A Five Sector Model of Agricultural Development, Industrialization And

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

A Five Sector Model of Agricultural Development, Industrialization And CARD Reports CARD Reports and Working Papers 11-1972 A five sector model of agricultural development, industrialization and food aid in a dual economy Center for Agricultural and Economic Development, Iowa State University Walter W. Haessel Iowa State University Earl O. Heady Iowa State University Leo V. Mayer Iowa State University Follow this and additional works at: http://lib.dr.iastate.edu/card_reports Part of the Agricultural and Resource Economics Commons, Agricultural Economics Commons, Agricultural Science Commons, Agronomy and Crop Sciences Commons, Natural Resource Economics Commons, and the Natural Resources Management and Policy Commons Recommended Citation Center for Agricultural and Economic Development, Iowa State University; Haessel, Walter W.; Heady, Earl O.; and Mayer, Leo V., "A five sector model of agricultural development, industrialization and food aid in a dual economy" (1972). CARD Reports. 49. http://lib.dr.iastate.edu/card_reports/49 This Book is brought to you for free and open access by the CARD Reports and Working Papers at Iowa State University Digital Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in CARD Reports by an authorized administrator of Iowa State University Digital Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. A FIVE SECTOR MODEL OF AGRICULTURAL DEVELOPMENT, INDUSTRIALIZATION AND FOOD AID IN A DUAL ECONOMY by Walter W. Haessel, Earl 0. Heady and Leo V. Mayer Center for Agricultural and Rural Development Iowa State University 578 East Hall CARD Report 43T November 1972 Ames, Iowa TABLE OF CONTENTS Page SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS. • • . • • • . • . • • .. • • . • . • . • . • . • • . • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • i Public investment in subsistence agriculture. ...................... ii Private capital accumulation •••••••••••••••• ....................... v Population growth and economic development. ........................ vii Intracountry effects of food aid ••••••••••••••••••••.•••••••••••••• vii INTRODUCTION. • • . • • • • . • • • . • • . • • . • . • • . • • . • • . • • • • • • • 1 Ob j ec t i ve s . • . • . • . • . 2 Organization of the study ••.••••••••••••••.•••• 3 Industrialization and agricultural development • .. .. .. .. .. 3 Industrialization.................................................. 4 Agricultural development........................................... 9 ALTERNATIVE METHODS OF INVESTIGATION •. 14 Interdisciplinary approach ••••••••••••••••••••..•.••• 14 Economic history and growth stage generalizations •• 15 Dual-economy models •••••••.••.• 16 THE MODELS: A HE URIS TIC EXPOS IT ION •.•.••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 19 The decentralized model............................................ 19 The centralized model.............................................. 28 THE DECENTRALIZED MODEL. • • . • . • • . • . • . • . • • . • • . • • • • • • . • • . • • • • . • • . • • • • • • • 2 9 The Welfare Function............................................... 31 The Production Functions........................................... 35 Government Expenditure and SOC. • • • • . • • • • • • • • • • • . • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • 3 7 Page FACTOR AVAILABILITIES. • • . • • • • • . • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • . • • • • . • • • • • • • • • • • • • . 40 Land................................................................ 40 Labor and wage rates. • • • • . • • • • • • • • . • • • • • • • • • • . • • . • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • 40 Manufactured inputs . ......... , . 41 Capital stocks...................................................... 41 INCOME DISTRIBUTION AND FLOWS. • • • • . • • • • . • • • • . • • • • • • • • . • . • • • • . • • • • • • . 42 Subsistence sector.................................................. 43 Commercial agriculture.............................................. 44 Manufacturing and capital goods sectors ••••......•••..•••••.•••••... 44 Labor income and consumption restraints .•••..•••••••.••••••••••.•••• 46 PRIVATE INVESTMENT....................................................... 47 WAGE, PRICE AND OUTPUT DETERMINATION. • • • • • • . • • . • • . • . • • • • . • • • . • . • . • • 50 A digression on supply response in agriculture .•••.....•..••.•...... 56 Finite Planning Horizons and Post-plan Considerations ••••.•••••.•••• 59 OPTIMIZATION OF THE DECENTRALIZED MODEL .•.••...••••....••.•••.•••••...••. 61 The Lagrangean Function. • • . • • . • . • • • . • • • . • . • • • • . • • • . • • • . • . • • . 61 The First-Order Conditions.......................................... 63 SOC Investment in the Subsistence Sector ...•••..•..•••••••••••••..•• 67 Alternative Investment Opportunities................................ 70 THE CENTRALIZED MODEL. • . • • • • • • • . • • • • • • • . • . • • . • • • • • • • • • • • . • • • . • • • • • • • . • • 7 2 A Reformulation of the Model........................................ 72 The First-Order Conditions.......................................... 75 SOC Accumulation .•.•.•••••.•••.••••.••.•..•••••...•••.•.•••.•....••. 79 Some simplifying assumptions and notation .••••••.••.••••.••••••••.•• 81 Relaxing the simplifying assumptions................................ 84 The significance of At and Bt....................................... 85 Economic considerations influencing the desirability of investing in subsistence versus commercial SOC •••••••.•••••.••••.• 90 Page PRIVATE CAPITAL ACCUMULATION............................................ 93 The relative social desirability of investment alternatives. 93 Economic factors affec~ing private investment •..•••••.••••••.•••.•• 94 The share of capital ...........·.........................•.......... 95 Social valuation of outputs •••.•••••••.•••.••.•••.•.•.••••••••••••• 96 The rate of technical change and SOC accumulation. 98 Changes in terms of trade . ............. ........................... 99 PRIVATE INVESTMENT VERSUS SOC ACCUMULATION .• ............................ 99 AN ANALYSIS OF THE IMPACT OF FOREIGN AID •. .............................. 101 Grants of Food to Consumers. • . • . • . • • • • • . • • • . • • • • • • • • . • • • • • • 102 Food Aid for Work Projects or Wages in Kind •. ...................... 105 Market Sales of Food.. • . 106 Comparisons Among the Three Distribution Alternatives .. 109 Commodity Aid in General .••••••••.•.••.•.••.• . .. 112 REFERENCES . • • • • . • • • • . • • • . • • . • . • . • . • . • . • • . • • • • . • • . • . • • • • . • • . • . • • • 113 8UMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS The over-all purpose of this study is to investigate the inter-relation­ ships between the agricultural and nonagricultural sectors during the process of economic development, with some particular attention to the effects of food aid. The major portion of the study is devoted to a theoretical analysis of these intersectoral relationships. A five-sector, optimizing model of an underdeveloped, dual economy is formulated and extensively analyzed. The five sectors include subsistence or traditional agriculture, commercial agricultur~ manufacturing goods production, capital goods production, and a government sector. Three products are produced: agricultural goods, which can only be consumed, manufacturing goods which can either be consumed or used as non­ durable factors of production, and capital goods, which can only be used as durable factors of production. The factors of production included in the model are land, labor, capital, and manufactured inputs. Production in the traditional agricultural sector requires land, labor, and manufactured inputs; production in the commercial agricultural sector requires capital goods in addition to the factors employed in the subsistence sector. Manufactured goods and capital goods production do not require land as an input and employ only labor, manufactured inputs, and capital as factors. Labor is assumed to be employed at a constant wage rate (measured in terms of manufactured goods) in the commercial agricultural sector, the manufacturing goods sector, and the capital goods sector. Any labor that cannot earn its marginal value productivity in these three sectors is employed in the subsistence sector at a lower wage rate. ii Two formulations of the model are considered, a centralized and a de­ centralized model, with the role of the government being the principal difference between the two models. In the first formulation, the government has control over four investment alternatives. These four alternatives are investment in social overhead capital in either the subsistence or commercial agricultural sectors and investment in "private" capital in either the manu­ facturing or the capital goods sectors. In the second formulation, the government's role is expanded considerably to include control over the allo­ cation of private investment funds as well as public tax revenue. These two versions of the model are extensively analyzed in an attempt to discern the economic and physical characteristics of an economy that would tend to make it socially desirable to develop agriculture relative to industr~ and vice versa. Similarly, an attempt is made to delineate the conditions under which food aid has the most positive effect on agricultural development, employment and consumer welfare. A detailed descriptive summary of the con­ clusions of the study follow. 1. Public investment in subsistence agriculture. In an economy with a given resource base, capital stock, level of technology, and wage-price configuration, the proportion of the labor force engaged in subsistence em­ ployment will increase as the size
Recommended publications
  • Whyalla and EP Heavy Industry Cluster Summary Background
    Whyalla and EP Heavy Industry Cluster Summary Background: . The Heavy Industry Cluster project was initiated and developed by RDAWEP, mid 2015 in response to a need for action to address poor operating conditions experienced by major businesses operating in Whyalla and Eyre Peninsula and their supply chains . The project objective is to support growth and sustainability of businesses operating in the Whyalla and Eyre Peninsula region which are themselves either a heavy manufacturing business or operate as part of a heavy industry supply chain . The cluster is industry led and chaired by Theuns Victor, GM OneSteel/Arrium Steelworks . Consists of a core leadership of 9 CEO’s of major regional heavy industry businesses . Includes CEO level participation from the Whyalla Council, RDAWEP and Deputy CEO of DSD . There is engagement with an additional 52 Supply chain companies Future direction for the next 12 months includes work to progress three specific areas of focus: 1. New opportunities Identify, pursue and promote new opportunities for Whyalla and regional business, including Defence and other major projects; 1.1 Defence Projects, including Access and Accreditation 1.2 Collective Bidding, How to structure and market to enable joint bids for new opportunities 1.3 Other opportunities/projects for Whyalla including mining, resource processing and renewable energy 2. Training and Workforce development/Trade skill sets 2.1 Building capability for defence and heavy industry projects with vocational training and industry placement 3. Ultra High Speed Internet 3.1 Connecting Whyalla to AARnet, very high speed broadband, similar to Northern Adelaide Gig City concept Other initiatives in progress or that will be progressed: .
    [Show full text]
  • The Underground Economy and Carbon Dioxide (CO2) Emissions in China
    sustainability Article The Underground Economy and Carbon Dioxide (CO2) Emissions in China Zhimin Zhou Lingnan (University) College, Sun Yat-Sen University, Guangzhou 510275, China; [email protected]; Tel.: +86-1592-6342-100 Received: 21 April 2019; Accepted: 9 May 2019; Published: 16 May 2019 Abstract: China aims to reduce carbon dioxide (CO2) intensity by 40–45% compared to its level in 2005 by 2020. The underground economy accounts for a significant proportion of China’s economy, but is not included in official statistics. Therefore, the nexus of CO2 and the underground economy in China is worthy of exploration. To this end, this paper identifies the extent to which the underground economy affects CO2 emissions through the panel data of 30 provinces in China from 1998 to 2016. Many studies have focused on the quantification of the relationship between CO2 emissions and economic development. However, the insights provided by those studies have generally ignored the underground economy. With full consideration of the scale of the underground economy, this research concludes that similar to previous studies, the inversely N-shaped environmental Kuznets curve (EKC) still holds for the income-CO2 nexus in China. Furthermore, a threshold regression analysis shows that the structural and technological effects are environment-beneficial and drive the EKC downward by their threshold effects. The empirical techniques in this paper can also be applied for similar research on other emerging economies that are confronted with the difficulties of achieving sustainable development. Keywords: carbon emissions; informal economy; EKC; industry structural effects; technological effects 1. Introduction During the past few decades, climate change has been a challenging problem all over the world [1].
    [Show full text]
  • How Important Are Dual Economy Effects for Aggregate Productivity?
    How Important are Dual Economy Effects for Aggregate Productivity? Dietrich Vollratha University of Houston Abstract: This paper brings together development accounting techniques and the dual economy model to address the role that factor markets have in creating variation in aggregate total factor productivity (TFP).Developmentaccountingresearchhasshownthatmuchofthevariationinincomeacrosscountries can be attributed to differences in TFP. The dual economy model suggests that aggregate productivity is depressed by having too many factors to low productivity work in agriculture. Data show large differences in marginal products of similar factors within many developing countries, offering prima facie evidence of this misallocation. Using a simple two-sector decomposition of the economy, this article estimates the role of these misallocations in accounting for the cross-country income distribution. A key contribution is the ability to bring sector specific data on human and physical capital stocks to the analysis. Variation across countries in the degree of misallocation is shown to account for 30 — 40% of the variation in income per capita, and up to 80% of the variation in aggregate TFP. JEL Codes: O1, O4, Q1 Keywords: Resource allocation; Labor allocation; Dual economy; Income distribution; Factor markets; TFP a) I’d like to thank Francesco Caselli, Areendam Chanda, Carl-Johan Dalgaard, Jim Feyrer, Oded Galor, Doug Gollin, Vernon Henderson, Peter Howitt, Mike Jerzmanowksi, Omer Moav, Malhar Nabar, Jonathan Temple, David Weil, and an anonymous referee for helpful comments and advice. In addition, the participants at the Brown Macroeconomics Seminar, Northeast Universities Development Conference and Brown Macro Lunches were very helpful. All errors are, of course, my own. Department of Economics, 201C McElhinney Hall, Houston, TX 77204 [email protected] 1 1Introduction One of the most persistent relationships in economic development is the inverse one between income and agriculture, seen here in figure 1.
    [Show full text]
  • CHAPTER 2 Patterns of Growth in Dual Economies: Challenges of Development in the 21St Century
    CHAPTER 2 Patterns of Growth in Dual Economies: Challenges of Development in the 21st Century Literature regarding the basics of classical development emphasizes on the relationship between economic growth and changes in production struc- ture. It also allocates special properties to industry, and more specifically to the ability of industrialization to create and combine a series of comple- mentarities, scale properties, and external economies to generate a sustain- able cycle of resource mobilization, increasing productivity, rising demand, income, and economic growth. Changes in the global economy have contributed to the renewed discussions on the role of structural transformation in achieving sustained economic growth and development. The catch-up failure of many devel- oping regions, which are often associated with “traps” and downturns (i.e., low-development traps, middle-income traps, and premature deindustrial- ization); the end of windfall export gains led by the commodity price boom in 2000s; and the continued vulnerability of many developing regions to external shocks have also added to this discussion (UNCTAD, 2016). The dual relationship between climate change and development serves as yet another important factor. On one hand, the effects of climate change create serious challenges to development; however, on the other hand, pri- oritization of economic growth and development has had major conse- quences on climate change and vulnerability. In its basic form, emission control and effective mitigation require not only the transformation of production systems but also the transformation of energy systems, includ- ing moving away from traditional high-carbon energy sources (a phase-out of coal-fueled power plants), increasing fuel efficiency, deploying advanced renewable technologies, and implementing measures to increase energy efficiency IEA,( 2008).
    [Show full text]
  • Cubanonomics: Mixed Economy in Cuba During the Special Period BRENDAN C. DOLAN
    Cubanonomics: Mixed Economy in Cuba during the Special Period BRENDAN C. DOLAN Fidel Castro is a man of many words. No other political figure in modern history has spoken more on the public record, varying the scope of his oration from short interviews to twelve hour lectures on the state of Cuban society. Starting in 1959, his ideas flooded Cuban society and provided a code of social expectations for all to obey. Cubans listened patiently, and over time enjoyed the fruits of an egalitarian socialist system: food, shelter, education and medicine for all. By the early 1980s, Castro had constructed a centrally planned economy and an economically favorable partnership with the Soviet Union. In 1989, however, the dissolution of the Soviet Union crippled the Cuban economy and forced millions of Cubans into poverty, resulting in widespread hunger and unemployment. Faced with the threat of an economic meltdown that could end his regime, Castro looked inward for ways to revive the Cuban economy. Though previously condemning and imprisoning Cubans illegally possessing black market dollars, Castro suddenly regarded these dollar holders as the key to his regime’s survival. This hard currency was crucial to restoring the national economy, and though its legalization would undermine his socialist, anti-American ideology, Castro saw no other option. In 1993, he decriminalized the possession of U.S. dollars and established state-run dollar stores to channel dollars to the government. Castro legalized self-employment, decentralized the agricultural sector and boosted Cuba’s tourist industry. Though they aided in reviving the national economy, these policy changes transformed the socioeconomic structure of Cuban society, creating a mixed economy that required Cubans to embrace certain market principles outside of socialist doctrine.
    [Show full text]
  • The Dynamics of Industrial Growth In
    The Dynamicsof Industrial Growth in the Old Northwest 1830-70:An InterdisciplinaryApproach Margaret Walsh Department of History, University of Birmingham and University of Illinois, Chicago Circle Historians have customarily talked about the economic devel- opment of the Old Northwest in the middle years of the 19th cen- tury within an agrarianframework. 1 Thoughthe Jeffersonianimage has been modernized and modified by studies of the rapid growth of commercial farming, of the national importance of mineral and for- est resources, and of urban frontiers, little systematic attention has yet been given to the growth of a manufacturing sector. Pre- sumablywestern industrial enterpriseswere either nonexistentor unimportant. A similar conclusion about the insignificance of manufactur- ing in the Old Northwest in the period 1830-70 could be reached from a different approach -- namely an analysis of the process of American industrialization. Throughout both the customary and "new" discussions of the timing, location, and causes of indus- trial growth, attention has been focused on the Northeastern States. Presumably cotton textiles, heavy goods, or the railroad provided the keys to understanding the rise of the factory system somewhere between 1815 and 1850. But neither the West nor the Southwas destined to playa noteworthypart in the modernization of the economy. Given this disinterest in or lack of information on western manufacturing in a period in which the American economy was under- going rapid change, some quantitative evidence must first be pro- duced to show that there was an industrial sector which fulfilled a significant function in both regional and national development. Then it is possible to discuss alternative approaches to analyzing the dynamics of growth before suggesting a new synthesis.
    [Show full text]
  • North East of England
    Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development Directorate for Education Education Management and Infrastructure Division Programme on Institutional Management of Higher Education (IMHE) Supporting the Contribution of Higher Education Institutions to Regional Development Peer Review Report: North East of England Chris Duke, Robert Hassink, James Powell and Jaana Puukka January 2006 The views expressed are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the OECD or its Member Countries. 1 This Peer Review Report is based on the review visit to the North East of England in October 2005, the regional Self-Evaluation Report, and other background material. As a result, the report reflects the situation up to that period. The preparation and completion of this report would not have been possible without the support of very many people and organisations. OECD/IMHE and the Peer Review Team for the North East of England wish to acknowledge the substantial contribution of the region, particularly through its Coordinator, the authors of the Self-Evaluation Report, and its Regional Steering Group. 2 TABLE OF CONTENTS PREFACE...................................................................................................................................... 5 ABBREVIATIONS AND ACRONYMS...................................................................................... 7 1. INTRODUCTION..................................................................................................................... 9 1.1 Evaluation Context and Approach
    [Show full text]
  • MEAT SOURCING Engaging Qsrs on Climate and Water Risks to Protein Supply Chains
    GLOBAL INVESTOR ENGAGEMENT ON MEAT SOURCING Engaging QSRs on climate and water risks to protein supply chains PROGRESS BRIEFING • APRIL 2021 1 Executive summary The Global Investor Engagement on Meat However, progress towards mitigating risks related Sourcing, initiated in 2019, consists of dialogues to water scarcity and pollution has been limited. between six of the largest quick-service restaurant In addition, only two of the six companies have (QSR) brands and institutional investors with over disclosed plans to conduct a 2°C scenario analysis, a $11 trillion in combined assets. Investors have urged key recommendation of the Task Force on Climate- the QSRs to analyse and reduce their vulnerability Related Financial Disclosures (TCFD). While the to the impacts of climate change, water scarcity, progress to date is encouraging, there are critical and pervasive threats to water quality driven by elements yet to be addressed around climate and animal protein production. water-related financial risks. Companies have made notable progress in addressing these concerns. All six target companies have now publicly stated they will set or have already set global GHG reduction targets. Five of the six QSRs have now set or committed to setting emissions reduction targets approved by the Science-Based Targets initiative (SBTi) that would align their businesses with the Paris Agreement’s goal to limit global temperature rises to well below 2°C. 2 Contents The case for engagement 4 Trends in company performance 6 Board oversight and ESG risk management
    [Show full text]
  • Labor Productivity and Energy Use in a Three Sector Model: an Application to Egypt
    DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES Labor productivity and energy use in a three sector model: An application to Egypt Rudiger von Arnim and Codrina Rada Working Paper No: 2011-06 University of Utah Department of Economics 260 S. Central Campus Dr., Rm. 343 Tel: (801) 581-7481 Fax: (801) 585-5649 http://www.econ.utah.edu Labor productivity and energy use in a three sector model: An application to Egypt ∗ Rudiger von Arnim Codrina Rada Assistant Professor Assistant Professor Department of Economics, University of Utah Department of Economics, University of Utah [email protected] [email protected] Abstract This paper presents a model of a developing economy with three sectors---a modern sector producing manufactures and services, a traditional sector producing agricultural goods, and a third sector providing energy. Modern and energy sector are assumed to be demand--constrained; the agricultural sector is supply--constrained. Simulation exercises confirm insights of existing theory on structural heterogeneity: A price--clearing agricultural sector can impose an inflationary barrier on growth. Further, emphasis is placed on the sources of productivity growth. Specifically, higher energy intensity rather than increases in energy productivity enable labor productivity growth, with the attendant complications for 'green growth.' Keywords: Structural heterogeneity, Multi-sector model, Energy use JEL Classification: O41, Q43, C63 ∗ Corresponding author. Labor productivity and energy use in a three sector model: An application to Egypt Rudiger von Arnim∗ Codrina Rada† February 14, 2011 Abstract This paper presents a model of a developing economy with three sectors—a modern sector producing manufactures and services, a traditional sector producing agricultural goods, and a third sector providing energy.
    [Show full text]
  • Engineering / Builders Risk at a Glance
    ALLIANZ GLOBAL CORPORATE & SPECIALTY® ENGINEERING / BUILDERS RISK AT A GLANCE SALES APPETITE THE BUSINESS WE WRITE Coverage Capacity Customers Direct Physical Loss or Damage Course of Construction •Building & Construction / Infrastructure Projects Optional Projects •Power & Utilities Physical Damage coverage can be extended to include –Erection All Risk (EAR) • Heavy Civils loss of income on behalf of a project owner (Delay in –Contractors All Risk (CAR) •Heavy Industry Start-up – DSU / Advanced Loss of Profit – ALOP) • Mining •Oil & Gas Direct Physical Loss or Damage Operational Risk • Power Business (all types of power plants, Optional – Power Business Segment including renewables) Physical Damage coverage can be extended to include – Mining Business Segment • Mining Business loss of income on behalf of the plant owner – Civil Engineering Completed • Bridges, roads etc. Risks (CECR) SAMPLE WINS Coverage Total Insured Value Risk Type Course of Construction $1.9 bn Airport Terminal Course of Construction $855 mn Combined Cycle Power Plant Course of Construction $1.65 bn Commercial / Residential Building Course of Construction $930 mn Grain Terminal Course of Construction $2.3 bn Open-pit Mine Operational All Risk $7.5 bn Operational Power Program Course of Construction $876 mn Petrochemical Plant agcs.allianz.com STANDARD & POOR‘S AA A.M. BEST A+ FOR MORE INFORMATION PLEASE CONTACT: TIM COOK Regional Head of Engineering, North America Tel: +1.212.823.8972 [email protected] CONTRACTORS ALL RISK / ERECTION ALL RISK / CIVIL ENGINEERING
    [Show full text]
  • Analysis and Comparison of Overall Gdp Depending Only on Three Major Sectors in Indian Economy
    © 2019 CJBM October - December 2019, Volume1, Issue 1 www.cms.ac.in/journals-cms.php ____________________________________________________________________ ANALYSIS AND COMPARISON OF OVERALL GDP DEPENDING ONLY ON THREE MAJOR SECTORS IN INDIAN ECONOMY Dr. Konda Hari Prasad Reddy Associate Professor, Department of Management Centre for Management Studies, Jain University Lalbagh Road, Bengaluru – 560027 ____________________________________________________________________ ABSTRACT Indian economy is characterized by a diverse mix of economic activities related to agricultural sector, industrial sector and service sector. Alternatively, from an economic point view, the Indian economy can be broadly decomposed into three major sectors, namely, primary sector, secondary sector and tertiary sector that are more commonly known as agricultural sector, industrial sector and service sector respectively. The adoption of New Economic Policy in 1991 witnessed a paradigm shift in Indian economy as it diluted the mixed economy model and opened the Indian economy to the world. Economic liberalization measures including industrial deregulation, privatization of state-owned enterprises and reduced controls on foreign trade and investment served to accelerate country’s economic growth. The present research study is aimed at analyzing and comparing the data with regard to the contribution of the major sectors of Indian economy (i.e. agricultural sector, industrial sector and service sector) in the overall GDP of the country during the period 1990-91 to 2009-10. The concerned GDP data have been retrieved from https://data.gov.in (Open Government Data Platform India). Moreover, for drawing useful inferences from the available secondary data, the statistical tools and tests like correlation analysis, analysis of variance and F-test have been used.
    [Show full text]
  • THE QUESTION of AGRICULTURAL COOPERATION” ( SPEECH, JULY 31, 1955) by Mao Zedong
    Primary Source Document with Questions (DBQs) “ THE QUESTION OF AGRICULTURAL COOPERATION” ( SPEECH, JULY 31, 1955) By Mao Zedong Introduction In the early 1950s, China chose to model its socialist economy after that of the Soviet Union. The Soviet model called for capital-intensive development of heavy industry, with the capital to be generated from the agricultural sector of the economy. The state would purchase grain from the farmers at low prices and sell it, both at home and on the export market, at high prices. In practice, agricultural production did not increase fast enough to generate the amount of capital required to build up China’s industry according to plan. Mao Zedong (1893-1976) decided that the answer was to reorganize Chinese agriculture by pushing through a program of cooperativization (or collectivization) that would bring China’s small farmers, their small plots of land, and their limited draught animals, tools, and machinery together into larger and, presumably, more efficient cooperatives. The farmers put up resistance, mostly in the form of passive resistance, lack of cooperation, and a tendency to eat animals that were scheduled for cooperativization. Many of the Communist Party leaders wanted to proceed slowly with cooperativization. Mao, however, had his own view of developments in the countryside, which he expressed in this speech of July 31, 1955. Document Excerpts with Questions (Longer selection follows this section) From Sources of Chinese Tradition: From 1600 Through the Twentieth Century, compiled by Wm. Theodore de Bary and Richard Lufrano, 2nd ed., vol. 2 (New York: Columbia University Press, 2000), 458-459.
    [Show full text]