Explaining Economic Growth the Macro Level

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Explaining Economic Growth the Macro Level Chapter 8 Explaining economic growth The macro level TAKE-HOME MESSAGES FOR CHAPTER 8 1. GDPpc growth is the cornerstone of development. Yet it is one of the most difficult economic outcomes to explain and predict, with many competing theories, but also many different potentially effective strategies to accelerate growth. 2. The standard growth model is based on a structural form with five key parameters: the rate of population growth, the rate of saving, the rate of depreciation of capital, the rate of technological change, and the parameters of the production function. The effect of the rate of population growth on the growth of per capita income is ambiguous. 3. The Harrod-Domar model identifies the rate of saving and the choice of technique (the incremental capital"output ratio, or ICOR) as the two determinants of a country's growth rate. By contrast, the Solow model focuses on the relative roles of technolog­ ical change and factor deepening in explaining growth, leaving, however, technology, which is the main determinant of long-term growth in per capita income, unexplained by the model. Predictions of universal convergence in per capita income, as technology is considered to be an international public good, are also questionable. 4. The technologies available as an international public good for developing countries may not be best for their current factor-price ratio. However, in accordance with Solow, they can help these countries leapfrog toward the use of advanced technologies. 5. Dual-economy models stress the importance of labor transfers out of agriculture and of cheap food to keep nominal industrial wages low for growth in employment in industry. In the Lewis classical model, there is surplus labor in agriculture and labor transfers have zero opportunity cost for food production. In the Jorgenson neoclassical model, there is full employment, and productivity growth in agriculture is necessary for labor transfers without rising food prices. In the Lele-Mellor model, there is surplus labor in ag'riculture, but productivity growth in agriculture is necessary to keep industrial wages low. 6. · Other models such as ADU (agriculture demand-led industrialization), sectoral linkages, and competitive advantages based on institutional capacity explain why investing in agriculture is important for industrialization as a source of effective demand of multi­ plier effects and of foreign-exchange earnings. 326 EXPLAINING ECONOMIC GROWTH THE GROWTH PUZZLE We have seen that economic growth is the cornerstone on which economic devel­ opment is built (Chapter 1). We have also seen that growth performances across nations have been highly unequal, with some developing countries converging in per capita income with industrialized countries while others have been lagging behind, leading to the concept of conditional convergence (Chapter 2). And we have seen that finding ways to catch up with industrialized countries has been a primary objective in the long history of thought in development economics (Chapter 3). Yet our ability to explain economic growth, a central purpose of economics as a sci­ ence, is highly deficient, leaving us with what has been called the "mystery of eco­ nomic growth" (Helpman, 2004) and the "elusive quest for growth" (Easterly, 2002). What we know is that output growth basically depends on two determinants: (1) factor accumulation (labor, capital, materials, land) and the way these factors are combined in production for a given technology, as represented by the production function; and (2) gains in factor productivity deriving from how technology, institu­ tions, and factor quality change over time. However, what drives factor accumulation and especially gains in factor productivity remains highly contentious. Different models offer different explanations with different policy implications for what to do to accelerate growth. The truth is that each of these models offers particular insights into the growth process under particular circumstances, without exhausting potential explanations. For that reason, there are lessons to be derived from each of the main models that have been proposed to explain growth. With growth, as with the other dimensions of economic development, we are interested in both the positive analysis of growth (what explains· economic growth) and its normative analysis (what can be done to accelerate growth). To answer these questions, economists use economic models and take these models to the data for estimation, simulation, and predictions. In the quest to explain income growth, we will meet two families of models: classical and neoclassical growth models with exogenous technological change (treated in this chapter), and endogenous-growth models with technological change an outcome of economic decision-making (Chapter 9). In both families of models, technological change plays a key role in explaining growth, yet with very different outcomes and policy implications. The first family of models predicts income con­ vergence across countries, while the second predicts conditional convergence or no convergence at all. The verdict on the validity of one family of models or the other thus requires empirical verification. GENERIC MODELING OF INCOME GROWTH Structure of economic models An economic model is a simplification of reality that captures a complex process to explain an outcome, here economic growth. Because it has to be a simplification of reality, a model is always "reductionist," i.e. it omits details and has a large ceteris paribus 327 EXPLAINING ECONOMIC GROWTH Exogenous variables Model .,.__.... ;:.~ Endogenous variables Uncontrolled X Structural form h( Y, X1, Xzl 1 Outcomes Y Reduced form Y == fCX 1, X2 ) Policy instruments X2 Figure 8.1 Structural and reduced forms of an economic model clause, whereby other economic processes beyond the one under study are held constant. The model will be useful or not depending on the realism of the assump­ tions made about the processes at work and the capacity to replicate observed growth and predict future growth. Hence all models need to be carefully assessed in terms of the validity of their assumptions relative to the field of application in which we would like the model to hold (its internal validity), and in terms of whether their predicted outcomes match reality. As shown in Figure 8 .1, a model includes exogenous variables (X) that fall into two categories: uncontrolled variables such as weather, the world economic con­ text, and past events (X1); and policy instruments such as taxes and tariffs, public investment, technology, new institutions, and transfers (X2). It includes endoge­ nous variables that represent the outcomes of interest (Y). And it includes a set of technological, institutional, and behavioral functions that relate Y, Xi. and X 2. These functions can be written in structural form as h(Y, X1, X2), representing the assumptions of the model. They can also be written in reduced form as the solu­ tion to the model: namely, Y = f (X1, X2 ), where J also derives from h. In positive analysis, the first purpose of models is to check the logical structure of the reasoning and derive unexpected predictions; and the second is to estimate the parameters in the h andf functions.The first purpose is important because it is when a model is fully constructed that we know that the logic of the reasoning is complete and rigorous. Theory and theoretical derivations thus play a fundamental role in securing rigor in economic reasoning and in tracking the implications of the assump­ tions made. The second purpose is important in taking ideas to the data, enabling links between theory and empiricism. The model helps us formulate the equations that we want to estimate to either test the validity of the model or use it for norma­ tive purposes. Since there are many competing equations we could take to the data, having an economic model from which these equations derive helps us know exactly what it is that we are estimating. In normative analysis, models are used for ~o purposes: policy simulations and predictions. Policy simulations have the purpose of answering the following questions: How does a change in X2 lead to a change in Y for given h and X1? How does a change in h lead to a change in Y for given X1 and Xi Predictions, or forecasts, have the purpose of answering the following question: For a future Xt+ 1, w_hat is the corresponding predicted Y1+1 for given h? 328 EXPLAINING ECONOMIC GROWTH Theoretical rigor, a link to empiricism, simulation, and prediction are thus the four purposes of modeling in economics. Generic structure of a growth model The generic structure of a per capita income growth model is as follows. Initial conditions at time t Say that output is a function of capital, labor, technology, and a way of organizing production. This can be represented as follows. Initial factor endowments: Kt (stock of capital), Lt (labor force). Initial total factor productivity (TFP): At (technology). Initial income (or output level): Yt = J (Au Kt, Lt), where Yt is aggregate income andf is the production function that transforms technology, capital, and labor into output.· Growth process Say that income growth originates in three sources: growth in the labor force accom­ panying population growth, growth in the stock of capital as part of income is saved and invested, and growth in TFP representing technological change. 1. Demographic behavior: 6.P! P = 6.L! L = L is the rate of population (P) and labor force (L) growth. A dot on top of a variable indicates the rate of growth of that variable. Here the rate of labor-force participation in the population is constant as there is full employment. As a consequence, the rate of labor-force growth is equal to the rate of population growth. This rate of population growth n may be a function of initial income Yt. The population-growth equation is thl.1s Lt+1= Li(l + n).
Recommended publications
  • How Important Are Dual Economy Effects for Aggregate Productivity?
    How Important are Dual Economy Effects for Aggregate Productivity? Dietrich Vollratha University of Houston Abstract: This paper brings together development accounting techniques and the dual economy model to address the role that factor markets have in creating variation in aggregate total factor productivity (TFP).Developmentaccountingresearchhasshownthatmuchofthevariationinincomeacrosscountries can be attributed to differences in TFP. The dual economy model suggests that aggregate productivity is depressed by having too many factors to low productivity work in agriculture. Data show large differences in marginal products of similar factors within many developing countries, offering prima facie evidence of this misallocation. Using a simple two-sector decomposition of the economy, this article estimates the role of these misallocations in accounting for the cross-country income distribution. A key contribution is the ability to bring sector specific data on human and physical capital stocks to the analysis. Variation across countries in the degree of misallocation is shown to account for 30 — 40% of the variation in income per capita, and up to 80% of the variation in aggregate TFP. JEL Codes: O1, O4, Q1 Keywords: Resource allocation; Labor allocation; Dual economy; Income distribution; Factor markets; TFP a) I’d like to thank Francesco Caselli, Areendam Chanda, Carl-Johan Dalgaard, Jim Feyrer, Oded Galor, Doug Gollin, Vernon Henderson, Peter Howitt, Mike Jerzmanowksi, Omer Moav, Malhar Nabar, Jonathan Temple, David Weil, and an anonymous referee for helpful comments and advice. In addition, the participants at the Brown Macroeconomics Seminar, Northeast Universities Development Conference and Brown Macro Lunches were very helpful. All errors are, of course, my own. Department of Economics, 201C McElhinney Hall, Houston, TX 77204 [email protected] 1 1Introduction One of the most persistent relationships in economic development is the inverse one between income and agriculture, seen here in figure 1.
    [Show full text]
  • CHAPTER 2 Patterns of Growth in Dual Economies: Challenges of Development in the 21St Century
    CHAPTER 2 Patterns of Growth in Dual Economies: Challenges of Development in the 21st Century Literature regarding the basics of classical development emphasizes on the relationship between economic growth and changes in production struc- ture. It also allocates special properties to industry, and more specifically to the ability of industrialization to create and combine a series of comple- mentarities, scale properties, and external economies to generate a sustain- able cycle of resource mobilization, increasing productivity, rising demand, income, and economic growth. Changes in the global economy have contributed to the renewed discussions on the role of structural transformation in achieving sustained economic growth and development. The catch-up failure of many devel- oping regions, which are often associated with “traps” and downturns (i.e., low-development traps, middle-income traps, and premature deindustrial- ization); the end of windfall export gains led by the commodity price boom in 2000s; and the continued vulnerability of many developing regions to external shocks have also added to this discussion (UNCTAD, 2016). The dual relationship between climate change and development serves as yet another important factor. On one hand, the effects of climate change create serious challenges to development; however, on the other hand, pri- oritization of economic growth and development has had major conse- quences on climate change and vulnerability. In its basic form, emission control and effective mitigation require not only the transformation of production systems but also the transformation of energy systems, includ- ing moving away from traditional high-carbon energy sources (a phase-out of coal-fueled power plants), increasing fuel efficiency, deploying advanced renewable technologies, and implementing measures to increase energy efficiency IEA,( 2008).
    [Show full text]
  • Cubanonomics: Mixed Economy in Cuba During the Special Period BRENDAN C. DOLAN
    Cubanonomics: Mixed Economy in Cuba during the Special Period BRENDAN C. DOLAN Fidel Castro is a man of many words. No other political figure in modern history has spoken more on the public record, varying the scope of his oration from short interviews to twelve hour lectures on the state of Cuban society. Starting in 1959, his ideas flooded Cuban society and provided a code of social expectations for all to obey. Cubans listened patiently, and over time enjoyed the fruits of an egalitarian socialist system: food, shelter, education and medicine for all. By the early 1980s, Castro had constructed a centrally planned economy and an economically favorable partnership with the Soviet Union. In 1989, however, the dissolution of the Soviet Union crippled the Cuban economy and forced millions of Cubans into poverty, resulting in widespread hunger and unemployment. Faced with the threat of an economic meltdown that could end his regime, Castro looked inward for ways to revive the Cuban economy. Though previously condemning and imprisoning Cubans illegally possessing black market dollars, Castro suddenly regarded these dollar holders as the key to his regime’s survival. This hard currency was crucial to restoring the national economy, and though its legalization would undermine his socialist, anti-American ideology, Castro saw no other option. In 1993, he decriminalized the possession of U.S. dollars and established state-run dollar stores to channel dollars to the government. Castro legalized self-employment, decentralized the agricultural sector and boosted Cuba’s tourist industry. Though they aided in reviving the national economy, these policy changes transformed the socioeconomic structure of Cuban society, creating a mixed economy that required Cubans to embrace certain market principles outside of socialist doctrine.
    [Show full text]
  • Labor Productivity and Energy Use in a Three Sector Model: an Application to Egypt
    DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES Labor productivity and energy use in a three sector model: An application to Egypt Rudiger von Arnim and Codrina Rada Working Paper No: 2011-06 University of Utah Department of Economics 260 S. Central Campus Dr., Rm. 343 Tel: (801) 581-7481 Fax: (801) 585-5649 http://www.econ.utah.edu Labor productivity and energy use in a three sector model: An application to Egypt ∗ Rudiger von Arnim Codrina Rada Assistant Professor Assistant Professor Department of Economics, University of Utah Department of Economics, University of Utah [email protected] [email protected] Abstract This paper presents a model of a developing economy with three sectors---a modern sector producing manufactures and services, a traditional sector producing agricultural goods, and a third sector providing energy. Modern and energy sector are assumed to be demand--constrained; the agricultural sector is supply--constrained. Simulation exercises confirm insights of existing theory on structural heterogeneity: A price--clearing agricultural sector can impose an inflationary barrier on growth. Further, emphasis is placed on the sources of productivity growth. Specifically, higher energy intensity rather than increases in energy productivity enable labor productivity growth, with the attendant complications for 'green growth.' Keywords: Structural heterogeneity, Multi-sector model, Energy use JEL Classification: O41, Q43, C63 ∗ Corresponding author. Labor productivity and energy use in a three sector model: An application to Egypt Rudiger von Arnim∗ Codrina Rada† February 14, 2011 Abstract This paper presents a model of a developing economy with three sectors—a modern sector producing manufactures and services, a traditional sector producing agricultural goods, and a third sector providing energy.
    [Show full text]
  • (C) 1995 Boston University International Law Journal Boston University International Law Journal
    Copyright (c) 1995 Boston University International Law Journal Boston University International Law Journal Fall, 1995 13 B.U. Int'l L.J. 295 ARTICLE: Symposium: A Recipe for Effecting Institutional Changes to Achieve Privatization: FOREWORD Tamar Frankel * * Professor of Law, Boston University School of Law. I am indebted to Professor Ingo Vogelsang, Boston University, for his guidance and ideas concerning this Foreward and to my research assistant Elizabeth L. Heick for her thorough research and dedicated help. SUMMARY: ... Both of us have been involved in attempts of developing countries to move from a government, centrally-planned economy to a private-sector, market economy. Of course, neither the division between government and private sector, nor the division between centrally-planned economy and market economy is clear cut, but rather is a matter of degree. ... In contrast, the performance of actors in the private sector, can be measured by profitability to the equity owners (the shareholders). ... Second, as compared to the private sector, the government operates under political and bureaucratic pressures. ... When traumatic experiences occur that shakeup large organizations, both "rejuvenated" government and the private sector can work well. ... In a few limited situations a government may be in a better position to operate a firm than the private sector. ... The private sector includes large, especially multinational, corporations, that are centrally managed. ... Most of us realize that the private sector cannot do it all. ... When people become disillusioned with private sector and market solutions they will turn to the government. ... In those public-sector dominated economies, taxation is far less important than in economies in which the private sector owns the enterprises.
    [Show full text]
  • Socio-Economic Dualism in South Eastern Europe
    Blue Bird Project Agenda for Civil Society in South East Europe SOCIO-ECONOMIC DUALISM IN SOUTH EASTERN EUROPE. EXPLORATORY NOTES ON DUALISM AND ITS REPERCUSSIONS FOR THE STATES OF THE REGION Paul Dragos Aligica Academy of Economic Studies Bucharest and Hudson Institute United Nations Development Program Split, 2001 1 SOCIO-ECONOMIC DUALISM IN SOUTH EASTERN EUROPE EXPLORATORY NOTES ON DUALISM AND ITS REPERCUSSIONS FOR THE STATES OF THE REGION 1. Introduction 2. Conceptual and theoretical background 3. Dualism, development and the state 4. Dualism and South East European countries 5. Dualism in the South East European countries: questions on meaning and implications 6. Exploratory overview of some implications of dualism INTRODUCTION The basic conjecture of this paper is the idea that the political societies, the civil societies and their impact on the structure and functioning of the states in South Eastern Europe are strongly determined by a long lasting specific feature of the economies of the region: their dualism. This feature has its origins in the modernization process, it is contemporary with it and has shaped in a distinctive way both the structure of the societies and of the states in these countries. The dualism of their economies is thus a key explanatory factor in any attempt to understand the nature, structure and functioning of the states of the region. Thus my contribution to this workshop is not laying the emphasis on ethnicity, nationalism or religion as the mainstream approaches to the states and problems of the region usually do, but on the regional political economies and on what I consider to be their key structural problem.
    [Show full text]
  • India's Economic Rise in the 21St Century and the Dual Economy
    Article Another great power in the room? India’s economic rise in the 21st century and the dual economy challenge DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1590/0034-7329202100105 Revista Brasileira de Rev. Bras. Polít. Int., 64(1): e005, 2021 Política Internacional ISSN 1983-3121 Abstract http://www.scielo.br/rbpi This article’s main objective is to examine the political economy of the economic reforms implemented in the 1990s and examine the main factors 1 Rafael Henrique Dias Manzi which explain India’s economic rise in the 21st century. We argue that the 1Centro Universitário Alves Faria, Regional Development, Goiânia, GO, Brazil productive investments and the country’s opening to the global economy have ([email protected]) contributed to economic growth, but that this rise leads to the formation of ORCID ID: a “dual economy.” Continuing reforms thereby become necessary for India orcid.org/0000-0001-8518-8329 in order to achieve inclusive growth and structural transformation, overcome Jean Santos Lima2 the dual economy challenge and gain strength in the international system. 2Universidade Católica de Brasília, International Relations, Taguatinga, DF, Brazil Keywords: International Economy; India; Economic Internationalization; ([email protected]) Emerging Countries; Economic Development. ORCID ID: orcid.org/0000-0003-4758-2389 Received: August 15th, 2020 Accepted: May 12th, 2021 Introduction hen it gained independence in 1947, India was still a Wpredominantly rural country. The working-age population employed in its manufacturing sector
    [Show full text]
  • Informal Economy in Latin America and the Caribbean: Implications for Competition Policy
    Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development DAF/COMP/LACF(2018)4 Unclassified English - Or. English 1 April 2019 DIRECTORATE FOR FINANCIAL AND ENTERPRISE AFFAIRS COMPETITION COMMITTEE Cancels & replaces the same document of 10 September 2018 LATIN AMERICAN AND CARIBBEAN COMPETITION FORUM - Session I: Informal Economy in Latin America and the Caribbean: Implications for Competition Policy - Background Note - 18-19 September 2018, Buenos Aires, Argentina This document was prepared by the OECD Secretariat to serve as a background note for the discussion during the session The Informal Economy in Latin America and the Caribbean: Implications for Competition Policy that will take place at the Latin American and Caribbean Competition Forum on 18-19 September 2018 in Argentina. The opinions expressed and arguments employed herein do not necessarily reflect the official views of the Organisation or of the governments of its member countries. More documentation related to this discussion can be found at: www.oecd.org/competition/latinamerica/programme/ Please contact Ms. Iraxte Gurpegui if you have any questions about this document [E-mail: [email protected]]. JT03445590 This document, as well as any data and map included herein, are without prejudice to the status of or sovereignty over any territory, to the delimitation of international frontiers and boundaries and to the name of any territory, city or area. 2 DAF/COMP/LACF(2018)4 Latin American and Caribbean Competition Forum Session I: The Informal Economy in Latin America and the Caribbean: Implications for Competition Policy – Background Note by the Secretariat* – There is a consensus amongst many researchers about the negative effects of informality in the competitive process.
    [Show full text]
  • The Wealth and Well-Being of Nations
    The Wealth and Well-Being of Nations Well-Being and Wealth The • Dani Rodrik Dani Contributors The Annual Proceedings of Dani Rodrik Ted Liu Sharun Mukand Jennifer Esperanza Rachel Ellett XI Volume 2018-2019 • Diep Phan Pablo Toral Darlington Sabasi Johnson Gwatipedza Xinshen Diao The Wealth and Well-Being of Nations Margaret McMillan Beatrice McKenzie Jonathan Mason Ivan Gradjansky 2018-2019 Department of Economics Volume XI: Globalization and the Wealth and Well-Being of Nations Dani Rodrik Diep Phan, Editor The Miller Upton Program at Beloit College he Wealth and Well-Being of Nations was Testablished to honor Miller Upton, Beloit College’s sixth president. This annual forum provides our students and the wider community the opportunity to engage with some of the leading intellectual figures of our time. The forum is complemented by a suite of programs that enhance student and faculty engagement in the ideas and institutions that lay at the foundation of free and prosperous societies. Cover Photo © Amanda Reseburg, Type A Images Senior Seminar on The Wealth and Well-Being of Nations: ach year, seniors in the Department of Economics participate in a semester- Elong course that is built around the ideas and influence of that year’s Upton Scholar. By the time the Upton Scholar arrives in October, students will have read several of his or her books and research by other scholars that has been influenced by these writings. This advanced preparation provides students the rare opportunity to engage with a leading intellectual figure on a substantive and scholarly level. Endowed Student Internship Awards: portion of the Miller Upton Memorial Endowments supports exceptional A students pursuing high-impact internship experiences.
    [Show full text]
  • How Important Are Dual Economy Effects for Aggregate Productivity?
    Journal of Development Economics 88 (2009) 325–334 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Development Economics journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase How important are dual economy effects for aggregate productivity? Dietrich Vollrath 1 Department of Economics, University of Houston, 201C McElhinney Hall, Houston, TX 77204, United States ARTICLE INFO ABSTRACT Article history: This paper brings together development accounting techniques and the dual economy model to address the Received 7 June 2006 role that factor markets have in creating variation in aggregate total factor productivity (TFP). Development Received in revised form 25 March 2008 accounting research has shown that much of the variation in income across countries can be attributed to Accepted 27 March 2008 differences in TFP. The dual economy model suggests that aggregate productivity is depressed by having too many factors allocated to low productivity work in agriculture. Data show large differences in marginal JEL classifications: O1 products of similar factors within many developing countries, offering prima facie evidence of this O4 misallocation. Using a simple two-sector decomposition of the economy, this article estimates the role of Q1 these misallocations in accounting for the cross-country income distribution. A key contribution is the ability to bring sector-specific data on human and physical capital stocks to the analysis. Variation across countries Keywords: in the degree of misallocation is shown to account for 30–40% of the variation in income per capita, and up to Resource allocation 80% of the variation in aggregate TFP. Labor allocation © 2008 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. Dual economy Income distribution Factor markets TFP 1.
    [Show full text]
  • The American Dual Economy. Race, Globalization, and the Politics Of
    International Journal of Political Economy, 45: 85–123, 2016 Copyright #Taylor & Francis Group, LLC ISSN: 0891-1916 print/1558-0970 online DOI: 10.1080/08911916.2016.1185311 The American Dual Economy Race, Globalization, and the Politics of Exclusion Peter Temin Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology (MIT), Cambridge, Massachusetts, USA Abstract: I describe the American economy in the twenty-first century as a dual economy in the spirit of W. Arthur Lewis. Similar to the subsistence and capitalist economies characterized by Lewis, I distinguish a low-wage sector and a finance, technology, and electronics (FTE) sector. The transition from the low-wage to the FTE sector is through education, which is becoming increasingly difficult for members of the low-wage sector because the FTE sector has largely aban- doned the American tradition of quality public schools and universities. Policy debates about public education and other policies that serve the low-wage sector often characterize members of the low- wage sector as black even though the low-wage sector is largely white. This model of a modern dual economy explains difficulties in many current policy debates, including education, health care, criminal justice, infrastructure, and household debts. Keywords criminal justice; dual economy; education; inequality; Nixon; Reagan; political economy; race The U.S. economy has come apart, with the rich getting richer and workers not advancing at all. As a politician said a decade ago, “We shouldn’t have two different economies in America: one for people who are set for life, they know their kids and their grand-kids are going to be just fine; and then one for most Americans, people who live paycheck to paycheck” (Edwards 2004).
    [Show full text]
  • Explaining and Tackling the Informal Economy: a Dual Informal Labour Market Approach
    This is a repository copy of Explaining and tackling the informal economy: a dual informal labour market approach. White Rose Research Online URL for this paper: http://eprints.whiterose.ac.uk/127143/ Version: Accepted Version Article: Williams, C.C. orcid.org/0000-0002-3610-1933 and Bezeredi, S. (2018) Explaining and tackling the informal economy: a dual informal labour market approach. Employee Relations, 40 (5). pp. 889-902. ISSN 0142-5455 https://doi.org/10.1108/ER-04-2017-0085 © 2018 Emerald Publishing Limited. This is an author produced version of a paper subsequently published in Employee Relations. This version is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial Licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. You may not use the material for commercial purposes. Reuse This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial (CC BY-NC) licence. This licence allows you to remix, tweak, and build upon this work non-commercially, and any new works must also acknowledge the authors and be non-commercial. You don’t have to license any derivative works on the same terms. More information and the full terms of the licence here: https://creativecommons.org/licenses/ Takedown If you consider content in White Rose Research Online to be in breach of UK law, please notify us by emailing [email protected] including the URL of the record and
    [Show full text]