The Bubble and the Lost Decade 269

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Bubble and the Lost Decade 269 BlackwellOxford,TWECThe0378-5920©March2631000OriginalTHEGARY 2003 World BUBBLE 2003R. BlackwellUKArticle SAXONHOUSEPublishing Economy AND Publishers THE TheLtd LOST AND Ltd DECADEROBERT (a Blackwell M. STERN Publishing Company) Bubble and the Lost Decade Gary R. Saxonhouse and Robert M. Stern Inthediscuss this evidence overview a number suggests of ofthe unconventional Symposium that looser fiscalpapers, and policybold we measures notewould that have thethat beenbubble the BOJineffective, that and occurred MOF monetary could in Japan’s pursue.policy asset measures It appears, markets might however, in the have late that worked. 1980s the political cameHowever at will a, the timeis absent BOJ when followed to the undertake conventional a relatively such1. indicators measures.tight monetary ofINTRODUCTION So Japan’s long policy as economic inthis 1991–93. is the performance case, In the the face effects were of the relativelyof theliquidity lost stable. decadetrap that Following will ensued continue the in collapsethe to actlast as ofof a thet hedrag 1990s,bubble, on the the neither economy. conventional the Bank tools of Japan of stabilisation (BOJ) nor thepolicy Ministry appeared of finance to be (MOF)of limited took use. timely To help and theeffective Japanese measures economy to deal to recovewith ther from recession the ‘lost that decade,’ followed. we While thus LITTLE more than a dozen years ago, in 1989, Japan was completing a decade Aof excellent economic performance. Its 3.9 per cent average annual rate of growth of gross domestic product, while slower than what it had achieved in any earlier decade since 1950, was still significantly better than the performance of the world’s other advanced industrialised economies. During this same decade, equity prices rose six-fold and land prices more than four-fold.1 Even as equity and land prices increased dramatically, in 1989, many econom- ists were prepared to argue that the new valuations were justified by Japan’s economic fundamentals.2 Japan’s distinctive, but superior system of economic management, both at the government level and within the firm, it was argued, justified more optimistic expectations of further exceptional economic growth even as Japan’s unusually high national savings rate kept real interest rates lower than those in other major industrialised economies. Indeed, its distinctive eco- nomic system was seen as working so well by comparison with those of other major economies that Japan was hailed by Chalmers Johnson (1989) as the only ‘Communist nation that works.’ In March 2002, when the Symposium was convened in Ann Arbor at which earlier versions of the papers were presented, Japan looked very different. Japan’s post-1989 GDP growth has averaged no more than 1.2 per cent annually, worse than that of any other major industrialised country. Japan’s equity markets, after reaching a peak at the end of 1989, have fallen by 75 per cent. Japanese land prices have fared still worse with prices falling by 80 per cent, so that in 2002, Japanese land prices are below levels prevailing 20 years ago. Thus, GARY R. SAXONHOUSE and ROBERT M. STERN are from the University of Michigan (Ann Arbor). The papers in this issue were prepared initially for a Symposium held on 22 March, 2002, at the University of Michigan. Support was provided by the Japan Foundation, Centre for Global Partnership. The latter stages of Saxonhouse’s work on this project were facilitated by a residency at the Rockefeller Foundations Bellagio Study and Conference Center. 1 See Figure 1 in Takatoshi Ito’s Symposium paper below. 2 Frankel (1991) reviews much of this literature. © Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2003, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford, OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA 267 268 GARY R. SAXONHOUSE AND ROBERT M. STERN Chalmers Johnson who wrote in 1989 that ‘Japan is the only Communist nation that works’ more recently (1998) has written that ‘Japan truly fits the crony capitalism description that has complacently continued to protect its structurally corrupt and sometimes gangster-ridden firms.’ As Nishimura and Kawamoto show in their Symposium paper below, the very economic institutions, such as community banking and permanent employment (and they might have added close government-business relationships) that for four decades were seen as enhancing Japanese growth prospects are now seen as standing in the way of renewed superior economic performance. With hindsight, it is easy to criticise the failure of so many observers in the late 1980s to foresee the marked change that was about to occur in Japan’s economic fortunes. In light of the experience of the United States in the 1990s, however, it is clear that such failures are not unique to Japan. In both Japan in the late 1980s and in the United States in the late 1990s, prices of assets, such as equities and land, rose rapidly even while the prices of goods and services were relatively stable. In such an environment, it admittedly is difficult to deter- mine, until after the fact, whether the asset-price increases represent speculative excess or a secular change in the rate of growth of productivity. But, for our purposes, we will assume that a bubble did occur in Japan. With this in mind the Symposium that follows seeks to explore: (1) whether the bubble could have been prevented; (2) how much of the economic pain that Japan faced during the 1990s was the result of the bubble’s collapse; and (3) what can be done today to help resolve Japan’s continuing economic problems.3 2. COULD THE BUBBLE HAVE BEEN PREVENTED? Takatoshi Ito addresses the first of the issues raised above in his Symposium paper. Mindful that it is difficult to know that a bubble has occurred until after it is over, Ito suggests that the Bank of Japan (BOJ), at the time of the Louvre Accord in February 1987, should not have cut the discount rate from 3 to 2.5 per cent. Failing that, he argues that the BOJ discount rate could still have been raised in August 1988 when the Federal Reserve and the Bundesbank raised interest rates. According to Ito, earlier tightening of monetary policy might have nipped the bubble in the bud, but even in the summer of 1988 tightening credit conditions might still have prevented some of the worst problems that ultimately arose. By May 1989 when the discount rate was finally raised, according to Ito, it was too late. 3 These and other current issues pertinent to Japan are also explored in depth in the papers in Stern (2003). © Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2003 THE BUBBLE AND THE LOST DECADE 269 To underline how politically difficult it might have been for the BOJ to raise its discount rate, it should be remembered that, during the very years that Ito says that the BOJ should have reversed policy, many observers abroad were not only praising Japan’s economic institutions, they were also praising the quality of Japanese macroeconomic management for simultaneously keeping interest rates low and inflationary expectations damped. For example, David Hale, a highly influential US business economist, wrote in August 1989 that: During the second half of the decade, it was the Japanese MOF [Ministry of Finance] which used a mixture of direct intervention and moral suasion to protect the US financial system from sharply rising interest rates at a time when foreign private investors lost confidence in the US dollar. the MOF and the BOJ pursued a low interest rate policy to boost the US dollar during 1987– 88 and neutralized the potential inflationary consequences on credit growth through administrat- ive guidance (pp. 60–61). Likewise, in 1988, C. Fred Bergsten, the Director of the Institute for International Economics, praised Japanese policies: Since 1986, in perhaps its most impressive performance to date, Japan has adjusted to a near doubling in the dollar value of the yen by shifting with remarkable speed from the export-led growth of the early 1980s to a domestic-led expansion that has produced a burst of rapid growth despite the steady decline of its trade balance in real terms. Japan’s new Five-Year Plan (1988–92) projects GNP growth of 3.75 percent annually and growth in domestic demand of 4.25 percent annually. It . seems both desirable and feasible for Japan to exceed targets in the plan, perhaps maintaining domestic demand at about 6 percent annually. In fact, domestic demand growth reached an estimated 7.4 percent in 1988 (pp. 63 and 103). Quite apart from an earlier move to more restrictive macroeconomic policies, Ito suggests that stricter prudential policies, had they been adopted, could have had a significant impact on the magnitude of the bubble. Ito believes that Japanese authorities could have: (1) introduced a regulation (or guidance) on the loan/value ratio on real estate lending, citing the increased risk of real- estate-price volatility; and (2) issued a regulation (or guidelines) to limit lending to real-estate-related sectors, citing the risks of concentrating loans too heavily in a single sector. Many market participants in the late 1980s already recognised that these very steps, that Ito now recommends with hindsight, were required. Interestingly enough, they believed that the Japanese government was taking just such measures. Quoting again from Hale: The BOJ ordered the banks to reduce the growth rate of total lending and sharply curtailed the supply of funds available for property speculation. As a result, the growth rate of bank lending for real estate fell from 32% to 8% and there was a modest decline in Tokyo real estate prices during 1987 and 1988 despite a monetary policy which was highly accommodating in every © Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2003 270 GARY R.
Recommended publications
  • Policy Response to Crises in Latin America
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE ROAD TO REDEMPTION: POLICY RESPONSE TO CRISES IN LATIN AMERICA Carlos A. Vegh Guillermo Vuletin Working Paper 20675 http://www.nber.org/papers/w20675 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 November 2014 Paper prepared for the 2013 IMF Annual Research Conference in honor of Stanley Fischer's 70th birthday. We are extremely grateful to Julia Ruiz Pozuelo and Collin Rabe for research assistance. On a personal note, Vegh owes a huge debt of gratitude to Stan for 20 years of unwavering mentorship, co-authorship, and support (dating back to Stan's arrival at the IMF in September 1994). Stan is one of those rare individuals who combines truly remarkable professional credentials with equally astounding personal qualities. Our profuse thanks to Vittorio Corbo as well as to two referees and the editors of this Journal for extremely helpful comments and suggestions. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer- reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2014 by Carlos A. Vegh and Guillermo Vuletin. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. The Road to Redemption: Policy Response to Crises in Latin America Carlos A. Vegh and Guillermo Vuletin NBER Working Paper No.
    [Show full text]
  • Is America Economically Headed for a 1990S-Style Japanese “Lost Decade” of Stagnant Growth?
    A SYMPOSIUM OF VIEWS An American Lost Decade? Is America economically headed for a 1990s-style Japanese “lost decade” of stagnant growth? THE MAGAZINE OF INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC POLICY 888 16th Street, N.W., Suite 740 Washington, D.C. 20006 Phone: 202-861-0791 • Fax: 202-861-0790 www.international-economy.com 6 THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY SUMMER 2009 No, but I worry America will face about something more than one different. “lost decade.” SAMUEL BRITTAN TADASHI NAKAMAE Columnist, Financial Times President, Nakamae International Economic Research take the question to mean “Is the United States likely he United States is in for more than just one “lost to endure a decade of stagnation?” My answer is no. decade.” Like Japan, which is well into its second IPresent problems are due to failure of the banking and Tlost decade, the United States is dealing with the monetary mechanism. In other words, insufficient pieces detritus of its ruptured bubble economy in the wrong way. of paper are being created or used to purchase potential In order to define Japan’s lost decade, a sketch of output. This problem is not beyond the wit of man to the bubble economy that preceded it might be in order. In solve, whether by injecting more Federally created dol- 1989, the grounds of the Imperial Palace in Tokyo were lars, “rescuing” the banks, or supplementing or replacing more expensive than the whole of California. Japanese them with government credit institutions. Fed Chairman companies, financial and non-financial, it was said, were Ben Bernanke and presidential counselor Larry Sum- about to conquer the world.
    [Show full text]
  • PERUVIAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION Peru's Great
    PERUVIAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION Peru's Great Depression A Perfect Storm? Luis Gonzalo Llosa Ugo Panizza Working Paper No. 45, May 2015 The views expressed in this working paper are those of the author(s) and not those of the Peruvian Economic Association. The association itself takes no institutional policy positions. Peru's Great Depression A Perfect Storm? Gonzalo Llosa and Ugo Panizza * The expression “Perfect Storm” refers to the simultaneous occurrence of events which, taken individually, would be far less powerful than the result of their combination. Such occurrences are rare by their very nature, so that even a slight change in any one event contributing to the perfect storm would lessen its overall impact. (Wikipedia) Introduction Over the 1970s and 1980s Peru went through a series of deep and protracted economic crises which generated enormous output losses. While output collapses are not uncommon in the emerging world (in a sample of 31 emerging market countries over the 1980-2004 period, Calvo et al., 2006 identify 22 events), Peru stands apart for the rapid succession of crises. For three times in a row, as soon as output would recover to its pre-crisis level, a new crisis would hit the country and destroy all the progress made during the previous years. As a consequence, the growth rate of Peru's GDP per capita averaged to 0 percent over a thirty-year period (1975-2005), a horrible performance even when compared to Latin America's dismal rate of economic growth. Moreover, while Calvo et al. (2006) document that great depressions tend to be V-shaped (i.e., characterized by a rapid collapse and a rapid recovery with almost no investment), the recovery from Peru's deepest collapse took 15 years, clearly not a V-shaped crisis.
    [Show full text]
  • The Rise and Fall of Argentina
    Spruk Lat Am Econ Rev (2019) 28:16 https://doi.org/10.1186/s40503-019-0076-2 Latin American Economic Review RESEARCH ARTICLE Open Access The rise and fall of Argentina Rok Spruk* *Correspondence: [email protected] Abstract School of Economics I examine the contribution of institutional breakdowns to long-run development, and Business, University of Ljubljana, Kardeljeva drawing on Argentina’s unique departure from a rich country on the eve of World ploscad 27, 1000 Ljubljana, War I to an underdeveloped one today. The empirical strategy is based on building Slovenia a counterfactual scenario to examine the path of Argentina’s long-run development in the absence of breakdowns, assuming it would follow the institutional trends in countries at parallel stages of development. Drawing on Argentina’s large historical bibliography, I have identifed the institutional breakdowns and coded for the period 1850–2012. The synthetic control and diference-in-diferences estimates here suggest that, in the absence of institutional breakdowns, Argentina would largely have avoided the decline and joined the ranks of rich countries with an income level similar to that of New Zealand. Keywords: Long-run development, New institutional economics, Political economy, Argentina, Applied econometrics JEL Classifcation: C23, K16, N16, N46, O43, O47 1 Introduction On the eve of World War I, the future of Argentina looked bright. Since its promulga- tion of the 1853 Constitution, Argentina had experienced strong economic growth and institutional modernization, which had propelled it into the ranks of the 10 wealthi- est countries in the world by 1913. In the aftermath of the war, Argentina’s income per capita fell from a level approximating that of Switzerland to its current middle-income country status.
    [Show full text]
  • Inflation and Instability: Brazil's Lost Decade And
    APPLIED ECONOMICS INFLATION AND INSTABILITY : B RAZIL ’S LOST DECADE AND CARDOSO ’S RESPONSE ISABELLA DI PAOLO Senior Sophister in the 1990's brazil suffered a turbulent period of hyperinflation. in this paper, is - abella di Paolo provides an intriguing explanation of the policies which led to brazil's crisis, and an evaluation of how the reforms of President Cardoso helped set brazil on its current growth path. 1. Introduction the famous joke goes: “brazil is, and always will be, the land of the future”. long strug - gling to achieve long-term, sustainable growth - despite its abundant resources and im - mense potential - brazil has recently seen considerable improvements in both its economic performance and poverty-reduction strategies. the recent consumer boom, experienced as millions filled middle-class ranks, makes it difficult to imagine that just two decades ago inflation was taking over everyday life.1 it was the centre of all policy concerns, caused hour-long queues in front of supermarkets and crushed innumerable hopes and dreams. today, a decade-long struggle for macroeconomic stability has rendered the daily reality of twenty years ago completely unimaginable to those who have only known recent pros - perity (leitão, 2011). after an initial taming of the ‘inflation monster’ via the Plano real, brazilian policy-makers have demonstrated continuity in their will to reform, as exemplified by the continued adoption of the inflation targeting mechanism and law of fiscal respon - sibility introduced at the end of the cardoso administration. as brazil begins to display difficulties in continuing down the path of rapid growth, (financial times, 2013) it is more important than ever to remember the recent past, and to consider the long way the coun - try has come.
    [Show full text]
  • IV. Revisiting Japan's Lost Decade
    IV. Revisiting Japan’s Lost Decade his chapter discusses Japan’s experiences with distress may be called for given the significant Tits banking crisis in the 1990s and the potential downside risks that remain. In all these areas, implications for resolving the current global crisis. Japan’s experiences provide a rich array of lessons Drawing on insights from a recent IMF seminar that could guide policy responses. (Box 4.1), the chapter revisits the Japanese fiscal, Accordingly, the chapter asks: monetary, and financial sector policy responses through the lens of the present turmoil. In doing so, x Based on Japan’s experience, can fiscal policy be it draws possible lessons for policymakers today, used to stimulate the economy and, if so, what including in Asia, as they attempt to stabilize their measures are likely to work? Looking ahead, economies and orchestrate a recovery. how concerned should policymakers be about Japan’s crisis was successfully resolved and most risks to medium-term fiscal sustainability? of the public funds deployed were recovered, but x How successful was Japan in easing credit not before a “lost decade” of stagnation and conditions and fighting deflation using prolonged deflation. While today’s policy challenges unconventional monetary policies? are compounded by the complexity of the distressed assets involved and the global scope of the crisis, x In the financial sector, what strategies did Japan they are in many ways similar to the problems Japan use to clean up bank and debtor balance sheets had to confront. Therefore, Japan’s eventual and to restore lending? How were the fiscal success—and early difficulties—in overcoming its costs of these interventions managed and what crisis could provide useful insights.
    [Show full text]
  • Argentina's Lost Decade
    CLAE WORKING PAPER NO. 0401 ARGENTINA’S LOST DECADE1 Finn E. Kydland Carnegie-Mellon University and Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas E-mail: [email protected] Carlos E. J. M. Zarazaga Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas 2200 N. Pearl Street, Dallas, TX 75201 E-mail: [email protected] August 2001 Forthcoming in Review of Economic Dynamics Corresponding Author: Carlos E. J. M. Zarazaga 1 The views herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the positions of the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas or the Federal Reserve System. The authors are grateful to Fernando Alvarez, Tim Kehoe, Jim MacGee, Ed Prescott, an anonymous referee and the participants at the Minneapolis Fed Conference on Great Depressions in October 2000 for extremely useful and constructive comments and suggestions on an earlier version of this paper. We also wish to acknowledge the diligent assistance of Francisco Contreras and Eric Millis in gathering and processing the necessary data at different stages of this project. Abstract Argentina suffered a depression in the 1980s that was as severe as the Great Depression experienced in the United States and Germany in the interwar period. Our paper examines this depression from the perspective of growth theory, taking total factor productivity as exogenous. The predictions of the growth model conform rather well with the observations during the ”lost decade” years. Journal of Economic Literature Classification Codes: E32. Key Words: Argentina, depression, growth model. 1. INTRODUCTION The unusual features and severity of the Great Depression in the United States has been the object of much speculation among economists and social scientists intrigued by a phenomenon still resistant to a widely accepted explanation.
    [Show full text]
  • Latin America's Debt Crisis and “Lost Decade”
    Learning from Latin America: Debt crises, debt rescues and when and why they work 20 February 2012 1 Latin America’s debt crisis and “lost decade” Luis Bértola and José Antonio Ocampo* Latin America´s State-led industrialization model began to come under criticism in the 1960s both from the advocates of orthodox economic thinking and from the political left.1 The former criticized it for its lack of macroeconomic discipline and inefficiencies generated by high tariffs and quantitative import restrictions and, more generally, by excessive State intervention. The latter criticized it because of its inability to overcome the economy’s external dependence and, in particular, the unequal social structures that were a legacy of the past. Although he did not necessarily share the views of the political left, Hirschman (1971, p. 123) expressed this idea brilliantly: “Industrialization was expected to change the social order and all it did was to supply manufactures”. As this model matured, it came to be associated with a great deal of economic, social and political tensions. Social conflicts first arose in the Southern Cone countries, which had been the first to witness major social changes as well as a slowdown in growth. The opportunities that growth periods provided for enhancing well-being and social entitlements were taken advantage of by vehement social and political movements, some of socialist inclinations while others of more populist leanings. However, as external shocks hit and balance-of-payments crises followed one upon another, these adjustments fueled growing discontent and opposition on the part of either popular sectors that demanded greater improvements in social conditions, or the elites, which saw their profit margins threatened by increased government regulation.
    [Show full text]
  • Populism of the Twenty-First Century” Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars Washington, D.C
    DRAFT—PLEASE CITE ONLY WITH PERMISSION Prepared for the conference “Populism of the Twenty-First Century” Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars Washington, D.C. October 8, 2009 Populism in Peru: From APRA to Ollanta Humala Cynthia McClintock George Washington University To one degree or another, in one form or another, populism has been not only recurrent in Peru since the 1920s, but almost constant. The persistence of populism in the country is not surprising. First, social and economic divides in Peru have been very deep, provoking intense resentments that politicians have galvanized to their advantage. The divides were deeper in Peru than in other Latin American nations because Peru was the home of one of the region’s two largest and most sophisticated indigenous civilizations and then one of Spain’s two viceroyalties; the Spanish conquest and colonial rule were especially traumatic. The divides were also deeper due to geography; in contrast to other Andean countries, Peru’s capital is on the coast, separated from the country’s indigenous peoples by some of the highest mountains of the Andes. Second, populism has persisted because, for a variety of reasons, liberal democracy has been perceived as not sufficiently successful in bridging Peru’s divides, and so frustrated Peruvians have turned to populist alternatives. Although the failures of Peru’s 1980-1990 liberal-democratic governments are the best-known, there is a long history of liberalism without social reform in Peru. The governments during the 1895-1914 “Aristocratic Republic,” of Manuel Prado (1939-1945 and 1958-1962), and Fernando Belaúnde (1963- 1968) were all elected governments (albeit with various degrees of restriction on the franchise and various promises of reform) that were perceived to be insufficiently committed to social reform.
    [Show full text]
  • The 1990S - a Lost Decade for the Brazilian NSI?*
    The 1990s - a lost decade for the Brazilian NSI?* Arlindo Villaschi Associate Professor of Economics, UFES (Federal University at Espírito Santo state ; Associate Researcher, RedeSist (Research Network on Local Productive and Innovative Systems) Rua Horácio Andrade de Carvalho 190 - 29.052-620 Vitória, Espírito Santo - Brasil PhoneFax: +55 27 3345-1404; [email protected]; [email protected] F I r s t D r a f t September, 2003 * - Prepared for The First Globelics Conference ‘Innovation Systems and Development Strategies for the Third Millennium in Rio de Janeiro, Brazil, 02-06 November, 2003 1. Introduction This paper deals with structural changes that took place in the Brazilian socio- economic formation throughout the 1990s and their impact on major elements of the Brazilian national system of innovation. Following a tradition which began with Freeman (1987){ XE "Freeman, C (1987), Technology policy and economic performance: lesson from Japan, London: Frances Pinter" } and Andersen and Lundvall (1988){ XE "Andersen, E and Lundvall, B-Å (1988), 'Small national systems of innovation facing technological revolutions: an analytical framework', in Freeman, C and Lundvall, B-Å, eds. (1988), Small countries facing the technological revolution, London: Pinter" } the major concern here is with interactions which take place amongst economic, social and political actors and which strength and/or limit their learning and searching capabilities in such a way that enhances and/or inhibits the development, diffusion, and use of innovations in a certain nation. Despite the new framework for these interactions at times of increasing relations at the world scale, the national dimension is highlighted here in order to capture the spatial-institutional reference for interactions geared towards learning processes which lead to innovation and enhances / inhibits both enterprises’ competitiveness and social capabilities.
    [Show full text]
  • Amaria F. Valdés, Coordinator of Tax Issues
    LATIN AMERICA ADVISOR A DAILY PUBLICATION OF THE DIALOGUE www.thedialogue.org Thursday, March 4, 2021 BOARD OF ADVISORS FEATURED Q&A TODAY’S NEWS Diego Arria Director, Columbus Group POLITICAL Devry Boughner Vorwerk Will Latin America Brazil Reports Chief Corporate Affairs Officer, Grubhub Second Straight Joyce Chang Global Head of Research, Levy New Taxes to Day of Record JPMorgan Chase & Co. Covid Deaths Paula Cifuentes Director of Economic & Fiscal Affairs, Cover Covid Costs? Brazil’s Health Ministry reported Latin America & Canada, 1,910 Covid-19 deaths, a record Philip Morris International total for the second consecutive Marlene Fernández day. Corporate Vice President for Page 2 Government Relations, Arcos Dorados (McDonald’s) Peter Hakim BUSINESS President Emeritus, Inter-American Dialogue Casino Sued Over Donna Hrinak Senior VP, Corporate Affairs, Beef Linked to Royal Caribbean Group Deforestation Jon E. Huenemann Council Member, Indigenous groups from Brazil and GLG Inc. Colombia filed suit against French James R. Jones retailer Casino over its sales of Chairman, Several countries in the region are debating tax reforms amid the economic downturns brought beef linked to deforestation in the Monarch Global Strategies by the Covid-19 pandemic. // File Photo: Argentine Government. Amazon. Craig A. Kelly Page 2 Senior Director, Americas Int’l Gov’t Relations, Exxon Mobil Economic downturns and gaps between the rich and the poor John Maisto that have been worsened by the Covid-19 pandemic have led POLITICAL Director, U.S. Education Finance Group to debate on tax reform proposals. In Latin America, coun- Press Groups Nicolás Mariscal Q tries including Argentina, Bolivia, Chile and Peru have either Demand Ortega Chairman, Grupo Marhnos implemented or are considering so-called “Robin Hood” taxes, or levies Stop Harassing Thomas F.
    [Show full text]
  • How (Not) to Lose a Decade
    Jeff Frieden How (not) to lose a decade Abstract Recovery from the Great Recession has been fraught with problems. The recovery has not been behaving like the aftermath of a typical cyclical recession, and this is because we are instead in the midst of an ongoing debt crisis. Debt crises are different, both economically and politically. Politically, debt crises lead to conflict over how the burden of adjustment will be distributed. And this conflict can seriously delay measures to alleviate the impact of the crisis – making everyone involved worse off. Theory and history suggest a variety of factors that make this sort of counter-productive conflict and delay more likely; and they also suggest possible ways to reduce both the conflict and the social cost of its consequences. The world has known a long and dismal array of lost decades, in which societies have stagnated economically, and often politically and socially as well. The sad catalogue goes back at least 200 years, and we are now adding to it. The decade past has already been lost to the advanced industrial world: whatever economic advances were realized between 2002 and 2007 were wiped out by the Great Recession that began at the end of 2007 and whose effects are still with us. Now we stand poised to lose another decade, as economic stagnation and political polarization have paralyzed the United States and Europe. In this context, it is worth asking what theory and history have to teach us about the causes of lost decades past – and how we can avoid joining them in the future.
    [Show full text]