986; Tarrow 1994; Bermeo 1997). Islamist parties’inclusionintheformalpoliticalstructure(suchaselections)ishighlightedastheleading

causeofmoderationbecauseitleads Islamistparties to recognize the constraints of a formal

system,andtomoderateasaresult.Ontheotherhand,exclusiveregimesleadtoradicalization

andlegitimatetheuseofviolence,asdiscussedinpreviouschapters(Hafez2003).Inarecent

analysis,Schwedler(2011)offersthemostcriticalreviewoftheinclusionmoderationhypothesis

108 to date. Schwedler, essentially, distinguishes threediscreteargumentswithinthebodyofthis argument:ideologicalmoderationofparties,ofindividuals,andbehavioralmoderation.

Othershavesuggestedvariantsoftheinclusionmoderationhypothesis.Wickham(2004) uses a combination of inclusionmoderation and social learning hypotheses to explain the emergence of the Wasat Party in Egypt, emphasizing middle generation Islamist leaders’ interactions with people from “other” convictions and ideologies as a key factor in their moderation. Cavatorta (2006) and Yilmaz (2009) also emphasize social learning in other contexts.Inasimilarway,electoralparticipationisviewedasakeycauseofmoderationand democratization(ElGhobashy2005;McFaulandWittes2008;Hovdenak2009).

Clark, however, challenges the inclusionmoderation hypothesis by arguing that any

meaningful crossideological cooperation—as an observable implication of moderation—

requiresa“spirit”ofcompromiseandanintraorganizationaldiscussionofcompromise(2006,

542). For Clark, inclusion/participation in a formal political structure of multiple ideological

stripesisnotsufficienttobringaboutmoderation;moderationonthepartoftheIslamistparty

(IAF)mustcomefirstforcooperationandcompromisetoemerge.Yet,Robinson(1997)argues

that Jordanian IAF’s moderation—as evidenced by its support for the democratic opening in

Jordaninthelate1980s—emanatedoutofselfinterest.ForRobinson,IAF’sdecisiontosupport politicalliberalizationthenwasnotbecausethegroupwasmadeupof“Jeffersoniandemocrats” butbecausethegrouphadagenuine“organizationalinterest”inliberalization.

Underscoringinstitutionalfactors,WegnerandPellicer(2009)arguethatthenatureof

therelationshipbetweentheIslamicpartyandtheIslamicmovementthepartyhailsfromisakey

dynamic of moderation. For moderation to emerge the Islamic party should be sufficiently

autonomousfromtheIslamicmovement,accordingtoWegnerandPellicer.Inthecaseofthe

109 PJDinMorocco,thepartyturnedouttobemoremoderatebecauseitsetupitsownmobilization resources,andthepartyorganizationwasinstitutionalizeddistinctlyfromtheIslamicmovement.

ThestrategicinteractionhypothesishighlightsIslamistparties’interactionswithsecular governmentsandmilitaryasadeterminantofIslamistmoderation.Thecredibilityofsignalssent bythemoderatingpartyisdeemedtobecrucialinconvincingthestateandothersthattheparty’s moderationisnota“Trojanhorse.”Thecostlinessofthesignalisafactorcontributingtothe credibility of moderation (Kalyvas 2000). In a variant, statemilitary repression of Islamist groups(suchasdeprivationoffreedomsofassemblyandreligiouspractice,arbitrarydetentions and imprisonment) forces Islamists to moderate their ideological stance on various issues in ordertoensuresurvival(Mecham2004;Ozbudun2006;Somer2007;Cizreed.2009).However, repressionalsohasthepotentialtofosterradicalizationandviolence,asdiscussedinprevious chapters.Ashour(2009:139)pointsoutthat“repressiveautocratsbreedviolenttheocrats”.For example,staterepressionhasledtomoderationofIslamistpartiesinTurkeywhereasrepression ledtoradicalizationoftheAlgerianFIS.

Finally, some scholars offered socioeconomic explanations for Islamist moderation.

Typically, the analogy is to Moore’s (1966) emphasis on the bourgeoisie’s role in bringing democracy.Thesizeofthemiddleclassdirectlycorrelateswiththemoderationanddemocratic disposition of the country in general (Demiralp 2009; Gulalp 2001; Gumuscu 2010; Langohr

2002;Lipset1994;Nasr2005and2009;Salame1994;Yavuz2009;Zakaria2004).Somemake thelinkbetweenastrongermiddleclassandIslamistmoderationmoreexplicit(Nasr2005and

2009),whileothersemphasizeeconomicliberalization’spotentialtocreateabusinessgroupwith

“astakeinopenness,inrules,andinstability”(Zakaria2004,16).

110 Table1summarizeskeyargumentsregardingIslamistmoderation.Overall,theliterature onIslamistmoderationisexpansive,yetlittleagreementexists.Twointerrelatedproblemsstand inthewayofageneralizabletheoryofIslamistmoderation:1)howmoderationisdefined,and2) thelargedegreeofvarianceofmoderationacrossdifferentstudies.Whileoneanalysisconsiders it sufficient for a party to participate in elections for moderation to occur (Robinson 1997), another account might find it insufficient because the adoption of democratic ideals and pluralism is deemed to be a more critical signal of moderation (ElGhobashy 2005). Hence, moderation takes on different meanings suggesting that there may be different kinds of moderation.Second,themultitudeofprocessesandcompetingexplanationsonmoderation—i.e., inclusion,participation,organizationalinterest,partyautonomy,sociallearning,socioeconomic factors—imply that varying mechanisms of moderationexist.Itmaybethecasethatforone particular kind of moderation to emerge (i.e., giving up violence) a particular set of factors shouldexist(i.e.,staterepression,orpoliticalliberalization).Insummary,thereisnoframework that systematically connects various explanations of moderation. Although most explanations deserve merit given the cases and their contexts, in the absence of a unified framework it is virtuallyimpossibletoreachatheoryofIslamistmoderation.

D. Communist Moderation in the Literature

In what follows I review the Communist moderation literature, and more broadly the party

moderation literature, in order to provide a more systematic explanation to the question of

moderation. Unlike the literature on Islamist moderation, Communist moderation literature presentsacoherentconceptualframeworkbywhichonecananalyzeIslamistmoderation.Both

Communistand Islamistparties areantisystemparties;theybothwanttoreplacethecurrent political,economicandsocialsystemwithonethatisinlinewiththeirideologicalcommitments.

111 I argue that two distinct kinds of moderation exist in both Communist and Islamist party moderation:tacticalmoderationandideologicalmoderation.Theydifferonboththeextentof moderationanditsunderlyingcauses.

I define tactical moderation asthekindofmoderationwhere antisystemparties (i.e.,

Communist or Islamist) strategically decide to embrace electoral democracy to realize their ideologicalgoalofadifferentpolitical,economicandsocialsystemwhilerenouncingtheuseof violence.Democracythuscarriesaninstrumentalvalue.Suchmoderationarisesinresponseto changesindomesticinstitutionalstructure(i.e.,politicalliberalization,economiccrises),shifting internationalinfluence,orthefailureofnondemocraticpathstoachieveideologicalgoals(Gray

1980; Pasquino 1980; Amyot 1981; Share 1988; Waller & Fennema 1988; Ishiyama 1995;

Gunther et al. 2004). I call these structural factors. The primary motivation behind tactical motivationisthatbyadaptingtochangingcircumstances,antisystempartiesarestillconvinced thattheycanfulfilltheirideologicalgoals.Hence,notwithstandingtheuseofdemocraticmeans, antisystempartiesretainmostoftheirideology.

Ideological moderation ,incontrast,ismarkedbyamajortransformationofthecentral tenets of party ideology. For Communist parties, this translates into modified positions on capitalism,westernalliance,andpluralistdemocracy.ForIslamistparties,itinvolvesembracing pluralistdemocracy,thefreemarket,andMuslimvalues.Electoraldynamicsunderlieideological moderation.Becausepartieswanttowinagreatershareofvotes and bemoreresponsivetothe electoratetopreventincreasingmarginalization,theymoderatetheirideologies.Societalfactors

(i.e.,intrapartydynamics,economicliberalization,economicgrowth,electorallossandchanging voter preferences) are deemed to play a key role in bringing about ideological moderation

112 (Amyot1981;Ishiyama1995;Share1988and1999;D’Alimonte1999;SánchezCuenca1999;

Greene2002;Berman2008;SomerTopcu2009). 35

Communist Moderation and the Italian Communist Party

SeveralmechanismsareofferedinthescholarlyliteraturetoexplainthemoderationofWestern

Communist parties. While some scholars focus on intraparty dynamics, others emphasize electoralincentivesandsurvivalconcerns.Theideologicalrigidityoftheparty(CuencaSánchez

2004), power struggles between radicals and reformists within the party, leadership change

(Charlton1979,Ishiyama1995;Tucker1967),thestructureofpoliticalsystem(Berman2008), electoral system (Ishiyama 1995; Share 1999), economic growth or crises (Berman 2008;

Putnam1978;Share1988)andinternationalfactors,suchasthedeclineoftheSovietinfluence

(Amyot1981;SánchezCuenca1999),areamongthecommonlycitedcausesofpostcommunist moderation.

Tucker(1967)arguesthataradicalmovementthatsurvivesforalongtimewithoutthe opportunity to implement its objectives undergoes a deradicalization process in which initial deradicalization creates pressure for further deradicalization. Tucker points out four manifestationsofthederadicalizationofMarxistmovements:1)changeinpatternsofaction,2) change in strategy and tactics, 3) intraparty conflict between reformists and radicals, and 4) ideologicalderadicalization.WhileTucker’sfirsttwomanifestationsofderadicalizationpertain to what I call tactical moderation, the latter two are examples of ideological moderation.

Charlton(1979)analyzesthederadicalizationoftheFrenchCommunistParty(PCF)inthe1970s based on Tucker’s framework and argues that changes in the domestic and international

35 Onideologicalmoderation,theliteraturesuggestsadditionalexplanations.Themostprominentamongsuch explanationsisDowns’(1957)medianvotertheorem,arguingthatoncepartiesstartplayingtheelectoralgame,they areforcedtoappealtothepluralityofvoters,whichinturnleadstobroad,centristplatforms.Challengingacrucial assumptioninthemedianvotertheorem,othersarguedthatideologicalchangeinpoliticalpartiesreflectsshiftsin voterpreferences(Stimson,Mackuen,andErikson1995;Adamsetal.2006). 113 environments played an important role in the PCF’s changes in actionpattern, strategy and tactics. This early phase of deradicalization is cited as a major causal factor for ideological deradicalization;thetensionbetweenideologyandpracticeeventuallyleadstomodificationof theideology.

According to CuencaSánchez (2004), ideological rigidity, which is affected by organizational reforms, generational renewal, and leadership, might prevent moderation even thoughmoderationmightpotentiallyleadtoelectoralgains.Forexample,thePSOEinSpain decreaseditsvotesharein1979andthegeneralsecretarysuggestedarenouncementofMarxism inordertogainmorevotes.However,61%ofPSOEdelegatesrejectedthisofferclaimingthat electoralbenefitswouldnotbeworththeideologicalsacrifice.Similarly,theBritishLaborParty lost all national elections between 1979 and 1997 due to its radical position, yet refused to moderateuntilthemid1990s(CuencaSánchez2004).

The structure of the political system is another factor which affects the likelihood of moderation.Inweakdemocracies,inwhichgovernmentsfailtomeetcitizens’demandsandto prevent the armed struggle of communists, communist political parties remain committed to revolutionary tactics, whereas the existence of strongdemocraciesandeconomicdevelopment facilitates moderation (Berman 2008). Lastly, failure of nondemocratic strategies to achieve ideologicalgoalsinthepastorinotherpartsof the world (Pasquino 1980), declining Soviet influence (Amyot 1981), and economic growth (Putnam 1978) also contributed to the moderationofcommunistparties.

WesternCommunistparties’initialexperiencewithmoderationdatesbacktothe1930s with the adoption of the Popular Front strategy. This twostage strategy—as dictated by the

Comintern—envisioned first an antifascist coalition coming to power through democratic

114 means, also called “progressive democracy,” and then preparing the society for a socialist revolution (Amyot 1981). The Popular Front was a new tactic rather than a fundamental ideologicalchangesinceCommunistpartiesremainedcommittedtoaMarxistLeninistideology and saw democracy as instrumental for their endgoal. The key change was giving up armed struggletoachievesocialistrevolution;henceitconformstotacticalmoderation.

Togliatti,PCI’sSecretaryGeneralbetween1926and1964,promotedtheItalianversion ofthePopularFrontstrategy, via italiana al socialismo (Amyot1981,41).Togliatti’sgradualist approach to acquiring state power emphasized a parliamentary road to rather than revolution.HeeliminatedthemilitantimageofthePCI,dismissedtheideaofnoncollaboration with nonleftist groups, and tried to legitimize the PCI as a national party prioritizing Italian nationalinterests(Gray1980;Samuels2003).AlthoughTogliatti’seffortsconstitutedakeystep inmovingthePCIawayfromradicalismandnonparticipation,thechangeultimatelyremained tactical.Togliattitriedtocreatea“partitonuovo,oneopentoCatholicsandformerfascistsas wellasdoctrinallyorthodox”thatdidnotcompromisetheparty’scoreideology(Samuels2003).

AlthoughmanyrefertoTogliatti’spragmaticpersonalitytoexplainPCI’stacticalmoderation

(Amyot 1981; Gray 1980; Pasquino 1980; Samuels 2003), external factors explain the transformation better. Togliatti viewed extreme leftismasriskysincesuchexperiencesinthe

1920salmostdestroyedtheItalianleft(Gray1980).Similarly,thedefeatofCommunistguerillas in Greece (19441949) showed the failure of armed struggle in a world divided between two ideological camps (Pasquino 1980). Hence, Samuels notes, Togliatti was convinced that “the domesticandinternationalbalanceofforceswould notsupporta[communist]insurrectionin any event” (2003, 303). Stronger governments of the postwar period also reinforced this perspectiveespeciallywhencontrastedwiththeinterwarperiodwhichwasplaguedwithweak

115 governments unable to prevent armed struggle and ideas about a revolutionary path to (Berman2008).

Beginningwiththe1960s,EurocommunismincreasinglygainedtractionamongWestern

Communistparties(Spieker1980).ItlaidoutthedisassociationfromtheSovietUnionanda breakwithLeninistideologyascornerstonesofanewera(GentiliandPanebianco1980;Waller andFennema1988).Forsome,Eurocommunismwasamajorsignofderadicalizationamong

WesternCommunistparties(Amyot1981;Devlin1979).Yet,otherschallengedthisviewasa vagueconcept,arguingthatitwasnotclearwhetherCommunistpartiesembraceddemocratic principals,orviewedthemasameanstoachieveMarxist ideological goals (SánchezCuenca

1999;Spieker1980).SkepticismaboutEurocommunismarosespecificallybecauseCommunist partiesstillviewedadualroleforthemselves,apartyofboth“government”and“revolution.”

Eurocommunism’semphasison“organizedmassmovements”andtheirroleas“thefirststepto thehiddenoftheCommunistparty”aggravatedsuspicions.Eurocommunistparties alsofailedtoguaranteecertainbasiccivilrightssuchasfreedomoforganizationandpolitical activity, and they were vague on property rights (Spieker 1980, 442443). Hence,

Eurocommunismexemplifiedanothercaseoftacticalmoderation.

As for the PCI, Eurocommunist ideals brought the party a step closer to ideological moderation.Withthe1964YaltaMemorandumandtheSovietinvasion ofCzechoslovakiain

1968,thePCIslowlydisassociateditselffromtheSovietUnionbyemphasizingpolycentrism

(multiple roads to socialism) (Pasquino 1980). Moreover, postwar economic growth led to gradualchangesinattitudestowardtheEuropeanEconomicCommunity(GentiliandPanebianco

1980). Yet, similar concerns about ideological conservatism and the limits of transformation wereleveledagainstthePCI.Whilepartybehaviorintheparliamentshowedloyalopposition,

116 messagesanddeclarationsofthePCIdidnotfavorademocraticsystem(Pasquino1980,91).

The rank and file of the party, especially older members, remained committed to the revolutionaryideology(Gray1980).Also,thepartydidnotstraytoofarfromtheSovietUnion albeitwitha“nationalemphasis”(Samuels2003).Yet,communistparties’moderationrequired thattheysevertieswiththeSovietUnion(SánchezCuenca1999,21).

PCI’s Historic Compromise in the 1970s and the accompanying policy shifts are examplesofideologicalmoderationthattransformedthepartyfromapolicyseekingonetoa voteseekingone.Changingsocioeconomicconditionsinthe1960sdidnotbodewellforPCIin terms of membership or party ideology. Italy experienced economic growth in the postwar period,underminingPCI’sexpectationforacapitalistcrisis.PCI’smembershipandorganization thusweakenedinthisperiod.Bythelate1960s,thePCIlostonethirdofitsentiremembership

(Samuels 2003). International economic constraints and domestic constraints played a crucial role in PCI’s dramatic shift on positions regarding a NATO alliance and the European

Community. Italy’s exportoriented postwar economic growth required integration with the worldeconomyaswell,especiallywithWesternEuropeandNorthAmerica.Publicopinionalso favoredEuropeanintegrationandgoodrelationswiththeUS.Europeanintegrationwaspopular even among the Communist electorate during late 1960s and early 1970s while Communist leadersremainedsuspiciousofit.TheseelectoralincentivesandPCI’sneedforanalliancewith nonCommunists put pressure on the PCI leadership to moderate positions on foreign policy

(Putnam1978).

The most crucial step toward ideological moderation of the Italian Communist Party camein1972,largelyasaresultofdeepsocioeconomictransformationinItaliansociety.Enrico

Berlinguer, PCI’s leader at the time, proposed the Historic Compromise at the XIII Party

117 Congress.Byacceptingtheproposal,thePCIdecidedtosupportgovernmentsledbyChristian

Democrats(DC)inreturnfortwotangiblebenefits:greaterlegitimacyandtheintroductionof structural reforms that would include elements of socialism (D’Alimonte 1999; Gentili and

Panebianco1980). 36 Increasingnumbersofmiddleclassyouth(196878),whojoinedtheparty for positions rather than revolutionary commitment, were also influential in the historic compromise(Amyot1981).Between1976and1979,thePCIsupportedDCled governments directly, or indirectly (through abstention in the Parliament). It also accepted NATO and

Europeanintegration,keyissuesthatwouldfacilitatecollaborationwiththeDC(Samuels2003).

Hence,keyelementsoftheparty’scommunistideologywererelinquished,pavingthewayfor ideologicalmoderation.Asatestamenttotheparty’sideologicalmoderation,betweentheearly

1960sandthelate1970s,thePCImovedfromtheextremeleft(30)tocenterleft(7)intheleft right spectrum (Manifesto Project). In the same period,thePCIvirtuallyeliminateditsstatist discourseontheeconomyandinsteadexpressedfavorable views on capitalism. 37 In the short

term,PCI’sideologicalmoderationledtoanincreaseinpopularsupport,confirmingtheideathat

societal changes and electoral concerns motivated PCI’s ideological moderation. The party

increaseditsvotesharefrom27%intheearly1970stoaround35%inthemid1970s.

However,itisimportanttonotethatthePCI’sideologicalmoderationwasstillaworkin progressinthe1970s.Forexample,accordingtoa majorityoftherankandfileoftheparty

members,theHistoricCompromisewasdrivenbytacticalmotivestoeventuallycometopower

(Amyot1981).TheHistoricCompromisealsoledtointrapartyconflictswithinthePCI;there

36 AnotherconcernforthePCIwasthepossibilityofafascistunionbetweenthecenterandtherightasexemplified bythe1973militarycoupinChilewherealeftwinggovernmentthattriedtoruleoutChristianDemocratswas crushedbythemilitary(Pasquino1980;Amyot1981;Sassoon1981).Byacceptingcapitalismanddemocracy,the PCIwouldbeabletoavoidtheworstoutcome. 37 Onmarketregulation,PCImovedfromover6pointstoalmost0;onnationalization,thepartymovedfrom3to0; onplannedeconomy,from9to2.Thepointsindicatethenumberofmentionsinpartyprograms;greaterfigures implymorementionsandgreatersignificance.ThedataarefromtheManifestoProjectDatabase. 118 were different interpretations on the new policy. Even though Berlinguer argued that the sacrificeswereneededtointroduceelementsofsocialisminItaly,someregardeditas“apolicy ofsubordination”(Sassoon1981:22829).Inapersonalinterviewin1977,Dr.AntonioTato, oneoftheclosestfigurestoBerlinguer,statedthat:

“Gramsci’sproletarianhegemonyhasnotbeenabandonedbythePCI.Thehegemonyis

notthehegemonyofapartybutofaclass.TheHistoricCompromisewillprovidethe

transitionperiodtothenewhegemony,andthemeansbywhichtheDCinparticular

accepts the new force (proletarian class) politically as the dominant trend in Italy”

(Rusceo1982:114).

TheriseofleftwingterrorismandRedBrigades’kidnappingofDCleaderMoroeventually

led to the PCI’s withdrawal from the DC led government in 1979 (Sassoon 1981). The PCI

continued its moderation later throughout the 1980s making the policy of “democratic

alternative”akeyelementofitsplatforminthe1980s.Yet,thePCIcontinuedtobecriticizedby

major portions of Italian society on various grounds, including a lack of internal democracy,

commitment to vestiges of MarxismLeninism, and a relative lack of commitment to Italy’s

internationalalliances(Daniels1987).Asaresult,thePCIwasleftpoliticallyisolated.While

someblamedthePCI’sHistoricCompromiseforitsdecliningpopularity,othersreferredtoleft

wing revolutionary terrorist episodes that were prevalent in the 1970s. Even though the PCI

condemnedtheterroristattacks,therhetoricoftheterroristsmadethepartyappeartobelongina

“Communistfamily”album(Weinberg1995:49).

Inafurthermovetocarveanicheinthepolitical landscape and move away from its

association with communism, the PCI adopted “new internationalism,” advocating a more

independentroleforWesternEuropebetweenthe,duringthe17 th partycongressin

119 1986.TheSovietUnion’sinvasionofAfghanistanwasalsocondemned.Themainmotivational factorsintheevolutionofthePCI’sinternationalchoicesweretogainclosertieswithotherleft wingpartiesinEuropeandtobecomeanacceptable,legitimatepartneringovernment(Daniels

1987). In 1988, Achille Occhetto, the young reformist leader of the PCI, proposed radical changes for the party, called the new discourse. Occhetto focused on a new political agenda, emphasizing the role of women in Italy, environmental problems, and an expansion of democraticrights.Intrapartydemocracywasalsostrengthened,endingtheideaofdemocratic centralism.AfterthefalloftheBerlinWall,Occhettopushedforfurtherchangesandproposed tochangetheparty’sname;anewpartyfoundedon the principles of democracy and human liberationwasneededsincetheoldconflictbetweencapitalismandsocialismbecameobsolete

(Weinberg1995).Finallyin1991,thePCIadoptedasocialdemocraticstrategyandtransformed itselfintotheDemocraticPartyoftheLeft(PDS).SánchezCuencaclaimsthatthefallofthe

Berlin Wall and the elimination of the Sovietconstraint enabled full moderation of the PCI:

“ModerationmeantforthePCIceasingtobecommunist;credibilitywasattainedatthecostof renouncingitsveryidentity”(1999,p.23).

In summary, PCI’s moderation was motivated by two sets of factors leading to two differentkindsofmoderation.InternationalfactorsandconstraintsconvincedthePCIoftheneed to relinquish the “militant liturgy” and adhere to procedural democracy in the 1940s. Such a limited moderation (tactical moderation) did not necessitate ideological compromise, while electoraldemocracycouldbeinstrumentallyvaluableinreachingcommunismgraduallyinstead ofrevolution.ThePCI’sideologicalchange(ideologicalmoderation)cameonlyafterthe1960s.

The party renounced central tenets of its communist ideology, thereby enabling the PCI to endorse pluralist democracy, capitalism, European integration and NATO. PCI’s tactical

120 moderationwaslargelydrivenbyitsreactiontounsuccessfulrevolutionaryexperiencesinItaly andtherestoftheworld,andtheinternationalcontext;moderationwasundertakentoensure organizationalsurvival.Incontrast,itwaslargelysocietalchangesinItalythatmotivatedPCI’s ideologicalmoderationandeventualtransformationintothePDS;internationalfactorssuchas thefalloftheBerlinWallplayedacomparativelyminorroleinthisprocess.InTable2,Ipresent asummaryofPCI’smoderationalongwiththatoftheMoroccanPJD,whichisdiscussednext.

E. Party for Justice and Development (PJD) in Morocco

LiketheItalianPCI,theMoroccanPartyforJusticeandDevelopment’s(PJD)experiencewith

moderation also came in two distinct phases: tactical moderation between the 1980s and the

1990s,andideologicalmoderationafter2000.Bothtypesofmoderationarediscussedbelow.

PJD’soriginslieintheIslamicYouthAssociation( Al-Shabiba ),anIslamistorganization

established in 1969, which was largely influenced by the Egyptian Muslim Brotherhood’s prominentandhighlycontroversialleader,Sayyid.Duringthisperiod,theIslamicYouth

Association viewed use of violence to establish an Islamic state as a legitimate tool, while participating in the political process was deemed to be against Islamic principles (Tlaidi

interview, 2009; Shahin 1997, 182). In 1970s, King Hassan II banned the organization and persecutedmanymemberswithinthegroupduetotheIslamicYouthAssociation’sinvolvement

inviolentactivities(WegnerandPellicer2009,159). 38

In 1981, a new organization called AlJama’a AlIslamiyya (the Islamic Group) was established by the younger leaders of the group. The new group emerged with revisions in organizationalstructure,ideologyandpractice.UnliketheIslamicYouthAssociation,AlJama’a

AlIslamiyya rejected the revolutionary ideology of Qutb and decided to participate in the

38 Despiteallegations,thegrouprejectedanypartintheviolence(BurgatandDowell1997,172).Eventhoughthe groupwasformallyoutlawedin1975,memberscontinueditsactivitiesforyears(Shahin1997,188). 121 politicalsystem.Thegoalwasto“push”thegovernmenttoapplyIslamiclawgradually.Wegner

and Pellicer note that Al-Jama’a ’s goals during this period conform to classical Islamist

discourse:“…Torenewtheunderstandingofreligion,toadvocatetheimplementationof

law, to achieve a comprehensive cultural renaissance, to work on accomplishing the unity of

Muslims,toconfrontideologiesandideaswhichtheybelievedweresubversivetoIslam,andto

raisetheeducationalandmoralleveloftheMoroccanpeople”(2009,160).

Al-Jama’a officiallyrecognized“thepoliticalandreligiouslegitimacyofthemonarchic regime”whilemanymembersofthegroupstillregardedparticipationinpoliticsasunIslamic

(haram).Thegrouppublishedareportcalled“ThePaperofPoliticalParticipation”tojustifythe political participation (Wegner and Pellicer 2009, 160). According to this report Al-Jama’a decidedtoparticipateinpoliticstoreachawideraudience,tobreakthe“siegeofsecularists”and toobtainparliamentaryimmunitytoensurethesecurity of dawa (religiousmission)activities

(Tlaidiinterview,2009).In1992, Al-Jama’a changeditsnameto Harakat al-Islah wal-Tajdid

al-Maghribiyya (MoroccanMovementforReformandRenewal)toreassertitscommitmentto

therulesofthepoliticalgameinMorocco(Shahin1997,191).Thusfar,thetrajectoryofthe

MovementcloselyresembledthatofthePCI.Initialextremismandrejectionofelectoralpolitics

wasfollowedbyaphaseoftacticalmoderationthatentailedtherecognitionthatrevolutionary

tacticswerenotservingtheideologicalgoalwell.Hence,tobetterserve dawa andtoestablishan

Islamic state, the Movement opted for tactical moderation, i.e., changing its strategy without

changingthecoreideology.

TheMoroccanMovementforReformandRenewalfirstproposedtoestablishapolitical partyin1992,butthegovernmentdidnotallowtheMovementtoformtheparty duetothe

domestic armed conflict in neighboring Algeria (ElKhalfi interview, 2009). Then, the group

122 soughttojoinanexistingparty’slegalumbrellaandcooperationwithAbdelkarimAlKhatib’s moribund Constitutional and Democratic Popular Movement (MPDC) (Desrues and Moyano

2001,30).In1997,theMPDCparticipatedinlegislativeelectionsandwonnineseats(Willis

2004).In1998,thepartyalsochangeditsnametothePartyforJusticeandDevelopment(PJD).

However,neitherthemergernorthenamechangegreatlyaffecteditsIslamistideology.While thePJDabandonedrevolutionaryideas,itmaintainedthecoreIslamistideology.Overthecourse of the next few years, the PJD underwent a substantial transformation, which resulted in ideological moderation. First, PJD’s platform evolved toward a moderate position, which emphasized pluralist democracy, liberal economy, and Muslim values. Second, the separation betweenthePJDandtheIslamicmovementthatthepartyhailedfrom(MovementofUnityand

Reform)facilitatedfurtherideologicalmoderationoftheparty.

In 2002, PJD officials held internal discussions on the party’s future direction. As

McFaul and Wittes (2008) note, electoral participation stimulated intraparty debates that are

deemedtoplayakeyroleinPJD’smoderation.Bilal Tlaidi, a member of the PJD’s national

councilandaresearcheronIslamicmovements,statedthatintrapartydebatesfocusedonparty

identity:wasthePJDanIslamicpartyorapoliticalpartywithanIslamicreference?Tlaidinoted

thedistinctionas,“WhenyousayanIslamicparty,issuesofIslamicidentityandmoralsshould bethemainpriorityfortheparty.WhenyousayapoliticalpartywithanIslamicreference,that meansthepriorityispublicpolicy,butthesolutionssuggestedbythePJDarebasedonIslamic values, not political Islam” (Tlaidi interview, 2009). After 2002, party programs clearly demonstrated that “public affairs” and problems around corruption and the economy took precedenceoverissuesofIslamicidentity(ElKhalfiinterview,2009).

123 PJDofficialsattributedtheideologicaltransformationofthepartytosocietalchanges.

Forexample,formerPJDleaderSaadEddinUthmaniemphasizedsuchchangesandstated,“Itis

impossible for societal changes not to change parties” (Uthmani interview, 2009). Similarly,

Nezha ElOuafi, a female legislator from the PJD, pointed out changes taking place both in

Moroccoandworldwide,andtheconcomitantnecessityforthepartytotransformitselfto“keep

up” with the changes in their own constituency (ElOuafi interview, 2009). The economic

liberalizationprocessthatMoroccowentthroughinthe1980sand1990sledtonewissuesand

demands in Morocco including economic development, democracy and social justice (Cohen

2004; Cammett 2007). Interviews with party officials show that the party considered

expectationsfromthepublicwhileformulatingthenewplatformtoechothepeople’s“agenda”

(ElKhalfiandUthmaniinterviews,2009).

Specifically, the PJD party program shows a commitment to democracy (PJD Party

Program2007,13),whichAmaradefinedas“transparency,cleanelections,humanrights,and

freedom of expression” (Amara interview, 2009). Critically, PJD officials likened the PJD to

Christiandemocraticparties(ElKhalfiinterview,2009).ThePJDassumesthatIslamic/Muslim

valuesrepresenttheauthenticidentityoftheparty(and,oftheMoroccansociety)andtherefore

theyshouldbeupheld;yet,itdoesnotgoasfarascallingfortheimpositionofanIslamicstate

on the society. Thus, the PJD was able to adopt a sincere democratic stance while keeping

Muslimvalues.Islamistparties,bycontrast,generallytakeonastrongerpositionontheroleof

IslambycallingforIslamicstateandapplicationofIslamiclaw,whichpreventsthemfromfully

embracingdemocraticprinciplessuchasfreedomofconscienceandminorityrights. 39

Economically, the PJD adopted a liberal discourse. Recognizing the “reality” of increasing economic globalization, the PJD called attention to Morocco’s “need” for greater 39 ForanexcellentreviewofIslamismandidentitypoliticsintheArabworld,seeIsmail(2004). 124 integration into global markets and its potential to benefit from it (Amara and ElOuafi interviews,2009).PJDlegislatorLahcenDaoudiexplainedthe“need”forMoroccaneconomic liberalizationasfollows:“InMorocco,economicopeningisanecessitybecauseweareasmall state. It is not possiblefor us to develop withour domestic market only; we don’t have oil, minerals,orgold”(Daoudiinterview,2009).Complementingthisstatement,anotherPJDofficial arguedthatMoroccansare“benefiting”fromeconomicliberalization,andhencethepartyfavors a liberal economic policy (Bouanou interview, 2009). Though similar in emphasizing market economy, the PJD’s liberal economic stance differs from Islamist parties’ conventional pro marketapproach.Islamistpartiesascribeadisproportionatelylargeroleforthestateinmanaging theeconomy,whereasthePJD’seconomicstancedoesnotincludethestate’smanagementofthe economy.Islamistparties’visionofthestate’sextensiveroleinregulatingandsupervisingthe economygoesbeyondtheliberaleconomicperspectivethatthePJDadopts.Overall,thenew partymantrastrivestocapturethesentimentofitsownconstituencywhileattemptingtobe“a partyofallMorocco”: Asalah , Adalah , Tanmiyah (Authenticity/Origins,Justice,Development)

(ElKhalfiinterview,2009).

Inadditiontosocioeconomicchanges,organizationalfactorssuchasseparationofthe

PJDfromitsfoundingorganization,MovementforUnityandReform(MUR),alsofosteredthe

ideological moderation process in late 1990s. The movement focused largely on “religious

activities,education,culture,socialwelfare”whereasthepartydealtwith“themanagementof publicaffairs,politicalactivities,andpublicpolicies.” 40 Themembershipinthemovementwas notaformalconditionformembershipinthepartywhichenabledthepartytoembraceideasnot

40 In2007,theMoroccandaily Al-Tajdid (partoftheMURnetwork)reportedonmovementpartyseparation, identifiedthefunctionsofthePJDandtheMURasdistinctorganizations,includingvariousissuesofdisagreement betweenthetwosuchasthe.“AlTamayuzBaynaalHarakawalHizbMasarLaRaja’ahFihi”[The SeparationbetweentheMovementandthePartyNowIrreversible] Al-Tajdid ,2829August,2007. 125 whollyendorsedbythemovement.In1997electionsallMPsexceptonewereMURmembers, whereasonly31%ofPJDcandidatesupforaparliamentaryseatwerealsoMURmembersin

2002 elections. Moreover, currently a lower percentage of intermediatelevel and locallevel officials in the party are also members of the MUR. The PJD set up its own “independent mobilization resources” accompanied by financial independence, institutionalization of party structure,andparallelstructures(WegnerandPellicer2009).Overall,thesechangesshowthat thepartywasbecomingincreasinglyindependentofthemovement.Thus,separationfromthe movementenabledthepartytoengagewithabroaderaudience.Sincethepartydidnotrepresent

Islaminitspoliticalplatform—thankstothemovementpartyseparation—ithadarelativelya greateropportunitytoaddressthedemandsofamorediversepeople.

Crucially, the PJD began enjoying greater popular support in the post2002 period followingitsideologicalmoderation.Whilethepartywonnineseatsinthe1997parliamentary elections, it received 13% and 11% of the votes in 2002 and 2007 elections, respectively, producing42and46parliamentaryseats.ThePJDwonthepluralityofseats(107seatsoutof

395)duringthemostrecentparliamentaryelectionsin2011.PJD’sreachtoawideraudienceis analogoustoPCIinItalyinthe1970s.ThePJDaimstorepresentabroaderconstituencyby moderating its policy platform, in response to perceived societal changes. The change in the constituency in the postliberalization Morocco and the party’s willingness to separate the

Islamicmovementfromthepartysupportmyargument.Hence,IconcludethatPJD’smoveto engage in ideological moderation in the post2002 period is motivated by societal dynamics ratherthanstructuralfactors.

126 F. Application of the Theoretical Framework to Other Cases

WhilethemoderationbythePCIandPJDsupportthetheoreticalframeworkproposedinthis

chapter, such a limited analysis prevents drawing more general inferences. In this section, I briefly review the moderation of several other Islamist parties, examine various arguments proposedbyscholarstoexplainmoderationoftheseparties,andtestthetheory’sgeneralizability

toothercases.Whilethecasesreviewedherearefarfrombeingexhaustive,itpresentsacross

sectionofargumentsexplainingIslamistmoderation.Below,Ibrieflyreviewthemoderationof

theEgyptianMuslimBrotherhood,theWasatPartyinEgypt,theWelfareParty,theJusticeand

DevelopmentParty,andtheFelicityPartyinTurkey,theHamas,andtheIslamicActionFront

(IAF)inJordan.

ThemoderationprocessoftheMuslimBrotherhood(MB)inEgypt,oneoftheoldestand popular Islamist movements, started in 1980s (ElGhobasy 2005). The MB experienced both

tacticalandideologicalmoderationthroughoutitshistory.TheMBgraduallymovedawayfrom

Sayyid Qutb’s (190666) radical ideologies to a more moderate stance. The shift from

“uncompromising”viewsofSayyidQutbtoHasanelBanna'smoderateviewsandanemphasis

on liberal democracy, an example of tactical moderation, occurred as a result of strategic

calculations and participation in parliamentary elections in the 1980s (ElGhobashy 2005;

Harnisch and Mecham 2009; Schwedler 2007). Elections and working within the system are

viewedaswaystospreadtheirmessage(Islamisthesolution);theMBparticipatedinthesystem

tospreadthewordofGod(AbedKotob1995;HarnischandMecham2009).Thepartyalso

wantedtobenefitfromtheincreasingpoliticalopennessofthenewMubarakregime (Harnisch

andMecham2009).Pargeter(2010)arguesthattheterroristattacksonSeptember11,2001and

thefearofbeinglabeledaterroristorganizationpushedMBtowardsmoremoderation.Onthe

127 otherhand,theMB’sideologicalmoderation,whichisdemonstratedbytheadoptionofamore

“democratic” and “moderate” stance on various controversial issues such as women’s rights, parties and political pluralism, and the role of Egyptian Copts, occurred as a result of generationalchange−growing,bettereducated,young,pragmaticactivistsbecamedominantin theMB−,andlearninginstitutionalrulesofparticipation(staterepression)(ElGhobashy2005;

Rurtherford2006).TheMBissuedstatementswhichemphasizewomen’srights,partypluralism, andequalrightsfortheChristianCoptsin199495.TheMB’sideologicalmoderationgained newmomentumasaresultofthepassingofold,radicalmindedmembersinthe2000s(El

Ghobashy 2005). However, whether MB’s ideological transformation is complete or not and whethertheircommitmenttodemocracyissincereornot,aredebatablequestions(ElGhobashy

2005;Masoud2008;Pargeter2010).TheMBclaimsacommitmenttoliberalprogressiveideas whilekeepingreferencestoSherialaw,whichcreatescontradictions(Pargeter2010). After the

2011 and toppling of Mubarek, The MBwonthefirstfreeelectionsandcameto powerin2012.Whilethemovementassuresthattheirgoalis“participation,notdomination,”

President Mohamed Morsi’s recent decision to grant himself extraordinary powers increased doubtsaboutthemovements’commitmenttoliberaldemocracy(Masoud2012).Tadros(2012) arguesthattheMuslimBrotherhoodisapragmaticmovement that has changed as a result of changingpoliticalcircumstancesbuttheMBhasahighly conservative ideology. To sum up, some refer to the Muslim Brotherhood's transformation as involving extensive ideological moderation(ElGhobashy 2005;Rutherford2006)whereas others view it merely as a tactical maneuvertograduallyestablishanIslamicstate(AbedKotob1995;Schwedler2007;Harnisch andMecham2009;Pargeter2010).

128 The Wasat Party, which split from the MB and formedin1996,alsotookthepathof ideologicalmoderationandalteredpositionsoncertaincontroversialissuessuchastheinclusion of women in parliament, and advocacy of equal rights for Egyptian Copts (Stacher 2002;

Wickham 2004). The Wasat Party’s ideological moderation was largely driven by strategic calculations, social learning, and intraparty debates. The core beliefs and values of leaders changedasaresultofinteractionwithsecularsandcrossideologicalcooperation(Clark2006;

Wickham2004).Moreover,fearofrepression,demandtoseizenewpoliticalopportunitiesand avoidconstraintswiththeautocraticelitealsocontributedtotheideologicalmoderationofthe party(Wickham2004).Wickhamarguesthatstrategicmoderationleadstochangesinthepublic rhetoric and behavior of actors which can eventuallycausechangeinultimategoals.Inother words,“Themaskbecomestheface”(Hoeber2003,ascitedinWickham2004,225).

TheJusticeandDevelopmentPartyofTurkey(JDP)engagedinideologicalmoderation whereas the Welfare Party (WP), and the Felicity Party (FP) experienced only tactical moderation.BoththeJDPandtheFPareoffshootsoftheWelfarePartywhichwasclosedbythe

ConstitutionalCourtafterthe1998postmodernmilitarycoup.Turkishpoliticsischaracterized by a power struggle between the secular elite (represented by the Constitutional Court, the

military and leftist parties) and religious parties. Islamic parties were banned from politics

several times by the Constitutional Court since they are regarded as a threat to secular

democracy.

TheWPgainedapluralityofvotesandcametopowerinthe1996elections.Survival

concerns and the realization of institutional constraints, such as the fear of closure by the

Constitutional court, motivated the tactical moderation of both the WPand the FP (Mecham

2004).EventhoughtheWPwascommittedtoliberaldemocraticprinciples,itremainedananti

129 systemparty;theelectioncampaignsemphasizedcreationofaninterestfreeIslamiceconomy, antiWestern sentiments, and religious freedom (Mecham 2004, 342). When the WP came to power,Erbakan,theleaderoftheparty,visitedIslamiststatessuchasIranandLibyainorderto

establishaneconomicblocofMuslimcountries.Erbakanalsoinvitedreligiousleaderstothe primeminister’sresidencewhichledtocriticismbytheseculareliteandtheeventualclosureof

theparty(Mecham2004).ThemembersoftheWPestablishedtheVirtuePartyaftertheclosure

of the WP. Meanwhile, there were intraparty debates and a power struggle between the

reformistyounggenerationandoldmemberswhowereloyaltoErbakan.TheVirtuepartywas

alsoeventuallyclosedbytheConstitutionalCourtin2001sinceitwasregardedascontinuation

oftheWP.Then,twosplinterpartiesestablished:reformistsandmorepragmatistsestablished

theJDPandthoseloyaltoErbakanformedtheFelicityParty.TheJDPcametopowerinthe

2002electionsandfocusedonlegislativeandconstitutional reforms that promote democracy,

market economy, and proEU reforms while avoiding religious references. Institutional

constraints−politicallearningfrompastexperiences−,generationalchange−existenceofyoung,

reformist leaders−, socioeconomic changes, and electoral incentives−the recognition that

majorityvotesfor centristparties−motivatedtheideological moderation of the JDP (Mecham

2004;Ozbudun2006;Tezcur2010;Yilmaz2009)Ontheotherhand,eventhoughtheFPfaced

similar institutional constraints with the JDP, its religious ideology remained intact. Tezcur

(2010)arguesthattheunresponsivenessoftheFPtoinstitutionalconstraintswasbecauseofthe

lack of reformminded leaders. The leaders of the FP kept a rigid Islamist ideology which preventedtheirfullmoderation.

HamasisanotherinfluentialIslamistgroupthatwentthroughtacticalmoderationfora

limitedtimeperiod.Hamaschoseviolentresistanceratherthanelectoralpoliticsandactedlikea

130 spoiler during the PalestinianIsrael peace process in 1990s. However, Hamas changed its strategybydeclaringaunilateralceasefiretowardsIsraelin2003andparticipatinginelectionsin

20052006. Hamas also changed uncompromising views regarding the borders of the future

Palestinian state and accepted pre1967 borders. Hovdenak (2009) argues that international pressure and demand for recognition led to the moderation of Hamas. However, unresponsivenessofinternationalactorstoHamas’scompromisesandtheboycottoftheHamas government after the 2006 elections weakened moderate leaders within Hamas. As a result,

Hamas reradicalized and violently took over the Gaza Strip in 2007 (Hovdenak 2009). The international constraints played a significant role during both the moderation and re radicalizationprocessofHamas.Inotherwords,internationalactors’unwillingnesstorewardthe tacticalmoderationoftheHamasbackfiredthemoderationprocess.

Finally, the Islamic Action Front (IAF) in Jordan experienced tactical and arguably ideological moderation to a certain extent. The IAF’s ideological platform emphasizes implementation of sharia, denouncing corruption, liberation of Palestine, women’s equality withinanIslamicframework,freedomanddemocracy.TheleadersofIAFclaimthattheparty believes in democracy, not as a tactic but as a strategy. The goal is of society, graduallyanddemocratically.Robinson(1997)explainstheIAF’sembracementofdemocracy

(tactical moderation) with strategic reasons; mainly to protect organizational and political interestsandtosecuresurvivalofthepartyinarepressiveregime.TheIAFplayedbytherules ofthegameeventhoughtheKingadoptedanewelectorallaw(1993)whichlimitedtheIAF’s chancesofgainingseatsintheparliament.TheKingalsosignedapeacetreatywithIsrael(1994) whichwashighly criticizedbythe IAF.Nevertheless,theIAFdidnotresorttoviolence.The

IAFstartedtocooperatewithleftistsandliberalsbythemid1990s.Schwedler(2006)argues

131 thattheIAFmoderatedbothbehaviorally(whatIcalltacticalmoderation)andtosomeextent ideologically.AccordingtoSchwedler(2006;2007),politicalinclusionleadstocooperationwith otherparties(andhencetacticalmoderation)butinclusionaloneisinsufficientforideological moderation; internal party debates within the party and Islamic justification of new practices−cooperationwithotherpartiesandparticipation−producedideologicalmoderationof

IAF.

Tosumup,twoobservationsstandoutfromthereviewofthesemoderationcases.First, with two notable exceptions (the Egyptian Muslim Brotherhood and the Jordanian Islamic

Action Front for which both tactical and ideological moderation explanations exist in the literature), the distinction between tactical and ideological moderation largely correlates with howIslamistmoderationisconceptualizedasadependentvariable.Casesoftacticalmoderation andhowtheyareoperationalizedcontrastssharplywithcasesofideologicalmoderation.While factorslikerenunciationofviolence,useofelectoralpolitics,andcrossideologicalcooperation areofferedasobservableimplicationsoftacticalmoderation,ideologicalmoderationismarked bythemoderationofIslamistideologyondemocraticvalues,pluralism,women’srights,market

economy,andadoptionofmorecentristpositions.

Second,regardingthecausesofmoderation,thereissomelevelofconvergence,although

theconvergenceistoalesserextentthantheone observed for types of Islamist moderation.

Amongthecausesoftacticalmoderationmentionedintheliteratureareinclusion,international pressure, political liberalization, internal debates, and organizational survival/interest. By

contrast, factors leading to ideological moderation are less coherent: institutional constraints,

rules of participation, generational differences, social learning, internal conflict, participation,

state repression, electoral concerns, and socioeconomic changes. Some of these factors are, in

132 fact, reminiscent of factors leading to tactical moderation. The incongruence between the theoreticalframeworkproposedinthischapterand thefactors assumedtoleadtoideological moderationispartlyrelatedtothewayideologicalmoderationisconceptualizedasideological change.Asdiscussedabove,thereexistsacertainlevelofdisagreement astowhether certain groups actually went through a process of ideological transformation or not. Overall, the theoretical framework largely captures the variationinIslamistmoderationinacrossnational setting.Nonetheless,amorerigoroustestofthetheoryisnecessarytoconfirmthepreliminary findingsinthisanalysis.

G. Conclusion

Moderationhasbeenbothakeyterminpopulardiscourseandanimportantresearchquestionin thescholarlyliteraturerecently.Inthischapter,IreviewedtheIslamistmoderationliteratureand demonstrated that the literature thus far failed to produce a systematic approach to analyze

Islamist moderation. Specifically, I showed that moderation stands for a wide array of ideas ranging from limited attitudinal selfrestraint (or, being tolerant) to farreaching ideological renunciation and democratization. Moreover, there is no consensus among scholars about the underlying causes of moderation; a number of competing arguments are provided to explain moderationofIslamistparties.Mygoalinthischapterwastointroduceapreliminaryframework toexamineIslamistmoderationinasystematicfashionacrossawiderangeofcontexts.Tothis end,IexaminedtheliteratureonCommunistparties’moderationinWesternEurope.Because

Communistpartieswentthroughdifferentwavesofmoderationthroughoutthe20 th centuryjust asIslamistpartieshavebeengoingthroughinrecentyears,thecaseofCommunistpartiesand theirmoderationisanalyticallyvaluable.

133 Iidentifiedtwokindsofmoderation:tacticalandideological.Tacticalmoderationrefers

toalimitedkindofmoderationinwhichradicalpartiesrenounceuseofviolencebuttheanti

system ideology remains largely intact, and democracy is instrumental in achieving the

ideologicalgoal.Ideologicalmoderation,incontrast,referstoanextensiveeffortinabandoning

majorelementsoftheantisystemideologyonissuessuchastheIslamicstate,economyand pluralistdemocracy.Buildingonthisframework,Ipresentedseveralcasestudies.Thefirstone

wasthemoderationoftheItalianCommunistParty(PCI)untilthe1990s.Thesecondcasestudy

wasthatoftheMoroccanPartyforJusticeandDevelopment(PJD)fromitsoriginsinthe1970s

untiltheearly2000s.Bothcasesservedtodemonstratethetheoreticalframeworkdevelopedin

thischapter.

The moderation processes of the PJD and the PCI indicate that similar paths of

moderationoccurasaresultofsimilarcausalfactors.ThePCI’sdecisiontoadoptthePopular

Frontstrategyandtoleavetherevolutionarypathwaslargelyduetotheinternationalcontext,

namely,thefailureofrevolutionarystrategiesinotherpartsoftheworld.Ontheotherhand,the

PJD decided to participate in the political system and recognized the political and religious

legitimacyofthemonarchicregimesincethemoreradicalformofthegroupwasbanned.Inboth

cases,thefearofrepressionandthefailureofnondemocraticalternativeswerethedrivingforce

for tactical moderation. Neither the PCI nor the PJD sacrificed ideological principles while participatinginthepoliticalsystemandmaintainingtheendgoalsofcommunismandIslamic

stateatthisstage.Socioeconomicchangesinthe1950sandthe1960sduetorapideconomic

growth in Italy and the economic liberalization process throughout the 1990s in Morocco

underlieideologicalmoderationinbothcasesinthefollowingdecades.Apreliminaryanalysisof

134 the moderation process of other Islamist parties provides partial support for the theoretical frameworkdevelopedinthischapter.

Thefindingsofpreviouschaptersindicatethatreligiousideologyand/orIslamisnota

significantfactorindrivingconflictsanddecisiontoresorttoviolenceintheMuslimworld;

othersocioeconomicfactorsandpoliticalopportunities/constraintslargelyshapethelikelihood

oferuptionofdomesticconflicts.Thefindingsofthischapterareinlinewithpreviousfindings.

Like radicalization and violence, moderation is significantly influenced by socioeconomic

factorsaswellasinternationalconstraints.Ideologiesandideaschangeovertime.Eventhough

someIslamistpartiesinitiallymoderateforstrategicpurposesandsurvivalconcerns,changing

electoral dynamics push for further ideological moderation. Thus, one can conclude that

political parties evenwithrigidradicalideologiesmaynotresistsocietal changes and hence

gradually moderate. Finally, the similarities between moderation of Communist parties and

Islamistpartiessuggestthatthereisno“Islamicexceptionalism”.Radical Islamistpartiesare

similartootherradicalpartiesandrespondtochangingsocietalconditionsinasimilarway.

135 Reference List Adams, J., M. Clark, L. Ezrow, and G. Glasgow. 2006. “Are Niche Parties Fundamentally DifferentFromMainstreamParties?TheCausesandtheElectoralConsequencesofWestern Parties’PolicyShifts,19761998.” American Journal of Political Science 50(3):513529. Amyot, Grant.1981. The Italian Communist Party : The Crises of the Popular Front Strategy. NewYork:StMartinPress. Barker, Bernard. 1973. “Anatomy of Reformism: The Social and Political Ideas of the Labour LeadershipinYorkshire.” International Review of Social History 18:127. Berman,Sheri.2008.“TamingExtremistParties: LessonsfromEurope.” Journal of Democracy 19(1):518. Bermeo,Nancy.1997.“MythsofModeration:Confrontation and Conflict During Democratic Transitions.” Comparative Politics 29:305–22. Botella,J.,R.Montero,andR.Gunther.2004. Democracy in Modern Spain. NewHaven:Yale UniversityPress. Brooks,RisaA.2002.“LiberalizationandMilitancyintheArabWorld.” Orbis 46(4):611621. Brumberg,Daniel.2002.“IslamistsandthePoliticsofConsensus.” Journal of Democracy 13(3): 109115. Burgat,FrancoisandWilliamDowell.1997. The Islamic Movement in North Africa .Austin,TX: UniversityofTexasPress. Cammett,MelaniC.2007. Globalization and Business Politics in North Africa: A Comparative Perspective .Cambridge:CambridgeUniversityPress. Cavatorta, Francesco. 2006. “Civil Society, Islamism and Democratisation: The Case of Morocco.” Journal of Modern African Studies 44(2):203222. Capoccia, Giovanni. 2002. “AntiSystem Parties: A Conceptual Reassessment.” Journal of Theoretical Politics 14(1):935. Charlton,SueEllenM.1979.“DeradicalizationandtheFrenchCommunistParty.” The Review of Politics 41(1):3860 Cizre,Ümit,ed.2009. Secular and Islamic Politics in Turkey: The Making of the Justice and Development Party .NewYork:Routledge. Clark, Janine. 2006. “The Conditions of Islamist Moderation: Unpacking CrossIdeological CooperationinJordan.” International Journal of Middle East Studies 38:539–560.

136 Cohen,Shana.2004. Searching for a Different Future: The Rise of a Global Middle Class in Morocco .Durham:DukeUniversityPress. D'Alimonte,Roberto.1999.“PartyBehaviorinaPolarizedSystem:TheItalianCommunistParty andtheHistoricCompromise”.In Policy, Office or Votes ? How Political Parties in Western Europe Make Hard Decisions eds. Wolfgang C. Müller and Kaare Strøm, pp.141171. Cambridge:CambridgeUniversityPress. Daniels, Philip A. 1987. “The ItalianCommunistParty:GoodbyetoEurocommunism” The World Today 43(8/9):139142. Demiralp, Seda. 2009. “The Rise of Islamist Entrepreneurs and the Decline of Islamic RadicalisminTurkey.” Comparative Politics 41(3):315336. Desrues, Thierry and Eduardo Moyano. 2001. “Social Change and Political Transition in Morocco.” Mediterranean Politics 6(1):2147. Downs,Anthony.1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy .NewYork:Harper. ElGhobashy, Mona. 2005. “The Metamorphosis of the Egyptian Muslim Brothers.” International Journal of Middle East Studies 37(3):373395. Fennema,MeindertandWaller,Michael1988eds. Communist Parties in Western Europe. New York:BasilBlackwellInc. Gentili,MariaAnnaandPanebianco,Angelo.1980.“ThePCIandInternationalRelations,1945 1975:ThePoliticsofAccommodation.”In The Italian Communist Party Yesterday, Today and Tomorrow, eds. Simon Serfaty and Lawrence Gray, pp.109128. Westport, CT: GreenwoodPress. Goertz, Gary. 2005. Social Science Concepts: A User's Guide. Princeton , NJ: Princeton UniversityPress. Gray,Lawrence.1980.“FromGramscitoTogliatti:ThePartittoNuavoandtheMassBasisof ItalianCommunism.”In The Italian Communist Party Yesterday, Today and Tomorrow, eds. SimonSerfatyandLawrenceGray,pp.2136.Westport,CT:GreenwoodPress. Greene, Kenneth F. 2002. “Opposition Party Strategy and Spatial Competition in Dominant Party Regimes: A Theory and the Case of Mexico.” Comparative Political Studies 35(7): 755783. Gülalp,Haldun.2001.“GlobalizationandPoliticalIslam:TheSocialBasesofTurkey’sWelfare Party.” International Journal of Middle East Studies 33(3):433448. Gumuscu, Sebnem. 2010. “Class, Status, and Party: The Changing Face of Political Islam in TurkeyandEgypt.” Comparative Political Studies 43(7):835861.

137 Hovdenak,Are.2009.“HamasinTransition:TheFailureofSanctions.” Democratization 16(1): 5980. Ishiyama,JohnT.1995.“CommunistPartiesinTransition:Structures,LeadersandProcessesof DemocratizationinEasternEurope.” Comparative Politics 27(2):147166. Ismail,Salwa.2004.“BeingMuslim: Islam, Islamism and Identity Politics.” Government and Opposition 39(4):614631. Kahneman,Daniel,andAmosTversky.1979.‘‘ProspectTheory:AnAnalysisofDecisionunder Risk.’’ Econometrica 47(2):263–92. Kalyvas, Stathis. 2000. “Commitment Problems in Emerging Democracies: The Case of ReligiousParties.” Comparative Politics 32(4):379398. Keren,Michael.2000.“PoliticalPerfectionismandthe‘AntiSystem’Party.” Party Politics 6(1): 107116. King, G., R. Keohane, and S. Verba. 1994. Designing Social Inquiry: Scientific Inference in Qualitative Research .Princeton,NJ:PrincetonUniversityPress. Kitschelt, Herbert. 1986. “Political Opportunity Structures and Political Protest: AntiNuclear MovementsinFourDemocracies.” British Journal of Political Science 16:5785. Langohr,Vickie.2002.“AnExitfromArabAutocracy.” Journal of Democracy 13(3):117122. Lipset, Seymour Martin. 1994. “The Social Requisites of Democracy Revisited.” American Sociological Review 59(1):122. Magaloni,Beatriz.1997. The Dynamics of Dominant Party Decline: The Mexican Transition to Multipartyism. UnpublishedDoctoralDissertation,DukeUniversity,Durham,NC. Mainwaring,ScottandTimothyScully.2003. in Latin America: Electoral Competition and Regime Conflicts .Stanford,CA:StanfordUniversityPress. Matesan, Emy. 2009. “The Effects of Political Integration on the Strategic and Tactical Moderationof IslamistGroups.”PaperPresentedat the Annual Meeting of the ISA, New York,NY. McFaul, Michael and Wittes, Tamara Cofman. 2008. “Morocco’s Elections: The Limits of LimitedReforms.” Journal of Democracy 19(1):1933. Mecham,QuinnR.2004.“FromtheAshesofVirtue,APromiseofLight:TheTransformationof PoliticalIslaminTurkey.” Third World Quarterly 25(2):339358. Moore,Barrington.1966. Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy .Boston:BeaconPress.

138 Nasr,Vali.2005.“TheRiseofMuslimDemocracy.” Journal of Democracy 16(2):1327. ––––––. 2009. The Rise of Islamic Capitalism: Why the New Middle Class Is the Key to Defeating Extremism .NewYork:FreePress. Onis,Ziya.2006.“GlobalizationandPartyTransformation:Turkey’sJusticeandDevelopment PartyinPerspective.”In Globalizing Democracy: Party Politics in Emerging Democracies , PeterBurnell.ed.London:Routledge. Ozbudun, Ergun. 2006. “From Political Islam to Conservative Democracy: The Case of the Justice and Development Party in Turkey.” South European Society and Politics 11(34): 543557. Pasquino, Gianfranco. 1980. “From Togliatti to Compromesso Strorico: A Party with a GovernmentalVocation.”In The Italian Communist Party Yesterday, Today and Tomorrow, eds. Simon Serfaty and Lawrence Gray, pp.75108. Westport, Connecticut: Greenwood Press. Przeworski, Adam and John Sprague. 1986. Paper Stones: A History of Electoral Socialism . Chicago:UniversityofChicagoPress. Putnam, Robert D. 1978. “Interdependence and the Italian Communists.” International Organization 32(2):301349 Robinson, Glenn E. 1997. “Can Islamists Be Democrats? The Case of Jordan.” Middle East Journal51(3):373387. Ruscoe,James.1982.OntheThresholdofGovernment:TheItalianCommunistParty,197681. NewYork:St.Martin’sPress. Salame,Ghassan.1994. Democracy Without Democrats? The Renewal of Politics in the Muslim World .NewYork:I.B.Tauris. Samuels,Richard.2003. Machiavelli’s Children: Leaders and Their Legacies in Italy and Japan. Ithaca,NY:CornellUniversityPress. SánchezCuenca, Ignacio. 1999. “The Logic of Party Moderation.”. Estudio/Working Paper 1999/135,InstitutoJuanMarchdeEstudioseInvestigaciones. ––––––. 2004. “Party Moderation and Politicians’ Ideological Rigidity”. Party Politics 10(3): 325342. Sartori, Giovanni. 1970. “Concept Misinformation in Political Science.” American Political Science Review 64(4):10331053. ––––––.1976. Parties and Party Systems .NewYork:CambridgeUniversityPress.

139 Sassoon,Donald.1981. The Strategy of the Italian Communist Party: From the Resistance to the Historic Compromise .London:FrancesPinterLimited Schwedler,Jillian.2006. Faith in Moderation: Islamist Parties in Jordan and Yemen .NewYork: CambridgeUniversityPress. ––––––. 2007. “Democratization, Inclusion and the Moderation of Islamist Parties.” Development 50(1):5661. ––––––. 2011. “Can Islamists Become Moderates? Rethinking the InclusionModeration Hypothesis.” World Politics 63(2):347–376. Shahin,EmadEldin.1997. Political Ascent: Contemporary Islamic Movements in North Africa . Boulder,CO:WestviewPress. Share, Donald. 1985. “Two Transitions: Democratisation and the Evolution of the Spanish SocialistLeft.” West European Politics 8(1):82103. ––––––.1988.“DilemmasofSocialDemocracyin1980s:TheSpanishSocialistWorkersParty inComparativePerspective”. Comparative Political Studies 21(3):408435. ––––––. 1999. “From Policy seeking to office seeking: the metamorphosis of the Spanish Socialist Worker’s Party.” In Policy, Office or Votes ? How Political Parties in Western Europe Make Hard Decisions eds. Wolfgang C. Müller and Kaare Strøm, pp. 89111. Cambridge:CambridgeUniversityPress. Somer,Murat.2007.“ModerateIslamandSecularistOppositioninTurkey:Implicationsforthe World,MuslimsandSecularDemocracy.” Third World Quarterly 28(7):12711289. SomerTopcu,Zeynep.2009.“TimelyDecisions:TheEffectsofPastNationalElectionsonParty PolicyChange.” The Journal of Politics 71(1):238248. Spieker,Manfred.1980.“HowtheEurocommunists Interpret Democracy.” Review of Politics 42(4):427464. Stimson, James, Michael MacKuen, and Robert Erikson. 1995. “Dynamic Representation.” American Political Science Review 89(3):54365. Tadros,Mariz.2012. The in Contemporary Egypt: Democracy Redefined or Confined? NewYork:Routledge. Tarrow,Sydney.1994. Power in Movement: Social Movements, Collective Action, and Politics . NewYork:CambridgeUniversityPress. Tezcur,GunesMurat.2010.“TheModerationTheoryRevisited:TheCaseofIslamicPolitical Actors.” Party Politics 16(1):6988.

140 Tilly,Charles.1978. From Mobilization to Revolution .Reading,MA:AddisonWesley. Tucker, Robert C. 1967. “The Deradicalization of Marxist Movements.” American Political Science Review 61(2):343358 Yilmaz, Ihsan. 2009. “Muslim Democrats in Turkey and Egypt: Participatory Politics as a Catalyst.” Insight Turkey 11(2):93112. Wegner, Eva and Miquel Pellicer. 2009. “Islamist Moderation without Democratization: The ComingofAgeoftheMoroccanPartyofJusticeandDevelopment.” Democratization 16(1): 157175. Weinberg, Leonard. 1995. The Transformation of Italian Communism . New Brunswick and London:TransactionPublishers. Wickham, Carrie Rosefsky. 2004. “The Path to Moderation: Strategy and Learning in the FormationofEgypt’sWasatParty.” Comparative Politics 36(2):205228. Willis,MichaelJ.2004.“Morocco’sIslamistsandtheLegislativeElectionsof2002:TheStrange CaseofthePartyThatDidNotWanttoWin.” Mediterranean Politics 9(1):5381. Zakaria, Fareed. 2004. “Islam, Democracy, and Constitutional .” Political Science Quarterly 119(1):120.

141 Appendix 1: List of Tables

Table 4.1: Arguments on Islamist Moderation in the Literature

Independent variable Type of moderation Definition of moderation Schwedler (2006) Inclusion Participate in “Movement from a democraticprocesses relatively closed and rigid worldview to one more open and tolerant of alternative perspectives” Wickham (2004) Inclusion & social Ideologicalmoderation Ideological moderation learning and respect for the democraticprocesses Brooks (2002) Inclusion & political Participation in liberalization democraticprocesses El-Ghobashy Ideological moderation Ideological (2005) Participation and democratic transformation understanding Clark (2006) 1) Spirit of compromise, 2) more than a mere “tactical” Crossideological compromise, and 3) cooperation intraorganizational discussion of compromise Robinson (1997) Organizational self Endorsingdemocracy Democracy interest Wegner and Partyautonomy 1) Level of Pellicer (2009) disagreement between “Increasing flexibility partyandIslamicsocial towards core ideological movement,and2)level beliefs” of cooperation with other(left)parties Somer (2007) Staterepression Ideologicalmoderation Nasr (2009) Moving away from Economy/capitalism Moderation extremism Zakaria (2004) Economicliberalization Ideologicalmoderation

142 Table 4.2: Summary of Cases Italian Communist Party (PCI) Party for Justice and Development (PJD) Pre- Marxist/Leninistideology Moroccansocietyin jahiliyya (preIslamicignorance) moderation Armedstruggle Useofforcelegitimate Socialistrevolution PoliticalparticipationunIslamic

Change Causes Outcome Change Causes Outcome Tactical Popular Front Risks associated Democracy as a Dissolution of Al- To break Break with Qutb’s moderation Strategy (“via withextremism means Shabiba & “secularist”siege extremist ideas italiana al Defeat of Limited ideological establishment of To obtain (Moroccan society is socialism” communist guerilla change Al-Jama’a Al- parliamentary not jahili ) (1940s) warfare in Greece Reach socialist Islamiyya (1981) immunity to ensure Use of force not (19441949) revolutiongradually security of dawa acceptable International activities Reach Islamic state opposition Desire to reach a and Islamic law Eurocommunism 1964 Yalta Disassociation from wideraudience gradually (1960s) Memorandum theS.U. Accept rules of 1968 Soviet Break with Leninist electoral game in invasion of ideology Morocco Czechoslovakia Uncertain democratic Engage with other commitment parties (political Conflicting views participation) fromtheparty Ideological Historic Socioeconomic Support for Christian Intraparty Socioeconomic Shiftfromidealismto moderation Compromise changes precipitated Democratic discussions on changesinthepost pragmatism (1970s) by the sustained governments party identity & 1980 economic Democratic & party name postwar economic Accept NATO and direction (2002)& liberalization commitment changed to growth Europeanintegration separation of the period Support for liberal Democratic Weakening social Accept free market movement and the To appeal to a economy and Party of the Left base capitalism party wideraudience globalization (PDS) 1/3ofmembership Democratic Emphasis on Islamic lost commitment values,notIslamicstate

Appendix 2:List of Interviewees

Mustapha ElKhalfi – PJD official and editor of Al-Tajdid newspaper; Rabat, December 8, 2009. SaadEddinUthmani–Formersecretarygeneral,PJD;Rabat,December8,2009. Dr. Driss Bouanou – Youth leader and member of Committee on Foreign Relations, PJD; Rabat,December10,2009. AbdulkadirAmara–PJDparliamentarianand memberofthePJDGeneralSecretariat;Rabat December17,2009. BilalTlaidi–PJDNationalCouncilmember,independentresearcher,andreporterfor Al-Tajdid newspaper;Rabat,December17,2009. LahcenDaoudi–PJDparliamentarian;Rabat,December18,2009. NezhaElOuafi–PJDparliamentarianandacademician;Rabat,December23,2009. NoureddineKarbal–PJDparliamentarian;Rabat,December23,2009.

144 CHAPTER 5

Conclusion

145 Therecentuprisingsandtheongoingviolent/nonviolentprotestsintheMiddleEastonceagain ledtopopulardebatesaboutwhatdrivesconflictintheMuslimworld.Thereareanumberof competingargumentsthatexplaindrivingforcesofviolenceintheMuslimworld,radicalization, deradicalization, and moderation of Islamist parties/groups. These explanations focus on a varietyoffactorssuchassocioeconomicanddemographicfactors,religion,culture,political opportunities, and constraints. Specifically, there is a theoretical debate about whether Islam fostersviolenceornot.Yet,thereisnoconsensusamongscholarsabouttheextenttowhich religionmaypromotepoliticalviolence.

This dissertation investigates the empirical nexus between Islam and political violence/nonviolence by specifically focusing on the incidence of domestic armed conflict, grouplevel political violence (such as insurgency, terrorism, and genocide), and party moderation. In chapter 2, I examine factors that increase a country’s risk of experiencing domestic armed conflict, whereas chapter 3 analyzes conditions under which ethnopolitical organizationsoptforviolentstrategiestoachievetheirgoals.Chapter4examinesmoderationof

Islamistparties.

Iarguethatreligiousdenominationalonedoesnotnecessarilymakecountriesmoreor lessconflictprone.Socioeconomicandpoliticalconditionsusuallydeterminethedecisionto resort to violence or alternatively to renounce violence and to moderate. While numerous conflictsintheworldmaybeframedasreligious,ignoringrootcausesofviolenceandsolely attributingconflictpronenesstoculturalorideologicalfactorswouldbeanoversimplification ofthesecomplexevents.Indeed,existingstudiesthatconcludethatMuslimmajoritycountries aremoreconflict/violencepronefailtocontrolforfactorsthatincreasetheriskofinsurgency, suchassocioeconomicdevelopment,staterepression,youthbulges,andoildependence,and

146 confoundmanyvariablesunder“Islam”.Itisnotpossibletodrawacausalrelationshipbetween

Islamandconflictpronenesswithoutcontrollingforfactorsthatincreasetheriskofdomestic conflict.Below,Ireviewthegeneralfindingsfromtheprecedinganalysisofthisdissertation.

First, I compare and contrast findings of chapter 2and chapter3,and organizemy findings based on key concepts tested in both chapters: religion, demographic factors, grievances, politicalopportunitystructure,andresources.Ialsosuggestpotentialexplanationsforsomeof thenullfindings,andprovidesuggestionsforfutureresearch.Next,Isummarizethefindings fromchapter4,whichfocusonIslamistpartymoderation.Finally,Iconcludebydiscussingthe policyimplicationsofmyoverallfindings.

Religion

What explains the prevalence of political violence in the Muslim world and to what extentdoesreligionplayaroleinpromotingviolence?Theseresearchquestionsmotivatedmy dissertation.Iconductedanumberofempiricalanalysestoevaluatetheimpactofreligionin fostering violence at both statelevel and grouplevel. The overall findings indicate that, contrarytosuggestionsandclaimsintheliterature,neitherreligiousfractionalizationnorIslam promotesconflictoncesocioeconomicandpoliticalfactorsaretakenintoaccount.

First,religiousfractionalizationisnegativeandinsignificantinalloftheregressionsin chapter2,whichsuggeststhatreligiousdiversityisnotasignificantfactorinincitingdomestic armed conflict. Second, intrastate conflicts are indeed more prevalent in Muslimplurality states,butsocial,economic,andpoliticalconditionsinthesestatescreateanenvironmentthatis verysusceptibletodomesticarmedconflicts.Muslimpluralitystatesarecharacterizedbymore repressiveregimes,oildependenteconomies,morepoverty,and ahigherproportionofyouth bulges.WhileIslamappearstobesignificantlycorrelatedtodomesticarmedconflictonsetina

147 bivariateregression,thesignificanceofIslamdisappearsoncethecorrelatesofdomesticarmed conflict are controlled for. Both Muslimplurality and interactions of Muslimplurality with variousexplanatoryvariablesremaininsignificantinmostoftheregressionsevenaftertrying different operationalization of Islam –use of Muslimplurality, Muslimmajority or Muslim proportion−, and alternative model specifications. Third, the findings from chapter 3 also confirmthatIslamistideologyisnotasignificantfactorindrivingviolenceatthegrouplevel.

EventhoughthelimitationoftheanalysestoMiddle Eastern region prevents making broad generalizations and comparing conflictproneness of organizations in Muslim countries with nonMuslimones,notalloftheethnopoliticalorganizationsintheMiddleEastareinspiredby religious/Islamist ideology. Thus, I was able to control for the influence of religion by comparingtheconflictpronenessoforganizationsthathaveareligious/Islamistideologywith nonreligiousones.LiketheMuslimpluralityvariableinthepreviouschapter,Islamistideology isinsignificantinallofthemodelsinchapter3.

Demographic Factors

Thedemographicstructureofacountryhasthepotentialtoincreasetheriskofdomestic armed conflict and grouplevel violence. Specifically, increasing population growth and the existenceoflargeyouthcohortsmakecountriesmorepronetoconflict/violence.Thecountries thathaveahighertotalpopulationareexpectedtobemorepronetodomesticarmedconflict sinceitishardtocontrolpeopleanddeterinsurgencyinhighlypopulatedcountries.Increasing population may also lead to resource scarcity, higher unemployment rates, and poverty.

Moreover,theexistenceofayouthbulge−whichisdefinedastheproportionofyoungmales betweentheagesof1524tototaladultpopulation−increasesbothgrievances(especiallywhen coupledwithpoverty,unemployment,andrepressiveregimes)andthesupplyofpotentialrebel

148 recruits (Urdal 2006). For example, some scholars argue that youth bulges have played a significantroleduringtherecentuprisingsintheMiddleEast;itisarguedthatthose young people,dissatisfiedwiththeiroppressiveregimesandfrustratedwithunemployment,rebelled againsttheirgovernments(HoffmanandJamal2012;Mohammed2011).

Thefindingsfromchapter2suggestthattotalpopulationindeedincreasestheriskof domesticarmedconflict,whereastheimpactofyouthbulgeisinconclusive.Whileyouthbulge is insignificant in most of the regressions, the Islamyouth bulge interaction in Model 8 is positiveandsignificant,suggestingthatMuslimpluralitycountrieswithahigherproportionof youngmalesaremoreconflictpronethantherestofthesample.However,furtheranalysisfrom themarginaleffectofyouthbulgesuggeststhatMuslimpluralitystatesbecomemoreconflict pronethannonMuslimcountriesforonlyextremely highvaluesof youthbulges.Whilethe impactofyouthbulgeinchapter2ispuzzling,thefindingsfromchapter3indicatethatyouth bulgessignificantlyincreasetheprobabilityofviolencebyethnopoliticalorganizations.Youth bulgeispositiveandsignificantinallofthemodelsinChapter3.Ialsointeractyouthbulge with several explanatory variables in chapter 3 to explore whether the positive influence of youthbulgesisconditionalonothersocioeconomicorpoliticalfactors.Ifindthattheyouth bulges autocracy interaction is positive and significant, whereas youthdemocracy, youth repression, youtheconomic grievance, and youthIslamist ideology interactions are all insignificant. Obviously, youth bulges create more problems in autocratic countries than democraticones.

Futurestudiesmayfocusonexploringtheroleofyouthbulgesinincreasingtheriskof domesticarmedconflictintheMuslimworld.Whatmakestheseyouthpopulationmoreprone totheuseofviolenceandwhyaretheymoreconflictpronethanotheragecohorts?Thisisan

149 important research question which remains underexplored. Grievances that stem from unfavorable socioeconomic and political conditions, such as high unemployment rate, high income inequality, and the existence of oppressive/ authoritarian regimes, may be mediating betweentheuseofviolenceandyouthbulges.Futureresearchcantesttheconditionalimpactof youth bulges by interacting youth bulge with unemployment rate, education, or income inequality.Currently,IcontrolforGDPpercapita,regimetype,andrepressionbutexistingdata oneducation,incomeinequality,andunemploymenthavemanymissingobservations.

Grievances

How significant are grievances in fostering violence and domestic armed conflict?

According to Gurr (1970)’s relative deprivation theory, social, economic, and political grievances lead to feelings of relative deprivation and frustration, which in turn motivates individuals to resort to violence. Yet, there is no solid empirical support for the relative deprivation hypothesis; existing studies provide mixed evidence regarding the impact of grievances in fostering violence (Canetti et al 2010; Collier and Hoeffler 2004; Fearon and

Laitin 2003; Gurr 1993; Mousseau 2011; Regan 2009). I examine the impact of economic, political,andculturalgrievancesinfosteringdomesticarmedconflictandgrouplevelviolence in chapters2and3,respectively.

Inchapter2,IuseGDPpercapitatooperationalizeeconomicgrievances.Highervalues ofGDPpercapitaindicatemoreeconomicdevelopmentandhencefewergrievances.Irelyon

GDPpercapita,whichisaverycrudeproxyofeconomicgrievances,duetolimitationsindata availability of better indicators at the crossnational level. Even though there is a negative relationship between GDP per capita and likelihood of domestic armed conflict, it reaches statisticalsignificanceinonlyModels5and8.GDPper capitalosesstatisticalsignificance

150 when oil dependence is added to the model. Oil dependence is known to increase risk of domesticarmedconflict.Perhaps,oilrichcountrieswithhighGDPpercapitasarestillproneto conflict.Inotherwords,thenegativeimpactofGDPper capitamay be overwhelmedby the positive influence of oil dependence in promoting domestic conflict. Political and cultural grievancesarenottestedinchapter2sincethereisnocrossnationaldataavailabletomeasure theseconcepts.

Inchapter3,IusethreeordinalvariablesfromtheMAROBorganizationalbehaviordata totesttheimpactofeconomic,political,andculturalgrievancesinpromotingviolenceatthe grouplevel. Unlike the previous chapter, the findings from chapter 3 suggest that economic grievancessignificantlyincreasetheprobabilityofadoptingviolentstrategiesbyethnopolitical organizations,whereasneitherpoliticalgrievancesnorculturalgrievanceshaveanysignificant impact. However, caution is necessary when interpreting the insignificance of political grievances. All of the ethnopolitical organizations in the MAROB dataset have political grievances, which prevents controlling for the impact of this concept since there is little variation in this explanatory variable. I only compared conflictproneness of separationist groups/independencemovementstothosethathavealessseverepoliticalgrievanceandthe difference between the two was not statistically significant. In sum, even though grievances seem to increase the risk of violence, the findings from both chapters remain inconclusive.

Futureresearchcanexploretheconditionaleffectofgrievances−suchasinteractingeconomic grievanceswithyouthbulges–andusebetterindicatorsofsocioeconomicgrievancessuchas incomeinequalityorunemploymentrateifdatabecomeavailable.

151 Political Opportunity Structure

Politicalopportunitiesandconstraintsavailableinasocietysignificantlyinfluencethe decisiontoresorttoviolence.Ifpoliticalinstitutionsgivepeopletheopportunitytoexpresstheir dissatisfaction/frustration through nonviolent/conventional means, the likelihood of violence andconflictdeclinessincerationalindividualswouldprefernonviolentoptions,whichareless risky andproventobe moresuccessful, comparedto violent ones (Stephan and Chenoweth

2008).Inotherwords,torebel,deprivedgroupsshouldbelievethatviolentactionistheonly option.Therefore,politicalopportunitiesplayasignificantroleintransforminggrievancesinto militant action. While exclusive and repressive regimes promote violence, inclusive regimes decreasetheprobabilityofuseofviolence(Hafez2003).

Staterepressionandregimetypeareusedinbothchapterstotesttheimpactofpolitical opportunities/constraintsinfosteringviolence.Repressionisadoubleedgedsword;repression candeter rebellionbyincreasingthecostofcollectiveaction,butitcanalsoincreaseriskof conflictthroughincreasing grievances. Inchapter2,IusetheCIRIintegrityscoretotestthe impact of repression. Repression was positive and significant, whereas its squared term was negative and significant inmostofthemodels.Lowlevelsofrepressionincrease the risk of domesticarmedconflict,whereashighlevelsofrepressionactuallydecreasetheriskofconflict, sincecollectiveactionbecomesverycostlyunderextremelyrepressiveregimes.Thefindings fromchapter3confirmthatrepressioningeneralfostersviolence;ethnopoliticalorganizations thatarerepressedbythestatearemorelikelytouseviolentstrategiesthanotherorganizations.

The literature on domestic armed conflict onset suggests that there is a curvilinear relationship between regime type and likelihood of domestic armed conflict; transitionary regimesareexpectedtobemorepronetodomesticarmedconflictsthanbothdemocraciesand

152 autocraciessincetransitionaryregimesusuallylackthecapacitytodeterinsurgencyaswellas thenonviolentmeanstoexpressfrustration.IusethePolityscorefromthePolityIVprojectand createadichotomousvariableforanocraciestoexaminetheimpactofregimetypeinchapter2.

Theempiricalanalysisconfirmsthattransitionaryregimesareindeedmoreconflictprone;an anocracy dummy is positive and significant in three of the five models and barely loses significance in the remaining two models. However, unlike theoretical expectations, the findingsfromchapter3suggestthatregimetypedoesnotseemtoaffectthedecisiontoresortto violencebyethnopoliticalorganizations.Iuseadichotomousvariablefordemocraciesandit was insignificant in all of the regressions. Alternatively, I include the polity score and its squared term in the analysis and it was also insignificant. 41 One potential reason for insignificance of regime type at the grouplevel analysis could be selection bias; the dataset includes only Middle Eastern countries. Most Middle Eastern countries are nondemocratic; thereislittlevariationinregimetypeamongMiddleEasterncountries.Israelistheonlycountry which is coded as ‘free’ by Freedom House and Israel has a long history of conflict with

Palestinians, which makes it a democratic but violenceprone nation. Future studies may examine more countries, and test the impact of regime type in fostering violence by ethno politicalorganizations.

Resources

Resource mobilization theory emphasizes the importance of resources required to mobilize rather than grievances in promoting rebellion. It is argued that frustration is not sufficientformobilization;groupsneedresourcestotransferindividualfrustrationintogroup mobilization.Therefore,bothexternalandinternal resources affect mobilization capacity and theprobabilityofrebellion(McCarthyandZald1977).Atthestatelevel,theexistenceofoilor 41 Themodelswithacontinuouspolityscorearenotreportedhere,buttheyareavailableuponrequest. 153 othernaturalresourcesareexpectedtoincreasetheriskofdomesticarmedconflict.Ross(2006) claimsthatoilandothermineralsincreasetheriskofconflictbecausetheymakeindependence moredesirableforresourcerichregions.CollierandHoeffler(2004)confirmthattheexistence ofnaturalresourcescreatesopportunitiestorebel.However,oilmoneycanalsobeusedtoco opt potential dissidents, especially in politically corrupt regimes, thus reducing the risk of domesticconflict(Fjelde2009).Atthegrouplevel,externalsupportforanorganizationfrom diasporasorfromotherinternationalactorsanddomesticsupportgenerallydetermineavailable resourcestomobilizeandcapabilitytoengageincollectiveaction.

Icontrolforbothoildependenceandnaturalresourcedependenceinchapter2andfind thatcountriesthathaveahigherproportionofoilrentsaswellasothernaturalresourcerentsare atgreaterriskofexperiencingdomesticarmedconflict.Inchapter3,Iincludetwodichotomous variablesfromtheMAROBdatathatmeasureinternalandexternalsupportfortheorganization toproxyresourcesavailabletoethnopoliticalorganizations.Whileexternalsupportincreases theprobabilityofviolencebytheseorganizations,domesticsupportfortheorganizationsdoes nothaveasignificantimpact.Overall,thesefindingsindicatethatresourcesareindeedcrucial inpromotingpoliticalviolence.

Insum,thefindingsfromchapter2andchapter3suggestthatstaterepression,regime type,availabilityofresources,youthbulges,andgrievancesallaffectthelikelihoodofdomestic armed conflict as well as the decision to resort to violence by ethnopolitical organizations.

Whilestaterepression,economicgrievances,andresourcesarefoundtobesignificantinboth chapters, the impact of other factors varies depending on the level of analysis. There is a curvilinear relationship between regime type and the risk of domestic armed conflict at the statelevel of analysis, whereas regime type fails to reach statistical significance when the

154 analysis is conducted at the grouplevel. On the contrary, youth bulge is positive and statisticallysignificantinalloftheModelsinchapter3,whereasitisinsignificantinmostofthe

Modelsinchapter2.Finally,religionfailstoreachsignificanceinalloftheregressionsinboth chapters. One can conclude that socioeconomic and political conditions rather than religion largelydeterminethedecisiontoresorttoviolence.

Moderation of Islamist Parties

In chapter 4, I analyze the moderation of Islamist parties, which has been a common trend for many Islamist parties. By building on the findings of the Communist moderation literature,IintroduceatwostageframeworktoexplainvariationinIslamistmoderation:tactical vs.ideologicalmoderation.Tacticalmoderationoccurswhenradicalpartiesrenouncetheuseof violenceanddecidetoacceptelectoraldemocracyasameanstoachievepoliticalgoalswithout compromising their core ideology. Structural factors such as political liberalization, internationalfactorssuchasfailureofrevolutionarytacticsinotherpartsoftheworld,andstate repression drive tactical moderation of radical parties. Some parties go beyond the tactical moderationandchangetheirideologicalpositionsondemocracy,theeconomicsystem,andthe politicalroleofIslam,whichIcallIdeologicalmoderation.Ideologicalmoderationislargely drivenbyelectoralmotives.Inotherwords,Islamistpartiesmoderatetheirradicalideologiesas aresponsetosocietalchangessuchaseconomicliberalization,economicgrowth,generational changes,electoralloss,andchangingvoterpreferencestogaingreaterpopularsupport.

Empirically, the Italian Communist Party (PCI) and the Party for Justice and

Development (PJD) in Morocco are analyzed in comparative perspective. PCI’s tactical moderationwaslargelydrivenbyitsreactiontounsuccessfulrevolutionaryexperiencesinItaly andtherestoftheworld,andtheinternationalcontext;moderationwasundertakentoensure

155 organizationalsurvival.Likewise,thePartyforJusticeandDevelopmentinMoroccooptedfor tacticalmoderationinordertobetterserve dawa (religiousmission)activities andtoestablish an Islamic state. In both cases, the fear of repression and the failure of nondemocratic alternativeswerethedrivingforcesfortacticalmoderation. Ontheotherhand,societalchanges andelectoraldynamicsinItalyledtotheideologicalmoderationofthePCI.Similarly,electoral participation,intrapartydebates,societalchanges,andorganizationalfactorssuchasseparation ofthePJDfromitsfoundingorganizationfosteredtheideologicalmoderationprocess.

Policy Implications

Theresearchquestionsexploredinthisdissertation are relevant for both scholars and policymakers.Thefindingsofthisresearchcanhelppolicymakersindevelopingstrategiesthat willreducethethreatofreligiousextremismanddomesticarmedconflict.Ididexploretherole ofreligionandIslamistideologyindrivingdomesticarmedconflictorlowerlevelviolencein the first two quantitative chapters whereas the qualitative chapter focused on Islamist party moderation. The overall findings indicate that religion by itself does not drive conflict; unfavorable socioeconomic and political conditions explain the high hazard of domestic conflictintheMuslimworld.Thisisgoodnewsforpolicymakers;itispossibletocontainor decreasethesedomesticconflictsbyimplementingpoliciesthatwillalleviatesomeofthesocial, economic,andpoliticalproblems. Hypothetically,therewouldbelittleonecandotoeliminate theseconflictsifreligionwasthemajorcausesincereligiouspreferencecanhardlychange.

Amongallofthesocioeconomicandpoliticalfactorsanalyzedinthisdissertation,state repressionisfoundtobesignificantinalloftheregressionsaswellasinthequalitativeanalysis.

While repression has the potential to deter insurgency, to foster insurgency, to motivate radicalization or moderation of Islamist parties, the overall findings suggest that repression

156 usuallybreedsmoreviolence.Therefore,policymakersshouldreconsidertheuseofrepressive measurestodeteroppositiongroups.Whilespreadingdemocraciesmaydecreasetheprobability ofconflictinthelongrun,transitionperiodsareusuallycharacterizedwithmoreviolenceand higherratesofdomesticarmedconflict.EventhoughtheanalysisislimitedtotheMiddleEast, the findings from chapter 3 suggest that regime type does not affect ethnopolitical organizations’decisiontoresorttoviolence.Perhaps,itisrepressivenessoftheregimerather thanitsautocraticnaturethatfostersviolence.Arguably, even democratic countries could be repressivetoacertainextent.

Finally,understandingtheevolutionofradicalIslamistparties(themoderationprocess) isnecessaryforbetterpolicymakingintheMiddleEast.Islamistpartiesarekeypoliticalactors, which are regarded as the only viable opposition group in many Muslim countries. Islamist parties won the most recent elections in Turkey, Egypt, Tunisia, and in Morocco. Whether

Islamistpartiesmoderateornot—or,towhatextenttheymoderate—mayshapethecourseof transitionsintheregion.TheprecedinganalysissuggeststhatIslamistpartiesactstrategically andrespondtosocietalchanges.Participationinthepoliticalsystemfostersmoderationandde radicalization whereas exclusive and repressive policies lead to radicalization and violence.

Therefore,developingpoliciesthatencourageIslamistparties’politicalparticipationmayhelp tominimizethreatofreligiousextremism.

157 Reference List

Canetti,Daphna,StevanEHobfoll,AmiPedahzurandEranZaidise.2010.MuchAdoAbout Religion: Religiosity, Resource Loss, and Support for Political Violence. Journal of Peace Research 47(5):575587. Collier, Paul and A. Hoeffler.2004. Greed and Grievance in Civil War. Oxford Economic Papers,50:56373. Fearon, James D. and David Laitin. 2003. Ethnicity, Insurgency, and Civil War. American Political Science Review 97(1):7590. Fjelde,Hanne.2009.BuyingPeace?OilWealth,CorruptionandCivilWar,1985—99. Journal of Peace Research 46(2):199218. Gurr,TedRobert.1993.WhyMinoritiesRebel:AGlobalAnalysisofCommunal MobilizationandConflictsince1945.” International Political Science Review , 14:161201. Hafez, Mohammed M. 2003. Why Muslims Rebel: Repression and Resistance in the Islamic World .Colorado:RiennerPublishersInc. Hoffman, Michael and Jamal Amaney. 2012. The Youth and the Arab Spring: Cohort DifferencesandSimilarities. Middle East Law and Governance 4:168–188 McCarthy,JohnD.andZald,MayerN.1977.ResourceMobilizationandSocialMovements:A PartialTheory. American Journal of Sociology 82(6):12121241. Mohammad,AlMomani.2011.TheArab“YouthQuake“:ImplicationsonDemocratization andStability.MiddleEastLawandGovernance,3(12):159170. Mousseau, Michael. 2011. Urban poverty and support for Islamist terror Survey results of Muslimsinfourteencountries. Journal of Peace Research 48(1):3547. Regan,PatrickM.2009. Sixteen Million One ,ParadigmPublishers. Ross, Michael. 2006. A Closer Look at Oil, Diamonds, and Civil War. Annual Review of Political Science .9:265300. Stephan,MariaJ.andEricaChenoweth.2008.WhyCivilResistanceWorks:TheStrategic LogicofNonviolentConflict. International Security .33(1):744.

Urdal, Henrik. 2006. A Clash of Generations? Youth Bulges and Political Violence. International Studies Quarterly 50(3):607629

158 VITA

Suveyda Karakaya received the B.A. degree in Business Administration from Bogazici

University,Istanbul,Turkeyin2007andtheM.A.degreeinPoliticalSciencefromKansasState

University in 2009. To pursuit Ph.D., shejoined the graduate program in the department of

Political Science at the University of Tennessee, Knoxville in 2009. During her Ph.D., she worked as a Teaching Associate and taught introduction to Political Science course to undergraduate students. Mrs. Karakaya will complete the Doctor of Philosophy degree in

PoliticalScienceinSummer2013.

159