Moral Views of Market Society

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Moral Views of Market Society ANRV316-SO33-14 ARI 31 May 2007 12:29 Moral Views of Market Society Marion Fourcade1 and Kieran Healy2 1Department of Sociology, University of California, Berkeley, California 94720-1980; email: [email protected] 2Department of Sociology, University of Arizona, Tucson, Arizona 85721; email: [email protected] Annu. Rev. Sociol. 2007. 33:285–311 Key Words First published online as a Review in Advance on markets, capitalism, moral order, culture, performativity, April 5, 2007 governmentality The Annual Review of Sociology is online at http://soc.annualreviews.org Abstract This article’s doi: Upon what kind of moral order does capitalism rest? Conversely, by University of California - Berkeley on 08/30/07. For personal use only. 10.1146/annurev.soc.33.040406.131642 does the market give rise to a distinctive set of beliefs, habits, and Annu. Rev. Sociol. 2007.33:285-311. Downloaded from arjournals.annualreviews.org Copyright c 2007 by Annual Reviews. social bonds? These questions are certainly as old as social science All rights reserved itself. In this review, we evaluate how today’s scholarship approaches 0360-0572/07/0811-0285$20.00 the relationship between markets and the moral order. We begin with Hirschman’s characterization of the three rival views of the market as civilizing, destructive, or feeble in its effects on society. We review recent work at the intersection of sociology, economics, and political economy and show that these views persist both as theories of market society and moral arguments about it. We then argue that a fourth view, which we call moralized markets, has become increasingly prominent in economic sociology. This line of research sees markets as cultural phenomena and moral projects in their own right, and seeks to study the mechanisms and techniques by which such projects are realized in practice. 285 ANRV316-SO33-14 ARI 31 May 2007 12:29 INTRODUCTION relations, corrupt political life, and corrode character. We call this view the commodi- In 1982, a soft-spoken economist with a self- fied nightmare. Finally, economic sociologists diagnosed propensity for subversion (and self- have leaned toward Hirschman’s third cate- subversion) published a short article on a big gory: markets as relatively feeble compared to topic (Hirschman 1982): How have intellec- culture and society. The dominant paradigm tual elites understood and judged market so- of embeddedness implies that culture and in- ciety throughout history? Somewhat contrary stitutions mediate, and often trump, the moral to his expectations, Hirschman (1977) found implications (good or bad) of capitalist mar- that the market was initially seen as a civilizing kets. In this view, markets do not have a moral force. For most of the eighteenth century, the nature outside the particular social and cog- doux commerce thesis held that market relations nitive arrangements from which they emerge made people more cordial and less inclined to and that sustain them. fight one another. By the late nineteenth cen- Despite the value of Hirschman’s frame- tury, however, this harmonious vision faced a work, we also seek to go beyond it. In his challenge. Marx, among others, argued that scheme, the causal relationship between the capitalist society tends to undermine its own market and the moral order is straightforward. moral foundations, to the point at which Markets can exert a huge direct effect for good it will ultimately self-destruct. In response or do tremendous damage. Alternatively, the to this gloomy prediction, the defenders of arrow points the other way, and fragile mar- the market revised the doux commerce thesis. kets are overwhelmed by the moral order (or, The market was still an essentially good more rarely, nurtured by it). We argue that a force but a too feeble one. According to this body of important work, most of it quite re- “feudal shackles” thesis, the persistence of cent, rejects this clean division between the cultural and institutional legacies from the moral order and the market. Instead, research past hampered the market’s beneficial effects. on the classification of exchange relations, the Conversely, the absence of such a heritage performativity of economics, and the regula- in the U.S. case was seen as a blessing and tion of countries and corporations in the inter- a critical element in explaining the country’s national economy is united by a view of mar- moral character and economic success. kets as intensely moralized, and moralizing, Markets, Hirschman suggested, have thus entities. We suggest that this new emphasis been cast as civilizing, destructive, or feeble in reflects not simply a shift in scholarly fashion, their effects on society. In the 25 years since but also trends in the public justification of by University of California - Berkeley on 08/30/07. For personal use only. the publication of his article, there has been the contemporary economic order itself. an explosion of research on markets in sociol- Annu. Rev. Sociol. 2007.33:285-311. Downloaded from arjournals.annualreviews.org ogy. In this article, we begin with Hirschman’s conceptual scheme and show how a good deal of this recent work fits within its categories. CIVILIZING MARKETS: First, economists still endorse the doux com- THE LIBERAL DREAM merce thesis and generally emphasize the pos- Economists need no convincing that compet- itive effect of market institutions on civil soci- itive markets constitute the best possible ar- ety, politics, and culture. We call the modern rangement for the satisfaction of individual version of this view the liberal dream. Second, needs and the efficient allocation of resources. public intellectuals and critics from various Both these arguments were made long ago by disciplines continue to critique the market. Adam Smith and Leon Walras, respectively, The “autodestruction” thesis that Hirschman and have generally withstood the test of time identified, however, has evolved into more within the discipline. At both micro and macro specific claims that markets undermine social levels, so it seems, economic theory elevates 286 Fourcade · Healy ANRV316-SO33-14 ARI 31 May 2007 12:29 egoism to paradigmatic status. “It is not from “trustees, not of civilization, but of the possi- the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, bility of civilization.” or the baker, that we expect our dinner, but from their regard to their own self-interest. We address ourselves, not to their human- A Virtue Ethics of the Market ity but to their self-love,” wrote Smith (1994, The reason morality seems a priori irrele- p. 15) in one of the most cited passages of the vant to economics is that, as Smith discov- Wealth of Nations. Today, the neoclassical ap- ered, a system may be virtuous and harmo- proach that formalized modern economic the- nious as a whole no matter how selfish its con- ory generally posits that individuals maximize stituent parts are. But here is the twist: Each their utility in all social relations. Principal- individual’s hunger for profit will be kept in agent theory, for instance, is predicated on check by a similar drive among other individ- the notion that actors will retain informa- uals. Rather than producing ruthless greed, tion and cheat organizational demands. Pub- self-interest will tend to make people polite, lic choice theory hypothesizes that corrup- serviceable, and honest. Thus, Smith (1978, tion, rather than benevolence in some degree, p. 538; cited in Stigler 1981, pp. 172–73) also is the natural condition of the government. wrote that “whenever commerce is introduced And an infamous leaked World Bank memo into any country, probity and punctuality al- about the comparative advantage of develop- ways accompany it .... Of all the nations of ing economies in attracting dirty industries Europe, the Dutch, the most commercial, are has become a canonical example of the po- the most faithful to their word.” tential gap between moral questions of justice Markets, then, not only produce eco- and cold-blooded considerations of allocative nomic harmony (the satisfaction of individ- efficiency (Economist 1992). uals’ desires and needs), they also create If economists exclusively made narrow social harmony. McCloskey (2006) is today claims about the allocation of resources, an ar- perhaps the most prominent defender of ticle about markets and morals would feature the view that markets encourage not only them only as a negative case. Yet the relation- public but also personal virtue. Like other ship of economic theory to morality is more virtue ethicists, she seeks to identify both the complex than this. First, economic theory is virtues that comprise good moral character built on assumptions whose implicit moral and the individual habits and social institu- content can be drawn out in detail (Hausman tions that cultivate such virtues in people. & McPherson 2006). Second, and more im- In broad outline, we may contrast this ap- by University of California - Berkeley on 08/30/07. For personal use only. portantly for our purposes, there is a long tra- proach with the Kantian and consequential- Annu. Rev. Sociol. 2007.33:285-311. Downloaded from arjournals.annualreviews.org dition within economic discourse of explicit ist traditions, which offer competing theories praise for the moral benefits of market society. for judging the morality of actions (whether The precise benefits vary. The doux commerce through the application of deontological prin- tradition is carried forward by arguments that ciples of moral duty or a utilitarian calcu- the market nourishes personal virtues of hon- lation of the good and bad consequences est behavior, civility, and cooperation. Oth- of one’s choices). For McCloskey, markets ers have seen markets as a necessary condi- nurture a long list of “bourgeois virtues,” tion for freedom in other aspects of life, most including integrity, honesty, trustworthiness, prominently in politics and in the cultural enterprise, respect, modesty, and respon- realm.
Recommended publications
  • Kant Y La Tesis Acerca Del Doux Commerce. Sobre La Interconexión Del Espíritu Comercial, El Derecho Y La Paz En La Filosofía De La Historia De Kant1
    CON-TEXTOS KANTIANOS. International Journal of Philosophy N.o 7, Junio 2018, pp. 375-385 ISSN: 2386-7655 Doi: 10.5281/zenodo.1299349 Kant y la tesis acerca del doux commerce. Sobre la interconexión del espíritu comercial, el derecho y la paz en la filosofía de la historia de Kant1 Kant and the thesis of le doux commerce. On the relation of the spirit of commerce, law, and peace in Kant’s philosophy of history DIETER HÜNING2 Universidad de Tréveris, Alemania Resumen Este artículo se centra en las apologías de Kant acerca de la sociedad comercial en su texto de Hacia la paz perpetua. Dichas apologías, que pueden resumirse bajo el título "le doux commerce", se difundieron en el siglo XVIII. Muchos filósofos e historiadores, como Montesquieu, Hume, Voltaire y Ferguson, formaron parte de este grupo. La cuestión decisiva para Kant fue combinar tal apología con su concepción teleológica de la historia, que desarrolló en su Ideas para una historia universal en clave cosmopolita. Palabras clave Apología de la sociedad comercial, paz perpetua, concepción teleológica de la historia, doux commerce 1 El presente texto ofrece una versión reducida del artículo aparecido inicialmente en alemán: "Es ist der Handelsgeist, der mit dem Kriege nicht bestehen kann". – Handel, Recht und Frieden in Kants Geschichtsphilosophie, en Olaf Asbach (coord.): Der moderne Staat und ‚le doux commerce’. Politik, Ökonomie und internationales System im politischen Denken der Aufklärung, Baden-Baden: Nomos 2014, pp. 251-274 [= Staatsverständnisse, Editado por Rüdiger Voigt, Bd. 68]. Agradezco al Prof. Dr. Oscar Cubo (Universitat de València) por la traducción de este texto al castellano.
    [Show full text]
  • Passions, Doux Commerce, Interest Properly Understood: from Adam Smith to Alexis De Tocqueville and Beyond Andreas Hess [email protected]
    FORUM Passions, doux commerce, interest properly understood: From Adam Smith to Alexis de Tocqueville and beyond Andreas Hess [email protected] Back to the future: Smith’s Theory of Moral Sentiments Sometimes the changing perceptions of classic books and their authors tell a larger, often more complex, story. So it is with Adam Smith’s Theory of Moral Sentiments (TMS). TMS was Smith’s first and last book. Having gone through five editions—the last one being prepared almost from the deathbed—, its various editions sandwiched his other classic book, The Wealth of Nations (WN) for which Smith became a household name. Today Smith is first and foremost identified as one of the founding fathers of political economy, a fact that is perhaps no better expressed than by the Bank of England’s twenty pound note, showing the man and paying reference to WN. Such was the perception of Smith—until the onslaught of the current economic crisis. As the current interest and wave of recent reception and scholarship makes clear, Adam Smith is making an unexpected comeback. What is new is that over the last ten years, and pretty much overlapping with the current economic crisis, the talk is now less about Smith the political economist and author of WN, or about political economy or the benefits of open markets and commercial activities, than about Adam Smith the moral philosopher and his ground breaking TMS. It seems that scholars have begun to discover and excavate the ‘real’ Adam Smith, the moral philosopher who wrote about sociability, virtuous behaviour and sympathy and who reasoned that these features must not necessarily be seen in contradiction to, but rather helped to embed market relations, commercial activities and pursuit of self-interest for the purpose of the common wealth.
    [Show full text]
  • The Ambiguous Birth of Political Economy: Montchrestien Vs. Cantillon-1
    The ambiguous birth of political economy : Montchrestien vs. Cantillon Jérôme Maucourant To cite this version: Jérôme Maucourant. The ambiguous birth of political economy : Montchrestien vs. Cantillon. 2011. halshs-01016945 HAL Id: halshs-01016945 https://halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-01016945 Preprint submitted on 3 Jul 2014 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. Jérôme Maucourant - Université de Lyon - Université Jean Monnet - UMR 5206 Triangle To quote this paper : « The ambiguous birth of political economy : Montchrestien vs. Cantillon », the 20th may of 2011, ESHET (European Society for the History of Economic Thought) 2011 – Competition, innovation and rivalry, Bogazici University, Istanbul. The ambiguous birth of political economy: Montchrestien vs. Cantillon-1 Summary The political constitution of markets is promoted by Montchrestien whereas, on the contrary, the absolute autonomy of the sphere of exchange is favoured by Cantillon. Yet, this article seeks to demonstrate that both authors participate in the emergence of a modern way of thinking about the economy. In both cases, we find the idea that the sphere of exchange acquires an autonomy which requires the application of a specific science. In the case of Cantillon, this autonomy is absolute and anticipates the foundations of contemporary economics.
    [Show full text]
  • Cadalso Y Montesquieu: «Le Doux Commerce»
    Emilio Martínez Mata 63 Cadalso y Montesquieu: lujo y doux commerce Emilio Martínez Mata (Universidad de Oviedo) La discusión sobre el lujo se convierte en una cuestión de vital importancia en el siglo XVIII porque, más allá de consideraciones de orden moral o de las explicaciones históricas sobre su papel en el devenir cíclico de las naciones (crecimiento, auge, decadencia) a partir de las disquisiciones sobre la decadencia del imperio romano, implica la licitud de las actividades económicas distintas de las entonces consideradas básicas, ganadería y agricultura. Es decir, frente a las incitaciones a la “virtud”, tanto las de naturaleza estoica como las cristianas, plantea la licitud y conveniencia de las motivaciones económicas en el ser humano, reflejo de una concepción focalizada en la vida del hombre, desligada de las preocupaciones por el más allá. Lo que se convierte en el centro de interés ahora es la “felicidad temporal del hombre” de la que habla Jovellanos en el Informe sobre la Ley Agraria (391). Desde una perspectiva más elemental, el debate sobre el lujo va a mostrar también las críticas a los excesos y los gastos superfluos de las clases adineradas. Pero el planteamiento que se efectúa en el siglo XVIII es mucho más complejo. Los ilustrados dieron, como es sabido, una gran importancia a la vida en sociedad, a la sociabilidad en todas sus vertientes. Frente a la actitud nostálgica, reverdecedora del mito de la Edad de Oro que se refleja en Fénelon y, más tarde, en Rousseau, que evocan con admiración una forma de vida primitiva, apegada a la naturaleza, dedicada a la ganadería y a la agricultura, los ilustrados propugnarán las virtudes de la vida social y los beneficios del desarrollo económico que se produce en las ciudades.
    [Show full text]
  • From Mandeville to Hegel
    Narrative Section of a Successful Application The attached document contains the grant narrative and selected portions of a previously funded grant application. It is not intended to serve as a model, but to give you a sense of how a successful application may be crafted. Every successful application is different, and each applicant is urged to prepare a proposal that reflects its unique project and aspirations. Prospective applicants should consult the Summer Seminars and Institutes application guidelines at http://www.neh.gov/grants/education/summer-seminars-and-institutes for instructions. Applicants are also strongly encouraged to consult with the NEH Division of Education Programs staff well before a grant deadline. Note: The attachment only contains the grant narrative and selected portions, not the entire funded application. In addition, certain portions may have been redacted to protect the privacy interests of an individual and/or to protect confidential commercial and financial information and/or to protect copyrighted materials. The page limit for the narrative description is now fifteen double-spaced pages. Project Title: Enlightenment Thinkers: from Mandeville to Hegel Institution: University of Chicago Project Director: Paul Cheney Grant Program: Summer Seminars and Institutes 400 7th Street, SW, Washington, D.C. 20024 P 202.606.8500 F 202.606.8394 E [email protected] www.neh.gov Table of Contents Invisible Bonds – The Enlightenment Science of Society from Mandeville to Hegel A Proposal for a three-week NEH Seminar for University and College Teachers Paul Cheney and Alexander Schmidt 1. Project Narrative 1 a. Intellectual Rationale 2 b. Seminar Organization 3 c.
    [Show full text]
  • Adam Smith's Warning on the Relation Between Commerce and War
    Trinity University Digital Commons @ Trinity Economics Faculty Research Economics Department 5-2019 Do Not Take Peace for Granted: Adam Smith's Warning on the Relation Between Commerce and War Maria Pia Paganelli Trinity University, [email protected] R. Schumacher Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.trinity.edu/econ_faculty Part of the Economics Commons Repository Citation Paganelli, M.P., & Schumacher, R. (2019). Do not take peace for granted: Adam Smith's warning on the relation between commerce and war. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 43(3), 785-797. doi: 10.1093/cje/ bey040 This Pre-Print is brought to you for free and open access by the Economics Department at Digital Commons @ Trinity. It has been accepted for inclusion in Economics Faculty Research by an authorized administrator of Digital Commons @ Trinity. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Do Not Take Peace for Granted: Adam Smith’s Warning on the Relation Between Commerce and War Maria Pia Paganelli & Reinhard Schumacher Cambridge Journal of Economics (Forthcoming) 2018 Abstract Is trade a promoter of peace? Adam Smith, one of the earliest defenders of trade, worries that commerce may instigate some perverse incentives, encouraging wars. The wealth that commerce generates decreases the relative cost of wars; it increases the ability to finance wars through debts, which decreases their perceived cost; and it increases the willingness of commercial interests to use wars to extend their markets, increasing the number and prolonging the length of wars. Smith therefore cannot assume that trade would yield a peaceful world. While defending and promoting trade, Smith warns us not to take peace for granted.
    [Show full text]
  • Democratic International Relations: Montesquieu and the Theoretical Foundations of Democratic Peace Theory
    Democratic international relations: Montesquieu and the theoretical foundations of democratic peace theory Author Patapan, Haig Published 2012 Journal Title Australian Journal of International Affairs DOI https://doi.org/10.1080/10357718.2012.672951 Copyright Statement © 2012 Taylor & Francis. This is the author-manuscript version of this paper. Reproduced in accordance with the copyright policy of the publisher. Please refer to the journal's website for access to the definitive, published version. Downloaded from http://hdl.handle.net/10072/48265 Griffith Research Online https://research-repository.griffith.edu.au Democratic International Relations: Montesquieu and the theoretical foundations of Democratic Peace Theory Haig Patapan The article examines the extent to which Montesquieu’s doux commerce thesis, which claims that commerce leads to softening of manners and therefore favours international peace, presents a challenge to democratic peace theory. It argues that Montesquieu’s claim that peace may be due to commerce, and not democracy, provides a theoretical challenge to those scholars who argue that there is a Kantian virtuous triangle of democracy. The practical implication of this theoretical challenge concerns the way democratic peace theory has influenced the practice of international politics, especially American foreign policy. The article argues that Montesquieu’s doux commerce thesis mediates between the contending claims of realism and liberal internationalism over the merits of democratisation as an essential means for
    [Show full text]
  • Montesquieu on Liberty and Sumptuary Law" a Discussion Held in November, 2015
    "MONTESQUIEU ON LIBERTY AND SUMPTUARY LAW" A DISCUSSION HELD IN NOVEMBER, 2015. Online: <http://oll.libertyfund.org/pages/lm-ideas> Ebooks: <http://oll.libertyfund.org/titles/2709>. Baron de Montesquieu (1689-1755) The Spirit of the Laws (1748) Summary The Baron de Montesquieu (1689-1755) was one of the most widely read authors before the American Revolution and had a profound impact on the formation of the American Republic. In this discussion of his economic thought, in particular his ideas about the need for sumptuary laws in republics, Henry Clark of Dartmouth College investigates this little appreciated aspect of Montesquieu's thinking and concludes that, before the theory of natural rights became better estanblished, "Sumptuary law is scarcely more than a blip on our historical radar screens, but it manages to remind us of what a mottled, murky landscape the history of liberty really is". Henry Clark is joined in the diuscussion by David Carrithers at the University of Tennessee, Chattanooga, Paul A. Rahe at Hillsdale College, Michigan, and Stuart D. Warner of Roosevelt University, Chicago. 1 of 28 About Liberty Matters and the Online Library of Liberty “Liberty Matters” is a project of Liberty Fund, Inc. which is part of the Online Library of Liberty website. Every two months we ask a leading scholar to present an argument on a particular topic “pertaining to liberty” in a “Lead Essay” and to develop this argument at some length. The “Lead Essay” is posted in the first week of the month. Three or four other scholars will respond to this essay in slightly shorter “Response Essays” during the second week of the month.
    [Show full text]
  • Traditional Paradisms for the Causes of War Applied to the International Trading System: Nation-State Institutions in a World of Market-States
    The Catholic University of America, Columbus School of Law CUA Law Scholarship Repository Scholarly Articles and Other Contributions Faculty Scholarship 2005 Traditional Paradisms for the Causes of War Applied to the International Trading System: Nation-State Institutions in a World of Market-States Antonio F. Perez The Catholic University of America, Columbus School of Law Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.edu/scholar Part of the International Law Commons, International Trade Law Commons, and the Military, War, and Peace Commons Recommended Citation Antonio F. Perez, Traditional Paradisms for the Causes of War Applied to the International Trading System: Nation-State Institutions in a World of Market-States, 37 STUD. TRANSNAT’L LEGAL POL’Y 178 (2005). This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at CUA Law Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Scholarly Articles and Other Contributions by an authorized administrator of CUA Law Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. TRADITIONAL PARADIGMS FOR THE CAUSES OF WAR APPLIED TO THE INTERNATIONAL TRADING SYSTEM: NATION-STATE INSTITUTIONS IN A WORLD OF MARKET-STATES ANTONIO F. PEREZ* I. Introduction Inquiry into the set of possible relationships between trade and peace is not a new object of study. Indeed, it is one of the oldest questions of human existence. While it is not a question that permits a final answer, it is, nonetheless, a question that requires continuing reflection. Indeed, how we have considered the question in the past may well be more interesting 'and useful than the current state of progress in developing empirically valid propositions on the subject.
    [Show full text]
  • Doux Commerce, Religion, and the Limits of Antidiscrimination Law Nathan B
    College of William & Mary Law School William & Mary Law School Scholarship Repository Faculty Publications Faculty and Deans 2017 Doux Commerce, Religion, and the Limits of Antidiscrimination Law Nathan B. Oman William & Mary Law School, [email protected] Repository Citation Oman, Nathan B., "Doux Commerce, Religion, and the Limits of Antidiscrimination Law" (2017). Faculty Publications. 1842. https://scholarship.law.wm.edu/facpubs/1842 Copyright c 2017 by the authors. This article is brought to you by the William & Mary Law School Scholarship Repository. https://scholarship.law.wm.edu/facpubs Doux Commerce, Religion, and the Limits of Antidiscrimination Law* NATHAN B. OMANt INTRODUCTION ......................................................... 693 I. RELIGION, SAME-SEX MARRIAGE, AND THE SCOPE OF ANTIDISCRIMINATION LAW...................................... 697 II. THE PUBLIC THEORY OF THE MARKET AND THE PRIVATE THEORY OF THE MARKET .......................................................... 703 A. THE PUBLIC THEORY OF THE MARKET........... .................. 703 B. THE PRIVATE THEORY OF THE MARKET ......................... 706 III. Doux COMMERCE AND THE REACH OF ANTIDISCRIMINATION LAWS.............. 709 A. THE Doux COMMERCE THEORY OF THE MARKET ........ ............ 710 B. Doux COMMERCE AND THE SCOPE OF ANTIDISCRIMINATION LAW ........ 714 C. OBJECTIONS AND RESPONSES......................... ............ 725 CONCLUSION ................................................... ......... 732 INTRODUCTION We are used to thinking about law and religion
    [Show full text]
  • David Hume, Colonial Slavery, and Commercial Incivility Onur Ulas INCE Singapore Management University, [email protected]
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Institutional Knowledge at Singapore Management University Singapore Management University Institutional Knowledge at Singapore Management University Research Collection School of Social Sciences School of Social Sciences 3-2018 Between commerce and empire: David Hume, colonial slavery, and commercial incivility Onur Ulas INCE Singapore Management University, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://ink.library.smu.edu.sg/soss_research_all Part of the Political Economy Commons, and the Political Science Commons Citation INCE, Onur Ulas. Between commerce and empire: David Hume, colonial slavery, and commercial incivility. (2018). History of Political Thought. 39, (1), 107-134. Research Collection School of Social Sciences. Available at: https://ink.library.smu.edu.sg/soss_research_all/9 This Journal Article is brought to you for free and open access by the School of Social Sciences at Institutional Knowledge at Singapore Management University. It has been accepted for inclusion in Research Collection School of Social Sciences by an authorized administrator of Institutional Knowledge at Singapore Management University. For more information, please email [email protected]. Between Commerce and Empire: David Hume, Colonial Slavery, and Commercial Incivility1 Abstract Eighteenth-century Enlightenment thought has recently been reclaimed as a robust, albeit short-lived, cosmopolitan critique of European imperialism. This essay complicates this interpretation through a study of David Hume’s reflections on commerce, empire, and slavery. I argue that while Hume condemned the colonial system of monopoly, war, and conquest, his strictures against empire did not extend to colonial slavery in the Atlantic.
    [Show full text]
  • Between Usury and the “Spirit of Commerce” Images of Jews and Credit from Montesquieu to the Debate on Emancipation in Eighteenth-Century France
    French Historical Studies Between Usury and the “Spirit of Commerce” Images of Jews and Credit from Montesquieu to the Debate on Emancipation in Eighteenth-Century France FRANCESCA TRIVELLATO abstract By bringing French history and Jewish history into dialogue, this article inter- venes in the vast scholarship on the relationship between commerce and toleration in eigh- teenth-century French thought. It focuses on the place of Jews in Montesquieu’s ideas about doux commerce and explores the legacy of Montesquieu’s views on the debate on Jewish emancipation in the 1770s and 1780s. It traces the survival and adaptation of the medieval trope of the Jewish usurer in a variety of discourses, ranging from irenic images of commer- cial cosmopolitanism to representations of Jewish moneylending marshaled by radical advo- cates of Jewish “regeneration.” The article concludes by showing that in 1790–91 the doctrine of doux commerce did not provide a consistent argument in favor of civic and political equal- ity even though commercial practices and policies in the French Southwest had favored the integration of Jews during the Old Regime. keywords Jews, commerce, usury, Enlightenment, French Revolution wo books of Montesquieu’s Spirit of the Laws (De l’esprit des lois)are T devoted to commerce and one to money. Additional reflections on how the economy intersects with politics, society, and culture pepper the entire work. Book XXI describes the history of commerce from antiquity to the eighteenth- century present. A climactic turning point figures in chapter 20, which bears the dramatic title “How Commerce Broke through the Barbarism of Europe” (“Comment le commerce se fit hour en Europe a` travers la barbarie”) and traces the waning of medieval anti-usury sentiments and the rise of “the spirit of com- merce” (l’esprit de commerce).AroundthetimeoftheEuropeantransoceanic voyages, commerce ceased to be “the profession only of mean persons,” and thus the exclusive province of “a nation covered with infamy” (by which French Historical Studies Vol.
    [Show full text]