California's Tax System

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

California's Tax System CALIFORNIA’S TAX SYSTEM LEGISLATIVE ANALYST’S OFFICE 2 INTRODUCTION California’s state and local governments rely on three main taxes. The personal income tax is the state’s main revenue source, the property tax is the major local tax, and the state and local governments both receive revenue from the sales and use tax. In addition, many smaller taxes raise revenue for state and local government operations. In 2015-16, taxes in California raised a total of $220 billion—equal to nearly 10 percent of the state economy. The chart to the right summarizes this tax system. The inner black pie chart shows that roughly two-thirds of tax revenues in California go to the state government with the other one-third collected by local governments. The middle ring shows each tax as a share of the whole system. (Note that the line from the inner black pie chart intersects with the sales and use tax segment to show the shares of sales tax revenue that go to the state and to local governments.) The outer ring breaks out each major tax by source. For example, the biggest source of personal income tax revenue is wage and salary income. In addition to taxes, the state and local governments rely on federal funds, fees, and other sources of revenue to fund government operations. This publication, however, focuses solely on taxes levied in California. LAO California’s Tax System | Overview 3 OVERVIEW OF CALIFORNIA’S TAX SYSTEM 2015-16 R Ow e s i n d e e r-Occupied n t i a l No s ie t r la R Sa e d Ow s n id a n e s e n e r-Occupiedti g al a W P ro p ert y Ta Co mmer x nal cial/In rso x e dustr Pe Ta Incom ial me ement Inco Retir L ividends, oc D t al Interest, and Ren Vehicle License Fee Other St ate s Taxe cal Bu her Lo siness Ot Income C o F rp Hotels Ot u e o il h ta d l ra e n e Ta r t a x io C St n Tax ap es s xe it s Ta a a s le s l Other Non-e R s t Ga in r e s le a e i u a S n B s Ta s e Us ol g Utilities h n xe W ri tu s c C fa o u rs r n e p a il o a G r M t D a a e i t Business s e s io R s e s o r n t s r e li r s O e d n o n t s l a e , e, t h n l h t r S n and e a a u o r O e i e e s a t l r t s Property Transfer i c e D a i t a Ot s d t a h t e l s B S n t h s a e R r a r e e E V a Payroll l e h r n r O a n c i P r l e e o t t R e o d h G s o n e d M a a r Entities n M a G n o ti c s e ru s e c t e r s i l n n o a t p o Stores i l C s S p p e u i e r p S g o A a s n r d s e e n e d v r c a Insurance Tax e a c , s G A B c d i d d n n n n a o a r a t d g s c l o n e a Tobacco Taxes i l o i h r t F e E , o t Alcoholic Beverage Tax l s a C g M n i g h n s i i d n l r i u u F B e m o H , e r u t i n r u F LAO California’s Tax System | Overview 4 CHAPTER 1 LAO California’s Tax System | Personal Income Tax (PIT) 5 PERSONAL INCOME TAX The personal income tax (PIT) is a broad-based tax that the state levies on most types of income, such as wages and capital gains. The PIT is an important revenue source for the state government, generating over two-thirds of the revenue for the General Fund— the state’s main operating account. In recent years, the PIT has generated more revenue than any other tax in California’s tax system. LAO California’s Tax System | Personal Income Tax (PIT) 6 ABOUT TWO-THIRDS OF INCOME COMES FROM WAGES AND SALARIES 2015 Capital Gains $118 Billion Pensions, Business Wages and Salaries Annuities, Income and IRA (Multiple Distributions Owners) $898 Billion $102 Billion $88 Billion Dividends, Business Interest, Income and Rent (Sole Owner) $56 Billion $53 Billion HOW DO PIT RATES WORK? Marginal and Effective Tax Rates, Single Filer, 2017 Personal income tax rates are marginal, meaning that higher income increments are taxed at higher rates. For example, a single filer with taxable income of $300,000 is taxed at 1 percent on the first $8,000 of their income, but 10.3 percent on the last $31,000 of their income. A taxpayer’s highest marginal rate is higher than their effective rate (the average rate at which their income is taxed). For example, a single filer with $100,000 in taxable income is taxed at 9.3 percent on their last dollar of income but their effective tax rate (before tax credits) is 6.7 percent. 14% Marginal Income 12 Rate Between Marginal Rate 1% $0K - $8K 10 2% $8K - $19K Effective Rate 4% $19K - $30K 8 6% $30K - $42K 8% $42K - $53K 6 9.3% $53K - $269K 4 10.3% $269K - $322K 11.3% $322K - $537K 2 12.3% $537K - $1M 13.3% $1M and Over 100,000 200,000 300,000 400,000 500,000 600,000 700,000 $800,000 LAO California’s Tax System | Personal Income Tax (PIT) 7 Step 1 Add up Income CALCULATING THE $60K in Wages $30K in Business Income PERSONAL INCOME TAX BILL $90K Adjusted Gross Income Married Couple With One Dependent Filing Jointly, 2017 Step 2 Add up Deductions Almost two-thirds of all filers take the standard deduction $8K in Mortgage Interest Do itemized $5K in Local Property Taxes deductions exceed $2K in Student Loan Interest $8,472 standard deduction? $15K Itemized Deductions Marignal Income Rate Between 1% $0-$16K Yes: take No: take 2% $16K-$39K itemized standard 4% $39K-$62K 6% $62K-$85K Step 3 Step 4 Calculate Taxable Income Apply Tax Rates in Table Above Step 5 Add up Tax Credits $90K Adjusted Gross Income First $16K Taxed at 1% = $164 $400 Child Care Tax Credit $15K Itemized Deductions Next $23K Taxed at 2% = $451 $114 X 2 Personal Exemption Credit Next $23K Taxed at 4% = $902 $353 Dependent Exemption Credit $75K Taxable Income Next $23K Taxed at 6% = $808 $981 Total Tax Credits Tax Liability Before Credits $2,325 Step 6 Calculate Tax Liability Tax Liability Before Credits $2,325 Filers Itemizing Deductions Tend to Be Higher-Income Taxpayers Minus Credits -$981 Standard Itemized Final Tax Bill = $1,344 100% 75 50 25 0-50K 50K-100K 100K-200K 200K-500K 500K-1M 1M-5M Over $5M LAO California’s Tax System | Personal Income Tax (PIT) 8 BREAKDOWN OF DEDUCTIONS In Billions, 2015 PIT deductions reduce taxpayers’ taxable incomes. In total, deductions reduced taxable income by about $200 billion in 2015. About $7 billion of the deductions shown here went unused because itemized deductions are phased out for high-income taxpayers. Standard $60.7 Deduction Mortgage $52.9 Interest Property $30.1 Taxes Charitable $30.0 Contributions Business and $20.4 Other Expenses Medical $10.6 Expenses Other $4.3 WHO USES DEDUCTIONS? Share of Deduction Value by Income Group, 2015 Standard Deduction Mortgage Interest Charitable Contributions 50% 25 r K K K K K e M v 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 5 2 $ O 5 2 1 $ $ - d $ $ $ - - n K - - - K K a 0 K K K 0 0 0 0 0 0 2 $ M 5 0 0 5 $ 1 $ 2 1 $ $ $ $ Property Taxes Medical Expenses Business and Other Expenses LAO California’s Tax System | Personal Income Tax (PIT) 9 BREAKDOWN OF CREDITS In Billions, 2015 PIT credits reduce tax liabilities dollar for dollar, resulting in a dollar-for-dollar reduction in state revenue. With the exception of the Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC), credits cannot reduce a taxpayer’s liability below zero. For this reason, the amount of credits shown in the chart is about double the amount of credits actually used by taxpayers to reduce liability. Dependent Credit $4.0 Personal Credit $2.3 Blind and Senior $0.4 Credit Enterprise Zones $0.3 EITC $0.2 Renter's Credit $0.1 Other $1.1 EITC 100 WHO USES CREDITS? Share of Credit Value by Income Group, 2015 Dependent Credit Personal Credit 50% 25 r K K K K K M e 0 0 0 0 0 1 v 2 5 0 0 0 $ o $ $ 1 2 5 - d $ $ $ - - n K - - - K K a 0 0 0 K K K 0 $ 2 0 0 0 M 5 Enterprise Zones $ 5 0 0 1 $ $ 1 2 $ $ $ 66 Blind and Senior Credit 55 LAO California’s Tax System | Personal Income Tax (PIT) 10 PIT LIABILITY CONCENTRATED AMONG TOP EARNERS Tax Statistics by Income Group, 2015 Share of Tax Returns Share of Adjusted Gross Income Share of Tax Liability $0 to $20K 27.7% 3.7% 0.1% $20K to $50K 31.0% 13.0% 2.0% $50K to $100K 21.2% 19.1% 8.6% $100K to $200K 12.9% 22.4% 18.0% $200K to $300K 3.2% 9.8% 10.7% $300K to $500K 1.7% 8.3% 10.6% $500K to $1M 0.8% 6.9% 10.3% Over $1M 0.4% 19.4% 39.6% Over Half of PIT Liability for Over $1 Million Group Paid by Filers With Adjusted Gross Income Over $5 Million 21% 10% 7% 5% 57% $1M $2M $3M $4M Over to 2M to 3M to 4M to 5M $5M LAO California’s Tax System | Personal Income Tax (PIT) 11 INCOME MAKEUP DIFFERENT FOR LOW- AND HIGH-INCOME TAXPAYERS 2015 The graphic below shows how taxpayers in different income groups derive their income.
Recommended publications
  • TTB F 5000.24Sm Excise Tax Return
    OMB No. 1513-0083 DEPARTMENT OF THE TREASURY 1. SERIAL NUMBER ALCOHOL AND TOBACCO TAX AND TRADE BUREAU (TTB) EXCISE TAX RETURN (Prepare in duplicate – See instructions below) 3. AMOUNT OF PAYMENT 2. FORM OF PAYMENT $ CHECK MONEY ORDER EFT OTHER (Specify) NOTE: PLEASE MAKE CHECKS OR MONEY ORDERS PAYABLE TO THE ALCOHOL AND TOBACCO TAX AND 4. RETURN COVERS (Check one) BEGINNING TRADE BUREAU (SHOW EMPLOYER IDENTIFICATION NUMBER ON ALL CHECKS OR MONEY ORDERS). IF PREPAYMENT PERIOD YOU SEND A CHECK, SEE PAPER CHECK CONVERSION ENDING NOTICE BELOW. 5. DATE PRODUCTS TO BE REMOVED (For Prepayment Returns Only) FOR TTB USE ONLY 6. EMPLOYER IDENTIFICATION NUMBER 7. PLANT, REGISTRY, OR PERMIT NUMBER TAX $ PENALTY 8. NAME AND ADDRESS OF TAXPAYER (Include ZIP Code) INTEREST TOTAL $ EXAMINED BY: DATE EXAMINED: CALCULATION OF TAX DUE (Before making entries on lines 18 – 21, complete Schedules A and B) PRODUCT AMOUNT OF TAX (a) (b) 9. DISTILLED SPIRITS 10. WINE 11. BEER 12. CIGARS 13. CIGARETTES 14. CIGARETTE PAPERS AND/OR CIGARETTE TUBES 15. CHEWING TOBACCO AND/OR SNUFF 16. PIPE TOBACCO AND/OR ROLL-YOUR-OWN TOBACCO 17. TOTAL TAX LIABILITY (Total of lines 9-16) $ 18. ADJUSTMENTS INCREASING AMOUNT DUE (From line 29) 19. GROSS AMOUNT DUE (Line 17 plus line 18) $ 20. ADJUSTMENTS DECREASING AMOUNT DUE (From line 34) 21. AMOUNT TO BE PAID WITH THIS RETURN (Line 19 minus line 20) $ Under penalties of perjury, I declare that I have examined this return (including any accompanying explanations, statements, schedules, and forms) and to the best of my knowledge and belief it is true, correct, and includes all transactions and tax liabilities required by law or regulations to be reported.
    [Show full text]
  • An Analysis of the Graded Property Tax Robert M
    TaxingTaxing Simply Simply District of Columbia Tax Revision Commission TaxingTaxing FairlyFairly Full Report District of Columbia Tax Revision Commission 1755 Massachusetts Avenue, NW, Suite 550 Washington, DC 20036 Tel: (202) 518-7275 Fax: (202) 466-7967 www.dctrc.org The Authors Robert M. Schwab Professor, Department of Economics University of Maryland College Park, Md. Amy Rehder Harris Graduate Assistant, Department of Economics University of Maryland College Park, Md. Authors’ Acknowledgments We thank Kim Coleman for providing us with the assessment data discussed in the section “The Incidence of a Graded Property Tax in the District of Columbia.” We also thank Joan Youngman and Rick Rybeck for their help with this project. CHAPTER G An Analysis of the Graded Property Tax Robert M. Schwab and Amy Rehder Harris Introduction In most jurisdictions, land and improvements are taxed at the same rate. The District of Columbia is no exception to this general rule. Consider two homes in the District, each valued at $100,000. Home A is a modest home on a large lot; suppose the land and structures are each worth $50,000. Home B is a more sub- stantial home on a smaller lot; in this case, suppose the land is valued at $20,000 and the improvements at $80,000. Under current District law, both homes would be taxed at a rate of 0.96 percent on the total value and thus, as Figure 1 shows, the owners of both homes would face property taxes of $960.1 But property can be taxed in many ways. Under a graded, or split-rate, tax, land is taxed more heavily than structures.
    [Show full text]
  • Download Article (PDF)
    5th International Conference on Accounting, Auditing, and Taxation (ICAAT 2016) TAX TRANSPARENCY – AN ANALYSIS OF THE LUXLEAKS FIRMS Johannes Manthey University of Würzburg, Würzburg, Germany Dirk Kiesewetter University of Würzburg, Würzburg, Germany Abstract This paper finds that the firms involved in the Luxembourg Leaks (‘LuxLeaks’) scandal are less transparent measured by the engagement in earnings management, analyst coverage, analyst accuracy, accounting standards and auditor choice. The analysis is based on the LuxLeaks sample and compared to a control group of large multinational companies. The panel dataset covers the years from 2001 to 2015 and comprises 19,109 observations. The LuxLeaks firms appear to engage in higher levels of discretionary earnings management measured by the variability of net income to cash flows from operations and the correlation between cash flows from operations and accruals. The LuxLeaks sample shows a lower analyst coverage, lower willingness to switch to IFRS and a lower Big4 auditor rate. The difference in difference design supports these findings regarding earnings management and the analyst coverage. The analysis concludes that the LuxLeaks firms are less transparent and infers a relation between corporate transparency and the engagement in tax avoidance. The paper aims to establish the relationship between tax avoidance and transparency in order to give guidance for future policy. The research highlights the complex causes and effects of tax management and supports a cost benefit analysis of future tax regulation. Keywords: Tax Avoidance, Transparency, Earnings Management JEL Classification: H20, H25, H26 1. Introduction The Luxembourg Leaks (’LuxLeaks’) scandal made public some of the tax strategies used by multinational companies.
    [Show full text]
  • Keeping the Government Whole: the Impact of a Cap-And-Dividend
    RESEARCH INSTITUTE POLITICAL ECONOMY Keeping the Government Whole: The Impact of a Cap-and-Dividend Policy for Curbing Global Warming on Government Revenue and Expenditure James K. Boyce & Matthew Riddle November 2008 Gordon Hall 418 North Pleasant Street Amherst, MA 01002 Phone: 413.545.6355 Fax: 413.577.0261 [email protected] www.peri.umass.edu WORKINGPAPER SERIES Number 188 KEEPING THE GOVERNMEGOVERNMENTNT WHOLE: The Impact of a CapCap----andandand----DividendDividend Policy for Curbing Global Warming on Government Revenue and Expenditure James K. Boyce & Matthew Riddle Political Economy Research Institute University of Massachusetts, Amherst November 2008 ABSTRACT When the United States puts a cap on carbon sure that additional revenues to government emissions as part of the effort to address the compensate adequately for the additional costs problem of global climate change, this will in- to government as a result of the carbon cap. We crease the prices of fossil fuels, significantly compare the distributional impacts of two policy impacting not only consumers but also local, alternatives: (i) setting aside a portion of the state, and federal governments. Consumers can revenue from carbon permit auctions for gov- be “made whole,” in the sense that whatever ernment, and distributing the remainder of the amount the public pays in higher fuel prices is revenue to the public in the form of tax-free recycled to the public, by means of a cap-and- dividends; or (ii) distributing all of the carbon dividend policy: individual households will come revenue to households as taxable dividends. out ahead or behind in monetary terms depend- The policy of recycling 100% of carbon revenue ing on whether they consume above-average or to the public as taxable dividends has the below-average amounts of carbon.
    [Show full text]
  • Taxation of Land and Economic Growth
    economies Article Taxation of Land and Economic Growth Shulu Che 1, Ronald Ravinesh Kumar 2 and Peter J. Stauvermann 1,* 1 Department of Global Business and Economics, Changwon National University, Changwon 51140, Korea; [email protected] 2 School of Accounting, Finance and Economics, Laucala Campus, The University of the South Pacific, Suva 40302, Fiji; [email protected] * Correspondence: [email protected]; Tel.: +82-55-213-3309 Abstract: In this paper, we theoretically analyze the effects of three types of land taxes on economic growth using an overlapping generation model in which land can be used for production or con- sumption (housing) purposes. Based on the analyses in which land is used as a factor of production, we can confirm that the taxation of land will lead to an increase in the growth rate of the economy. Particularly, we show that the introduction of a tax on land rents, a tax on the value of land or a stamp duty will cause the net price of land to decline. Further, we show that the nationalization of land and the redistribution of the land rents to the young generation will maximize the growth rate of the economy. Keywords: taxation of land; land rents; overlapping generation model; land property; endoge- nous growth Citation: Che, Shulu, Ronald 1. Introduction Ravinesh Kumar, and Peter J. In this paper, we use a growth model to theoretically investigate the influence of Stauvermann. 2021. Taxation of Land different types of land tax on economic growth. Further, we investigate how the allocation and Economic Growth. Economies 9: of the tax revenue influences the growth of the economy.
    [Show full text]
  • Ecotaxes: a Comparative Study of India and China
    Ecotaxes: A Comparative Study of India and China Rajat Verma ISBN 978-81-7791-209-8 © 2016, Copyright Reserved The Institute for Social and Economic Change, Bangalore Institute for Social and Economic Change (ISEC) is engaged in interdisciplinary research in analytical and applied areas of the social sciences, encompassing diverse aspects of development. ISEC works with central, state and local governments as well as international agencies by undertaking systematic studies of resource potential, identifying factors influencing growth and examining measures for reducing poverty. The thrust areas of research include state and local economic policies, issues relating to sociological and demographic transition, environmental issues and fiscal, administrative and political decentralization and governance. It pursues fruitful contacts with other institutions and scholars devoted to social science research through collaborative research programmes, seminars, etc. The Working Paper Series provides an opportunity for ISEC faculty, visiting fellows and PhD scholars to discuss their ideas and research work before publication and to get feedback from their peer group. Papers selected for publication in the series present empirical analyses and generally deal with wider issues of public policy at a sectoral, regional or national level. These working papers undergo review but typically do not present final research results, and constitute works in progress. ECOTAXES: A COMPARATIVE STUDY OF INDIA AND CHINA1 Rajat Verma2 Abstract This paper attempts to compare various forms of ecotaxes adopted by India and China in order to reduce their carbon emissions by 2020 and to address other environmental issues. The study contributes to the literature by giving a comprehensive definition of ecotaxes and using it to analyse the status of these taxes in India and China.
    [Show full text]
  • Taxation in Islam
    Taxation in Islam The following article is based on the book Funds in the Khilafah State which is a translation of Al-Amwal fi Dowlat Al-Khilafah by Abdul-Qadeem Zalloom.1 Allah (swt) has revealed a comprehensive economic system that details all aspects of economic life including government revenues and taxation. In origin, the permanent sources of revenue for the Bait ul-Mal (State Treasury) should be sufficient to cover the obligatory expenditure of the Islamic State. These revenues that Shar’a (Islamic Law) has defined are: Fa’i, Jizya, Kharaj, Ushur, and income from Public properties. The financial burdens placed on modern states today are far higher than in previous times. When the Caliphate is re-established it will need to finance a huge re-development and industrial programme to reverse centuries of decline, and bring the Muslim world fully into the 21st century. Because of this, the Bait ul-Mal’s permanent sources of revenue may be insufficient to cover all the needs and interests the Caliphate is obliged to spend upon. In such a situation where the Bait ul-Mal’s revenues are insufficient to meet the Caliphate’s budgetary requirements, the Islamic obligation transfers from the Bait ul-Mal to the Muslims as a whole. This is because Allah (swt) has obliged the Muslims to spend on these needs and interests, and their failure to spend on them will lead to the harming of Muslims. Allah (swt) obliged the State and the Ummah to remove any harm from the Muslims. It was related on the authority of Abu Sa’id al-Khudri, (ra), that the Messenger of Allah (saw) said: “It is not allowed to do harm nor to allow being harmed.” [Ibn Majah, Al-Daraqutni] Therefore, Allah (swt) has obliged the State to collect money from the Muslims in order to cover its obligatory expenditure.
    [Show full text]
  • Critical Tax Policy: a Pathway to Reform? Nancy J
    Northwestern Journal of Law & Social Policy Volume 9 | Issue 2 Article 2 2014 Critical Tax Policy: a Pathway to Reform? Nancy J. Knauer Recommended Citation Nancy J. Knauer, Critical Tax Policy: a Pathway to Reform?, 9 Nw. J. L. & Soc. Pol'y. 206 (2014). http://scholarlycommons.law.northwestern.edu/njlsp/vol9/iss2/2 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Northwestern University School of Law Scholarly Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Northwestern Journal of Law & Social Policy by an authorized administrator of Northwestern University School of Law Scholarly Commons. Copyright 2014 by Northwestern University School of Law Vol. 9, Issue 2 (2014) Northwestern Journal of Law and Social Policy CRITICAL TAX POLICY : A PATHWAY TO REFORM ? ∗ Nancy J. Knauer TABLE OF CONTENTS INTRODUCTION .................................................................................................... 207 I. THE COSTS OF FALSE NEUTRALITY ............................................................... 214 A. All Part of a Larger “Blueprint” ............................................................ 215 B. Hidden Choices and Embedded Values .................................................. 218 Taxpayer neutrality ..................................................................................... 219 Equity and efficiency .................................................................................. 221 C. Critical Tax Theory and Scholarship ...................................................... 223 II. CHOOSING A CRITICAL
    [Show full text]
  • Externalities in International Tax Enforcement: Theory and Evidence∗
    Externalities in International Tax Enforcement: Theory and Evidence∗ Thomas Tørsløv (University of Copenhagen) Ludvig Wier (UC Berkeley) Gabriel Zucman (UC Berkeley and NBER) December 25, 2020 Abstract We show that the fiscal authorities of high-tax countries can lack the incentives to combat profit shifting to tax havens. Instead, they have incentives to focus their enforcement efforts on relocating profits booked by multinationals in other high-tax countries, crowding out the enforcement on transactions that shift profits to tax havens, and reducing the global tax payments of multinational companies. The predictions of our model are motivated and supported by the analysis of two new datasets: the universe of transfer price corrections conducted by the Danish tax authority, and new cross-country data on international tax enforcement. ∗Thomas Tørsløv: [email protected]; Ludvig Wier: [email protected]; Gabriel Zucman: [email protected]. We thank the Danish Tax Administration for data access and many conversations, the Editor, three referees, and numerous seminar and conference participants. Financial support from the FRIPRO program of the Research Council of Norway and from Arnold Ventures is gratefully acknowledged. The authors retain sole responsibility for the views expressed in this research. 1 Introduction Multinational firms can avoid taxes by shifting profits from high-tax to low-tax countries. A number of studies suggest that this profit shifting causes substantial losses of tax revenue (Criv- elli, de Mooij and Keen, 2015; Bolwijn et al., 2018; Clausing, 2016; Tørsløv et al., 2020). In principle, tax authorities in high-tax countries can attempt to reduce profit shifting by increas- ing the monitoring of intra-group transactions and enforcing more strongly the rules governing the pricing of these transactions.1 Why, despite the sizable revenue losses involved, does profit shifting nonetheless persist? This paper provides a novel answer to this question by studying the incentives faced by tax authorities.
    [Show full text]
  • An Overview of Capital Gains Taxes FISCAL Erica York FACT Economist No
    An Overview of Capital Gains Taxes FISCAL Erica York FACT Economist No. 649 Apr. 2019 Key Findings • Comparisons of capital gains tax rates and tax rates on labor income should factor in all the layers of taxes that apply to capital gains. • The tax treatment of capital income, such as capital gains, is often viewed as tax-advantaged. However, capital gains taxes place a double-tax on corporate income, and taxpayers have often paid income taxes on the money that they invest. • Capital gains taxes create a bias against saving, which encourages present consumption over saving and leads to a lower level of national income. • The tax code is currently biased against saving and investment; increasing the capital gains tax rate would add to the bias against saving and reduce national income. The Tax Foundation is the nation’s leading independent tax policy research organization. Since 1937, our research, analysis, and experts have informed smarter tax policy at the federal, state, local, and global levels. We are a 501(c)(3) nonprofit organization. ©2019 Tax Foundation Distributed under Creative Commons CC-BY-NC 4.0 Editor, Rachel Shuster Designer, Dan Carvajal Tax Foundation 1325 G Street, NW, Suite 950 Washington, DC 20005 202.464.6200 taxfoundation.org TAX FOUNDATION | 2 Introduction The tax treatment of capital income, such as from capital gains, is often viewed as tax-advantaged. However, viewed in the context of the entire tax system, there is a tax bias against income like capital gains. This is because taxes on saving and investment, like the capital gains tax, represent an additional layer of tax on capital income after the corporate income tax and the individual income tax.
    [Show full text]
  • Environmental Taxes and the Double-Dividend Hypothesis: Did You Really Expect Something for Nothing?
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Research Papers in Economics Environmental Taxes and the Double-Dividend Hypothesis: Did You Really Expect Something for Nothing? by Don Fullerton Department of Economics University of Texas Austin, TX 78712-1173 and NBER [email protected] and Gilbert E. Metcalf Department of Economics Tufts University Medford, MA 02155 and NBER [email protected] August 1997 This paper was prepared for a "Symposium on Second-Best Theory" to appear in the Chicago- Kent Law Review. We are grateful for helpful comments and suggestions from Charles Ballard, Larry Goulder, Ian Parry and Kerry Smith. The first author is grateful for financial support from a grant of the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA R824740-01-0), and the second author is grateful for financial support from a grant of the National Science Foundation to the National Bureau of Economic Research (NSF SBR-9514989). This paper is part of NBER's research program in Public Economics. Any opinions expressed are those of the authors and not those of the EPA, the NSF, or the National Bureau of Economic Research. Environmental Taxes and the Double-Dividend Hypothesis: Did You Really Expect Something for Nothing? ABSTRACT The "double-dividend hypothesis" suggests that increased taxes on polluting activities can provide two kinds of benefits. The first dividend is an improvement in the environment, and the second dividend is an improvement in economic efficiency from the use of environmental tax revenues to reduce other taxes such as income taxes that distort labor supply and saving decisions.
    [Show full text]
  • Seigniorage and Fixed Exchange Rates: an Optimal Inflation Tax Analysis
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SEIGNIORAGEANDFIXED EXCHANGERATES: ANOPTIMALINFLATION TAX ANALYSIS Stanley Fischer Working Paper No. 783 NATIONALBUREAUOF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge MA 02138 October 1981 The research reported here is part of the NBER's research program in Economic Fluctuations and International Studies. Any opinions expressed are those of the author and not those of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER Working Paper #783 October 1981 Seigniorage and Fixed Exchange Rates: An Optimal Inflation Tax Analysis ABSTRACT A country that decides to fix its exchange rate thereby gives up control over its own inflation rate and the determination of the revenue received from seigniorage. If the country goes further and uses a foreign money, it loses all seigniorage. This paper uses an optimal inflation tax approach to analyze the consequences for optimal rates of income taxation and welfare of the alternative exchange rate and monetary arrangements. From the viewpoint of seigniorage, a system in which the country is free to determine its own rates of inflation is optimal; fixed exchange rates are second best, and the use of a foreign money is worse. The paper notes that seigniorageis only one of the factors determining the choice of op- timalexchange rate regime, but also points out that rates of seigniorage collection are high, typically accounting for five or more percent of government revenue. StanleyFischer Hoover Institution Stanford University Stanford, CA 94305 (415)497—9175 Fischer September 1981 Seigniorage and Fixed Exchange Rates: An Optimal Inflation Tax Analysis Stanley Fischer* In choosing fixed over flexible exchange rates, a country gives up the right to determine its own rate of inflation, and thus the amount of revenue collected by the inflation tax.
    [Show full text]