From Mercantilism to Neoliberalism Determined Latin America's Economic Progress

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

From Mercantilism to Neoliberalism Determined Latin America's Economic Progress Frederick Stirton Weaver. Latin America in the World Economy: Mercantile Colonialism to Global Capitalism. Latin American Perspectives Series. Boulder: Westview Press, 2000. xix + 252pp. $25.00, paper, ISBN 978-0-8133-3809-5. Reviewed by Ralph Lee Woodward Published on H-LatAm (April, 2002) From Mercantilism to Neoliberalism determined Latin America's economic progress. In a work more substantial than its relatively Its focus places Latin America within the chang‐ few pages might suggest, Frederick Stirton ing international political economy. Nor is it nar‐ Weaver succinctly summarized and analyzed the rowly economic deterministic, for the author im‐ relationship between Latin American develop‐ parts a good sense of social and cultural issues ment and the world economy since the sixteenth that are related to the economic history of the re‐ century. He develops and refines ideas and ap‐ gion. And while he provides considerable atten‐ proaches that frst appeared in earlier articles, es‐ tion to economic theories and forces, he con‐ pecially his "Capitalist Development, Empire, and cludes that Latin America's future ultimately de‐ Latin American Underdevelopment: An Interpre‐ pends on human political choices, not simply on tive Essay," Latin American Perspectives 3: 17-53, the forces of technology and the market. A profes‐ and more recently for Central America in his In‐ sor of economics and history at Hampshire Col‐ side the Volcano: The History and Political Econo‐ lege, Weaver offers this book as "part of a continu‐ my of Central America (Boulder: Westview, 1994). ing dialogue among those committed to under‐ The author's ability to synthesize concisely large standing current changes in ways that might en‐ periods and concepts and his clear and didactic able more people in the world to live with less style makes this an especially appropriate work material deprivation and political oppression" (p. for undergraduate courses on Latin America's xiv). economic history, or even for general surveys of More than half the book focuses on the latter Latin American history. two-thirds of the twentieth century, yet the three It is not primarily, however, an economic his‐ chapters synthesizing the previous four centuries tory of Latin America, but rather an analysis of are remarkably sound. While this reviewer would the ways in which economic systems and process‐ have preferred greater elaboration on several as‐ es in the North Atlantic world have affected and pects of earlier history, he nevertheless must ap‐ H-Net Reviews plaud the work's success at condensing a very rhetoric that accompanied it, however, it is diffi‐ large literature into an effective summary. cult to determine whether the operation was prin‐ An initial chapter overviews the rise of Euro‐ cipally an old-fashioned helping hand for rich pean capitalism and its application to the New friends or whether it was informed mostly by a World (1492-1700), while a second treats competi‐ global anti-Communist strategy that genuinely tive capitalist industrialization, free trade imperi‐ saw Guatemala as a bridgehead for an assault on alism, and Latin American independence the Americas. But beyond the usual mix of mo‐ (1700-1850). The third chapter deals with the rise tives, it is important to note that preserving a cap‐ of fnance capitalism, the New Imperialism and italist system of private property in production Latin American export economies from 1850 to (anti-Communism) and preserving the private 1930, in which Weaver notes important differ‐ property of a powerful U.S. corporation abroad ences between nineteenth-century German-led in‐ (corrupt connections) can easily be made to sound dustrial growth and England's eighteenth-century like the same thing" (pp. 109-10). industrial revolution, both drawing Latin America A ffth chapter explains import substitution more fully into the North Atlantic trading system and industrialization in Latin America in the mid- with its agroexports. twentieth century, weighing the varying effects-- Much of the work focuses frst on the eco‐ successes and failures--of this approach to Latin nomic history of Europe and the United States and American economic development. Again, the au‐ then relates how they affected Latin America. thor's ability to condense to few words complex Chapter 4 describes the rise of transnational cor‐ historical developments is evident, as, for exam‐ porations and the dominant features in the inter‐ ple, in his treatment of the Argentine in the late national economy. It contains a splendid synthesis twentieth century: "The most serious problem for and analysis of international theories dominating the military government...was the enduring lega‐ world trade and relations in the mid-twentieth cy of Perón's political mobilization of large pro‐ century. It does a particularly good job of explain‐ portions of the working population. The military ing the increasingly complexity of U.S. business government's failures in trying to demobilize the interests in Latin America. His synthesis of the workers set the stage for severe fscal crises. Con‐ U.S. intervention in Guatemala in 1954 is charac‐ tinuing working-class political pressure hindered teristic of his brief yet perceptive analyses: the government's ability to curtail social expendi‐ "Democracy in Guatemala (1944-1954)...had wor‐ tures or shift the tax burden onto the shoulders of ried the Truman administration a bit, but it be‐ the poor. Tax reductions for the well-to-do, then, came deeply disturbing to the U.S. government in led to such general declines in tax rates that tax the early 1950s when the United Fruit Company, revenues shrank not only as proportions of GDP which had close connections with the very top but even in absolute terms" (p. 141). The result echelons of the Eisenhower administration, had is throughout the Southern Cone, he argues, was property threatened by the reformist govern‐ that "the mobilization of workers had gone too far ment. Corrupt connections and the fear of Com‐ for standard military coups or the resumption of munist influence in Guatemala, in good part pro‐ ISI [Import-Substituting Industrialization], and all duced by an extensive media campaign by the three military governments [Uruguay, Argentina, United Fruit Company, were a powerful combina‐ and Chile] abandoned the ISI project altogether tion, and in 1954, the CIA went ahead with its and opted for another economic model. There is plans to overthrow the Guatemalan govern‐ no question that the ISI project contained serious ment....Despite the overheated anti-Communist technical problems, and its prospects for propel‐ ling continued economic dynamism were not 2 H-Net Reviews bright. Nevertheless, the frst nations to jettison shifting government-citizen relationships" (p. ISI were not responding to failures of ISI's eco‐ 150). nomic logic to generate economic growth; rather Much of the fnal chapter is devoted to what they were reacting to its political logic: the real Weaver calls Neoliberal Democracy, as he argues and immediate political challenges that ISI's eco‐ that "contrary to conventional wisdom, the mutu‐ nomic successes had produced. The military gov‐ al compatibility that links democracy with free ernments used brutal force to dismantle the state- markets is not a common commitment to individ‐ centric ISI structures and to replace them with po‐ ualism and decentralized authority; the presence litically safer 'free market' mechanisms. Unlike of large, powerful corporations makes such asso‐ earlier, short-lived experiments of this kind, how‐ ciations highly tenuous. The principal connections ever, these shifts in policy occurred at a time between free markets and democracy are to be when the contradictions of Modern Times in the found in other directions, and Neoliberal Democ‐ leading capitalist powers were already producing racy is my name for the powerful combination of new patterns of economic organization and inter‐ debt crisis, neoliberal political economy, and elec‐ national political economics. The politically op‐ toral politics" (p. 188). In Weaver's view, "neoliber‐ portunistic policies, then, were economically con‐ al reforms have been essentially negative, elimi‐ sonant with new patterns that changed the con‐ nating public policies that restricted the wealthy texts of actions so markedly that entirely new or protect the poor. Free markets mean freedom courses were forged throughout the world" (p. for capital, and therefore national democratic 144). (i.e., electoral) procedures prevail at the time that In a sixth chapter, Weaver focusses on more political channels are closed as a means for citi‐ recent times and international competition and zens to affect the material welfare, which is dele‐ the dissolution of the "Modern Times," as he la‐ gated to undemocratic decisions by private capi‐ bels the relationship that had emerged following tal, foreign and domestic" (p. 189). Weaver warns World War II. This chapter deals almost exclusive‐ of the danger of a "tightly knit global elite" (p.205) ly with United States economic development as he with its "increasing concentration of income and lays the foundation for a fnal chapter, in which private power throughout the world," as he con‐ he describes Latin America in terms of its "debt, cludes with a condemnation of neoliberal policies. democracy, and uncertain transformations" (p. Closing on an optimistic note, however, he assures 169). Acknowledging that capitalism has changed us that "This era, like all prior eras, is a time of in significant ways over the last two hundred transition, and the outcomes of the process will be years, he insists that there are two fundamental determined primarily by humans' political efforts characteristics that are still "integral to its very and choices and not by Technology, History, The definition as a mode of production: the frst is the Market, or any other mystical influence" (p. 206). wage labor system, with the resulting conflict be‐ Weaver is thus highly effective at synthesiz‐ tween propertyless workers, who have only their ing Latin America's economic development within labor services to sell, and the propertied classes the context of world economic history.
Recommended publications
  • Challenging Mercantilism: the Impact of David Hume on the Evolution of Monetary Thought
    Student Economic Review, Vol. 22, 2008 CHALLENGING MERCANTILISM: THE IMPACT OF DAVID HUME ON THE EVOLUTION OF MONETARY THOUGHT ALEXANDER TOFT Senior Sophister Despite its somewhat irrational and outdated nature, mercantilist sentiment is very much alive today. In times of economic slowdown, it often bubbles to the surface of popular economic discourse, threatening to make an unwelcome return to politics and policy. The spirits of mercantilism and protectionism have always gone very much hand in hand. In this paper, Alexander Toft provides an excellent appraisal of David Hume’s monetary thought, in particular examining his attack on the 17th century mercantilist monopoly over economic discourse. Introduction The history of economic thought can be viewed as a series of ideological battles, and key amongst them must rank the debate surrounding the notion that the government has a role to play in ensuring a more favorable balance of trade – what is commonly called mercantilism. Adam Smith is often credited with initiating this debate when he attacked the concept in The Wealth of Nations (Smith, 1776). However, this paper will examine the work of another original detractor from mercantilist thinking, David Hume. A philosopher and historian first and foremost, Hume was also an eminent economist. This paper will argue that through his analysis of the influence of money on inflation and the balance of payments, Hume played a pioneering role in challenging the mercantilist monopoly on economic thought. He contributed towards the development of an alternative theory which centered on free trade, as opposed to a ‘fear of goods’ and ‘love of money’.
    [Show full text]
  • Schools of Economic Thought (Pdf)
    SCHOOLS OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT A BRIEF HISTORY OF ECONOMICS This isn't really essential to know, but may satisfy the curiosity of many. Mercantilism Economics is said to begin with Adam Smith in 1776. Prior to that, nobody thought of economics, or markets, as an object of study. It is not that they didn't pay attention to economic matters, it is simply that they didn't think of it in any systematic or coherent manner. It was all just off-the-cuff intuition and policy proposals by a myriad of merchants, government officials & journalists, principally in Britain. It is common to denote the period before 1776 as "Mercantilism". It wasn't a coherent school of thought, but a hodge-podge of varying ideas about improving tax revenues, the value & movements of gold and how nations competed for international commerce & colonies. Mostly protectionist, 'war-minded', and all haphazardly argued. (the principal features of the Mercantilist school are discussed in our "Gains from Trade" handout). There was some opposition to Mercantilist doctrines, notably among French and Scottish thinkers (e.g. Pierre de Boisguilbert, Francois Quesnay, Jacques Turgot and David Hume) Classical School The Enlightenment era (mid-1700s) in Europe brought a new spirit of scientific inquiry. Thinkers began looking to apply scientific principles not only to the physical world, but also to human society. In the same spirit that Sir Isaac Newton 'discovered' the "law of gravity" to explain the interaction of natural forces and decipher how the physical world operates, Enlightenment thinkers began trying to discover the "laws" of human interaction, to explain how human society operates.
    [Show full text]
  • Embedded Mercantilism and Open Regionalism: the Crisis of a Regional Political Project
    Third World Quarterly, Vol 24, No 2, pp 339–355, 2003 Embedded mercantilism and open regionalism: the crisis of a regional political project KANISHKA JAYASURIYA ABSTRACT This paper advances the argument that moves towards regional integration need to be understood as ‘regional governance projects’ undertaken by domestic actors and coalitions. Regional political projects—such as open regionalism—have roots in domestic structures, and it is this which defines the broad configuration of the regional political economy. On the basis of this frame- work the paper suggests, first, that the strategy of open regionalism was con- tingent on a particular configuration of power and interests in the domestic and external economy (embedded mercantilism). Second, this system of embedded mercantilism depended on a set of domestic coalitions between tradeable and non-tradeable sectors of the economy. The non-tradeable sector in Southeast Asia was entrenched within a particular system of political patronage. Third, the Asian crisis and other structural changes in the international economy have made these domestic coalitions less sustainable, thereby creating opportunities for new forms of regional governance projects. Strategies of regional integration as political projects Open regionalism, in terms of the conceptual framework advanced in this paper, is not so much a strategy of economic liberalisation as a regional regime of political economy that encompasses a set of institutions, domestic coalitional structures and international strategies. The nature of regional integration in East Asia, it will be argued, needs to be understood in the context of the manner in which domestic structures have underpinned a particular project of regional integration that goes under the rubric of open regionalism.
    [Show full text]
  • Finance and Class in the Marginalist Revolution Yair Kaldor*
    Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ser/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/soceco/mwy043/5238113 by Ben Gurion University of the Negev-Medical Library user on 28 July 2019 Socio-Economic Review, 2018, Vol. 0, No. 0, 1–19 doi: 10.1093/soceco/mwy043 Article Article The cultural foundations of economic categories: finance and class in the marginalist revolution Yair Kaldor* Department of Sociology, University of Wisconsin-Madison, Madison, WI, USA *Correspondence: [email protected] Abstract Economic categories are part of the everyday concepts people use to apprehend social reality. While scholars recognize their importance for social and economic processes, it is not clear how these categories develop when reality itself changes. I address this issue with a framework that incorporates a cultural emphasis on meaning-making with a macro-structural analysis of the conditions in which they take place. I apply this framework to the marginalist revolution of the late 19th century, which marks the birth of neoclassical economics and focus on the new understanding of ‘value’ that emerged during this period. I trace it to the rise of finance and the problem of price fluctuations, and show how its class standpoint helps explain the different outcomes of the marginalist revolution in England, Austria and France. The analysis provides insights into the power of economic ideas and the cultural dimension of structural changes. Key words: economic categories, culture, finance, value, neoclassical economics, economic sociology JEL classification: B History of Economic Thought, N2 History of Financial Markets and Institutions, N1 Macroeconomic and Monetary History 1. Introduction The basic categories of economics appear as self-evident and are hardly in need of explana- tion.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 4: British Mercantilism and the Cost of Empire
    Page 14 Chapter 4 British Mercantilism and the Cost of Empire hree hundred years ago, nations wanted colonies in order to increase their power. According to the economic thinkers of those days, colonies would help the mother country become self-sufficient Tand wealthy. No great nation could exist without colonies. This was the idea behind mercantilism, a forerunner of the present day idea of imperialism. England, Spain, France, and other nations competed with each other to own colonies in North America, South America, Asia, and Africa. Their competition often led to wars. The mercantilists reasoned that even wars were worth the price, because each colony would be a help to its conqueror. England needed raw materials that her colonies could supply. Lumber, wool, iron, cotton, tobacco, rice, and indigo were among the products needed in England. British manufacturers in the meantime needed markets for the goods they produced. The American colonies bought their cloth, furniture, knives, guns, and kitchen utensils from England. In addition, England’s survival as a nation depended on her navy, and the colonies were a constant source of both the timber for her ships and the men who could sail them. Since each nation's wealth in those days was measured in the amounts of gold and silver it possessed, England had yet a another reason for establishing and ruling a vast colonial empire: the colonists would supply their British masters with gold and silver simply by selling their raw materials and buying England’s manufactured products. The difference between what the colonists could pay through their sales of raw materials, and what they owed because of the purchase of manufactured goods, is called the balance of trade.
    [Show full text]
  • Evaluation of the Chinese State Capitalist Model in Light of Financial Institutions’ Oil Related Investments Overseas
    Henrik Bergsager Evaluation of the Chinese State Capitalist Model in Light of Financial Institutions’ Oil Related Investments Overseas Paper Prepared for International Culture Conference 15.09-18.09 Henrik Bergsager Draft Draft Draft 1 Henrik Bergsager Abstract In this article prepared for the International Culture Conference, I provide a short introduction to the framework of state capitalism, and discuss Chinese national oil policy in light of the principles based on this framework. To best illustrate this overarching strategy, this paper presents one of the institutions involved in shaping China’s overseas oil acquisitions, namely the Chinese policy banks and their requirements when issuing Energy Based Loans (EBLs) to overseas trade partners. The purpose of this paper is to illustrate how state capitalism plays a pivotal role throughout the Chinese oil investments, whether being commercially or politically initiated investments. This underscores the originality of my research vis-à-vis previous attempts to evaluate the Chinese decision-making process within the oil sector. Based on the institutional framework represented through China’s version of state capitalism, this paper presents an introduction to this research by presenting the principles that are relevant when the financial institutions proceed with Energy Based Loan agreements. Introduction As any person who has studied economic development theory should know, the possibility of determining a country’s economic policy strategy within the framework of a single economic theory is close to impossible. The reason for this is not that there are no applicable choices, but that states tend to implement various theoretical tools from different frameworks suited to their stage of development.1 As underscored by Max Weber: most theoretical frameworks for economic development do not exist in their “pure” form, but instead are coordinated with others to provide the best possible result.
    [Show full text]
  • (The Neo-Capitalist Assault) — Neoliberalism And
    The Jus Semper Global Alliance Living Wages North and South The Neo-Capitalist Assault Essay One of Part III (The Neo-Capitalist Assault) August 2001 GLOBAL ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT – A TLWNSI ISSUE ESSAY SERIES Neoliberalism and Its Summary Dogma: The Implications of Towards a New Global Economic its Philosophical Postulates Architecture A New Global Business Strategy for By Alvaro J. de Regil a Maximum Profits Towards an Economic Dogma for the Wealth From time to time TJSGA will issue essays on topics relevant to The Living Wages North and Neoliberal Mercantilism: “liberalize to South Initiative (TLWNSI). This paper is the eight globalize” in the series “The Neo-Capitalist Assault” –a collection in development about Neoliberalism. Neoliberalism and its Dogmatic Postulates - The Theoretical This first essay of Part III is also the first to formally Framework analyze The Neo-Capitalist Assault in theory and practice and its consequences. The author The fallacies of Friedman’s eulogy: describes the new business mentality that is based “Free to Choose” on maximum profitability and deprived of any social responsibility and discusses the theoretical The Wolf in Sheep’s Clothing framework. The author opens by discussing the exhaustion of the Fordist Method and the move to the new flexible production ethos with management concepts such as just-in-time- inventory, total quality, zero defects, global tive cost could be achieved. Providing a greater sourcing and global access to labour markets, all variety of products to regional markets, instead of critical elements for achieving maximum specific country markets, entailed the opening of profitability. national economies to give access to the products sourced from different manufacturing centres.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Economics 446-01 History of Economic Thought Spring 2019
    Economics 446-01 History of Economic Thought Spring 2019, Tuesday and Thursday 12:30-1:50PM, Blow 333 Professor Clyde Haulman Office: Tyler 430 Tele: 1-2365 email: [email protected] Office Hours: TTh 11:00-12:20 and by appointment COURSE OBJECTIVES “...the ideas of economists and political philosophers, both when they are right and when they are wrong, are more powerful than is commonly understood.” In reality, even practical people “... are usually the slaves of some defunct economists.” With these words, John Maynard Keynes provides a rational for this course. Economic ideas have indeed played a critical role in shaping the world we know and they have day to day impacts on the lives of people everywhere. Understanding the origins of these ideas and how they have developed and transformed into the foundations of the current state of economic analysis is the purpose of this course. Studying the primary works of the some of the ‘giants’ of economics (as well as the works of some lesser giants), we will consider how economic ideas, analysis, and method have both changed and remained the same over time. We will focus on four major ‘schools’ of economic thought -- Classical, Marxian, Neo-Classical, and Keynesian. Classical political economy emerged in the late eighteenth century as an important component of Enlightenment thinking. In part, it developed in response to government intervention in the economy, and its proponents provided theories and policies for the emerging market revolution. The Classical school is represented by the work of Adam Smith, Thomas Malthus, David Ricardo and John Stuart Mill.
    [Show full text]
  • The 2019 Global Mercantilist Index: Ranking Nations’ Distortive Trade Policies
    The 2019 Global Mercantilist Index: Ranking Nations’ Distortive Trade Policies CALEB FOOTE AND STEPHEN EZELL | NOVEMBER 2019 The Global Mercantilist Index, ranking 60 nations on 18 variables ranging from market access and forced localization to currency manipulation and intellectual property protections, finds that China is the world’s most innovation-mercantilist nation. KEY TAKEAWAYS ▪ In the global race for leadership in the most advanced technology industries, many countries are resorting to “innovation mercantilism” to create unfair advantages for own industries at the expense of foreign competitors and global innovation progress. ▪ Ranking 60 nations on 18 variables such as market access, forced localization, currency manipulation and intellectual property protections, the 2019 Global Mercantilist Index finds that China is the world’s most innovation-mercantilist nation. ▪ While China ranks as the most mercantilist nation, others such as India, Indonesia, and Russia have also engaged in innovation mercantilist practices, placing them in the report’s “moderate-high” category. ▪ To counter global mercantilist policies, the U.S. government should pursue three types of reforms: government restructuring, diplomatic pressure, and systemic funding. ▪ The U.S. Trade Representative should also construct its own biennial index to better understand other nations’ mercantilist practices and identify which are the worst offenders. INFORMATION TECHNOLOGY & INNOVATION FOUNDATION | NOVEMBER 2019 INTRODUCTION As countries increasingly vie to both
    [Show full text]
  • Why Did Economic Systems Begin to Shift During the Industrial Revolution?
    Why did economic systems begin to shift during the Industrial Revolution? Objectives: Describe what an economic system is and why economic systems begin to shift during the Industrial Revolution. Directions: Read the chart below. Respond to the questions. ​ What is economics? Every society has access to resources, however, these resources are limited. There is a limited amount of water. There is a limited amount of fertile land. There is a limited amount of human labor. Economics is the the study of how people make choices about how they use their limited resources to meet their wants and ​ ​ needs. Essentially, all nations must answer the question of scarcity of resources. What is an economic system? An economic system is the method used by a society to produce and distribute good and services. Through an economic system, each society answers three important questions: What to produce? How to produce? For whom to produce? Why do economic systems change over time? Until the modern age, people focused largely on land and agriculture. However, as nations began to trade and industrialize, new economic systems were needed to make sense of how they should make choices about how they use their limited resources to meet their wants and needs. The economic system that was most widely supported from the 1500s and until the 1700s was mercantilism. Mercantilism was a system of wealth accumulation and trade for profit. Mercantilists ​ believed that there was a fixed amount of wealth and the job of a nation was to accumulate and extract as much wealth as possible. This system emerged around the the period of the Age of Exploration when new colonies were being established and many European nations believed that through trade, the accumulations of gold and the control of colonies would bring the most wealth.
    [Show full text]
  • Nine Rules of Mercantilism (For the Mother Country) 1
    Nine Rules of Mercantilism (for the mother country) 1. Inspect the earth/land carefully and use every material possible. 2. Manufacture raw materials in mother country and sell for high prices 3. Create a well-rounded, qualified, & productive workforce 4. Keep gold and silver in circulation within the mother country to avoid poverty 5. Limit trade with foreign countries & buy mostly from the mother country 6. If you must trade with foreign countries, don’t trade with gold or silver 7. Buy raw materials from foreign countries to manufacture within the mother country. Sell the manufactured goods for a high price 8. Sell manufactured goods for gold and silver 9. Buy domestic even if it’s more expensive than foreign goods. How does this relate to the key concepts? The mother countries controlled the colonial economies by regulating trade, in order to gain wealth which gave them power. Pros and Cons of Mercantilism Good for the mother country (MC)- The MC gets rich and has a great source of raw materials that they can buy for cheap. Also, the colonies provide them with a new market for them to sell their manufactured goods. It’s a win-win situation for the MC. Bad for the mother country (MC) - makes the colonies resent the mother country because they control the economy completely and get rich while the colonies do not. Eventually the colonists may get so angry that they may rebel. Good for the colonies-The colonies have a guaranteed market for their raw materials. This means that they can always sell to the mother country so they will always have someone with whom to trade.
    [Show full text]
  • Centuries That Could Be Described As 'Mercantilist'
    Owen Southam Outline, including examples as appropriate, the main commercial policies adopted in the 17 th and 18 th centuries that could be described as ‘mercantilist’ Mercantilist policy dominated economic thought in Europe throughout the 17 th to 18 th century; this essay shall focus on mercantilist commercial policy including examples from the English Empire followed by the British Empire, France and the Dutch Republic. The first section will introduce the core ideas behind mercantilism and its policies; the second section will examine the commercial policies adopted by mercantilist policy makers; finally, the third will examine if mercantilism was an important factor in the development of these countries, concluding that despite the mixed results of commercial policy, mercantilism was a crucial element in the development of these nations. Section 1 Mercantilist principles This section will illustrate the main mercantilist objectives to introduce how commercial policy was used to achieve these objectives. These ideas will also be examined to see how they are viewed by different schools of thought as this gives us an insight to why the mercantilist legacy is interpreted as it is: as a doctrine that damaged economic prosperity. 1 The Nation's prosperity Mercantilist principles to some extent within these countries during the 17 th to 18 th centuries. However mercantilism was driven mainly by pragmatic forces rather than being a unified system of economic thought. These forces are the result of the mercantilist’s main objective of protecting and advancing their nation, so they were willing to contradict principles if it was for the national interest.
    [Show full text]