<<

Twixt and . Town and Country in the Medieval Economy of the Southern from the 6th to the 12th century* Jean-Pierre Devroey, Université libre de Bruxelles

Henri Pirenne, writing in the early 20th century in what was ultimately to become his monumental Histoire de Belgique, sketched the basic outlines of the development of our part of Europe. Belgian history cannot be conceived of and described as if the world ends at its boundaries. is a ‘microcosm of Western Europe (...). The Scheldt and Meuse basins have not only served as the cockpits of Europe: they were also the place where ideas were traded between the Latin and German world (...), it was their ports which for centuries were the ‘entrepôts’ for merchandise from both North and South’1. Opposed to geographical and linguistic determinism, Pirenne was convinced that the ‘Belgian nation’ (‘a land of contrasts, a country lacking natural frontiers, where two languages are spoken’), was born of a political, economic, and cultural community, forged from the urban freedoms, which had grown up on the banks of the Meuse and Scheldt. By the end of the , the Burgundian ‘State’ was a step on the road, which would inevitably lead to the establishment of 19th century Belgium. Although his finalistic vision of the Belgian nation is now seen as belonging to another age, Pirenne's thesis continues to be the most imaginative and powerful to be developed in the 20th century about medieval European history and its Belgian microcosm2. How can we explain the extraordinary blooming of economy and urban society in the Southern Netherlands during the Middle Ages? What was the basis of this growth and how quickly did it proceed? Could it have started in 7th century with the birth of new flows of trade in Northwest Europe, or in the 9th century with the Carolingian renaissance, or perhaps in the 11th century with the rebirth of the towns? Did this growth come from outside - a part of the reestablishment of large-scale trading in the 10th and 11th centuries - or was it internal, pushed by the dynamism of the countryside, the appearance, followed by control by the non-producing classes, of the agricultural surpluses so essential to urban life? Who helped to create this growth: the great merchants - entrepreneurs and capitalists; the king or the Carolingian monks who controlled the great estates; or the peasants who pioneered new lands? The answers suggested by Pirenne were inspired by the fact that he was a historian committed to a particular vision, ‘a child of his times, nationalist, liberal, bourgeois and optimistic (...), who saw history as a record of progress, driven by

* Originally published as ‘Twixt Meuse and Scheldt: Town and Country in the Medieval Economy of the Southern Netherlands from the Sixth to the Twelfth Century’, The Fascinating Faces of : Through Art and Society, Lisbon, 1998, pp. 48-76, © Jean-Pierre Devroey. Translated from French by Van Lokeren, edited by Prof. dr. A. Verhulst. The original text has been slightly corrected for the on- line version. This paper has been published one year before Verhulst’s Rise of Cities in North-West Europe (Cambridge, 1999), with a different view on relations between urban and rural phenomenon. Three years later, Verhulst was taking up the idea of a ‘long slow rise’ of the European economy in his last book, The Carolingian Economy (Cambridge, 2002). 1 Pirenne 1900. 2 Verhulst 1986.

1 urban development, trade and capitalism’3. However, modern research tends to put the accent on the dynamism of the relationship between town and countryside since the and the patent role in economic development played by figures from the religious and political worlds. The creation of wealth is essential for the production of art and culture. The accumulation of capital was made possible by the transfer of economic surpluses from the base to the centres of control, from the country to the town, from the peasant, the subsistence producer, to the consumer, nobleman or burgess. The countryside and its economy are the essential preconditions for the development of Europe. Mohammed and The celebrated question of Mohammed and Charlemagne stresses continuity between the Ancient World and the Middle Ages4. Historians of Church and State nowadays tend to speak more of a transition when referring to the passage from late Antiquity to the successor states such as the Merovingian kingdoms of our regions. For Pirenne the turning point in the development of the West was not the Germanic invasions of the 5th century, but came later, in the early 7th century with the arrival of Islam, which brought an end to the economy of the Mediterranean world. For Carlo Cipolla and Roberto Lopez, the West went through a long period of depression, lasting almost a thousand years, between the crisis of the Late Empire and the beginnings of the trading revolution of the 12th century5. The first signs of economic recovery were not felt before the 10th century, which must be seen as the inflection point in a long economic cycle starting in the 3rd century. We now know that the decline of Mediterranean commerce started in the middle of the 4th century and reached an absolute low point in about 7006. However, this did not lead to a general contraction of the economy, a return to the countryside and the disappearance of town life between the 7th century and the year one thousand. What really happened was that the centre of economic gravity gradually moved away from the Mediterranean to the northwest of Europe7. The routes and circuits, venues, materials, and people involved in trade changed profoundly. In the heart of the Frankish world, between the Loire and the Rhine, the independent merchant was squeezed out to make way for agents of the king and church. The abbeys of Northern Gaul slowly abandoned the arduous transport ventures, which took them south of the Loire, where they could buy valuable merchandise such as olive oil, wax, fish and spices. From then on their involvement in the trading economy seems to have been primarily motivated by the desire to sell the agricultural surplus of their estates to best advantage, be it at fairs (wine at the big fairs held at Saint-Denis near ), town and country markets, in the ancient river ports of or and at the new emporia, such as Quentovic, on the mouth of the Canche, or , on the confluence of the Rhine and the Lek8. The bulk of trade in northwest

3 Verhulst 1986. 4 Pirenne 1937. 5 Cipolla 1956; Lopez 1974. 6 Claude 1985, Handel. 7 Claude 1985, Aspekte; Verhulst 1993. 8 Devroey 1984.

2 Europe did not consist of luxury goods, but rather of food products (cereals, wine and salt), and other basic commodities (textiles, wood and minerals) and the output of craft workshops (millstones and grindstones from the Eifel region, pottery from Badorf, Rhenish glassware, Frankish weapons, ‘Frisian’ and Frankish linen, etc.). This new start, sustained as it was by demographic and agricultural growth, coincided with the military expansion of the Frankish kingdom and the colonization of land to the north and east, including , Saxony, and , an unprecedented campaign of evangelization and territorial organization, and the installation between the Rhine and the Loire of the structures of the great estate system. Starting in the 7th century, the West appears to have entered an extended cycle of development, culminating in the 13th century, in which various factors united to produce effects such as demographic growth, diffusion of new technologies, changes in the organization of work, the rebirth of trade, the flowering of urban life. The role of agri- culture in this development cannot be denied! The Countryside in the Early Middle Ages It is impossible to ignore the evidence - in the Middle Ages nine out of ten people were peasants. The historian has every reason to be modest. Despite the advances in our knowledge contributed by archaeologists, and the new disciplines devoted to the study of ancient environments (palynology, paleopathology, paleoclimatology, etc.), we are still far from being able to provide an explanation or even a general picture of the development of the natural environment between the 3rd and the 11th centuries. Nonetheless it seems that we are now able to speak of two very different periods in the general environment in Western Europe, that are characterized by a series of natural and human factors: climate, health, nutrition and demographic change. Even so it is extremely difficult to measure their impact in regional terms. Starting with the crisis in the Late Empire, the European climate became slowly worse, turning colder and moister. In all likelihood this trend bottomed out in the 6th century, with a fall in mean temperatures of 1.5°C. Written sources (such as the Histoire des Francs of Gregory of Tours) and archaeological findings suggest that there may have been a disastrous conjunction of ecological factors in the 6th century, marked by a series of natural calamities including famine, floods, epidemics (two pandemics: the Justinian plague, which started in 541 and a plague of smallpox starting in 570) which hit a population already weakened by malnutrition. It is likely that the population fell and that certain regions were depopulated. The transition from the Ancient World to the Middle Ages left traces in both the natural and human landscape the extent of which historians have long wondered at. These include the abandonment of the large farm units of the Romans, the movement of populations and their division into the romance and germanic groups. There was a generalized discontinuity in the coastal region between the Aa and the Scheldt-Maas-Rhine delta, caused by a large incursion by the sea in the 3rd century. Furthermore forests grew larger and the acreage of land under cultivation fell between the 3rd and the 5th centuries, while herding developed at the expense of crop growing. There were also considerable regional differences. The continuity of occupation of the most populous areas in Antiquity and the Early Middle Ages, the region between the Scheldt and the Dender and the /Haspengouw area, was very great, as can be seen from the survival of Roman names. The end of Antiquity was in particular marked by a movement from the plateaux to the valleys, a change in the appearance of agricultural units, with the abandonment of the Roman

3 ‘colonial’ villae and a style of agriculture formerly oriented to supplying the towns and garrisons of the Rhenish limes. Other features were the appearance of smaller country farms, mainly run as family units, and a decline in the area of land under cultivation. These lands continued to be used for agriculture, although marginal land with heavier or poorer soils became derelict, often until the clearances of the 11th and 13th centuries. The typical Merovingian countryside was a habitat containing scattered hamlets, with numerous isolated fields separated by uncultivated lands. Elsewhere, where stock breeding predominated, the habitat, situated in clearings in the heart of the forest, could have been semi-permanent. Germanic toponyms ending in -sali, -sele, -zelles, which were used for such places mostly disappeared after the 10th century, with the clearance of the forest in which this kind of settlement was situated9. New archaeological techniques have now made it possible to demonstrate the existence of quantitative and qualitative variations in the plant environment (advance of forests, clearances). During the first thousand years of the Christian era the geography of cereal crops underwent considerable changes, although it settled down after the year one thousand. These changes were marked by the appearance in the 4th century of cultivated cereal crops, which were new to Western Europe, such as rye and oats. They spread slowly at first, a process which speeded up in the 7th century and really took off in the 10th century. That there was a slow but fundamental change in the geographical distribution of cereal cropping in the Middle Ages10 cannot be disputed. Prior to the 9th century the wheat variety commonly cultivated was a ‘dressed’ wheat, that is the kernel was attached to the husk. Known as spelt it was dominant on the seigniorial estates of the region as well as on the royal lands in the area until about 800; while it was used on the Corbie abbey lands prior to 826; and on the lands of the Abbey of Lobbes in 868-869, between the Sambre and the Meuse, the area, and Southwest Brabant. Peasant farms often grew a wider variety of crops, with cereals (wheat, rye, barley), vegetables and fibrous plants (hops and flax), stock farming (poultry, pigs, and sheep), as well as engaging in various craft activities such as the production of items and objects in wood, cloth and fabrics, and even semi-industrial activities such as iron ore extraction near St. Hubert, pig- iron production and iron utensils. Textile production merits special consideration. Flax and hemp are demanding and labour intensive crops, and were produced chiefly by peasant farmers. Textile production was in part the work of collective workshops11, where specialized workers or women from the estate gathered to spin, weave, and make clothes as well as in the royal villae (for example around 800 in Annappes) or in monastic centres (Saint-Bertin), by the domestics of the great lay houses of the 10th century, like the ‘...gynaeceum of Count Henry established in the portus of Ename in 1014’12. Nonetheless the bulk of textile production was the work of the family, as can be seen from the distribution of archaeological finds relating to textile activities at Early Middle Age sites. Fabrics were woven on vertical looms built in a ‘weaving shed’ (a single excavated room of 6 to 8 m²) located within the walls of the main

9 Verhulst 1990, Slavery; Verhulst 1990, Rurale. 10 Devroey 1990. 11 Herlihy 1990. 12 Vita Sancti Macharii.

4 residence13. In the 9th century, textile production was an entirely female activity, and included washing and shearing the sheep before carding and spinning the wool; picking and threshing the flax before rotting it and preparing it for spinning. Flax in the form of seeds or tow was the typical rent for free peasants, just as the production of linen cloth or woollen fabric was the rent for serfs14. Cloth and fabric were an integral part of the trade between estates. The free and larger manses (holdings) had also to breed oxen as draft animals. The dominant cereal on the demesne land (land farmed directly by the great landlord) was spelt, together with barley and oats, whereas poorer soils would be sown with barley and oats. Oats were the sole crop in the harsher conditions of the , where it was associated with rye and barley. Polyptychs from the 9th century show three changes. As of the 10th century there was a general decline in spelt in favour of naked cereals such as wheat and rye. The rise of wheat, which first came to demesne lands in the 10th century and prevailed in the 11th bears witness to a seigniorial choice for higher prices and yields. The homelier nature of rye and oats meant that they played a leading role in the cerealization15 of Europe in the Middle Ages, by permitting the cultivation of cereal crops on land which had hitherto been ignored. Starting in the 8th century, the climate became steadily warmer, reaching a peak in the 11th century, with average temperatures of between 1.5 and 2°C higher than the mean (4° higher in sub-Arctic regions - leading the Scandinavian navigators who first reached North America to call the new territories ‘Greenland’ and ‘Vin(e)land’). On the other hand the Merovingian period seems to have been one of widespread malnutrition, as the archaeological evidence indicates a high incidence of rickets and diseases due to dietary deficiencies. Studies of human bones seem to indicate that as the 7th century gave way to the 8th there was a general decline in chronic malnutrition. Paradoxically, famine becomes more frequently reported (64 between the 8th and 11th centuries, or an average of one famine every six or seven years). Nonetheless, we must be careful how we interpret such data. Once a distinction is made between the ‘major famines’ of a cyclical nature, the shortages arising in transitional periods, and localized famines, we see that the number of large-scale famines dwindled in the 10th century and started to rise again during the 11th. Is the recurrence of generalized famine proof that growth had stopped? Should we not consider them more as ‘incidental occurrences, as the heavy price the peasantry had to pay to guarantee expansion’16. The picture we see is of population growth progressing in a saw tooth curve. Whereas malnutrition has disastrous effects on the general health of the population in the long term, famine, if it eliminates the weak, spurs the survivors to produce more. The study of demographic data from Carolingian polyptychs (for Champagne and the Paris basin) reveals a pioneering population, relatively young and mobile, sensitive to sudden peaks in the mortality rate, but capable of responding quickly by pushing up birth rates17. Undoubtedly no rapid and generalized rise in the population occurred before the ‘demographic boom’

13 Devroey 1998. 14 Devroey 1998. 15 Abel 1978. 16 Bonnassie 1990. 17 Devroey 1981.

5 of the 11th century. On the other hand there had already been demographic growth in the richest farming areas since the end of the 8th century. It is quite likely that the 18 population doubled in the space of a century . Population densities of 20 to 30 per- sons per km² could well have been reached in the Paris region or on the estates of Saint-Bertin abbey near Saint-Omer19 since the middle of the 9th century. Until the year one thousand the countryside in Northwest Europe therefore displayed a sharp contrast between those regions, which had been densely populated since ancient times, and large underpopulated areas, which were exploited in semi-permanent fashion. This picture of a natural environment of marked contrasts applies particularly well to Flanders. Picardy, its fertile neighbour, exported large quantities of cereals to Flanders in the 13th century, and 75 % of its villages were recorded before the year one thousand. In Flanders, however, such population densities were not attained until the 3rd quarter of the 12th century20. The progressive retreat of the sea meant that salt tolerant vegetation could develop in the coastal region, which had been virtually deserted since the 3rd century. In the 8th century communities of herders were already starting to make use of it. By the 9th century, the crown and various abbeys were operating large dairy farms and sheep ranches in the coastal strip. Away from the coast the earliest land reclamation operations we know of date from the 7th century. The vitality of the countryside is evident from the dense population of some areas of the countryside. Toponymic study in the area reveals early evidence of clearances taking place in the late 7th century. We see an increase th in the Germanic suffixes -rohda, -rodona in the 9 century. It seems that this reclamation of land for agriculture was launched from established agricultural land in the most fertile areas. The large areas which began to be abandoned in the 3rd century were unaffected by this phenomenon. In the 8th century, we see for the first time the Frankish aristocracy and the major abbeys assembling large complexes of arable lands at the heart of the most fertile estates, owned by the crown. These were known as coutures (fr)/kouters (nl)/cultura (lat), and were undoubtedly the result of the regrouping of scattered fields and collective clearances. In the Ghent area, this micro-scale open-field system contrasts with the mixed woods and pastures of the moister lower lying land taken into cultivation in the 13th century. In these areas, Verhulst tells us, there were two contrasting ‘styles’ of organizing the land. The leading characteristic of the one was a collective approach to exploiting the soil, typical of the Early Middle Ages, the other was typified by a sort of agricultural ‘individualism’ unique to Flemish agriculture in the 13th century21. An open landscape was indicative of land exploited as part of a large estate. Open-field farming, already subjected to regular three yearly rotation in the estates of northern France in the 9th century and the performance of the onerous services associated with the feudal tenure system led to the appearance of communal disciplines. The domination of the lord over an area and its inhabitants, who became his ‘men’ and the formulation of a collective system of rights and obligations (ius villae) ended up by giving social and territorial cohesion to the land-holding estate. Clearances and the regrouping of land

18 Toubert 1986. 19 Schwarz 1985; Nicholas 1991. 20 Nicholas 1991. 21 Verhulst 1966; Verhulst 1995, Economics; Verhulst 1995, Landschap.

6 coincided with a profound transformation of the human habitat, which locally was characterized by the abandonment of the hamlets, which had appeared during the preceding period and the regrouping of the population in village communities, centred on a church (in the Ghent area, a kouter corresponded to a village). The regrouping of land thus went hand in hand with the birth of the village, the conversion to Christianity of rural populations and their embedment in new structures of power and land use. From Seine to Rhine the advance of the great estate accompanied these changes. The geographical extent of the Merovingian villa was more restricted. It covered less arable land and much less of the land was in cultivation. Tenancies held by peasants who were dependent on the lord of the estate were less numerous and moreover their connections with the demesne land was only weak. The main revenues were derived from working the land by slaves and revenues paid by tributary peasants. It was during the 7th century that the main 22 elements of what modern historians have called ‘the classic great estate’ began to make their appearance. Its leading characteristic was its bipartite aspect: the demesne land, now larger and redistributed, was worked by services imposed on the ‘manses’ (Germanic: ‘hoba’), accurately defined by a contemporary text as the terra unius familiae, which meant a farm consisting of a house and sufficient land to provide for the needs of a family of peasants, and perhaps also the draught animals they needed for working it. This therefore is the origin of an economic and social cell suited to the conjugal family, a ‘ménage’, as this word comes from the mediaeval Latin word mansionaticum. The peasants, free or otherwise, who occupied these manses had community rights to use the forest and uncultivated land, and could transmit their tenancy to their children while in exchange they had to settle certain charges, whether in money or in kind as well as services determined by the custom of the estate. The most onerous services included working in the fields of the demesne and cartage, which was made available to the lord for the collection, concentration, or transportation to places of trade of the surpluses resulting from the operation of the estate, and which might consist of cereals, wine, wood, textiles and so on. The organization of the villa reflected the demands of cereal production. It implied the installation or permanent settlement on the holdings of a group of specialized farmers, labourers and herdsmen skilled in handling the plough. The ruling echelons of the Frankish world, the King, the aristocracy around him, and the Church played a vital role in the creation and spread of the classic great estate in the numerous lands they held in the heart of the kingdom between the Seine and the Rhine. The rural lords, whose activities were directed towards the cultivation of cereals on light and fertile alluvial soils, had to meet the growing nutritional needs of the State and involve themselves in both regional and interregional trade. The creation of the manse went hand in hand with the growing place of the couple in the social and religious thinking of the Frankish world. The Problem of Rural Growth Modern historians offer two models to explain the growth of the Early Middle Ages. Adriaan Verhulst looks primarily at Northern Europe and the role of seigniorial initiative and the immense success of the large estate. Since Verhulst the estate has

22 Verhulst 1966; Verhulst 1992; Devroey 1993, Domaine.

7 been seen as a dynamic and evolutionary structure that grew progressively from the 6th and 7th centuries. Whereas some historians view it as an outmoded relic of the Ancient world, or as ineffective economic institution and at the very least unrepresentative of the rural world as a whole, the ‘evolutionary model’ of the great estate is founded on the idea that the ‘classic’ estate system was economically efficient, based on the integration and development of peasant farms in the context of a system of large holdings of land. The expansive model of the estate stresses three determining factors: a vigorous reawakening of demand for consumer goods following the restoration of the State, the development of the Church and the reconstitution of the aristocracy; the growing predominance in the countryside of the small dependent farm, suited to the needs of the nuclear family; and the ability of the nobility to manage the population, control their territory and secure the extraction and 23 centralization of farm surpluses . Nonetheless, the classic large estate model is less applicable to many other areas of the Christian West. Although it was imposed in Northern Italy after the Carolingian appropriation of the Kingdom of the Lombards, and in Saxony after Charlemagne's military conquest, it occurred only sporadically in Southern Gaul, where structures of the ‘Merovingian’ type (large farms dependent on slave labour and small farms th 24 belonging to free peasants) persisted until the 10 century . Chris Wickham's comparative approach culminates in the demonstration of the existence of autonomous peasant societies governed mainly by the exigencies of the subsistence economy in regions such as Britanny, Iceland, Catalonia and Central Germany in the Early Middle Ages25. These social groups do not exclude either slavery nor the existence of a certain social stratification, however, they are fundamentally rooted in the dominance of a peasant population which controls its own lands, is more or less autonomous, and where the hierarchies of dependence are fairly lax. The dominant class here consists of village chiefs and notables. The state and the society of the great are distant and have relatively little bearing on the rural world. In certain cases, the military aristocracy dominates from outside, and surpluses have be to exacted from the peasants by force. The existence between the Seine and the Rhine of peasant communities firmly embedded in the structures of the great estate or more autonomous micro-societies of peasants, is revealed solely by the exceptional richness of the historical record: detailed polyptychs here; exceptional series of charters and records of land transactions there. What do these sources still conceal? In the Southern Netherlands the new estate system established itself in the most fertile areas. Elsewhere, particularly in the north of inland Flanders and in the (a large tract of sandy heathland to the north and east of modern ), ‘the small peasant properties, more numerous here, also put up greater resistance’26. Land ownership in such areas remained more often in the hands of the minor nobility or the most prosperous ranks of the peasantry. Even in areas held by the great landowners, for example around Ghent on the land of the Saint Bavo monastery, or

23 Verhulst 1966; Verhulst 1995, Economics; Verhulst 1995, Landschap 24 Bonnassie 1990. 25 Wickham 1992; Wickham 1995. 26 Verhulst 1990, Slavery; Verhulst 1990, Rurale.

8 in the possessions of the abbey of Saint Bertin near Saint-Omer, other structures existed side by side the classic estate. How far were these peasant micro-societies removed from the apparently rigid structures of the bipartite villa? Was the great estate a fixed element of the physical landscape since the 9th century, as we might assume from the polyptychs, or was it merely a matter of boundaries and lines, set out at the dictate of the great hereditary fortunes across a totally different peasant landscape? Might areas of peasant autonomy, areas where the aristocracy closely supervised the people, and yet other areas where the estate originally only came into contact with other peasant structures not have existed simultaneously from region to region? Essentially this is the hypothesis lying at the heart of the models developed by Verhulst, Bonnassie and Wickham. The social and political structures organizing the countryside vary in form and intensity. Nonetheless it is the dynamism of the peasantry, which is the driving force behind growth. The Early Middle Ages thus appear to have laid the foundations in the West for a form of social organization based on the family farming unit, which persisted until the industrial revolution. This development affected the non-free, although their economic and social status had irrevocably evolved beyond slavery when their masters gave them tenancy rights which could be passed on to their children and allowed them to establish a true family household centred around man and wife. The clearances could have allowed freemen to create manses, whereas what happened was that independent peasants elected to contribute their lands to a great landowner in return for tenancy, in order to escape the responsibilities of the freemen (compulsory military service and taxation) and to benefit from the privileges and protection of the new master. All these changes meant that the peasant and his family, with his know-how, his animals and agricultural tools, was the essential figure in rural life. Seen in this way, the demographic and economic ‘growth’ is undoubtedly a reflection of a certain improvement in family welfare27. The emergence of the couple as the basic unit of social life in the countryside had a considerable impact on the condition of men and women and their mutual relations. Life as a couple implies a mutual relationship which cannot be simply reduced to the traditional legal dependence of the woman on the man or to the economic interdependence of the peasant household: there must have been an entire emotional dimension to the relationship as well, which is of course not reflected in our sources. The ‘improvements’ seen in the countryside did not take place suddenly. They were not revolutionary. Rather they were the gradual result of an intensification of agricultural practice. The spread of new techniques was accompanied by institutional and social innovations (transition from slavery to serfdom, the taking up of the rural population into the seigniorial system and its christianization, and the establishment of the family-based farming unit). In the sixties, Georges Duby created a sensation by publishing figures revealing the extremely low yields of cereal farming in the Early Middle Ages28. The measurement of the growth of agricultural yields prior to the 12th century would seem to be very hit and miss, as no direct sources are available to us, and indeed remain rare before the 14th century. The value of generalizing from the extremely low seed yields suggested by Georges Duby, which he deduced from a description of Annappes near Lille has been hotly disputed, and the Annappes

27 Toubert 1986. 28 Duby 1966.

9 figures have been revised upwards29. The most severe criticism came from agricultural experts, who pointed out that ‘...agriculture with a normal yield of 1.6 to 1 would be physically impossible, as it would not produce sufficient energy for it to be sustained’. Nowadays it is estimated that cereal production must have at least doubled between the Carolingian period and the 13th century30. In reality, regardless of the figures put forward, the generalization of yields calculated on the basis of single crops on the seigniorial demesne leads to the assumption that there was only one model of agricultural production, whereas all the evidence is that the Carolingian countryside was divided between family farming, which was more meticulous, more intensive and more varied, and made frequent use of draught animals, and the extensive farming of the large demesnes, worked by gangs of peasants, and where most certainly it was the total volume of the crop which counted. Networks, forms and flows of trade We must now give our attention to the relationship between the country and the town, or rather to the relationship between the rural world, the producer of provisions and supplies and the other parts of society, which it nourished. These relations are expressed in unequal trading structures, which were at the same time expressions of power. Their establishment and consolidation are one of the driving forces in the transformation of mediaeval society. To use a formulation already expressed by Henri Pirenne, the mediaeval town is the point of convergence of a regionally integrated market system, with well-balanced production and distribution systems. However, the goods in the trading network did not necessarily end up in the town as a geographical, economic and social entity. Rather it was the royal palace, the 's castle, and the abbey, which were the centres for the concentration and redistribution of wealth. The networks did not just constitute a physical route, but also a social, economic and political system. It is in this respect that historians draw our attention to the ‘role of the great estate’ and the institutional players in the economic rise of the West between the 8th and the 10th centuries. The development of the towns takes place ‘against the background of the older flourishing of the estates’31. The Meuse valley lies at the centre of the old Carolingian heartland (Herstal, , Aix-la-Chapelle (Aachen), etc.) and it is between the Meuse and the Rhine that the hereditary lands of the Austrasian Mayors of the Palace and their descendants lay. From the 7th to the 9th century the symbol of this prosperity was not the waterborne merchant but rather the country palace and the royal monastery and their structured network of great estates. The estate system steered this dynamism so that it favoured the crown and the grandees by the implementation of a concept of centrality, which was applied to all kinds of economic transactions and social control32. Essentially, the estate system, which in the late 19th century and early 20th century had been considered as the best illustration of the priority primitive economies gave to their own consumption, is nowadays regarded as one of the main levers used to effect a transition to a trading economy.

29 Fumagalli 1966; Montanari 1985; Delatouche 1977. 30 Rösener 1992; Verhulst 1990, Rurale; Verhulst 1990, Slavery. 31 Violante 1953. 32 Toubert 1988.

10 Again we must avoid anachronisms when defining the scope of the economy, or better, of the trading economies of the Early Middle Ages. First of all attention must be given to the local level, the level of the pagus, in which a first network of primary markets, was doubtless essentially oriented towards the trading of ordinary consumer goods. The increase in the number of markets during the 9th century, either by royal grant, as was generally the case east of the Rhine, or more spontaneously elsewhere, and their integration into these trading networks is also explained by the flourishing of the estate economy. The majority of the local markets did, however, not give birth to towns. Their appearance seems rather to have been more an element of the basic structure of the physical environment, which was expressed at the local level. Society in general continued to be profoundly rural, although there was traffic, movement and trade. In the countryside the estate system shattered the traditional framework of peasant farming, based as it was on self-sufficiency and the satisfaction of the basic needs of the producer. It forged the links of a chain of markets and rural market towns, leading peasants into producing for sale and allowing the number of non-agricultural producers in the village to grow. The rural market town, with its market organized to fit in with peasant needs and located at the centre of a small area, was the link and precondition for the establishment of dense and regular relations between town and country33. Despite the dynamic image conferred nowadays on the networks of estates in the Early Middle Ages, it would be unwise to ignore a number of signs that could be a indication, as Henri Pirenne thought, of the contraction of local markets experienced by the Carolingian economy. The Frankish kingdom was never an area in which a sole coinage was adopted, and the circulation of some coins was limited to the regional level. The interregional networks and the ‘circulation areas’ of the monasteries must have been essentially linear in the 9th century. Their existence does not mean that they were from then on at the apex of a hierarchical trading network. There could be differences depending on whether the linear trading relationship was linked (in the Meuse basin) or passed by (the Scheldt) a regional space. The Frankish economy produced surpluses although it was characterized within its boundaries by regional barriers and the absence of generalized trading. The quickening of international trading circuits can be explained by the closeness of areas producing food surpluses and the creation of new markets with lively demand in the British Isles, the Rhine estuary and Northern Europe. Three main trading circuits came into being. The oldest, dating from the 6th century joined the two shores of the ‘Britannic Sea’, between the Loire and the Irish Sea. In the 7th century, the trading impulse reached the shores of the Channel and the , with trading between England, the Seine estuary and the Rhine delta. Two main trading circuits were established in this region: to the East was a circuit that covered the Rhine basin as far as Mainz, the Rhine-Meuse delta and East Anglia and the Thames. The other more westerly circuit linked the Paris basin, the Somme and Northern France with the coasts of the West of England. Few travelled these trading routes. It was primarily Anglo-Saxon, and later Frisian, mariners who provided the links and kept the trade going. Furthermore there is clear evidence of a certain interchange between 34 the two networks . That this was so is underlined by the fact that a new coin

33 Devroey-Zoller 1991. 34 Lebecq 1983.

11 appeared on both sides of the sea between 66o and 67035. This was the silver penny (denier). The chronology, the conditions which occasioned its growth and the functioning of the third circuit, which was established in the North of the Frankish world is still poorly understood. Relations between the peoples living on the shores of the North Sea most certainly continued throughout the Early Middle Ages. In the latter half of the 8th century, staging posts appeared along the rivers and coasts leading towards Frisia and Jutland. Around the year 800, the North saw the establish- ment of new and prosperous trading centres, such as the Haithabu emporia in Schleswig and those of Birka in the Swedish heartland’36. At about the same time silver Arabic coins were making their first appearance in Sweden, and would continue to arrive until the mid 10th century. This third circuit brought the societies of the North Sea coasts into contact with the Baltic and the Scandinavian east. The idea that there was a direct trading route along which ‘long-distance merchants’ carried silver, silks and other luxury goods from Baghdad to Sweden has now been abandoned. Archaeological findings have shown that there was an immense degree of permeability at that time, with exchanges from place to place, and between 37 neighbouring regions . There were trading frontiers between these separate regions, which had their own ports and central towns, and which served their respective hinterlands. Nor should we really concentrate on looking for the existence of commerce in the general complex of economic and social relations which passed along these trading routes: men and things were also subject to other forms of exchange, including migration, war, exchanges of gifts, the collection of tribute, etc.38. The variety of the forms trade took is illustrated by the new turn taken by the relations between Anglo-, Franks and after 820/830, when war gained the upper hand over commerce. Towards 850 the Baltic region became cut off from Rhenish ceramics and Dorestad coinage. The decline of the wiks was a general phenomenon. Pillaged on seven successive occasions after 834, Dorestad failed to revive after the final sack in 863. War had been preceded by economic recession (perhaps in about 820?). War did not close the circuits; it simply transformed the ‘methods’ of trade. The Origins of the Towns Another aspect of the continuity between Antiquity and Middle Ages has rightly been stressed by Pirenne, namely the life of the towns. In the regions we are speaking of the significant archaeological findings of recent decades have tended to highlight the Roman origins of many medieval urban centres39. Such findings must nevertheless be interpreted with care and without imposing a non-existent systematic order on them. The historian often finds it difficult to disentangle the evidence in the sources and the archaeological record for real continued occupation and functionality from that indicative of the reoccupation of a site or a full return to functionality. After the move of the Episcopal seat to Maastricht in the 6th century and then to Liège in the

35 Grierson 1986. 36 Ambrosiani 1988. 37 Jansson 1985. 38 Grierson 1959; Grierson 1961. 39 Verhulst 1987; Spa 1990.

12 7th century, the ancient capital city of became no more than a centre of estate management in the Early Middle Ages. A series of ancient conurbations owe their survival to the continuance of their central political, administrative and religious functions: the Merovingian pagi such as Ghent, Kortrijk, Aardenburg, , Thérouanne, and are named after the urban centres whose existence in Roman times is well established. Sometimes though such continuity is merely topographical: Germanic names such as Aardenburg, Antwerp, and Bruges suggest that there may well have been a break in occupation. Activities disappeared: the Roman forges of Ganda (Ghent) were abandoned in Merovingian times40. Cases where topographic and functional continuity are beyond dispute are still rare: at Huy, craft activities and techniques continued during the Merovingian period in the workshops of the Batta district, where smiths, goldsmiths, potters and bone carvers were all active41. In reality one should speak of a slow discontinuity between the town of ancient times and the mediaeval town and acknowledge the great variety of ways town life developed. In contrast to the Roman period, the town was no longer a ‘social model’, with a native population, civilization and organization. At the same time it should be stressed that one of the most telling indications of the transition from Antiquity to the Middle Ages in the West was the extraordinary decline in the life-style of the prince and the elite. Regardless of whether it was an ancient civitas (such as Tournai), or a vicus (like Maastricht) or a trading post (like Dorestad), the town of the Early Middle Ages is revealed as combining craft and commercial activities and farming. The vicus or commercial centre serves as a point of coalescence in the ‘town’. Even so the latter by no means conforms to the formal topographic criteria of what might be understood to be a town (high density, conurbation). It would have been more a cluster of population nucleii where it would have been possible to find a centre of administration, newly built concentrations of housing, and recognizable districts devoted to a particular craft or to farming. This multiplicity of habitats can thus not be reduced to the traditional duality of fortress- plus-commercial settlement. In reality things were far more complex and would vary depending on the place and period. In the 11th century these multi-centred concentrations of population started to merge together and soon became ‘a sole and single town, largely due to the establishment of an export industry at its heart’. Another important factor was the consolidation or establishment of a recognizable rural hinterland and a network of trading circuits linked to these urban centres. Consequently the town of the Early Middle Ages, like the abbey or rural palace at the heart of the estate system, became a nexus of trading networks where the surpluses of agricultural production were concentrated. The favourable situation of a place for the purposes of defence or for traffic explains the appearance in the late 8th century and subsequently of new centres of activity next to the most ancient centres: the vicus, castrum or portus. The development is first seen in the valley of the Meuse and appeared later along the course of the Scheldt and in the Scheldt estuary. Trading in these centres was largely local. On the other hand the ephemeral ‘ports of trade’, which appeared along the North Sea coasts between the 7th and 9th centuries, effectively played a ‘gateway’ role, and saw international trading. These ‘wiks’, which were often founded by Royal decree, were

40 Verhulst 1989, Towns. 41 Devroey-Zoller 1991.

13 compulsory stopping posts for travelling merchants, were the place where custom dues were collected, and where foreign coinage not current in the realm of the Franks could be changed or overstruck. Like the other ‘ancient’ settlements, which attracted a vicus or portus in the 9th century, they served a central function and the roots of their development were nourished by a structured hinterland. The distribution of archaeological findings indicates that with the exception of pottery, which tended to be concentrated in the largest production centres, craftwork was basically a domestic business. Traces of bone and horn carving, leather working, and metalworking are typical of all of these sites and is suggestive of a population of specialist craft workers, something, which can also be found in the centres of the Meuse valley (Maastricht, Huy and )42. Textile production before the year one thousand tended to be more of a country activity, with centres in estate workshops and above in all vast numbers of domestic looms in peasant farms. Rural linen and cloth were supplied to the great abbeys from their holdings in the North-West, in Flanders, Frisia, and Northern Germany. In the past historians thought that upstream of the ‘trading frontier’ on which Dorestad lay, the territory of the South Netherlands and the Meuse valley were covered and crossed by international trading routes. Since the publication of Rousseau's book, it has been realized that the Meuse area had a head start over the Flanders in commercial and urban development43. There is no trace of any significant commercial activity in the Scheldt valley before the end of the 8th century. The entire region was isolated from the main trading routes, which tended to run a little further to the south (Quentovic) or more to the north (Domburg on Walcheren and Dorestad). As for the coast, it had been deserted since the incursion of the sea in the 3rd century. The network of towns was largely subordinated to central functions44. The Meuse Region The hypothesis of the synchronous development of the towns of the Meuse in terms of both their nature and their scale must likewise be abandoned before the idea of variable rates of growth and the diversity of urban types. River traffic generated by trade appears to have occurred both upstream and downstream. The centre of gravity of the Meuse Region was to the north, in the delta of the Meuse and Rhine, where the had since about 600 organized a major clearing house for trade between the Frankish world, the British Isles and Northern Europe. Maastricht appears to have been a gateway, which was linked to Dorestad. In the 7th century the upstream valley did not play the role of major corridor for international trade so often attributed to it45. The four portus of the Meuse valley: Maastricht, Huy, Namur and Dinant formed an enduring armature of urban development between the 6th and the 10th centuries. Here there is evidence that the land was divided into parcels, and was subject to a tax payable solely in coin. There are that numerous traces of oratories. These are not primitive churches; rather they existed to serve the needs of the inhabitants of the portus46. At Maastricht there were numerous foreign merchants

42 Spa 1990. 43 Rousseau 1930. 44 Verhulst 1989, Towns. 45 Rousseau 1930; contra Despy 1968. 46 Despy 1995.

14 living in the vicus47. It may be assumed that a similar state of affairs existed in the other portus of the Meuse and that these merchants attended to the links with the hinterland. However, archaeology and written sources only provide us with direct evidence of craft and trading activities before the year 800 in Maastricht and Huy. Numismatic history attests to the unity of the Meuse area, where a degree of trade was common, although it was limited to a single area and prior to the second half of the ioth century without any opening to neighbouring regions such as the Frankish Rhineland in the east and the old Neustrian lands to the west48. Trade in the Meuse region had been even more localized, as indicated by the relations established by the vici in the Meuse valley with the hinterland and the birth in the Carolingian period of rural markets and fairs just large enough to serve the needs of a local area, such as Saint-Hubert near Bastogne. At Fosses, merchants came to the fair to sell and to buy. Based as it was on the relationship between town and country, the regional economy of the Meuse area turned on craft production, local markets, and the central religious or political functions of the palaces, abbeys, towns and the larger villages49. All in all the significance of the Meuse region owes far more to its place in the power structures of the Carolingian kings - palaces, great estates, monasteries, than role of its river as ‘a running road’50. After the decline, which started in the period 820-830, the ‘wiks’ of the North Sea coast (Domburg, Dorestad, Quentovic, and Yserae Portus in the Southern Netherlands) disappeared during the 2nd half of 9th and the 10th centuries. There are no simple explanations (military, economic or political) for their disappearance. This, however, does not mean that trade came to an end in this part of Europe. The Viking raids did not make the old established settlements disappear. To the contrary it could well be that they benefited from the disappearance of the emporia and were able to attract the flows of international trade in the Scheldt and Meuse valleys and at Tiel and Deventer in East . Did some sort of passing of the baton take place in the Scheldt valley, as Verhulst suggests might have happened in Antwerp in the latter half of the 9th century?51 The rarity and fragility of the sources for the first half of the zoth century oblige us to be cautious. It would be too bold to follow Rousseau and speak of the continuity of urban life from the 5th to the 12th century52. We have only a very approximate idea of the development of the economy in the Frankish world during the 9th and the 10th centuries. Without a doubt there were a series of crises, perhaps between 820 and 830, followed by a period of growth, perhaps between 850 and 860. In the Meuse region, the recession, which was marked by a pronounced decline in the money supply and the emission of coinage, was severe between 880 and 950. Examination of the various forms of coins provides an insight into coinage emissions, and we see only 19 sorts of coins struck in the mints of the Meuse (with 11 in Maastricht) during the first half of the 10th century. After 950, trade revived and

47 Despy 1968. 48 Devroey-Zoller 1991. 49 Despy 1968. 50 Rousseau 1930. 51 Verhulst 1989, Towns. 52 Rousseau 1930.

15 we see 107 different sorts being struck (10 of which were struck in Maastricht)53. Studies of coin hoards in the Baltic region dating from the 10th and 11th centuries tend to confirm this picture. Between 950 and 990 no discovered hoards contain pennies struck in the mints of the middle Meuse, Utrecht or Frisia. The currents of trade which linked the Germanic world to the Baltic only brought in Cologne pennies mixed with other imperial coinage. The economic frontier of the 9th century between the Meuse and Rhine basins still existed in the second half of the 10th century. Links to the North and the Baltic from the Rhine and Meuse delta were slow to be reestablished. Around the year one thousand, coin hoards show a complete reversal in their provenance. From then on, Meuse coinage was used in Cologne and was taken to the east mixed up with Cologne coinage, which is the first evidence for contacts and monetary flows between the two regions. Later on a significant proportion of Meuse-struck coins reached the Baltic by more direct routes, indicating that other routes for the circulation of coins had been established between the Meuse and Eastern Europe54 By the close of the 10th century, Cologne was playing a leading role as a centre for the trade between Germany and Eastern Europe, two centuries before Cologne was to become, as Lamprecht puts it, “The great seaport of the Empire”. The evolution of the Meuse region between the 9th century and the millennium is well illustrated by the rise of Liège. Originally a small country estate where Bishop Lambert was murdered in about 700, it became the seat of the Bishop of Tongeren (Tongres) during the second half of the 8th century. Designated a vicus publicus in 769, the small clerical settlement which grew up around the Saint Lambert basilica gave Liège a central function, helped no doubt by the proximity of the palace at Herstal, which since 769 had been the centre of a pagellus - a royal residence and royal mint at the end of the 8th century. It is not until to the end of the 10th century, however, that we find pennies struck bearing the name of the town. The Bishops of Liège had certainly struck coins, no doubt within the episcopal precincts, but these bore the name of the bishopp. The vicus of Liège had the appearance of an urban agglomeration, with houses, stone walls and other dwellings when it was flooded in 958. Though laid waste by the Normans in 881, it was quickly rebuilt. Wine from Worms was sold there in 960. Nonetheless this town life must have consisted primarily of passive consumers, clerics and members of the bishop's court and other hangers-on. The relatively late appearance in the records of the collection of stall dues, in 960, the lack of any mention of a river port or a market before the end of the iith century makes it probable that Liège continued to be preoccupied with its political and religious functions until the mid-tenth century. A generation later the town was surrounded by a wall, built on the orders of Bishop Notger (972-1008). Similarly it was in the latter half of the same 10th century that the bishops of Liège built their position as princes holding temporal sway over extensive lands. Under Bishop Notger Liège embarked on an ambitious programme of construction, leaving an indelible mediaeval imprint on the town55. By the year one thousand merchants from Liège were trading side by side with merchants from Huy in London. They regularly travelled in the Rhine valley in the 11th century. However little is known about the precise activitives of these 11th and 12th century merchants, “Were they mainly

53 Devroey-Zoller 1991. 54 Devroey-Zoller 1991. 55 Kupper 1990.

16 importers of wine, unfinished wool, or linen or were they rather exporters of the products of Liège's metalworkers and leatherworkers?”56. There is no certain evidence for the systematic sale of metal products until the latter half of the 12th century. Furthermore Liège linen was little known in other regions before 1250. The town never joined either of the two great leagues of trading cities: the London-based Hansa League or the XVII cities. Like Despy, it appears that one must conclude that the Liège of the first half of the 13th century was primarily concerned with tertiary functions, whose prosperity was based on its central role as the liturgical and political capital of the bishop57. Around 1100, there were eight chapters in the episcopal ‘cité’ with roughly 270 prebendaries and two abbeys occupied by between 70 and 80 chorister monks. Indeed one has to look to the bishop and the Church in Liège to understand the links between the production of artistic and cultural works, power centres and the accumulation of wealth. Before 972, the bishops held property and rights in the most important centres of the Meuse region, as well as various large abbeys such as Saint-Hubert and Lobbes. Under Notger, the , Otto II, granted general immunity for the Saint-Lambert possessions. In 985, Otto II, granted the Comté of Huy to Notger. In 987, he added the Comté of Brugeron between the Gete (Gette) and the Dijle () rivers, the market dues and coinage of Maastricht, the abbeys of Lobbes, Fosses, and Gembloux, and in 992 the abbey of Brogne. By the time Notger died, the foundations of a solid temporal principality had been laid, form- ing a welcome buffer between the and the ambitions of the French kings in (Lorraine) and, very soon, the expansionist plans of the Counts of Flanders. Nor did the accretion of property come to a halt in the 11th century. In 1040 the Comté of Haspinga, lying between the Geer and the Meuse, was added, while the Comté of Hainaut was enfeoffed in 107158. By the time the generosity of the Holy Roman Emperors comes to an end towards the close of the 11th century, the ‘...riches of the Church in Liège allow her to buy virtually anything it wants and to nourish the heritage of Saint Lambert simply by paying for it’59. Between 1071 and 1096, Bishops Theoduin and Otbert spent 100 gold pounds on such operations and over 2,000 silver marks. Their wealth sprung from the exercise of royal prerogatives and their vast estates, whose revenues all flowed into Liège. These were collected and checked by a system established during the 11th century comprising a clerical arm (the cathedral chapters, collegial churches and abbeys, archdeaconates, deaconates and parishes), a military arm (fortresses commanded by constables invested by the bishop); and an estate arm (forty or so centres of operations spread evenly over the lands of Saint Lambert, which were entrusted to members of the episcopal familia). In order to maintain authority over the lands the Prince Bishops adopted a system of clientism. ‘To the nobles they granted fiefs, to the emerging burgesses they granted charters of liberties’60. Examples include Huy in 1066, Sint Truiden (Saint-Trond) in 1146, and Liège at the end of the 12th century.

56 Despy 1975. 57 Despy 1975. 58 Kupper 1981. 59 Kupper 1981. 60 Kupper 1981.

17 This powerful apparatus made the Church the most powerful political force throughout the Meuse region. In 1107, abbot Étienne de Saint-Jacques declared, ‘Nothing can equal the power of the bishops whose court and opulence rivals that of the kings themselves’61. The clergy of Liège, recounting the battle of Steppes in 1213, makes William of Salisbury, half-brother of John Lackland (King John of England), say these bitter words, ‘Perish those who have given such power to a Priest’62. The Scheldt Region The first indications of territorial cohesion in Flanders begin to emerge in 862 with the success of Baldwin I (Baudouin/Boudewijn), a Carolingian count, who carried off and subsequently wed the daughter of , Judith, already twice widowed by a King of Wessex. With his appearance and that of his son Baldwin II, the Counts of Flanders commenced a long period in which they played a key political role in the West of the Frankish Kingdom. Certain basic traits of the policies of the Counts of Flanders emerged by the end of the 9th century and during the 10th century. These included matrimonial policies aimed at creating closer relations with the Anglo-Saxon kingdoms; taking an active part in French affairs of state; and territorial expansion, although to the south this came up against the new-found might of the Dukes of Normandy. The first ‘Grand Marquis’, Arnold I, son of Baldwin II, ruled lands, which stretched from the Somme and the Canche to the Zwin. His successors were soon to direct their expansionist dreams towards the East. Mediaeval chroniclers were well aware of the paradoxical nature of the extraordinary success of the Flemish ‘princes’, who reigned over a ‘terre brehaigne, peu valant et plaine de palus’ (a barren land, worthless and full of marshes)63. The apparent paradox hides three fundamental elements which underpinned the spectacular economic and urban growth of the County, namely long-term rural expansion since the Carolingian era; the establishment of power structures which had been based on fortifications and sites of refuge since the end of the 9th century; and the rise of the towns with rights, liberties and their own administrative system. The rapid growth of the Flemish towns during the course of the 11th and the 12th centuries can only be understood if the vital role of agriculture is acknowledged. In the nineteen-sixties the question of the respective interaction of demographic expansion and rural growth lead to fierce argument between neo-Malthusians, who stressed the key importance of technical innovation, and sociologists such as Boserup, who considered that demographic pressure led to both expansion and deepening in all areas64. The acceleration of demographic growth already observable in the 8th century, and which was sustained throughout the 11th, 12th and 13th centuries was not the result of a ‘technical revolution’ in the year one thousand65. The majority of the technical innovations of the Middle Ages, such as the heavy plough, harnesses, and watermills, were already known in ancient times66. What happened in the Middle Ages was that an awareness of these techniques was spread and that they became integrated into farming practice. Demographic pressure

61 Vita s. Modoaldi. 62 Triumphus s. Lamberti in Steppes. 63 Istore et Chronikes de Flandre. 64 Boserup 1965. 65 White 1940; Duby 1966. 66 Medieval Farming 1997.

18 was an important factor “either as the direct cause or indirectly as a catalyst” in the astonishing increase in the area of land under cultivation67. The trend to clearing new land for cultivation and putting other land to good use by empolderment or the construction of dykes, the multiplication or expansion of centres of settlement, and the colonization of entire new areas, between the 10th and the end of the 13th century, did by no means proceed in linear fashion, in time or in space. It has been the great land clearances, which have really captured the imagination of historians. Nonetheless the greatest impact on country life and the elements, which nourished the rise of the towns, was made by the intensification and specialization of farming. The very real economic boom experienced during the central period of the Middle Ages was not due to the ‘great clearances but the phase following them, the return to interregional trade in agricultural products’68. In Flanders the peak of the clearances was reached in the 11th and 12th centuries, a century before the remainder of the Southern Netherlands69. It is evident that since the 9th century the clearances were above all the result of the more intensive occupation of ancient lands. This element is also applicable to the great clearances after the year one thousand, which were launched from long-populated areas. The most densely populated regions in the 12th century were Ghent, where clearances had started in the 10th century and , Aalst (Alost) and Diksmuide (Dixmude). The improvement of depopulated regions during the Early Middle Ages was part of the second wave of clearances, which started at the end of the 11th and th continued during the 12 century. After a pause in clearances between about 1175 to 1215, the improvement of the extensive heathlands in the Northern Flanders continued well into the 13th century. The first phase of the expansion of agricultural land consisted of putting the old lands into use until saturation point was reached. A third of the new concentrations of population, which appeared in the 11th century were located in the Ghent area. The density of the rural population in the 11th century explains the rapidity of urban growth. Hardly a few decades before, leper (Ypres), where in 1127 a fair was held that attracted merchants from far-off Italy, was hardly more than a hamlet where an estate collection office was sited. Calais was a tiny fishing village in 1165, but by 1300 had become a town with a population of 15,000, representing a tripling in population with every generation. Saint-Omer is known to have tripled its population every century70. Ghent, Bruges, and leper reached the th peak of their development in the 13 century, with populations of 64,000, 42,000 and 35,000 respectively71. By the mid-14th century, about 40 % of the Flemish population lived in towns. The expansion of the land area under cultivation is insufficient in itself to resolve the paradox of Flemish agriculture, where we see an awkward environment, frequently poor soils (particularly when compared to neighbouring Picardy); combined with advanced techniques (horses, intensive crop rotation, forage crops, etc.); as well as a spectacular rise in yields, which can only be explained by the dynamism of the small

67 Verhulst 1990, Slavery; Verhulst 1990, Rurale. 68 Wickham 1992. 69 Verhulst 1990, Rurale 70 Derville 1991; Derville 1995. 71 Verhulst 1982; Verhulst 1990, Rurale.

19 Flemish farm. The best modern hypothesis is inspired by the idea that the rural economy in the County of Flanders had since the 11th century been rooted in a macro-economic agrarian ‘ecosystem’, based partly on pronounced regional specialization in three different areas: 1) the coastal strip, which specialized in stock- farming products; 2) the southern part of the County with its loam soils, which was the granary of the County and exported cereals along the Scheldt and Leie () to the cities of the North; and 3) the sandy soils of the Flemish heartland, where a type of extensive cash-crop farming grew up which supplied the needs of ale brewers72. The coastal region was taken into use in progressive steps. The first shepherding operations appeared on artificial mounds in the centre of salt marshes known as th th schorren in the 8 century, but it was not until the 10 century that the first villages appeared. The saline land was originally drained naturally via the channels taken by the floodwater. In the following century, however, following the third incursion, the first small collective dykes (seawalls or embankments) begin to appear. These were then followed in about 1050 by major works such as the Oude Zeedijk east of Veurne (Furnes). The second phase, which started in about 1130, saw the construction of what might be termed offensive dykes rather than defensive dykes. These were built with the object of reclaiming land or ‘polders’ from the sea. The desalination of the soil led to the creation of new resources. Until the end of the 12th century, land reclamation was primarily left to a few large abbeys, like the Abbey of the Dunes (near Veurne). In the 13th century, the nobility and patrician burgesses took a part in dyke construction enterprises. The activities of the coastal communities existing before the establishment of new ports by the 13th century Counts included fishing, cattle farming and the handling of goods in transit. The oldest markets in the towns such as Ghent and Bruges were fish markets. Stock farming was, however, the main activity of the entire coastal region. Great herds of cattle and sheep were raised for meat, dairy products, leather and wool and sent to towns inland. The growth in the number of polders allowed the expansion of grazing land and cultivated fields. By end of the 12th century cash crops such as madder were being raised. Other products of growing importance were sea salt and peat73. Nowadays historians think that agriculture adopted intensive methods between the 12th and 13th centuries, before the economic crisis of the Late Middle Ages74. Three yearly rotation was practised on the rich soils in the south of the County even in Carolingian times by the great estate75. In 1120 it was being used on the land of the Abbey of Marchiennes between the Lys and the Scheldt to the north of the Lille. The ‘Gros Brief’ of 1187 shows that it was widely used by the great estates in the County north of Lille. The long application of crop rotation would explain why in the mid-13th century other ways of intensifying farming methods were sought on the loam soils of Southern Flanders where cereal cropping had approached the limits of its possibilities both in terms of yields and area76. Vetch was sown on old fallow and cattle allowed to graze it. As a result the field would become enriched by natural

72 Thoen 1994. 73 Thoen 1994; Verhulst 1995, Landschap. 74 Verhulst 1985; Thoen 1992. 75 Derville 1989; Morimoto 1994. 76 Derville 1978; Derville 1989.

20 manure and the nitrogen fixed by the vetch. This practice became widespread in the mid-13th century in the Tournai-Lille region and in Haspengouw (Hesbaye). The practice of catch-cropping (or intercropping) opened new ecological prospects making it possible to achieve a diversification of cultivated products, improved stock yields, organic and green manures, which in turn made it possible to grow other crops. For example woad, a demanding cash crop grown for dyers, made its first appearance in the 13th century77. The practice of growing forage and industrial crops was introduced mainly by peasant farmers, and was often prohibited on the great tenanted farms. Throughout the Middle Ages the line between intensive and extensive farming practice largely coincides with the line between the small and the large farmer. The light sandy soils of inland Flanders produced mainly rye and oats and were farmed on the ‘dries’ system (a type of outfield rotation system). Rye was the staple of the peasant diet, while the oats were used to feed the horses and make ale. The woodlands, which were still fairly extensive in the 11th and 12th centuries, were used for raising pigs. That pigs were a regular feature of the diet in the Middle Ages has been confirmed by archaeological finds in Ghent. Nonetheless it is likely that inland Flanders played a much more limited role in the mediaeval trading economy, than did the coastal strip or the south of the County78. The importance of oats in Flemish agriculture also explains the early abandonment of oxen as draught animals in favour of the horse. Indeed the horse was probably already being used by Flemish farmers in the year 1000. Even though further investigation is required, it appears that oxen had been all but completely replaced by the second half of the 12th century. As it was quicker than the ox and more suitable for small intensive farms, the horse could plough much greater areas. With the concurrent improvement of the cart, peasant farmers could travel further than the nearby villages and even reach the smaller towns. The abandonment of the ox as a draught animal also made it possible to concentrate cattle-farming activities on dairy and beef production. Other elements of technical advance, such as water resource management and peat cutting, are indicative of the advanced state of Flemish th th 79 farming in the 11 and 12 centuries . Flanders therefore developed an original system for diversifying its agricultural production, which encompassed a better balance with cattle farming and regional specialization, which began to appear in the 12th century. Such trade flows would not have been possible without the establishment of a true regional economy covering the entire County and neighbouring regions. The loam plains of , and Picardy (the territorial losses of the County did not affect trading patterns) were the granary which nourished the valleys of the Leie (Lys) and Scheldt. Examination of the urban development of the cereal regions shows that simply equating cereal production with urban growth is fallacious. There is no large town at all in the rich lands of Picardy. Towns do not grow up spontaneously in the country. Stockfarming goes a long way to explaining the dynamism of the Flemish countryside. Between the 8th and the 12th centuries, intensive sheep farming on the

77 Verhulst 1985; Thoen 1992. 78 Thoen 1994. 79 Thoen 1994; Verhulst 1995, Landschap.

21 ‘schorren’ and peat soils permitted the production of vast quantities of wool, which were carried via the estate network to Ghent in the year 1000. In the 12th century, Flanders was blessed with a coast which produced a wealth of saleable goods (unprocessed wool, meat, dairy products, fish, salt, peat, and madder), as well as densely populated regions around Ghent, leper and Aalst with a possibly more fragile nutritional balance, and intensifying agricultural practice on the most fertile lands combined with easy access to cereal resources. The hypothetical early specialization of the coastal strip should not result in the progress made by stock farmers elsewhere being ignored. When Galbert de Bruges writes about peasant life between the Scheldt and Leie he confirms this, as do the toponymic distributions of place names relating to sheep farming in inland Flanders, wool production in Artois and the Tournai area in the early uth century or the importance of the drovers' roads (Middle Dutch: herdgang) uncovered by archaeologists in the Ghent area80. The prosperity of stock farming in Flanders was striking enough for contemporaries to remark on it. Sometime between 1055 and 1065, Archbishop Gervais of Rheims expressed his admiration to Count Baldwin V of the latter's success in making, ‘... by his invention and energy (...) a land [fertile] that only a short time ago was hardly good for farming at all (...), to such an extent that it surpasses in this respect lands more suited to production; (...) so that it produces from its bosom fruit in abundance and a profusion of harvests; making it smile on those who till it and swell so with fecundity that it even provides enough to fatten the beasts in the fields and meadows’81. The Role of the Prince? There remains one particularly thorny question. Namely should the growth of the rural economy be explained by the independence and dynamism of the Flemish peasantry and the moderate demands of the lords regarding newly cleared land82 or was it rather a matter of seigniorial initiative? The idea of internally fuelled growth runs into certain theoretical and practical objections. An intensification of farm practice on small peasant farms is not a sustained and irreversible process. It could be nipped in the bud by population growth and an abundance of cheap agricultural labour. Large farms also found ways of adapting to the market by entering into tenancy agreements. The growing practice of collecting taxes in coin encouraged the development of the intensive use of money in the countryside83. The Flemish boom and the transfer of capital away from the countryside could have been stimulated by the residential and consumption patterns of the Flemish elite. The established a princely court and gathered the most powerful lords around him during the 11th century. In Brabant, the Duke did not attempt to call his 84 great noblemen to court before the close of the Middle Ages . The Count's coffers appear to have been well filled with gold and silver, precious stones and valuable linen (!) since the reign of Baldwin V. It is hardly surprising that both the murderers

80 Verhulst 1995, Landschap. 81 Ganshof 1943. 82 Thoen 1994. 83 Thoen 1994. 84 Van Uytven 1976; Thoen 1994.

22 and avengers of Charles the Good searched for them in vain. The luxurious life of the Count and the nobility was a stimulus to industry and trade. The charitable acts of the Count attracted the poor to the towns, to whom he gave food, money and clothing (!). Galbert de Bruges's enumeration of the measures taken by the Charles the Good for the alleviation of the famine of I124-1126 is a good indication of the extent to which the town dominated the countryside in the early 12th century and the degree to which the Count could influence the economy. Halfway through Lent in 1125, the bread ran out. Peasant farmers from Ghent and the Leie to the Scheldt had no option but to slaughter their livestock in order to feed their families. The famine caused hundreds of deaths in the countryside and peasants flocked to the towns. The Count dealt severely with those wealthy boarders who had been speculating in grain, which in itself illustrates the not inconsiderable economic role played by the rich in the trade in agricultural produce. He suspended brewing operations and fixed wine prices in order to encourage cereal imports. He gave orders for bread to be made from oats and regulated loaf sizes. He ruled that one unit of agricultural land in all parts of the County should be sown with beans and peas in order to bring the next harvest forward. He instructed all his estates to maintain a hundred poor people and suspended the payment of tenancy dues85. From this it is possible to conclude that such a thing as a commodity foodstuffs market existed in Flanders in the early 12th century, which it was possible to push in the direction of cereal purchases and bread production by forbidding the brewing of beer and cutting purchases of wine from the French wine-producing regions of Laon, Beauvais and Rheims. There is nothing to indicate that the players in this market were primarily professional merchants. The speculators were the rich and probably belonged to the elite who lived in the town. As the story of the uprisings in Laon in 1112 and Bruges in 1127 tells, the nobles, senior clerics and important officials had ‘hôtels’ or residences in town, where they stored the foodstuffs collected from the country. The political decisions of Count Charles are striking for their diversity and their nature. However, we must ask ourselves what they say about the role of politics and the social fabric in the growth of rural and urban Flanders. Jan Dhondt regarded the complex of ‘castle, collegiate church, and fair’ as the fruit of the Count's initiatives in the mid-11th century86. Hans Van Werveke spoke of the economic policies of his successor, Philippe d'Alsace, typified by the foundation of a series of ports along the Flemish coast87, which were the key element of a new drainage system and the exploitation of the coastal plains of Flanders88. And as we have seen the Bishop of Rheims was fulsome in his praise of Baldwin V, whom he saw as responsible for the new fertility of the Flemish lands. The references to a surge in violence in 11th and early 12th century Flemish sources have led David Nicholas to draw a picture of a Flanders which is ‘rough, violent and badly governed...’ at the end of the 11th century89. Galbert of Bruges's story, however, makes Charles the Good the heir to a tradition of peace and public order guaranteed

85 Galbertus Notarius. 86 Dhondt 1948. 87 Van Werveke 1952. 88 Verhulst 1967, Comtale; Verhulst 1967, Politique. 89 Nicholas 1991.

23 by the Counts. One of the most serious crimes of the Erembalds was the breach of the Count's peace and the conduct of a private war. The recurrence of the theme of violence in the chronicles is not an indication of the existence of unbridled barbarism, but a reflection by contemporaries of the feeling that they were witnessing a confrontation between the public peace and private violence. In the period between the mid-11th century and the early 12th century, the Counts of Flanders made every effort to enforce the Count's peace (truce, peace of the town and the market, free passage for merchants) throughout the County. Historians tend to be more willing to point out the role of the Counts in the development of the towns and urban trade than in the countryside. Nonetheless one is inclined to think that the limitation on lordly violence in the form of the public peace and early development of a network of smaller towns accessible to country-dwellers must have helped to foster the return to rural growth in the 11th and 12th centuries. The history of Charles the Good as recorded by Galbert of Bruges is based on a paradigm (which may have been inspired by the author's social environment), namely the effect of the social forces unleashed by the murder in 1127 of the Count. The Count, the guarantor of the Peace, encourages foreign merchants to come to the fairs of Flanders. We learn of the unbridled rise and wealth of Bertulf and his fellows, we see the formation of a new elite of clerics, administrators and soldiers growing up which owes its prosperity to the Count. We read of the robber knights and bandits who prey on the roads, careless of death, in order to capture and ransom the merchants. He argues for the Count and the urban economy to take control of the peasant economy rather than for internally driven rural growth. The Development of the Flemish Towns For Henri Pirenne, the development of the towns in the Southern Netherlands was ideal material for drawing a general picture in support of his hypotheses. The towns were established in the 11th century under the impulse of the revival of international trade. There origins could be traced to a common characteristic, ‘The Flemish town was born of the juxtaposition of a stronghold and a merchant settlement where, to borrow the terms used in the sources there was a castrum and a portus’. For Pirenne, a castrum was not a town; it was not even urban in nature. Only the fact of its pre-existence determined the location of commercial and industrial settlements90. Archaeological discoveries show that this general picture was in reality far more complicated and much more diverse both in space and in time. For example, at both Ghent and there was a portus before any fortifications were built. Furthermore not all Flemish strongholds were built as defences against the Norsemen, examples include several pre-urban sites such as in all likelihood Bruges in the middle of the 9th century, Saint-Omer before 891, Tournai in 898, Cambrai between 888 and 901. The main fortification works at Ghent and date only from the middle of the 10th century91. Admittedly whereas parts of the fortifications were built in response to a clear and present danger, the castle is essentially ‘the material expression of the establishment of a feudal power’92.

90 Pirenne 1905. 91 Verhulst 1994. 92 Verhulst 1994.

24 The numerous case studies that have appeared in recent decades reveal a reality, which was far more complex and varied both in time and space than the simple dualism of stronghold and settlement. Antwerp had had military function since the 8th century. A trading settlement sprung up a kilometre downstream which survived the sack of the castrum by the Vikings in 83693. However, the seeds of the modern town only germinated after 980, when the ancient vicus was fortified and transformed into a castrum (Het Steen) and merchants settled outside its walls. A fish market (Vismarkt), which grows up below the walls, suggests that like Bruges and Ghent the main activity of the new settlement was to provision the castle. In the 7th century Ghent started to coalesce around two centres, the Abbey of Saint Peter and the Abbey of Saint Bavo, both of which administered large estates. The merchant th settlement of the 9 century was located on the Scheldt about 500 metres upstream of Saint Bavo. The second portus in Ghent referred to in the sources appeared in the middle of the 10th century on the banks of the Leie (Lys), at the foot of the new castle 94 built by the Count of Flanders . The impressive size of the Count's estates in the northern part of Flanders at the end of the 10th century has already been referred to. In this region the Count was by far the largest landholder. Farming methods, the nature and direction of the circuits used for transferring farm surpluses, consumer and trading patterns affecting estate produce would therefore have had a considerable impact on the regional trading economy.

However our attention should first go to the particular pattern of incastellamento in Flanders. The Flemish plain saw a spate of castle building both at the end of the 9th century and the close of the 10th century. They had a characteristic plan, being either circular (Bourbourg, Bergues-Saint-Winnoc, Veurne (Furnes), Diksmuide (Dixmude), and Gistel) or semi-circular and protected on one side by a river (Saint-Omer, , Ypres (leper), Armentières, Kortrijk (Courtrai), Tournai, Ghent, , and Aalst (Alost). Some of these had been built on an emerging pre-urban site (Bruges, Ghent, and Saint-Omer)95. Walled refuges built in flat countryside often gave rise to a small 96 mediaeval town . Their development contrasts sharply with that of isolated strongholds like the large castles built by the Bishops of Liège in the Meuse region. As of the early 11th century, this network of defences formed the basis of a new way of dividing the County into administrative districts. The new districts were smaller than the Carolingian pagi they replaced. They were administered by a ‘castellan’ (or viscount) appointed by the Count, and the castrum became the main centre of the ‘castellany’. In addition to the traditional military and legal functions these centres were granaries, the place where the revenues of the Count and the resources of his domain were concentrated and redistributed. One key characteristic of the urbanization process in Flanders was therefore the density of its network of secondary centres. The interplay of castrum and portus, which Pirenne regarded as fundamental to the growth of the big towns, probably had

93 Verhulst 1978. 94 Verhulst 1989, Ghent. 95 De Meulemeester 1990. 96 De Meulemeester 1990.

25 the greatest effect in these smaller centres, where the initiative of the Count meant that there were mouths to feed (the milites castri, sergeants, clerks, and petty officials, domestics, leatherworkers and blacksmiths, etc.). The construction of various residences (the Flemish court continued to travel hither and thither in the County well into the 12th century) and, by establishing canonical chapters in some of them, the Count helped to increase the demand for commercial and craft activities. The ‘Gros Brief’ of 1187 gives quite a good idea of the stimulating role the establishment of a collection office for the Count's estate dues could play; and which could result in a concentric estate organization issuing ultimately into ‘épiers’ (granaries), lardaria, vaccariae (for dairy products) and local counting houses to handle the money; and in consumption (for maintenance or payment in kind or by the establishment of fief-rents or charity rents); and the sale of part of the farm produce by the collectors, etc.97. Regional Economy, the Urban Phenomenon and Trade Circuits The network of secondary centres was complemented by a primary system of local and regional fairs. The oldest of these was the Saint Bavo fair, which would start on the 1st of October. Undoubtedly of spontaneous origin, it appears in the records shortly after the year 1000. Hagiographies of the 11th and 12th centuries reveal the importance of the Ghent market as an outlet for products such as wool and ale from the upper Scheldt valley. There is abundant reference to the plentifulness of money and the crowds thronging to the fair. Prior to 1100, fairs are reported in various pre- urban centres such as Saint-Omer (about 1050), Douai (1076), Aardenburg (about 1100), and on central monastic estates such as Wormhout (1076), Torhout (about 1084), Tronchiennes (1087) and Messines (end of the 11th century (?)). The fairs of leper and Lille were subjected to the Market Peace in 1127. Texts from the 12th century illustrate the primitive nature of the Flemish fairs as interregional centres for primary farm produce98. As of the 8th century and to a large extent in the following centuries, the great abbeys controlled traffic areas by means of estate curtes, whose central establishments had to take turns in supplying the abbey. This was the system employed at Saint- Wandrille near Rouen in 719-739 and at Corbie in 82299. These systems, which supplied the needs of the Frankish state and its superstructures, are linked as we have seen to the great ‘portes’ (lit. gateways) of the Carolingian period on the western coast-trading frontier. The great innovation of a network like the one established in Flanders in the 11th and 12th centuries has nothing to do with its topology, rather it lies in its evolutionary nature of the centres (estate curtes or castra), the character of the main actors (nobility, clerical or secular administrative elite), and in the nature of the traffic from the periphery to the centre (centralized consumption and sale or a partial transfer to the peripheries). When reduced to simple formulations, the evolutionary nature of each of these nodal points in the Flemish model is expressed as a series of dynamic factors: the traditional central functions such as justice and administration, infrastructure (the defence apparatus, church, markets, etc.), the existence of a consuming population, demand for services

97 Gros Brief 1962. 98 Yamada 1991. 99 Devroey 1993 Monasterii.

26 (craftsmen, retailers), supplies of farm products sold at market prices by the recipients, and guarantees of peace and safety. As for traffic itself, it clearly develops in relation to supply, regional specialization and demand. Peat, salt and fish are sent to the markets in the towns, where retailers sell them. In 1187, the administrators of the Count's estates allow the local collectors to choose either to consume or sell farm surpluses. From then on it tends to be money, rather than estate carts, that travels from the periphery to the centre. Finally the trading networks are not confined to a single physical organization. Traffic networks and areas instituted by the Count, church organizations great and small, and the nobility cross one another continuously. In Ghent, wool arrives via estate routes of the Abbeys of Saint Peter and Saint Bavo and by merchant traders on the Scheldt. At those places where for geographical or political reasons concentration or redistribution points coincide the evolutionary nature of the system is amplified. Pierre Toubert describes a parallel development in Northern Italy, where as of 920, a degree of fortification was given to numerous curtes, often accompanied by a market. Trading networks then grew up that tended to favour the ‘castelli curtensi’ and the close relationship between curtis, castrum and mercatum. It is ‘highly revealing of the positive adjustments to the commercial boom and the current redistribution of population patterns and local power structures’100. The establishment and consolidation of networks of power, production and trade appear to have been one of the forces driving the transformation of mediaeval society. According to a formula already enunciated by Henri Pirenne, the mediaeval town is the point of convergence of a regionally integrated market system, with fully articulated production and distribution systems. A town comes into existence by its ability to control an ‘area di strada’ and organize itself around and towards its rural hinterland (with a multiplicity of actors, interests and power structures). In the early 11th century the interplay of taxation and exemption helps to confirm the power of the town markets over the countryside. With exemptions being granted to the populations of about a hundred surrounding villages, people flocked to the market in Rheims, or, at the same period, to the men of the familia of Saint Vaast, who lived in a 60 km circle centred on Arras101. The peasant farmer came to the market with his cart, to sell primary products, wood for heating, unfinished wool, and above all cereal products. More importantly, however, he also came to buy things such as wine and beer, salt, fish, lumber and finished iron. The dominance of the town over the surrounding area will ultimately come with the rise of linen weaving in the towns to the detriment of the peasants in the surroundings who work wool and flax102. Two major problems are left. The first is the question of where the ways of the proto- urban settlements of the Early Middle Ages, which became small towns serving largely rural needs (such as Gembloux or Saint-Hubert) and those, which gave rise to towns thriving on commerce and production, begin to part. The second concerns the links between the rather coarse estate networks that served rural needs and the main roads of trade.

100 Toubert 1988. 101 Devroey 1993, Échange. 102 Derville 1991.

27 In Toubert's view, it was the same networks that were used for a superimposed flow of non-local trade, sometimes by persons whose status was ambiguous, such as agents of the king and certain large abbeys instructed with seeking goods which could not be obtained locally further afield, and sometimes merchants working for their own account. Franz Irsigler thinks that the Frankish merchants slowly eclipsed foreigners, who could have been Frisians or Jews, and who hitherto had dominated long distance trade. By the end of a long period of slow change accompanied by ever greater professionalism, at least some of these 11th century ‘long-distance merchants’ were the heirs of these local estate merchants. Although more independent, many of them continued to be protected by the Church in order to enjoy various commercial immunities103. This attractive hypothesis nonetheless strands on the hiatus in the documentary record of the first half of the 10th century. After the decline of the emporia located in the Northern Netherlands, the commercial role of the Frisians was eclipsed for more than a century. It was only at the end of the 10th century and more clearly at the start of the 11th century that we see Frisian merchants trying to feel their way back into their traditional markets. They pop up on the Rhine route, never totally abandoned, and further afield as far as the Western routes towards England and the Nordic countries. By the year one thousand they have contacts in the North Sea area with other coastal peoples, including Scandinavians, Anglo-Danes and Anglo-Saxons, Old Saxons from Bremen and Hamburg, Rhenish folk from Cologne and Duisburg, Flemings and people from the Meuse. Did those competitors ‘rush to fill the gap left vacant by Frisian merchants th 104 and the decline of Dorestad’ in the first years of the 10 century? . All along the Meuse, there is hardly a sign of a revival of interregional trade before the second half of the 10th century. It is unlikely that the portus of the towns on the banks of the Scheldt played a significant role in international trade before the close of the 10th century105. Nonetheless the presence of 9th, 10th and 11th century ceramics imported from Northern France and the Rhine in Ghent, Bruges, Antwerp and elsewhere seems to indicate a certain continuity of interregional contacts, which were in all probability commercial in nature106. The sudden halt to growth caused by the Norse incursions was not irreparable. For the time being though it must be acknowledged that we do not know all the participants in trading relations in the 10th century. The idea of agents acting for the estates being slowly transformed into ‘long-distance merchants’107 or the hypothesis of the Frisian gap being filled by local merchants108 must be carefully explored by future research. All we can say about 11th and 12th century merchants is that we know little about them109. We know nothing of the status (where they free or protected?) of the merchants who start to be mentioned in textual records shortly after the year 1000. For example, we know of a certain Robert, the son of Alward of Saint-Omer, who sells linen in Barcelona, and we know about all

103 Irsigler 1989; Verhulst 1993. 104 Lebecq 1983. 105 Devroey-Zoller, 1991. 106 Verhulst 1994. 107 Irsigler 1994. 108 Lebecq 1983. 109 Derville 1992.

28 those from Flanders, Ponthieu, Normandy and France, and from Huy, Liège and Nivelles, who pay stall dues to the Port of London on the Thames. Some of the merchants of Arras (mentioned in a text whose date is still uncertain (1030-1040) th th th were part of the familia of Saint-Vaast in the early 11 century. In the 12 -13 centuries the wine traders of Ghent were still paying dues to the abbeys of Saint Peter and Saint Bavo110. We must also ask if the dusty travellers – adventurers who spent most of the year tramping the roads were particularly numerous111. Towards the end of the 11th century we know that at Valenciennes guild brothers travelled in armed caravans for a three day march from the town. Shortly after the year one thousand, a merchant from Tournai came to the Saint Bavo fair to sell his load of wool. Until about 1050, perhaps 1100, it would have been this kind of interregional trade which was carried on by the itinerant merchants. London and England were two days away in a small sailing ship, other familiar destinations would have been Laon, Artois and Picardy, the Meuse, and the Rhine as far as Cologne. Not so much adventurers, more colleagues united in a guild in order to share the immediate dan- gers of the robber knight and excessive tolls. The Flemish merchant of the 11th century is difficult to discern from the sources. The Meuse Region gives us a clearer picture of the merchants, and it seems that here the growth of the towns was not so fast as in Flanders. Liège, the largest town on the Meuse in the 13th century still appears to be a town engaged primarily in tertiary activities. The large Flemish towns of the period were completely different. They were larger, pursued economic activities and dominated the surrounding countryside. To understand this asynchronicity between Flanders and the Meuse basin we must examine a final problem: namely the conditions under which the transfer of an industry and the concentration of labour, which had hitherto been largely rural, had taken place. The latter could indeed have been stimulated by demographic growth and the breakdown of estate structures in the countryside112. In the Middle Ages cloth was the only industrial product exported on a large scale. Hans Van Werveke argues that systematic manufacturing for export started in the Flemish town in the 11th century. This moment coincided with the use of English wool for the manufacture of luxury goods. Hitherto cloth had been produced solely for the domestic market and primarily to meet the needs of the family. ‘Frisian’ linen were made in the home, but sold outside the area where they were made,113 which according to the Pirenne School meant that they did not enter the commercial economy. Cloth and fabrics were part of the products supplied by peasants in the context of the estate trading circuits in North-West Europe. Archaeology and a re- examination of the textual evidence have made it possible to restore the parentage of the famous pallia fresonica to Frisia. Frisia in the Early Middle Ages was not just a country with a large sheep-farming industry, it also had a manufacturing industry, and was a country where everywhere wool was spun and woven in numerous small 114 workshops scattered over the countryside and in the towns . In about 830 we learn

110 Irsigler 1989. 111 Ganshof 1943. 112 Van Werveke 1949; Verhulst 1993. 113 Van Werveke 1951; Van Werveke 1954. 114 Lebecq 1983.

29 that the Abbey of Fulda received close to 855 pieces of cloth from its Frisian territories. In the 10th century, the Abbey of Werden received close to a thousand from the same area. In the 9th and 10th centuries, the monks of Saint Bavo in Ghent had lands in Frisia ‘for the convenience of the monks and particularly for their clothes’115. The homines franci installed on the estates of the abbey around the year 800 had to deliver a coat every year116. Whereas the monks of Ghent turned again to Frisia at the end of the 10th century, a text written in Trier (Treves) in about 1075, entitled Conflictus ovis et lini, reveals that Flemish cloth, prized for its colours and quality, had become an export product117. Accompanied by their fellows from the Meuse, Flemings travelled the Rhine valley to Koblenz between 1000 and 1070118. The few texts dating from the 8th and 10th centuries show that sheep farming existed on the coast. Specialized sheep-farming operations grew up on the ‘schorren’’ and the peat soils in the 11th and 12th centuries. After the marine incursions on the IJzer (Yser) river flood plain in the 1014 and 1042, numerous sheep farms were set upp. leper, which had hitherto only been an estate centre, became a town in the last decades of the 11th century. In 1127, its fair was visited by merchants from all the neighbouring kingdoms and particularly from Northern Italy, and Count Charles purchased a silver vessel from them. Verhulst thinks that these ‘Lombards’ could have come to leper to buy cloth119. Ghent received local wool, which was brought in to sell at the Saint Bavo fair by a merchant from Tournai since the start of the 11th century. It appears that the Abbeys of Saint Peter and Saint Bavo in Ghent brought the wool from their ‘’schorren’ north of Bruges and Aardenburg to these pre-urban centres or to Ghent. In the current state of documentary studies, it would seem that the growth of sheep farming in the 10th century favoured the spread of textile craft skills in the countryside and pre-urban centres. Clothes making in fact appears to be the only activity that allowed Carolingian craftswomen to gain a certain degree of independence, and consequently a potential for mobility, and to make a living from their skills. There were, for example, the camsilariae, who were women who made panels of cloth for shirts, and who lived on smallholdings near Tournai. They sold their products for 8 pennies apiece120. Did an increase in the availability of wool encourage the sale of unfinished wool (shortly after the year 1000 in Ghent) and the arrival of craft weavers in the town? It could well be that this first flowering of the Flemish cloth industry, a century before the first direct evidence of the arrival of English wool (perhaps in about 1113) was firmly and primarily based on local wool supplies. Was the ‘hunger’ for wool the result of the shrinkage of sheep flocks, itself a consequence of the construction of dykes around the ‘schorren’ and the gradual empoldering of the entire coastal region?121. Verhulst's field studies tend, however, to suggest a different chronology. The growth in the area of agricultural land is a phenomenon of the end of

115 Miracula s. Bertini. 116 Verhulst 1971. 117 Verlinden 1972. 118 Tissen 1989; Kölzer 1992. 119 Verhulst 1995 Economic; Verhulst 1995, Landschap. 120 Hägermann 1991. 121 Janssen 1982.

30 the 11th and of the 12th centuries122. In 1120, when an import of wool from England to Ghent is beyond dispute, the burgesses of Ghent were also having wool produced in the Vier-Ambachten (Quatre-Métiers) area, about 30 km north of the town123. In the early 12th century therefore textile production in Flanders was large enough to absorb all the local wool and to extend the market for raw wool to England. The Conflictus ovis et lini also indicates another change, namely that wool, unlike linen, which continued to be women's work, was from then on being worked by men124. In 1137, the monks of Sint-Truiden (Saint-Trond) condemned the behaviour of that ‘impudent and arrogant race of workers who are weavers of wool and linen’, without mentioning women at all. The author even praises the superiority of the ‘rusticus textor et pauper’ over the ‘urbanus exactor’125. The entry of men into an area, which since ancient times had been entirely the business of women, is indicative of the tremendous changes taking place. A final aspect, which should be considered, is the introduction of the horizontal loom. Rashi, who saw it at Troyes in mid-11th century, first reported it. The next innovation was a pedal loom, which appeared in the 12th century126. Such improvements made it possible to weave longer and more even pieces. The old vertical loom was indeed nothing more than a frame for holding the weft. The spread of new looms must have led to the rise of two new crafts: the construction of looms, and their operation by skilled workers. The shift of the textile industry away from the country and the domestic sphere towards the town and the professional sphere cannot be explained exclusively by the need for weavers and fullers to live in the towns where the merchants had their homes127. The facts as we know them are indicative of a more complex hypothesis: and where we see restrictions in demand: urban consumers (including more luxurious products); and in supply: appearance of new products, accompanied by changes in technology; rapid changes in the context and division of the work (from work in the home to work in a workshop, from opera rnuliebria to the superbia of the weavers) at the point where possibilities converge: urban centres; population growth in the countryside; abundant supplies of raw materials; and lively trading circuits. These were the conditions which were in effect in Flanders in the 11th century and which led to the appearance of an urban textile industry. The history of Ghent, illuminated by recent archaeological findings, indeed makes one suspect an even earlier chronology. A new wooden residence and a castle chapel was built in the first half of the 10th century on the ‘Oudburg’ site, after the Counts of Flanders had made themselves the masters of the Ghent area. The leatherworkers' district was very nearby. By no later than 966, the old Carolingian portus on the Scheldt had expanded to the Leie, opposite the castle of the Counts. It was here that the oldest market of the portus, the Fish Market (Vismarkt) was situated, the primary purpose of this market being to supply the inhabitants of the portus, the craftworkers and the garrison on the ‘Oudburg’ with food. The reason why the portus expanded towards

122 Verhulst 1995, Economic; Verhulst 1995, Landschap. 123 Blockmans 1983; Verhulst 1972. 124 Herlihy 1990. 125 Gesta Abbatum Trudonensium. 126 Janssen 1982. 127 Van Werveke 1951; Van Werveke 1954.

31 the Leie was the presence of this military centre. The Scheldt played a key role in interregional trade. This was the route by which the wool destined for the Fair of Saint Bavo arrived from Tournai in the early 11th century. The fair was held on the days following the feast day of the Patron Saint on the 1st of October. The sale of unfinished indicates that textile activities were already present in Ghent. The portus, where a representative of the Count (comes Gandavi portus) had been instead area, subject to its own judicial organization. The largest Flemish town in the Middle Ages had thus acquired the diverse characteristics required by the traditional definition of a 128 town by the year 1000 . The long slow rise of the economies of Northwest Europe th Pirenne's central idea was that the mediaeval town was born. In the 11 century, urban life revived under the effects of the revival of international trade ‘on virgin soil, without any antecedents from an earlier age’. Breaking with the division into the traditional periods of Western history has made possible to revise such theses. Pirenne himself suggested the enormously generative idea of a relatively continuous transition from Antiquity to the Merovingian period. Verhulst's studies of the origin of the towns in Northwest Europe confirm the relevance of this notion. For Pirenne, the Carolingians, which he describes as that ‘anticommercial civilization’ ruled over a rural West, dependent on a subsistence economy, the Norsemen moreover having totally destroyed trade. Since then the economy of-Carolingian times has been totally reviewed, with the intensity and nature of trade being examined, the start of demographic regeneration, and the importance of rural growth. The breakpoint represented by the millennium has in fact never been really questioned by historians. The majority of modern studies stop in the early 10th century. It is not a matter of seeking new continuities, for example, between the 9th and the 12th centuries. The unity of the process of historical development does not lie in the aspect which has remained immutable during the entire process, but in the continuity by which one particular change flows almost seamlessly into another in a constant succession of transformation. As Norbert Elias writes, for example, what links the Northern Netherlands of the 15th century with the 10th century (...) is not so much an essential core which has remained unchanged but the continuity of transformations whereby 20th century society proceeds from 15th century society (...) identity not being so much as a substance but more of a continuity of transformations leading from one stage to the next’129. Changing the frame of reference in order to deal with the historical evolution of the Southern Netherlands between the 6th and 12th centuries helps to highlight other series of changes. The 11th century in Flanders is one of urban harvest. The first fruits of the 10th century are the result of the slow and fundamental transformation of the countryside. Nowadays we are fortunate in having a synoptic picture that enables us to review the ‘Pirennean’ theories of the birth of the towns in their entirety130. In the Southern Netherlands the continuity of existence of the urban centres of Antiquity into the Middle Ages is far greater than was thought. This is not necessarily manifested in topographical continuity. The maintenance of central functions (whether religious,

128 Verhulst 1989, Ghent. 129 Elias 1996. 130 Verhulst 1987; Verhulst 1989 Towns.

32 administrative, military or other) plays an important role in the phenomena associated with the permanence of non-agricultural settlements. The topography of these urban habitats cannot be reduced to the traditional dualism of fortification and trading settlement. The reality prior to the year one thousand is far more complex than that, and these pre-urban settlements appear to have been closer to multi-centred accretions of people and activities than anything else. Pirenne regarded the fortification simply as a passive attractor of commercial activity. Nonetheless it now seems that the stronghold must have played an active economic role both as a centre of concentration and consumption131. The other break with ‘Pirennean’ models is the reassessment of the role of consumption in the trading economy. Pirenne thought that not only was the Flemish castrum not a town it had none of the features of a town either. Its population did not produce anything for itself and from the economic point of view it was nothing more than a consumer. Even so, as we have seen, the definition of the mediaeval town must be adjusted to account for both the emergence and divergence of the urban phenomenon in the Southern Netherlands. The town was a centre of consumption as well as a centre of commercial activity (or more broadly speaking a place where trading exchanges took place) and of production. As Pierre Toubert expresses it, this was a matter of circuits, activities and superimposed networks. Apart from the merchants, room must be allowed for the other components of the urban population, such as the clerical and secular elites, officials, sergeants and servants, craftsmen and so on. The role played by the Count's épiers and lardaria, or those of an abbey, nobleman, or high official deserve just as much attention as the market hall or merchant's stores. This view of things, based on a very broad sociological definition of trade, ought to make us just as interested in the private fortune of Chancellor Bertulf as in the more typical ‘Pirennian’ figure of Guillaume Cade132. Essentially this is a matter of applying the same epistemological broadening which allows the carts of the Carolingian monasteries to enter the trading economy to the 11th and 12th centuries. Nor should the role of the seigneuries in the 11th century trading economy be forgotten. In 1095, the Count of Hesdin's carts travelled laden with grain and wine through the Canche valley to the sea (where Quentovic arose) and returned with a cargo of salt and fish133. Viewing the history of the regional economies of the Southern Netherlands between the 7th and the 12th centuries as a single entity helps bring out how important the long-term trends are. The 7th century saw a shift in the European centre of gravity from the Mediterranean to Northwest Europe. Modern historians are well aware of the extent of interregional trading between the Frankish, Anglo-Saxon and Scandinavian worlds between the 7th and 9th centuries. The economic crisis of the early 9th century, the ‘Norse incursions’ and the documentary scarcity of the 10th century go a long way to supporting the view that this system of interregional trading was interrupted for an extended period of time. The Carolingian pagi of the Count of Flanders grew up on the edges of the trading areas. For people of the time, the success of this ‘terre brehaigne’ (barren

131 Verhulst 1987. 132 Derville 1992. 133 Fossier 1996.

33 land) was an event. Our understanding of the phenomenon nonetheless improves if we consider the development of North Western Europe as a space-time continuum, and stop thinking of the hiatus of the 9th century as a divide between two periods. If we ignore its specific form, we see that trading - be it commerce, migration, pillage and war, gifts and tributes -was not interrupted by the Norse incursions nor the crisis of the . Hiatus? Flemish merchants are known to have been regular visitors to the Port of London shortly after the year 1000. In 1127 the news of the death of Count Charles arrived in London the very next morning. English wool was being landed in Ghent in 1120. The world of Godric of Finchal, who lived at the end of the 11th century and is the archetypal merchant adventurer ‘inspired by the spirit of capitalism’ as Henri Pirenne puts it, was bounded by the shores of the North Sea: England, Scotland, Denmark, and Flanders134. Continuity? Count Baldwin I kidnaps and marries Judith, widow of two Wessex kings, while their son takes a leaf out of the parental book by carrying off Elftrude, daughter of Alfred the Great, King of Wessex. Other Anglo-Flemish marriages illustrate the permanence of contacts in the roth century. There was also commerce in thought and ideas. Dunstan and Ethelwood, two Englishmen, were in contact with Ghent, where Gerard de Brogne had just revived the abbey of Mont-Blandin. In about 1030 the Danes and the Normans in 1066 set about establishing states, which straddled the trading circuits of the 8th and the 10th centuries. Ships from Rouen loaded with wine discharged in London around the year 1000, just like the carts belonging to the Count of Hesdin which travelled to the mouth of the Canche in 1095. The continuum view is also useful for thinking about the historic conditions of the sustained growth of the economy of North-western Europe. It is this which is the proper scale for measuring phenomena of varying intensity and duration such as the ‘Frisian crossroads’ (7th to 9th centuries), the growth of Carolingian agriculture, the vitality of the money economy in England (7th to 12th centuries), the diversification of the Flemish economy (10th to 13th centuries), the industrialization and concentration of textile production in the towns (11th to 12th centuries), and the establishment of more far-flung trading networks and new continental ports, linking the North West to the South (fairs in Flanders and Champagne, Ghent and Bruges) and to the East (Cologne) (10th/11th to the 13th centuries). The long growth of agriculture started in the 8th century. The process speeded up in 11th century with the progressive diversification of the rural economy, nourished towards the south by cereal-growing country and stimulated in the north by the exploitation of the coastal strip and the production of local wool. The small family farm makes its appearance as a driving force in the intensification of farming methods with the general introduction of the horse as a draught animal, the adoption of an increasing diversity of farming techniques, an improvement in the balance between stock-farming and cultivation, and the introduction of new forage and cash crops. In return, the Flemish countryside is covered with a remarkably dense network of defended villages and fairs. This mesh of trade and power slowly starts to become centred on the towns in about the year 1000. We still find it difficult to gauge the power of attraction the towns had on the rural population of the times. The growth of

134 Derville 1992.

34 the urban population, which started in the 11th century, was rapid and sustained. The appearance of a wage-earning class and masculinization of the textile workforce during the 11th century was undoubtedly a crucial element in this process. It helped to shape the two faces of mediaeval society: the countryside and the ‘true’ town, self- aware and capable of attracting elite and poor alike. In the final analysis the mediaeval town must be considered as a social fact, a ‘human habitat’, which in turn begs the question about the emergence of urban society. When seen like this, numerous roads lead to the town. The town is ‘large’ if it becomes the political and administrative seat, the economic, religious and cultural centre of a large area135. Single-stranded explanations relying solely on commerce, the merchant or industry must be rejected, although the importance of such factors must be acknowledged. Long-distance commerce creates a powerful new link between the various regions of Europe. The Lombard merchants, who arrived in leper in 1127, were the heralds of a new and lasting dimension of economic, artistic and cultural exchanges between the Mediterranean and the North Sea. As of the 11th century, the town becomes distinct from the countryside by the nature, culture and dynamism of its elites. These meliores are not the mediaeval carpetbaggers suggested by Pirenne, rather they are a mixture of established and, more especially, new elites (the younger scions of noble families, vassal knights, ecclesiastical and lay administrators, etc.). From then on, the surplus of rural production was concentrated (directly in warehouses, or indirectly as money tithes) and consumed in the town. Such consumption could take the form of public and private buildings, luxury goods or works of art, customers, wage earners, and charitable works. Within the town walls princes occupied their palaces, clerics prayed, architects designed new buildings, sculptors and goldsmiths pursued their arts. Commerce is a consequence of urban life not a cause. The new elites were a driving force in the birth of what Verhulst calls the ‘town as such, with its own laws, administration and justice (and) free burgesses”136. They withdrew the town from the governance of the nobles and ruled themselves, without denying the authority prince and acquiring the total independence of the ‘urban republics’ of Italy. Every inhabitant of the town benefited from this ‘freedom’, which was an essential part of the urban landscape. Nonetheless it was the meliores who governed the town and thus secured their grip on the finance and trade passing through it until the great revolts of the early 14th century. In the process of the concentration of industry came later (metal working and linen) and came to a halt at the close of the Middle Ages. Indeed until the 18th century industry in Wallonia was to remain a largely rural affair. The industrialization of the textile industry in the towns explains the earliness and extent of urban concentration in Flanders. The unusual size of the Flemish towns greatly stimulated the demand for foodstuffs and industrial raw materials in the countryside. In turn it explains the intensification and progress of Flemish agriculture in the 13th and 14th centuries. The hypotheses advanced in the foregoing argue in favour of the continuity of economic expansion from the Carolingian era into the 11th, 12th and 13th centuries. This lengthy start should not be thought of as a progressive and continuous process, lacking crests and troughs. Proper studies of the economic cycles concerned remain

135 Genicot 1973. 136 Verhulst 1993.

35 to be made. The economic view in itself does not provide a complete picture of town and country. The birth of the ‘urban habitat’ as a physical space and a way of life requires an integrated approach, which pays attention to the social and cultural facts and the production and consumption of material goods137.

137 Verhulst 1997.

36 Bibliography Abel 1978 W. Abel, Geschichte der deutschen Landwirtschaft vom frühen Mittelalter bis zum 19. Jahrhundert, 3. Aufl., Berlin, 1978. Ambrosiani 1988 B. Ambrosiani, ‘The prehistory of towns in Sweden’, The rebirth of towns in the West, AD 700-1050, ed. R. Hodges, B. Hobley, Oxford, 1988 (CBA Research report n° 68), pp. 63-68. Blockmans 1983 W. Blockmans, ‘Vers une société urbanisée’, Histoire de Flandre, éd. E. Witte, Bruxelles, 1983, pp. 43-103 Bonnassie 1990 P. Bonnassie, ‘La croissance agricole du Haut Moyen Age dans la Gaule du Midi et le -Est de la péninsule ibérique: chronologie, modalités, limites’, La croissance agricole du Haut Moyen Age. Chronologie, modalités, géographie, Auch, 1990 (Flaran, 10), pp. 13- 35. Boserup 1965 E. Boserup, The conditions of agricultural growth, London, 1965. Cipolla 1956 C.M. Cipolla, Money, Prices and Civilization in the Mediterranean World, Fifth to Seventeenth Century, Princeton, 1956. Claude 1985, Handel D. Claude, Der Handel im westlichen Mittelmeer während des Frühmittelalters, 2, Göttingen, 1985 (Untersuchungen zu Handel und Verkehr der vor- und frühgeschichtlichen Zeit im Mittel- und Nordeuropa, 2). Claude 1985, Aspekte D. Claude, ‘Aspekte des Binnenhandels im Merowingerreich auf Grund der Schriftquellen’, Der Handel des frühen Mittelalters, Göttingen, 1985 (Untersuchungen zu Handel und Verkehr der vor- und frühgeschichtlichen Zeit im Mittel- und Nordeuropa, 3), pp. 9-99. Delatouche 1977 R. Delatouche, ‘Regards sur l'agriculture aux temps carolingiens’, Journal des Savants (1977), pp. 73-100. De Meulemeester 1990 J. De Meulemeester, ‘Karolingische castra en stadsontwikkeling: enkele archeotopografische suggesties’, La genèse et les premiers siècles des villes médiévales dans les Pays-Bas méridionaux. Un problème archéologique et historique, Bruxelles, 1990 (14e Colloque international, Spa, 6-8 sept. 1988), pp. 117-149. Derville 1989 A. Derville, ‘L'assolement triennal dans la France du Nord au moyen âge’, Revue Historique, 280, 1989, pp. 337-376. Derville 1991 A. Derville, ‘Villes et campagnes dans la région Nord/Pas-de-Calais de Charlemagne à Charles Quint’, Villes et campagnes au moyen âge. Mélanges Georges Despy, Liège, 1991, pp. 207-222. Derville 1992 A. Derville, ‘De Godric de Finchale à Guillaume Cade, l'espace d'une révolution’, Le Marchand au moyen âge, Paris, 1992, pp. 35-47. Derville 1995 A. Derville, Saint-Omer des origines au début du 14e siècle, Lille, 1995. Despy 1968 G. Despy, Villes et campagnes aux IXe et Xe siècles: l'exemple du pays mosan, Revue du Nord, 50 (1968), pp. 145-168. Despy 1975 G. Despy, ‘Naissance de villes et de bourgades’, La Wallonie. Le pays et les hommes. Histoire-économie-société, 1, Bruxelles, 1975, pp. 93- 129. Despy 1995 G. Despy, ‘L'Occident entre 800 et l'an mil: sous-développement ou croissance économique?’, Bulletin de la Classe des Lettres et des Sciences morales et politiques de l'Académie Royale de Belgique, 6e sér., 6, 1995, pp. 495-518.

37 Devroey 1981 J.-P. Devroey, Les méthodes d'analyse démographique des polyptyques du haut moyen âge, Acta Historica Bruxellensia, 4 (1981), pp. 71-88; repr. Devroey 1993, Domaine. Devroey 1990 J.-P. Devroey, La céréaliculture dans le monde franc, L'ambiente vegetale nell'alto medioevo, Spoleto, 1990 (Settimane di studio del Centro italiano di studi sull'alto medioevo, 37), pp. 221-253; repr. in Devroey 1993, Domaine. Devroey-Zoller 1991 J.-P. Devroey, C. Zoller, Villes, campagnes, croissance agraire dans le pays mosan avant l'an mil : vingt ans après ..., Villes et campagnes au moyen âge. Mélanges Georges Despy, Liège, 1991, pp. 223-260; repr. Devroey 1993, Domaine. Devroey 1993, Échange J.-P. Devroey, Courants et réseaux d'échange dans l'économie franque entre Loire et Rhin, Mercati e Mercanti nell'alto medioevo: l'area euroasiatica e l'area mediterranea, Spoleto, 1993 (Settimane di studio del Centro italiano di studi sull'alto medioevo, 40), pp. 327-389. Devroey 1993, Monasterii J.-P. Devroey, ‘Ad utilitatem monasterii. Mobiles et préoccupations de gestion dans l'économie monastique du monde franc’, Le monachisme à Byzance et en Occident du VIIIe au Xe siècle. Aspects internes et relations avec la société, Revue bénédictine, 103, 1993, pp. 224-240. Devroey 1993, Domaine J.-P. Devroey, Études sur le grand domaine carolingien, Aldershot, 1993. Devroey 1998 J.-P. Devroey, ‘Femmes au miroir des polyptyques. Une approche des rapports du couple dans l'exploitation rurale dépendante entre Seine et Rhin au IXe siècle’, Femmes et pouvoirs des femmes à Byzance et en Occident (VIe-XIe siècles), Colloque international, 28, 29 et 30 mars 1996, Lille, 1998. Dhondt 1948 J. Dhondt, ‘Développement urbain et initiative comtale en Flandre au XIe siècle’, Revue du Nord, 30, 1948, pp. 144-156. Duby 1961 G. Duby, L'économie rurale et la vie des campagnes dans l'Occident médiéval, 2 vol., Paris, 1961. Duby 1966 G. Duby, ‘Le problème des techniques agricoles’, Agricoltura e mondo rurale in Occidente nell'alto medioevo, Spoleto, 1966 (Settimane di studio del Centro italiano di studi sull'alto medioevo, 13), pp. 267-283. Elias 1996 Norbert Elias, Du temps, Paris, 1996. Fossier 1996 R. Fossier, ‘Le problème des marchés locaux en Picardie aux XIe et XIIe siècles’, Foires et marchés dans les campagnes de l'Europe médiévale et moderne, Toulouse, 1996, pp. 15-24, (Flaran 14). Fumagalli 1966 V. Fumagalli, ‘Rapporto fra grano seminato e grano raccolto, nel polittico del monastero di S. Tommaso di Reggio’, Rivista di storia dell'agricoltura, 6, 1966, pp. 360-362. Ganshof 1943 F.-L. Ganshof, La Flandre sous les premiers comtes, Bruxelles, 1943. Genicot 1973 L. Genicot, Histoire de la Wallonie, Toulouse, 1973. Grierson 1959 P. Grierson, ‘Commerce in the dark Ages: a critique of the evidence’, Transactions of the Royal Historical Society, 5e s., 9, 1959, pp. 123- 140. Grierson 1961 P. Grierson, ‘La fonction sociale de la monnaie en Angleterre aux VIIe- VIIIe siècles’, Moneta e scambi nell'alto medioevo, Spoleto, 1961 (Settimane di studio del Centro italiano di studi sull'alto medioevo, 8), pp. 341-362). Grierson 1986 P. Grierson, Medieval European Coinage, 1, The Early Middle Ages (5th to 10th Centuries), Cambridge, 1986.

38 Gros Brief 1962 Le Compte Général de 1187 connu sous le nom de ‘Gros Brief’, et les institutions financières du comté de Flandre au XIIe siècle, ed. A. Verhulst, M. Gysseling, Bruxelles, 1962. Hägermann 1991 D. Hägermann, ‘Grundherrschaft und Stadtischer Besitz in Urbarialen Quellen des 9. Jahrhunderts (Saint-Maur-des-Fossés, Saint-Remi de und Saint-Amand-les-Eaux)’, Villes et campagnes au moyen âge. Mélanges Georges Despy, Liège, 1991, pp. 355-365. Herlihy 1990 D. Herlihy, Opera muliebria : Women at Work in Medieval Europe, Philadelphia, 1990. Irsigler 1989 F. Irsigler, ‘Grundherrschaft, Handel und Märkte zwischen Maas und Rhein im frühen und hohen Mittelalter’, Grundherrschaft und Stadtentwicklung am Niederrhein, édité par K. Flink, W. Janssen, Kleve, 1989, pp. 52-78 Janssen 1982 H.P.H. Janssen, ‘Handel en Nijverheid 1000-1300’, Algemene Geschiedenis der Nederlanden, 2e éd., 2, Haarlem, 1982, pp. 148- 186. Jansson 1985 I. Jansson, ‘Communications between Scandinavia and Eastern Europe in the Viking Age’, Untersuchungen zu Handel und Verkehr der vor- und frühgeschichtlichen Zeit im Mittel- und Nordeuropa, hrsg. v. K. Duewe, H. Jankuhn, H. Siems, D. Timpe, t. 4, Der handel der Karolinger- und Wikingerzeit, Göttingen, 1987, pp. 773-807. Kölzer 1992 T. Kölzer, ‘Nochmals zum ältesten Koblenzer Zolltarif’, Aus Archiven und Bibliotheken. Festschrift für Raymund Kottje zum 65. Geburtstag, Freiburger Beiträge zur mittelaterlichen Geschichte, 3, 1992, pp. 291- 310. Kupper 1981 J.-L. Kupper, Liège et l'Église impériale. XIe-XIIe siècles, Paris, 1981. Kupper 1990 J.-L. Kupper, ‘Archéologie et histoire: aux origines de la cité de Liège (VIIIe-XIe siècles’, La genèse et les premiers siècles des villes médiévales dans les Pays-Bas méridionaux. Un problème archéologique et historique, Bruxelles, 1990 (14e Colloque international, Spa, 6-8 sept. 1988), pp. 377-389. Lebecq 1983 S. Lebecq, Marchands et navigateurs frisons du haut moyen âge, Lille, 2 vol., 1983. Lopez 1974 R. S. Lopez, La révolution commerciale dans l'Europe médiévale, Paris, 1974. Medieval Farming 1997 Medieval Farming and Technology. The Impact of Agricultural Change in Northwest Europe, ed. G. Astill, J. Langdon, Leiden, 1997. Montanari 1985 M. Montanari, ‘Techniche e rapporti di produzione: le rese cerealicole del IX al XV secolo’, Le campagne italiane prima e dopo il Mille. Une società in trasformazione, Bologna, 1985, pp. 45-68. Morimoto 1994 Y. Morimoto, ‘L'assolement triennal au haut Moyen Age. Une analyse des données des polyptyques carolingiens’, Économie rurale et économie urbaine au Moyen Age, Gand-Fukuoka, 1994, pp. 91-125 (Centre belge d'histoire rurale, Publication n° 108). Nicholas 1991 D. Nicholas, ‘Of Poverty and Primacy: Demand, Liquidity, and the Flemish Economic Miracle, 1050-1200’, The American Historical Review, 96, 1991, pp. 17-41. Nicholas 1992 D. Nicholas, Medieval Flanders, London, 1992. Pirenne 1900 H. Pirenne, Histoire de Belgique des origines au commencement du XIVe siècle, Bruxelles, 1900. Pirenne 1905 H. Pirenne, ‘Les villes flamandes avant le XIIe siècle’, Annales de l'Est et du Nord, 1, 1905.

39 Pirenne 1937 H. Pirenne, Mahomet et Charlemagne, Paris, 1937. Rösener 1992 W. Rösener, Agrarwirtschaft, Agrarverfassung und ländliche Gesellschaft im Mittelalter, München, 1992 (Enzyklopädie deutscher Geschichte, 13). Rousseau 1930 F. Rousseau, La Meuse et le pays mosan en Belgique. Leur importance historique avant le XIIIe siècle, Namur, 1930. Schwarz 1985 G.M. Schwarz, ‘Village populations according to the polyptyque of the abbey of St-Bertin’, Journal of Medieval History, 11, 1985, pp. 31-41. Spa 1990 La genèse et les premiers siècles des villes médiévales dans les Pays-Bas méridionaux. Un problème archéologique et historique, Bruxelles, 1990 (14e Colloque international, Spa, 6-8 sept. 1988). Thoen 1992 E. Thoen, ‘Technique agricole, cultures nouvelles et économie rurale en Flandre au bas moyen âge’, Plantes et cultures nouvelles, Auch, 1992 (Flaran 12), pp. 51-67. Thoen 1994 E. Thoen, ‘Le démarrage économique de la Flandre au Moyen Age: le rôle de la campagne et des structures politiques (XIe-XIIIe siècles). Hypothèses et voies de recherches’, Economie rurale et économie urbaine au Moyen Age. Landwirtschaft und Stadtwirtschaft im Mittelalter, ed. A. Verhulst, Y. Morimoto, Gent-Fukuoka, 1994, pp. 165- 184. Tissen 1989 B. Tissen, ‘Het oudste Toltarief van Koblenz. Een bijdrage tot de bronnenkritiek’, Fonteyn der ewiger Wijsheit. Opstellen aangeboden aan Prof. Dr. A.G. Weiler, éd. P. Bange, P. de Kort, Nijmegen, 1989, pp. 180-222. Toubert 1986 P. Toubert, ‘Le moment carolingien’, A. Burguière et al. (éd.), Histoire de la Famille, Paris, 1986, 1, pp. 333-359. Toubert 1988 P. Toubert, ‘La part du grand domaine dans le décollage économique de l'Occident (VIIIe-Xe siècles)’, La croissance agricole du Haut Moyen Age. Chronologie, modalités, géographie, Auch, 1990 (Flaran 10), pp. 53-86. Van Uytven 1976 R. Van Uytven, ‘Vorst, adel en steden: een driehoeksverhouding in Brabant van de twaalfde tot de zestiende eeuw’, Bijdragen tot de Geschiedenis, 29, 1976, pp. 93-122. Van Uytven 1981 R. Van Uytven, ‘Het stedelijk leven, 11de-14de eeuw’, in:Algemene Geschiedenis der Nederlanden, 2e éd., 1, Haarlem, 1981, pp. 187- 253. Van Werveke 1949 H. Van Werveke, ‘Essor et déclin de la Flandre’, Studi in onore di Gino Luzatto, Milano 1949, pp. 152-160; repr. Van Werveke 1968. Van Werveke 1951 H. Van Werveke, ‘Landelijke en stedelijke nijverheid. Bijdrage tot de oudste geschiedenis van de Vlaamse steden’, Verslag van de algemene vergadering der leden van het Historisch Genootschap, Utrecht, 1951, pp. 37-51; repr. Van Werveke 1968. Van Werveke 1952 H. Van Werveke, De economische politiek van Filips van de Elzas (1157-68 tot 1191), Brussel, 1952. Van Werveke 1954 H. Van Werveke, ‘Industrial Growth in the Middle Ages. The Cloth Industry in Flanders’, Economic History Review, 6, pp. 237-245. Van Werveke 1968 H. Van Werveke, Miscellanea Medievalia. Verspreide opstellen over economische en sociale geschiedenis van de middeleeuwen, Gent, 1968. Verhulst 1966 A. Verhulst, ‘La genèse du régime domanial classique en France au haut moyen âge’, Agricoltura e mondo rurale in Occidente nell'alto

40 medioevo, Spoleto, 1966 (Settimane di studio del Centro italiano di studi sull'alto medioevo, 13), pp. 135-160; repr. Verhulst 1992. Verhulst 1967, Comtale A. Verhulst, ‘Initiative comtale et développement économique en Flandre au XIIe siècle: le rôle de Thierry et de Philippe d'Alsace (1128- 1191)’, Miscellanea Medievalia in honorem J.F. Niermeyer, Groningen, 1967, pp. 227-240. Verhulst 1967, Politique A. Verhulst, ‘Un exemple de la politique économique de Philippe d'Alsace comte de Flandre: la fondation de Gravelines (1163)’, Cahiers de Civilisation médiévale, 10, 1967, pp. 15-18. Verhulst 1971 A. Verhulst, ‘Das Besitzverzeichnis der Genter Sankt-Bavo-Abtei von ca. 800’, Fruhmittelalterliche Studien, 5, 1971, pp. 193-234. Verhulst 1972 A. Verhulst, ‘La laine indigène dans les anciens Pays-Bas entre le XIIe et le XVIIe siècle. Mise en œuvre industrielle, production et commerce‘, Revue Historique, 504, 1972, pp. 281-322. Verhulst 1978 A. Verhulst, ‘Het Ontstaan en de vroege topografie van Antwerpen van de Romeinse tijd tot het begin van de 12de eeuw’, De Stad Antwerpen van de Romeinse tijd tot de 17de eeuw. Topografische studie rond het plan van Virgilius Bononiensis 1565, Brussel, 1978, pp. 13-40. Verhulst 1982 A. Verhuslt ‘Occupatiegeschiedenis en landbouweconomie in het Zuiden circa 1000-1300’, Algemene Geschiedenis der Nederlanden, 2de uitg., 2, Haarlem, 1982, pp. 83-104. Verhulst 1985 A. Verhulst, ‘L'intensification et la commercialisation de l'agriculture dans les Pays-Bas méridionaux au XIIIe siècle’, La Belgique rurale du moyen âge à nos jours. Mélanges offerts à Jean-Jacques Hoebanx, Bruxelles, 1985, pp. 89-100. Verhulst 1986 A. Verhulst, ‘L'actualité de Pirenne’, La fortune historiographique des thèses d'Henri Pirenne, Bruxelles, 1986, pp. 149-153. Verhulst 1987 A. Verhulst, ‘Les origines urbaines dans le nord-ouest de l'Europe : essai de synthèse’, 14 (1987), pp. 57-81; repr. Verhulst 1992.. Verhuslt 1989, Towns A. Verhulst, ‘The Origins of Towns in the and the Pirenne Thesis’, Past and Present, n. 122, 1989, pp. 3-35; repr. Verhulst 1992. Verhulst 1989, Ghent A. Verhulst, G. Declercq, ‘Early Medieval Ghent Between Two Abbeys and the Count's Castle’, Ghent. In defence of a Rebellious City, ed. J. Decavele, Antwerp, 1989, pp. 1-52; repr. Verhulst 1992. Verhulst 1990, Slavery A. Verhulst, ‘The decline of slavery and the economic expansion of the early Middle Ages’, Past and Present, n° 133 (1991), pp. 195-203. Verhulst 1990, Rurale A. Verhulst, Précis d'histoire rurale de la Belgique, Bruxelles, 1990. Verhulst 1992 A. Verhulst, Rural and Urban Aspects of Early Medieval Northwest Europe, Adershot, 1992. Verhulst 1993 A. Verhulst, ‘Marchés, marchands et commerce au haut moyen âge dans l'historiographie récente’, Mercati e Mercanti nell'alto medioevo: l'area euroasiatica e l'area mediterranea, Spoleto, 1993 (Settimane di studio del Centro italiano di studi sull'alto medioevo, 40), pp. 23-43. Verhulst 1994 A. Verhulst, ‘Grundherrschaftliche Aspekte bei der Entstehung der Städte Flanderns’, in Économie rurale et économie urbaine au Moyen Âge, Gand, Fukuoka, 1994, pp. 157-164. Verhulst 1995, Economic A. Verhulst, ‘Economic Organisation’, The New Cambridge Medieval History, 2, c.700-c.900, ed. by R. McKitterick, Cambridge, 1995, pp. 481-509.

41 Verhulst 1995, Landschap A. Verhulst, Landschap en Landbouw in Middeleeuws Vlaanderen, Gent, 1995. Verhulst 1997 A. Verhulst, ‘The State of Research. Medieval Socio-Economic Historiography in Western Europe: Towards an Integrated Approach’, Journal of Medieval History, 23, 1997, pp. 89-101. Verlinden 1972 C. Verlinden, ‘Marchands ou tisserands ? A propos des origines urbaines’, Annales ESC, 1984, pp. 570-589. Violante 1953 C. Violante, La società milanese nell'eta precomunale, Bari, 1953. White 1940 L. White, ‘Technology and Invention in the Middle Ages’, Speculum, 15, 1940, pp. 141-159. Wickham 1992 C. Wickham, ‘Problems of comparing rural societies in early medieval Western Europe’, Transactions of the Royal Historical Society, 6e série, 2 (1992), pp. 221-246. Wickham 1995 C. Wickham, ‘Rural Society in Carolingien Europe’, The New Cambridge Medieval History, 2, c.700-c.900, ed. by R. McKitterick, Cambridge, 1995, pp. 510-537. Yamada 1991 M. Yamada, ‘Le mouvement des foires en Flandre avant 1200’, Villes et campagnes au moyen âge. Mélanges Georges Despy, Liège, 1991, pp. 773-789.

42