How to Change a Group's Collective Decision?

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

How to Change a Group's Collective Decision? Proceedings of the Twenty-Third International Joint Conference on Artificial Intelligence How to Change a Group’s Collective Decision? Noam Hazon Raz Lin Sarit Kraus Department of Computer Science Bar-Ilan University Ramat Gan Israel 52900 fhazonn,linraz,[email protected] Abstract the members of the group have a specific (and restricted) type of preferences, and tends to avoid computational aspects. Persuasion is a common social and economic ac- The work in social choice literature studies manipulation and tivity. It usually arises when conflicting interests bribery and considers richer (and more complex) preference among agents exist, and one of the agents wishes models, but an explicit model of persuasion has not been con- to sway the opinions of others. This paper consid- sidered in this context (we discuss the connection to manipu- ers the problem of an automated agent that needs to lation and bribery in Section 3). influence the decision of a group of self-interested In this paper we model persuasion in the context of social agents that must reach an agreement on a joint ac- choice. Specifically, we assume that there is one agent, the tion. For example, consider an automated agent sender thereafter, that needs to influence the decision of a that aims to reduce the energy consumption of a group of self-interested agents. The group members reach an nonresidential building, by convincing a group of agreement through a voting procedure, which is a common people who share an office to agree on an economy mechanism by which a collective decision is made. In a vot- mode of the air-conditioning and low light inten- ing procedure, participants (voters) express their preferences sity. In this paper we present four problems that via votes, and a voting rule then defines the social outcome address issues of minimality and safety of the per- chosen as a function of the votes cast. suasion process. We discuss the relationships to In every election, there is a need for a reliable entity, similar problems from social choice, and show that responsible for handling the elections; we assume that the if the agents are using Plurality or Veto as their sender is that entity. During the election, each voter submits voting rule all of our problems are in P. We also her vote to the sender, that determines the winner. Thus, the show that with K-Approval, Bucklin and Borda vot- sender will have complete information on the voters’ pref- ing rules some problems become intractable. We erences. Since the voters will agree to use only a reliable thus present heuristics for efficient persuasion with entity as the election organizer, we assume that the sender is Borda, and evaluate them through simulations. compelled (say, by law) to report the true winner of the elec- tion, according to the pre-specified voting rule. However, the 1 Introduction sender may still affect the elections in the following way. Af- ter all the voters submit their votes, the sender may suggest Persuasion is a tool that enables social influence in many cru- that some of them change their minds and commit to different cial areas of human interaction in both personal and business votes. These voters are not allowed to vote again or change relationships. Persuasion is a key component that shapes mar- their votes arbitrarily. Instead, they are given the opportunity keting campaigns [Tybout, 1978], litigation [Bell and Loftus, to approve or disapprove the vote suggested to them by the 1985], and domestic and international political policy [Cobb sender. The voters are not compelled to accept the sender’s and Kuklinski, 1997]. As computers make decisions with suggestion, and they may want to retain their current vote. people in increasingly complex settings, a need has arisen for However, as a reliable entity, the sender sends a suggestion the ability of computers to influence people to adopt strate- only to voters who benefit from her suggestions. gies that will benefit themselves and the group. Consider the example of the agent that tries to reduce the This paper considers an automated agent that needs to in- energy consumption of a nonresidential building where hu- fluence the decision of a group of self-interested agents that man occupants do not have direct financial incentive to save must reach an agreement on a joint action. Traditionally, energy. If the agent is able to convince some of the oc- most of the work on group persuasion appears in economic cupants to agree to her suggestion, then the overall energy and political science literature (see [Lupia, 1992] for a brief consumption of the building will be reduced. Suppose that survey)1. Previous work in these areas usually assumes that the listener. We follow the works in economic which use this term in 1We note that “persuasion” is also a common term in the field any situation where an agent with some preferences tries to influence of argumentation, where there is a dialog between the persuader and the decision of other agents. 198 there are 4 options, and 9 people, with the following prefer- the election organizer, this assumption is well-justified (see ences. Two people prefer 3 4 1 2, two people prefer also [Xia, 2012] which renders this distinction). 4 2 1 3, two people prefer 2 3 1 4 and three In this paper, we investigate the algorithmic aspects of the people prefer 1 2 3 4. Suppose also that 1 is the four persuasion problems. We show that all problems are easy option with the lowest energy consumption and 2 is the most when using Plurality or Veto voting rules. Although PERSUA- wasteful option. Using the Borda rule, which will be defined SION is easy for K-Approval and Bucklin, we show that k- later, the chosen alternative is 2. However, if the agent per- PERSUASION and k-SAFE-PERSUASION are hard (in terms of suades the first two people to approve the vote 3 1 4 2 computational complexity) with these rules. With Borda, all instead of their original vote, option 1 will be selected, which of our problems are hard. We thus propose heuristics for k- is more energy efficient and is also preferred over option 2 PERSUASION and k-SAFE-PERSUASION with Borda, and evalu- by the people that were convinced. We note that since the ate their performance through simulations. Our heuristics are people do not know the preferences of the others, they will not complete, but they are proven correct, e.g., if the heuristic not have an incentive to submit a non-truthful vote in order for SAFE-PERSUASION finds a set of suggestions, it is guar- to manipulate the system. In addition, as a reliable entity, anteed to be safe and benefit the sender and the voters. the agent’s decision making should be operated with trans- parency, so she cannot decide on an alternative by her own, 2 Preliminaries and Definitions ignoring the preferences of the people, and she cannot change their votes without their approval. We have a set of actions (also referred to as alternatives) We propose four variants of the group persuasion problem. A = fa1; : : : ; amg and a set of voters V = f1; : : : ; ng. Each The basic problem is PERSUASION, where we ask the sender voter i is represented by her preference Ri, which is a to- to find a set of voters together with suggestions that will ben- tal order over A; we will also refer to total orders over A as efit her and these voters. Since sending messages to many votes. For readability, we will sometimes denote the order Ri voters may be costly (in terms of time or money), we are by i (and thus a 6i a). Given a preference Ri, we will de- also interested in an optimization version, where the sender is note the alternative that is ranked in the j-th position in Ri as interested in influencing the election while sending the least Ri(j), and by rank(a; Ri) the position of alternative a in Ri. number of messages. The corresponding decision problem is The vector R = (R1;:::;Rn) is called a preference profile. k-PERSUASION. Since the voters are not compelled to accept We have one sender, s, which also has preferences over the the sender’s suggestions (even though they are guaranteed a available actions, denoted Rs. more favorable alternative should they all accept the sugges- We will use voting rules to determine which action will tions), the sender or the voters may attain an even worse out- be selected. A voting rule F is a mapping from the set of come if not all the voters accept the senders suggestions. The all preference profiles to the set of actions. The voting rules set of suggestions that can never lead to a worse outcome is that we consider assign scores to all alternatives; one winner called safe, and we introduce the safe variants of the PERSUA- is then selected among the alternatives with the highest score SION and k-PERSUASION problems, SAFE-PERSUASION and k- using a tie-breaking rule. To simplify the analysis, we assume SAFE-PERSUASION, respectively. Our suggested problems are that the tie-breaking rule is lexicographic, i.e., given a set of very similar to other problems in social choice. Specifically, tied alternatives, it selects one that is maximal with respect to PERSUASION is very similar to the unweighted coalition ma- a fixed ordering . nipulation problem (UCM) [Conitzer and Sandholm, 2002; We will now define the voting rules considered in this pa- Conitzer et al., 2007] and k-PERSUASION is very similar to per.
Recommended publications
  • Individual and Collective Information Acquisition: an Experimental Study
    Individual and Collective Information Acquisition: An Experimental Study∗ P¨ellumb Reshidi† Alessandro Lizzeri‡ Leeat Yariv§ Jimmy Chan¶ Wing Suen‖ September 2020 Abstract Many committees|juries, political task forces, etc.|spend time gathering costly information before reaching a decision. We report results from lab experiments focused on such information- collection processes. We consider decisions governed by individuals and groups and compare how voting rules affect outcomes. We also contrast static information collection, as in classical hypothesis testing, with dynamic collection, as in sequential hypothesis testing. Generally, out- comes approximate the theoretical benchmark and sequential information collection is welfare enhancing relative to static collection. Nonetheless, several important departures emerge. Static information collection is excessive, and sequential information collection is non-stationary, pro- ducing declining decision accuracies over time. Furthermore, groups using majority rule yield especially hasty and inaccurate decisions. ∗We thank Roland Benabou, Stephen Morris, Salvo Nunnari, and Wolfgang Pesendorfer for very helpful discussions and feedback. We gratefully acknowledge the support of NSF grants SES-1629613 and SES-1949381. †Department of Economics, Princeton University [email protected] ‡Department of Economics, Princeton University [email protected] §Department of Economics, Princeton University [email protected] ¶Department of Economics, The Chinese University of Hong Kong [email protected] ‖Faculty of Business and Economics, University of Hong Kong [email protected] 1 1 Introduction 1.1 Overview Juries, boards of directors, congressional and university committees, government agencies such as the FDA or the EPA, and many other committees spend time deliberating issues before reaching a decision or issuing a recommendation. An important component of such collective decisions is the acquisition of information.
    [Show full text]
  • Some Worries About the Coherence of Left-Libertarianism Mathias Risse
    John F. Kennedy School of Government Harvard University Faculty Research Working Papers Series Can There be “Libertarianism without Inequality”? Some Worries About the Coherence of Left-Libertarianism Mathias Risse Nov 2003 RWP03-044 The views expressed in the KSG Faculty Research Working Paper Series are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect those of the John F. Kennedy School of Government or Harvard University. All works posted here are owned and copyrighted by the author(s). Papers may be downloaded for personal use only. Can There be “Libertarianism without Inequality”? Some Worries About the Coherence of Left-Libertarianism1 Mathias Risse John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University October 25, 2003 1. Left-libertarianism is not a new star on the sky of political philosophy, but it was through the recent publication of Peter Vallentyne and Hillel Steiner’s anthologies that it became clearly visible as a contemporary movement with distinct historical roots. “Left- libertarian theories of justice,” says Vallentyne, “hold that agents are full self-owners and that natural resources are owned in some egalitarian manner. Unlike most versions of egalitarianism, left-libertarianism endorses full self-ownership, and thus places specific limits on what others may do to one’s person without one’s permission. Unlike right- libertarianism, it holds that natural resources may be privately appropriated only with the permission of, or with a significant payment to, the members of society. Like right- libertarianism, left-libertarianism holds that the basic rights of individuals are ownership rights. Left-libertarianism is promising because it coherently underwrites both some demands of material equality and some limits on the permissible means of promoting this equality” (Vallentyne and Steiner (2000a), p 1; emphasis added).
    [Show full text]
  • Conventional Wisdom – Benefits and Consequences of Annealing Understanding of Engineering Principles
    EE 508 Lecture 40 Conventional Wisdom – Benefits and Consequences of Annealing Understanding of Engineering Principles by Randy Geiger Iowa State University Conventional Wisdom: Conventional wisdom is the collective understanding of fundamental engineering concepts and principles that evolves over time through interactions of practicing engineers around the world Conventional Wisdom: • Guides engineers in daily practice of the Profession • Widely use to enhance productivity • Heavily emphasized in universities around the world when educating next-generation engineers • Often viewed as a fundamental concept or principle • Validity of conventional wisdom seldom questioned Are Conventional Wisdom and Fundamental Concepts and Principles Always Aligned? Much of Society till Pythagoras 520BC 1200AD to 1600AD and later Aristotle 300BC http://greenfunkdan.blogspot.com/2008/11/csiro-warns-of-climate-change-doomsday.html http://www.christiananswers.net/q-aig/aig-c034.html Sometimes the differences can be rather significant ! Conventional wisdom, when not correctly representing fundamental principles, can provide conflicting perceptions or irresolvable paradoxes Are Conventional Wisdom and Fundamental Concepts always aligned in the Microelectronics Field ? Are Conventional Wisdom and Fundamental Concepts always aligned in the Microelectronics Field ? Records of • Conventional Wisdom • Fundamental Concepts Conventional Wisdom • Occasional Oversight of Error • Key information embedded in 13 tremendous volume of materials (noise) Do Conventional Wisdom
    [Show full text]
  • Society Persuasion In
    PERSUASION IN SOCIETY HERBERT W. SIMONS with JOANNE MORREALE and BRUCE GRONBECK Table of Contents List of Artwork in Persuasion in Society xiv About the Author xvii Acknowledgments xix Preface xx Part 1: Understanding Persuasion 1. The Study of Persuasion 3 Defining Persuasion 5 Why Is Persuasion Important? 10 Studying Persuasion 14 The Behavioral Approach: Social-Scientific Research on the Communication-Persuasion Matrix 15 The Critical Studies Approach: Case Studies and “Genre-alizations” 17 Summary 20 Questions and Projects for Further Study 21 2. The Psychology of Persuasion: Basic Principles 25 Beliefs and Values as Building Blocks of Attitudes 27 Persuasion by Degrees: Adapting to Different Audiences 29 Schemas: Attitudes as Knowledge Structures 32 From Attitudes to Actions: The Role of Subjective Norms 34 Elaboration Likelihood Model: Two Routes to Persuasion 34 Persuasion as a Learning Process 36 Persuasion as Information Processing 37 Persuasion and Incentives 38 Persuasion by Association 39 Persuasion as Psychological Unbalancing and Rebalancing 40 Summary 41 Questions and Projects for Further Study 42 3. Persuasion Broadly Considered 47 Two Levels of Communication: Content and Relational 49 Impression Management 51 Deception About Persuasive Intent 51 Deceptive Deception 52 Expression Games 54 Persuasion in the Guise of Objectivity 55 Accounting Statements and Cost-Benefit Analyses 55 News Reporting 56 Scientific Reporting 57 History Textbooks 58 Reported Discoveries of Social Problems 59 How Multiple Messages Shape Ideologies 59 The Making of McWorld 63 Summary 66 Questions and Projects for Further Study 68 Part 2: The Coactive Approach 4. Coactive Persuasion 73 Using Receiver-Oriented Approaches 74 Being Situation Sensitive 76 Combining Similarity and Credibility 79 Building on Acceptable Premises 82 Appearing Reasonable and Providing Psychological Income 85 Using Communication Resources 86 Summary 88 Questions and Projects for Further Study 89 5.
    [Show full text]
  • COLLECTIVE ACTION FEDERALISM: a GENERAL THEORY of ARTICLE I, SECTION 8 Robert D
    COLLECTIVE ACTION FEDERALISM: A GENERAL THEORY OF ARTICLE I, SECTION 8 Robert D. Cooter* & Neil S. Siegel** The Framers of the United States Constitution wrote Article I, Section 8 in order to address some daunting collective action problemsfacing the young na- tion. They especially wanted to protect the states from military warfare by fo- reigners andfrom commercial warfare against one another. The states acted in- dividually when they needed to act collectively, and Congress lacked power under the Articles of Confederation to address these problems. Section 8 thus au- thorized Congress to promote the "general Welfare" of the United States by tack- ling many collective actionproblems that the states could not solve on their own. Subsequent interpretationsof Section 8, both outside and inside the courts, often have focused on the presence or absence of collective action problems in- volving multiple states-but not always. For example, the Supreme Court of the United States, in trying to distinguish the "truly national" from the "truly local" in the context of the Commerce Clause, United States v. Morrison, 529 U.S. 598, * Herman Selvin Professor of Law, University of California at Berkeley. ** Professor of Law and Political Science, Duke University School of Law. I dedicate this Article to the loving memory of my mother, Sharon Ruth Siegel, for giving me life-and a whole lot more. For illuminating comments, we thank Jack Balkin, Sara Beale, Stuart Benjamin, Joseph Blocher, Curtis Bradley, Geoffrey Brennan, Samuel Buell, Erwin Chemerinsky, Jesse Cho- per, Eric Freedman, Philip Frickey, Barry Friedman, Jamal Greene, Daniel Greenwood, Grant Hayden, Laurence Helfer, Don Herzog, Roderick Hills, Donald Horowitz, John Inazu, Margaret Lemos, Anne Joseph O'Connell, Sanford Kadish, Richard Lazarus, Margaret Le- mos, Paul Mishkin, Julian Mortenson, Michael Munger, Richard Pildes, Eric Posner, Robert Post, H.
    [Show full text]
  • Memetic Media and Collective Identity Through Streamer Performance on Twitch
    Selected Papers of #AoIR2020: The 21st Annual Conference of the Association of Internet Researchers Virtual Event / 27-31 October 2020 “I’VE GOTTA DO IT FOR THE BIT”: MEMETIC MEDIA AND COLLECTIVE IDENTITY THROUGH STREAMER PERFORMANCE ON TWITCH Nathan J Jackson School of the Arts and Media, UNSW Sydney Videogame livestreamers on the platform Twitch present a carefully curated version of themselves negotiated in part via interactions with their viewers. This persona is encoded not just through their live performance, but also through other platform features including streamer-specific emoticons (emotes) and audio-visual overlays triggered by stream events such as donations and subscriptions (alerts). From these customisable features emerges a complicated feedback loop between the streamer and non-streamer participants that ultimately results in a set of collective values performed and refined by both parties over time. In this paper I interrogate how the incorporation of Internet memes into streaming personas creates accessible avenues for communication with and between members of this collective that contribute significantly to this value system. Memes operate based on a core duality between commitment to a fixed set of properties and creative variation – this duality has been referred to using several different terminologies (see Wiggins & Bowers, 2015; Milner, 2016; Phillips & Milner, 2018). As such, there is a necessary plurality to memes considering their diverse manifestations, as emphasised by Limor Shifman’s (2014) definition of the term. This complicates the meaning-making process of memes as they carry not just the intended value of each manifestation’s creator, but also the latent values of the meme template and the referent texts.
    [Show full text]
  • The Cognitive Mechanisms Underlying Information Cascades
    1 Wise or mad crowds? The cognitive mechanisms underlying 2 information cascades 1 1;2 3 Alan N. Tump ([email protected]), Tim Pleskac , Ralf H. J. M. Kurvers1 1Max Planck Institute for Human Development, Center for Adaptive Rationality, Lentzeallee 94, 14195 Berlin, Germany 2University of Kansas, Department of Psychology, Jayhawk Blvd, Lawrence, KS 66045, USA 4 November 26, 2019 5 Abstract 6 Whether getting vaccinated, buying stocks, or crossing streets, people rarely 7 make decisions alone. Rather, multiple people decide sequentially, setting the stage 8 for information cascades whereby early-deciding individuals can influence others' 9 choices. To understand how information cascades through social systems, it is es- 10 sential to capture the dynamics of the decision-making process. We introduce the 11 social drift-diffusion model to capture these dynamics. We tested our model using 12 a sequential choice task. The model was able to recover the dynamics of the social 13 decision-making process, accurately capturing how individuals integrate personal 14 and social information dynamically over time and when they timed their decisions. 15 Our results show the importance of the interrelationships between accuracy, con- 16 fidence, and response time in shaping the quality of information cascades. The 17 model reveals the importance of capturing the dynamics of decision processes to 18 understand how information cascades in social systems, paving the way for appli- 19 cations in other social systems. 20 21 Keywords: collective intelligence, information cascades, sequential decision-making, social 22 information, confidence, herding, conformity, social impact, collective behaviour 23 Main 24 In many situations|be they financial investments, consumer choices, or simply crossing the street| 25 one is generally not making a decision alone.
    [Show full text]
  • Collective Bargaining Agreement Between City of Bend and the Bend Police Association 2019-2022
    COLLECTIVE BARGAINING AGREEMENT BETWEEN CITY OF BEND AND THE BEND POLICE ASSOCIATION 2019-2022 City of Bend and Bend Police Association Collective Bargaining Agreement 2019-2022 TABLE OF CONTENTS Section One. Recognition ...............................................................................................................4 Section Two. Check-Off/Payroll Deductions ................................... .............................................. 5 Section Three. Employee Rights ..................................................................................................... 5 Section Four. Management Rights ........ .......................................................................................... 6 Section Five. City Security ............................................................................................................. 6 Section Six. Association Business .................................................................................................. 6 Section Seven. Association Bargaining Team ................................................................................ 7 Section Eight. Special Conferences ................................................................................................ 7 Section Nine. Personnel Manual/Agreement .................................. ........... ................ ..................... 7 Section Ten. Bulletin Board .............................................................. .......................................... .. .. 7 Section Eleven. Outside
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 16 Information Cascades
    From the book Networks, Crowds, and Markets: Reasoning about a Highly Connected World. By David Easley and Jon Kleinberg. Cambridge University Press, 2010. Complete preprint on-line at http://www.cs.cornell.edu/home/kleinber/networks-book/ Chapter 16 Information Cascades 16.1 Following the Crowd When people are connected by a network, it becomes possible for them to influence each other’s behavior and decisions. In the next several chapters, we will explore how this ba- sic principle gives rise to a range of social processes in which networks serve to aggregate individual behavior and thus produce population-wide, collective outcomes. There is a nearly limitless set of situations in which people are influenced by others: in the opinions they hold, the products they buy, the political positions they support, the activities they pursue, the technologies they use, and many other things. What we’d like to do here is to go beyond this observation and consider some of the reasons why such influence occurs. We’ll see that there are many settings in which it may in fact be rational for an individual to imitate the choices of others even if the individual’s own information suggests an alternative choice. As a first example, suppose that you are choosing a restaurant in an unfamiliar town, and based on your own research about restaurants you intend to go to restaurant A. However, when you arrive you see that no one is eating in restaurant A while restaurant B next door is nearly full. If you believe that other diners have tastes similar to yours, and that they too have some information about where to eat, it may be rational to join the crowd at B rather than to follow your own information.
    [Show full text]
  • Coalition of Collective Investment Trusts White Paper
    Collective Investment Trusts Prepared by the Coalition of Collective Investment Trusts Table of Contents Overview ....................................................................................................................................................... 2 Collective Investment Trusts Defined ....................................................................................................... 3 Two Broad Types of Collective Trusts ....................................................................................................... 3 Investment Strategies – Short Term Investment Funds……………………………………………………………………………4 The Investment Option Selection Process .................................................................................................... 5 The Evolution of CITs ..................................................................................................................................... 6 Features of CITs ........................................................................................................................................... 10 Governing Documents ............................................................................................................................ 10 Regulatory Oversight of CITs ................................................................................................................... 11 Federal and State Banking Laws ......................................................................................................... 11 DOL .....................................................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Information Libertarianism
    Information Libertarianism Jane R. Bambauer & Derek E. Bambauer* Legal scholarship has attacked recent First Amendment jurisprudence as unprincipled: a deregulatory judicial agenda disguised as free speech protection. This scholarly trend is mistaken. Descriptively, free speech protections scrutinize only information regulation, usefully pushing government to employ more direct regulations with fewer collateral consequences. Even an expansive First Amendment is compatible with the regulatory state, rather than being inherently libertarian. Normatively, courts should be skeptical when the state tries to design socially beneficial censorship. This Article advances a structural theory that complements classic First Amendment rationales, arguing that information libertarianism has virtues that transcend political ideology. Regulating information is peculiarly difficult to do well. Cognitive biases cause regulators to systematically overstate risks of speech and to discount its benefits. Speech is strong in its capacity to change behavior, yet politically weak. It is a popular scapegoat for larger societal problems and its regulation is an attractive option for interest groups seeking an advantage. Collective action, public choice, and government entrenchment problems arise frequently. First Amendment safeguards provide a vital counterpressure. Information libertarianism encourages government to regulate conduct directly because when the state censors communication, the results are often DOI: https://dx.doi.org/10.15779/Z38Z31NN40 Copyright
    [Show full text]
  • The Path to the Next Normal
    The path to the next normal Leading with resolve through the coronavirus pandemic May 2020 Cover image: © Cultura RF/Getty Images Copyright © 2020 McKinsey & Company. All rights reserved. This publication is not intended to be used as the basis for trading in the shares of any company or for undertaking any other complex or significant financial transaction without consulting appropriate professional advisers. No part of this publication may be copied or redistributed in any form without the prior written consent of McKinsey & Company. The path to the next normal Leading with resolve through the coronavirus pandemic May 2020 Introduction On March 11, 2020, the World Health Organization formally declared COVID-19 a pandemic, underscoring the precipitous global uncertainty that had plunged lives and livelihoods into a still-unfolding crisis. Just two months later, daily reports of outbreaks—and of waxing and waning infection and mortality rates— continue to heighten anxiety, stir grief, and cast into question the contours of our collective social and economic future. Never in modern history have countries had to ask citizens around the world to stay home, curb travel, and maintain physical distance to preserve the health of families, colleagues, neighbors, and friends. And never have we seen job loss spike so fast, nor the threat of economic distress loom so large. In this unprecedented reality, we are also witnessing the beginnings of a dramatic restructuring of the social and economic order—the emergence of a new era that we view as the “next normal.” Dialogue and debate have only just begun on the shape this next normal will take.
    [Show full text]