British Financial Experience, 1790-1830 283

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

British Financial Experience, 1790-1830 283 BRITISH FINANCIAL EXPERIENCE 1790-1830 NORMAN J. SILBERLING HE monetary and financial events which attended brought down to 1837 in the History of Prices,1 with the Tthe military operations carried on by Great Britain assistance of Mr. M. L. Merac, who likewise derived and her continental allies against the armies of France, practically all of his figures from the Price Current. The between 1793 and 1815, have acquired at this time a table of prices as given in this volume includes the high special interest. The wars of the Napoleonic era pre- and low quotations at four periods within each year: sent, in their political and economic aspects, numerous (1) about the middle of January, (2) the last days of points of similarity to, as well as interesting points of March and first days of April, (3) about the middle of contrast with, the great war of the past five years. An July, and (4) about the middle of November. There examination of some of the financial experiences of are many gaps in the data, especially in the quotations England during and immediately following this earlier for the first and last periods during the earlier years. period may be useful, not only in setting forth historical This series was continued in the subsequent volumes of parallels and contrasts, but in furnishing valuable the History of Prices. In the early sixties, Professor lessons for our own time. Jevons conceived the plan of casting these materials It is proposed to consider in this paper, certain as- into the form of an index number, in order that the pects of the financial history of England for a period general trend of prices might be ascertained. His re- beginning just before the war and extending to the year sults first appeared in the Journal of the Royal Statistical 2 1830, thus including the interval of recovery and return Society for June, 1865. Jevons utilized practically all of to normal conditions. The object of this study is Tooke's quotations, as given in the History of Prices, primarily to bring together statistical data concerning and supplemented these by a very few others from dif- currency, prices, the rate of interest, etc., which are ferent sources. No attempt was made to average the available without elaborate research and special cal- four sets of quotations for each article each year, and culation. It is not intended to enter at any length into Jevons used merely those for the second quarter, for a causal inquiry or reasoned interpretation of the events which the figures were on the whole most complete. disclosed, but rather to present the materials in clear This fact is of importance in the proper use and under- and usable form, enabling comparison to be made be- standing of his results. Taking the prices of 1782 as tween the various sets of data and laying a basis for a base, Jevons constructed a series of index numbers, further investigation. using the geometric mean of the individual ratios to obtain the final indices. No weights were given to the COMMODITY PRICES various commodities except by the inclusion in some Statistics of price movements form a natural starting instances of several varieties of the same article, as in point for an inquiry of this sort. For the well-known the case of cotton, coffee, and sugar. Jevons also ob- index numbers of W. Stanley Jevons, for the years from tained index numbers for various groups of commodities 1782 until 1865, we are primarily indebted to Mr. such as " corn " (six cereals), metals, fibres, oriental Thomas Tooke, an English merchant in the Russian and tropical produce. The commodities entering into trade whose career extended through and beyond the his general index number, and the composition of the war period. Tooke, an earnest student of currency and special groups for the limited period 1782-1830 are prices, published in 1823 a work entitled Thoughts and enumerated in Table 1. An examination of this list Details on the High and Low Prices of the Last Thirty Years, later expanded into the first two volumes of his TABLE 1. —COMMODITIES REPRESENTED IN more widely familiar History of Prices. In his Thoughts JEVONS' INDEX NUMBERS FROM and Details Tooke included a table, extending from 1782 1782 TO 1830 to 1822, of the prices of seventy-eight raw materials and CORN foodstuffs (including different varieties) which were fur- Wheat, Gazette average nished by a friend, Mr. A. Hinrichs. The principal Barley, " Oats, source was Prince's Price Current established in 1782, Rye, the leading publication of its kind in that day. Only Beans, « about forty of these quotations were later copied and Peas, " " from 1792. 1 Vol. 2, Appendix, 1838. MEAT 2 Reprinted in his Investigations in Currency and Finance, 1884, Mutton, St. Thomas' Hospital average. pp. 119 f. In the reference above to the Journal of the Royal Statistical Society I have used the present name of the publication. Previous to Beef, St. Thomas' Hospital average. 1887 it was called the Statistical Journal. Irish mess beef, St. Thomas' Hospital average. [282] Digitized for FRASER http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/ Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis BRITISH FINANCIAL EXPERIENCE, 1790-1830 283 FIBRES base year, 1782; and for eight commodities, later than Cotton, Upland, 1793 Tooke until 1801; after 1801 1790, the year from which I shall hereafter compare " Pernam, 1788 from Journal of the Royal Statis- Jevons' series with various other series.1 All the articles " Surat, 1790 tical Society, December 1862. in Jevons' list are foods and raw materials, but they " Surinam, 1782-1844; Demerara after 1820. include a fair proportion of the important articles of Wool, Southdown, average 1784-1845, McCulloch's Dic- tionary. this nature for the period concerned. Table 2 contains Silk, China, raw. Flax, St. Petersburg. TABLE 2. —JEVONS' INDEX NUMBERS OF PRICES TIMBER FOR FORTY COMMODITIES AND FOR CEREALS, Memel fir, in bond. METALS, AND ORIENTAL PRODUCE, 1782-1830.* Quebec yellow pine, 1784-1806, 1820-39, 1813-21, McCulloch's Dictionary. Year (usually the Forty Oriental second quarter) commodities Cereals Metals produce OILS 1782 IOO IOO IOO IOO Gallipoli, in bond. 1783 I27 IOO IOI Fish. 1784 93 Il6 9O 94 FODDER 1785 90 IO4 89 93 Hay, Gentlemen's Magazine^ 1798. 1786 85 IO5 95 82 Clover, Gentlemen's Magazine, 1803. 1787 87 IO2 93 9i Straw, Gentlemen's Magazine, 1798. 1788 87 99 96 9i 1789 85 I05 93 85 METALS I79O 87 117 92 80 Copper, tough cakes. 1791 89 112 IOO 89 Lead, British pigs. I792 93 no 108 107 Tin, English bars. 1793 99 129 113 96 Pig. 1794 98 140 in 84 Iron Wrought, Russia. 1795 117 168 108 96 Bars, Welsh. 1796 125 I53 117 DYES 1797 no 112 123 85 Logwood, Jamaica. 1798 118 116 122 107 Indigo superior and inferior, East India. 1799 130 IS9 127 IOO Cochineal, Spanish. l8oo 141 252 *35 80 I8OI 153 253 152 87 TROPICAL FOODS, ETC.* I8O2 119 140 148 80 Sugar, Muscovados, Tooke 1782-1805, Gazette average after 1803 128 127 148 76 1804 122 138 1800. 151 73 " Havannah, for exportation, after 1801. I805 136 182 166 81 1806 *33 163 i74 81 ng0U Tea ^° - 1807 hyson 132 173 156 75 Coffee, superior British plantation. 1808 149 201 160 86 " inferior British plantation. 1809 161 211 164 88 " St. Domingo, for exportation, after 1807. l8lO 164 203 165 96 Rum, Jamaica, l8ll 147 182 161 81 81 Rice, Carolina. I8l2 148 272 i45 Pepper, East India black. 1813 149 256 144 88 Cinnamon, first quality, in bond. 1814 153 165 151 121 Tobacco, Virginia, in bond. I8I5 132 137 138 98 I8l6 109 148 115 82 1817 120 198 83 MISCELLANEOUS no I8l8 135 209 122 93 Butter, Waterford, etc. 1819 117 186 119 78 Tallow, St. Petersburg. I82O 106 152 109 67 Ashes, barilla, Carthagena in bond. I82I 116 101 68 u 94 pearl; Danzig or Russia. l822 88 92 IOO 67 Hemp, St. Petersburg, clean. 1823 89 125 107 65 Tar, Stockholm. 1824 88 147 108 61 * Another group of " oriental produce " for which a separate 1825 103 i57 123 80 series was calculated includes sugar, tea, pepper, cinnamon, indigo, 1826 90 152 III 56 China silk, and Surat cotton. 1827 90 155 103 58 1828 81 136 95 53 discloses an aggregate of fifty-two items — counting 1829 79 135 89 5i different varieties of the same article — and of about 183O 81 138 81 52 forty distinct commodities. For several articles the first quotations obtained were for years later than the * Based on currency prices relative to those in 1782. Jevons' data for various groups of articles are given for the years 1801-20 inclusive, 1 The years in which the quotations begin are as follows: 1792, in terms of gold; these figures were therefore reconverted to paper by 1793, 1798, 1801, 1803, 1806, and 1808. the index of the price of gold which Jevons used. Digitized for FRASER http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/ Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 284 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMIC STATISTICS CHART 1. —JEVONS' INDEX NUMBERS OF PRICES FOR FORTY COMMODITIES, FOR CORN, FOR METALS, AND FOR ORIENTAL PRODUCE, 1782-1830 (DATA GIVEN IN TABLE 2) (a) FORTY COMMODITIES. UNITS OP ONE PER CENT. (C) METALS. UNITS OF ONE PER CENT. (b) CORN (CEREALS). " « « " (d) ORIENTAL PRODUCE. " « " « * SERIOUSLY DEFICIENT HARVESTS. the index numbers derived for all articles, and for those with the exception of beans, peas, mutton, Georgia of three important special groups, namely, " corn," cotton, fodder, and wrought iron; and in addition it metals, and oriental produce.
Recommended publications
  • Anwar Shaikh and Isabella Weber the U.S.-China Trade Balance and The
    Anwar Shaikh and Isabella Weber The U.S.-China Trade Balance and the Theory of Free Trade: Debunking the Currency Manipulation Argument May 2018; revised December 2019 Working Paper 05/2018 Department of Economics The New School for Social Research The views expressed herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the New School for Social Research. © 2018 by Anwar Shaikh and Isabella Weber. All rights reserved. Short sections of text may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit is given to the source. Anwar Shaikh The New School for Social Research Department of Economics Isabella Weber* University of Massachusetts Amherst Department of Economics The U.S.-China Trade Imbalance and the Theory of Free Trade: Debunking the Currency Manipulation Argument Abstract The U.S.-China trade imbalance is commonly attributed to a Chinese policy of currency manipulation. However, empirical studies failed to reach consensus on the degree and kind of RMB misalignment. We argue that this is not a consequence of poor measurement but of theory. At the most abstract level the conventional principle of comparative cost advantage suggests real exchange rates will adjust so as to balance trade. Therefore, the persistence of trade imbalances tends to be interpreted as arising from currency manipulation facilitated by foreign exchange interventions. By way of contrast, the absolute cost theory provided by Smith and Harrod theory explains trade imbalances as the outcome of free trade among nations that have unequal real costs. We argue that a disparity in real costs is the root cause of the U.S.-China trade imbalance.
    [Show full text]
  • The Unsolved Problem of Economic Crisis As a Turning Point of Marxs
    The Unsolved Problem of Economic Crisis as a Turning Point of Marx’s Critique of Political Economy, 1844-45 Timm Graßmann Abstract: With the continuing publication of the complete works of Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels (Marx-Engels-Gesamtausgabe, MEGA), a bulk of new material concerning Marx’s studies of economic crises has been made available-with further releases expected to follow. These publications have revealed Marx’s enormous efforts to examine in detail every economic cri- sis through which he lived. The most prominent examples are the three Books of Crisis( Kris- enhefte), which he compiled in 1857-58 amidst the first truly global economic crisis. This paper sets out to, first, provide an overview of new MEGA-texts regarding Marx’s studies of contemporaneous 19th century revulsions. In the main part, a closer look will be taken at the origin of Marx’s crisis studies in the 1840s. A comparison between his notes on James Mill’s Elements of Political Economy, written in the Paris Notebooks( 1844), and his excerpts from John Stuart Mill’s Essays on Some Unsettled Questions of Political Economy, taken in his Manchester Notebooks( 1845), reveals Marx’s changing stance on classical political econo- my’s ‘general glut controversy,’ i.e., the debate over the( im)possibility of overproduction cri- ses in commodity-producing societies. In between his stays in Paris and Manchester, Marx took extensive notes on the works of Simonde de Sismondi in his Brussels Notebooks (1845), which played a major role in his break from anthropological-essentialist thinking. JEL classification numbers: B 00, B 51, E 32.
    [Show full text]
  • The Bank of England and the Bank Act of 1844 Laurent Le Maux
    Central banking and finance: the Bank of England and the Bank Act of 1844 Laurent Le Maux To cite this version: Laurent Le Maux. Central banking and finance: the Bank of England and the Bank Act of1844. Revue Economique, Presses de Sciences Po, 2018. hal-02854521 HAL Id: hal-02854521 https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-02854521 Submitted on 8 Jun 2020 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. Central banking and finance: the Bank of England and the Bank Act of 1844 Laurent LE MAUX* May 2020 The literature on the Bank of England Charter Act of 1844 commonly adopts the interpretation that it was a crucial step in the construction of central banking in Great Britain and the analytical framework that contrasts rules and discretion. Through examination of the monetary writings of the period and the Bank of England’s interest rate policy, and also through the systematic analysis of the financial aspect of the 1844 Act, the paper shows that such an interpretation remains fragile. Hence the present paper rests on the articulation between monetary history and the history of economic analysis and also on the institutional approach to money and banking so as to assess the consequences of the 1844 Act for the liquidity market and the relations between the central bank and finance.
    [Show full text]
  • A Brief Overview of Thomas Tooke's Monetary Theory
    Ayse Ozden Birkan, Int.J.Eco.Res, 2016, v7i1, 28 - 35 ISSN: 2229-6158 A BRIEF OVERVIEW OF THOMAS TOOKE’S MONETARY THEORY Ayse Ozden Birkan , 1Department of Economics, Yasar University, Izmir, Turkey Abstract The arguments developed by The British scholar Thomas Tooke in the context of the Banking School- Currency School debates over the Bank Act of 1844 constitute the starting point for many important threads of discussion in contemporary monetary and macroeconomic theory. The ideas Tooke developed in his important pamphlet An Inquiry into the Currency Principle and his six volume A History of Prices and the State of Circulation have been quite influencial. In particular, his discussions on the nature of credit money, the endogeneity of money supply, the interest rate as a cost component, the monetray transmission mechanism, the speed of balance of payments adjustments and free banking have all been recurrent themes in the literature. In this context this paper aims to provide a brief overview of Tooke’s original ideas, which have somewhat been underappreciated. Keywords: Thomas Tooke, monetary theory, Banking School JEL Codes: B1, E3, E4, E5 1. INTRODUCTION Thomas Tooke (1774-1858) who is considered to be one of the prominent contributors to the monetary theory and policy discussions of the 19th century England, was a successful businessman and a respectable public figure as well as one of the founders of the Political Economy Club alongside Ricardo, Malthus and James Mill. In addition to writing many policy briefs, pamphlets, letters and books, he gave evidence before the parliement on several occasions regarding the gold standard, free trade, Corn Laws and the Bank Charter Act.
    [Show full text]
  • Currency School Versus Banking School: an Ongoing Confrontation
    Charles Goodhart and Meinhard Jensen Currency School versus Banking School: an ongoing confrontation Article (Accepted version) (Refereed) Original citation: Goodhart, Charles and Jensen, Meinhard (2015) Currency School versus Banking School: an ongoing confrontation. Economic Thought, 4 (2). pp. 20-31. ISSN 2049-3509 © 2015 The Authors. This version available at: http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/64068/ Available in LSE Research Online: October 2015 LSE has developed LSE Research Online so that users may access research output of the School. Copyright © and Moral Rights for the papers on this site are retained by the individual authors and/or other copyright owners. Users may download and/or print one copy of any article(s) in LSE Research Online to facilitate their private study or for non-commercial research. You may not engage in further distribution of the material or use it for any profit-making activities or any commercial gain. You may freely distribute the URL (http://eprints.lse.ac.uk) of the LSE Research Online website. This document is the author’s final accepted version of the journal article. There may be differences between this version and the published version. You are advised to consult the publisher’s version if you wish to cite from it. Currency School versus Banking School: An ongoing confrontation C. Goodhart1 and M. Jensen Financial Markets Group Department of Economics London School of Economics University of Copenhagen [email protected] [email protected] ABSTRACT The Chicago Plan and Laina’s full-reserve banking proposal are themselves extensions of Ricardo’s earlier proposal for separating money creation from bank intermediation, as incorporated in the 1844 Bank Act.
    [Show full text]
  • On the Transformation in Tooke's Monetary Thought
    HETSA Conference 14-17 July 2009 1 On the Transformation in Tooke’s Monetary Thought Matthew Smith University of Sydney 1. Introduction Among those commentators who have closely studied Thomas Tooke‟s (1774-1858) political economy there is general agreement that there was a transformation in his monetary thought after 1838, from an „orthodox‟ quantity theory position to an anti- quantity theory position embodied within his novel banking school theory. 1 For this reason Tooke‟s monetary thought is considered to consist of two main phases in its evolution. The first is the pre-banking school phase, covering Tooke‟s writings and parliamentary evidence from 1819 to 1838 when, broadly speaking, his monetary thought remained within the bounds of the quantity theory approach orthodox among most classical economists of the early nineteenth century. The second phase comprises Tooke‟s writings and parliamentary evidence from 1840 to 1857 when he developed his banking school theory as an alternative to the classical‟s quantity theory approach. The only accounts in the secondary literature of this transformation are provided by T.E. Gregory in his one-hundred-and-twenty page „Introduction‟ to the 1928 reprint of Tooke‟s History of Prices and by Arnon in his book, Thomas Tooke: Pioneer of Monetary Theory (1991). In our view neither of these authors provides a satisfactory explanation for Tooke‟s transformation, mainly because their accounts of his monetary thought, both of his pre-banking school position and banking school theory, is incomplete. After all, the essential question here is what did Tooke transform from and to what did he transform into? The question therefore resolves around both an interpretation of Tooke‟s pre-banking school monetary thought as well as his banking school thought.
    [Show full text]
  • Emp, An& Juapoleon
    gmertca, , ?|emp, an& JUapoleon American Trade with Russia and the Baltic, 1783-1812 BY ALFRED W. CROSBY, JR. Ohio Sttite University Press $6.50 America, IXuaata, S>emp, anb Napoleon American Trade with Russia and the Baltic, 1783-1812 BY ALFRED W. CROSBY, JR. On the twelfth of June, 1783, a ship of 500 tons sailed into the Russian harbor of Riga and dropped anchor. As the tide pivoted her around her mooring, the Russians on the waterfront could see clearly the banner that she flew — a strange device of white stars on a blue ground and horizontal red and white stripes. Russo-American trade had irrevocably begun. Merchants — Muscovite and Yankee — had met and politely sounded the depths of each other's purses. And they had agreed to do business. In the years that followed, until 1812, the young American nation became economically tied to Russia to a degree that has not, perhaps, been realized to date. The United States desperately needed Russian hemp and linen; the American sailor of the early nineteenth century — who was possibly the most important individual in the American economy — thought twice before he took any craft not equipped with Russian rigging, cables, and sails beyond the harbor mouth. To an appreciable extent, the Amer­ ican economy survived and prospered because it had access to the unending labor and rough skill of the Russian peasant. The United States found, when it emerged as a free (Continued on back flap) America, Hossia, fiemp, and Bapolcon American Trade with Russia and the Baltic, 1783-1812 America, llussia, iicmp, and Bapolton American Trade with Russia and the Baltic, 1783-1811 BY ALFRED W.
    [Show full text]
  • The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo
    THE WORKS AND CORRESPONDENCE OF DAVID RICARDO volume xi plan of the edition volume I. Principles of Political Economy and Taxation II. Notes on Malthus III. Pamphlets and Papers, 1809–1811 IV. Pamphlets and Papers, 1815–1823 V. Speeches and Evidence VI. Letters, 1810–1815 VII. Letters, 1816–1818 VIII. Letters, 1819–June 1821 IX. Letters, July 1821–1823 X. Biographical Miscellany XI. General Index THE WORKS AND CORRESPONDENCE OF David Ricardo Edited by Piero Sraffa with the Collaboration of M. H. Dobb 8 volume xi General Index liberty fund indianapolis This book is published by Liberty Fund, Inc., a foundation established to encourage study of the ideal of a society of free and responsible individuals. The cuneiform inscription that serves as our logo and as the design motif for our endpapers is the earliest-known written appearance of the word “freedom” (amagi), or “liberty.” It is taken from a clay document written about 2300 b.c. in the Sumerian city-state of Lagash. First published by Cambridge University Press in 1951. ᭧ 1951, 1952, 1955, 1973 by the Royal Economic Society Typographical design ᭧ 2004 by Liberty Fund, Inc. This edition of The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo is published by Liberty Fund, Inc., under license from the Royal Economic Society. 10 09 08 07 06 05 04 p 54321 All rights reserved Printed in the United States of America Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Ricardo, David, 1772–1823. [Works. 2004] The works and correspondence of David Ricardo / edited by Piero Sraffa; with the collaboration of M. H.
    [Show full text]
  • Forms of Money and Laws of Monetary Circulation: on the Origin of Controversies in Modern Credit Theory1
    Forms of Money and Laws of Monetary Circulation: On the origin of controversies in modern Credit Theory1 Piruz Alemi Salim Khan February, 1998 Working paper - not to be quoted without consent of the authors. Abstract The theoretical debates of the Banking and the Currency school is a powerful framework for the study of the dynamics of capitalist production. The origin of these debates cuts across both financial and real sectors and continues to permeate through present monetary controversies. Their debates is applied to a wide range of official statistics and empirically demonstrated. It is shown that Thomas Tooke’s classification of different forms of money are crucial and the different functions of money have different explanatory powers for bank reserves, price fluctuations and credit policies. We locate the controversy in the context of statistical data from the resumption of Bank of England specie payment (Gold convertibility) in 1821, to the passing of the Bank act of 1844-45, up to the financial crises of 1866. A synthesize of these seemingly contradictory theories traces its implications for post Keynsian, Monetarist and Marxian economics with applications for Government, Banking and Corporate finance / credit policies. We conclude: 1). Break down of monetary categories and understanding their different functions and modus operandi is absolutely crucial for analysis of any financial crises. We find that bills of exchange and bank notes are not associated yet the constituent parts of bills of exchange do affect bank note circulation as well as commodity prices. The relation of these two categories was a major point of contention. This result highlights the short coming of any monetary aggregate analysis 2).
    [Show full text]
  • Rival Notions of Money
    RIVAL NOTIONS OF MONEY Thomas M. Humphrey Introduction Bullionist Controversy (1797-1821) The rise of Milton Friedman’s version of mone- Monetarism did not begin with Friedman nor did tarism in the 1960s and early 1970s provoked an antimonetarism originate with Kaldor or Keynes’s antimonetarist backlash culminating in the late General Theory. Those doctrines clashed as early as Nicholas Kaldor’s The Scourge of Monetarism (1982). the Bank Restriction period of the Napoleonic wars Friedman stressed the ideas of exogenous (i.e., when the Bank of England suspended the converti- central bank determined) money, money-to-price bility of its notes into gold at a fixed price on de- causality, inflation as a monetary phenomenon, and mand. The suspension of specie payments and the controllability of money through the high-powered resulting move to inconvertible paper was followed monetary base. He traced a chain of causation run- by a rise in the paper pound price of commodities, ning from open market operations to bank reserves gold bullion, and foreign currencies. A debate be- to the nominal stock of money and thence to aggre- tween strict bullionists, moderate bullionists, and an- gate spending, nominal income, and prices. tibullionists then arose over the question: Was there By contrast, Kaldor postulated the opposite notions inflation in England and if so what was its cause? of endogenous (i.e., demand-determined) money, reverse causality, and inflation as a cost-push or Strict Bullionists: the classical monetarists supply-shock phenomenon. He denied the possibility Led by David Ricardo, the strict bullionists argued of base control given the central bank’s responsi- that inflation did exist, that overissue of banknotes bility to guarantee bank liquidity and the financial by the Bank of England was the cause, and that the sector’s ability to engineer changes in the turnover premium on gold (the difference between the market velocity of money via the manufacture of money and official mint price of gold in terms of paper substitutes.
    [Show full text]
  • Abstract David Ricardo's Macroeconomics
    ABSTRACT DAVID RICARDO'S MACROECONOMICS Doctor of Philosophy, 1998 Timothy Sean Davis Graduate Department of Economics University of Toronto This thesis confronts the tendency in the literature of the history of economic thought to criticize Ricardo's macroeconomics, specifically his knowledge of contemporary events, his analysis of postwar crises, and his monetary and fiscal policies. To this end, the historical introduction in Chapters One and Two is critical, for it dispenses with the traditional view that the postwar decade was a period of chronic depression caused by underconsumption and, to a lesser extent, by monetary contraction associated with the 1819 Resumption Act. Chapter Three completes the foundation of our study by showing that Ricardo was well informed regarding Britain's economic and political situation. That he used this knowledge as a basis for his analysis of contemporary events is established in Chapters Four and Five, which chapters also refute the view that his treatment of postwar crises was merely a rationalization of the crude quantity theory and the strict law of markets in the face of overwhelmingly contradictory evidence. Chapter Six argues the merits of his monetary policies, particularly his insistence on the gold standard as a means to curb abuses by the Bank of England and the Government, which together were responsible for gross mismanagement of the currency. The chapter fiuther examines whether Ricardo accepted the "Treasury View" of fiscal policy, and whether his position implies adherence to a doctrinaire version of Say's Law. My conclusions differ from those of authors critical of Ricardo largely because I have adopted a methodological approach to the history of economic thought that differs from theirs.
    [Show full text]
  • The Classical Economic Stage
    © Copyright, Princeton University Press. No part of this book may be distributed, posted, or reproduced in any form by digital or mechanical means without prior written permission of the publisher. CHAPTER ONE The Classical Economic Stage I. The Period of Classical Economics In any detailed discussion of a particular body of ideas, it is perhaps helpful to begin by indicating to the reader the period during which those ideas were of importance. There can be little doubt that the heyday of Classical economics was during the years 1800–1850. Delineation of the period during which Classical economics developed as a body of thought, came to be the ruling approach to economics, ultimately experienced a measure of stag- nation and decay, and was finally supplanted by the young and vigorous development of neo-Classical economics in the “Marginal Revolution,” is however a good deal less easy. At one end it is usual to date the era of Classical economics as begin- ning in 1776, with the publication of Adam Smith’s mighty Wealth of Nations. Such an approach has a strong prima facie appeal, but closer ex- amination raises doubts about it. On the one hand Classical economics owed a great deal to David Hume in certain critical areas, especially that of monetary theory. The relevant part of Hume’s Essays was published in 1752; and it is therefore doubtful if too much weight can be placed on the year 1776. Indeed the influence of Hume upon Smith cannot be ignored; they were close friends, and Hume was appointed by Smith to be his lit- erary executor.1 In addition the work of Adam Smith himself did not sud- denly spring from nothing in 1776.
    [Show full text]