Stochastic Calculus 1

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Stochastic Calculus 1 Contents 3 Stochastic Calculus 1 3.1 References...................................... .............. 1 3.2 GaussianWhiteNoise .............................. ............... 2 3.3 StochasticIntegration . .................. 3 3.3.1 Langevinequationindifferentialform . ................... 3 3.3.2 Defining the stochastic integral . ................. 3 3.3.3 Summary of properties of the Itˆostochastic integral ....................... 5 3.3.4 Fokker-Planckequation. ............... 7 3.4 Stochastic Differential Equations . ...................... 7 3.4.1 Itˆochangeofvariablesformula . ................. 8 3.4.2 Solvabilitybychangeofvariables . .................. 9 3.4.3 MulticomponentSDE... .... ... .... .... .... ... .... ............ 9 3.4.4 SDEs with general α expressed as ItˆoSDEs (α =0)........................ 10 3.4.5 ChangeofvariablesintheStratonovichcase . .................... 11 3.5 Applications.................................... ............... 12 3.5.1 Ornstein-Uhlenbeckredux . ............... 12 3.5.2 Time-dependence ............................... ............ 13 3.5.3 Colorednoise .................................. ........... 13 3.5.4 Remarksaboutfinancialmarkets . ............... 15 i ii CONTENTS Chapter 3 Stochastic Calculus 3.1 References – C. Gardiner, Stochastic Methods (4th edition, Springer-Verlag, 2010) Very clear and complete text on stochastic methods, with many applications. – Z. Schuss, Theory and Applications of Stochastic Processes (Springer-Verlag, 2010) In-depth discussion of continuous path stochastic processes and connections to partial differential equations. – R. Mahnke, J. Kaupuzs,ˇ and I. Lubashevsky, Physics of Stochastic Processes (Wiley, 2009) Introductory sections are sometimes overly formal, but a good selection of topics. – H. Riecke, Introduction to Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Differential Equations (unpublished, 2010) Good set of lecture notes, often following Gardiner. Available online at: http://people.esam.northwestern.edu/~riecke/Vorlesungen/442/Notes/notes 442.pdf – J. L. McCauley, Dynamics of Markets (2nd edition, Cambridge, 2009) A physics-friendly discussion of stochastic market dynamics. Crisp and readable. Despite this being the second edition, there are alas a great many typographical errors. 1 2 CHAPTER 3. STOCHASTIC CALCULUS 3.2 Gaussian White Noise Consider a generalized Langevin equation of the form du = f(u,t)+ g(u,t) η(t) , (3.1) dt where η(t) is a Gaussian random function with zero mean and η(t) η(t′) = φ(t t′) . (3.2) − The spectral function of the noise is given by the Fourier transform, ∞ ˆ −iωs 1 2 φ(ω)= ds φ(s) e = lim ηˆT (ω) , (3.3) T →∞ T Z −∞ D E using the notation of 2.6.3. When φ(s) = Γδ(s) , we have φˆ(ω) = Γ , i.e. independent of frequency. This is the § case of Gaussian white noise. When φˆ(ω) has a nontrivial dependence on frequency, the noise is said to be colored. Gaussian white noise has an infinite variance φ(0), which leads to problems. In particular, the derivative u˙ strictly speaking does not exist because the function η(t) is not continuous. As an example of the sort of problem this presents, consider the differential equation u˙(t) = η(t) u(t). Let’s integrate this over a time period ∆t from tj to tj+1, where tj = j ∆t. We then have u(tj+1)= 1+ η(tj )∆t u(tj ). Thus, we find u(t )= 1+ η(t ) ∆t 1+ η(t ) ∆t u(t ) . (3.4) N N−1 ··· 0 0 Now let’s compute the average u(t ) . Since η(t ) is uncorrelated with η(t ) for all k = j, we can take the average N j k 6 of each of the terms individually, and since η(t ) has zero mean, we conclude that u(t ) = u(t ). On average, j N 0 there is no drift. Now let’s take a continuum limit of the above result, which is to say ∆t 0 with N∆t finite. Setting t = 0 and → 0 tN = t, we have t u(t)= u(0) exp ds η(s) , (3.5) Z0 and for Gaussian η(s) we have t t u(t) = u(0) exp 1 ds ds′ η(s) η(s′) = u(0) eΓ t/2 . (3.6) 2 Z Z 0 0 In the continuum expression, we find there isnoise-induced drift. The continuum limit of our discrete calculation has failed to match the continuum results. Clearly we have a problem that we must resolve. The origin of the problem is the aforementioned infinite variance of η(t). This means that the Langevin equation 3.1 is not well- defined, and in order to get a definite answer we must provide a prescription regarding how it is to be integrated1. 1We will see that Eqn. 3.4 corresponds to the Itˆo prescription and Eqn. 3.5 to the Stratonovich prescription. 3.3. STOCHASTIC INTEGRATION 3 3.3 Stochastic Integration 3.3.1 Langevin equation in differential form We can make sense of Eqn. 3.1 by writing it in differential form, du = f(u,t) dt + g(u,t) dW (t) , (3.7) where t W (t)= ds η(s) . (3.8) Z0 This is because W (t) is described by a Wiener process, for which the sample paths are continuous with probability unity. We shall henceforth take Γ 1, in which case W (t) is Gaussianly distributed with W (t) =0 and ≡ h i W (t) W (t′) = min(t,t′) . (3.9) The solution to Eqn. 3.7 is formally t t u(t)= u(0) + ds f u(s),s + dW (s) g u(s),s . (3.10) Z Z 0 0 Note that Eqn. 3.9 implies d dW (t) dW (t′) W (t) W (t′) = Θ(t t′) = η(t) η(t′) = δ(t t′) . (3.11) dt′ − ⇒ dt dt′ − 3.3.2 Defining the stochastic integral Let F (t) be an arbitrary function of time, and let t be a discretization of the interval [0,t] with j 0,...,N . { j } ∈ { } The simplest example to consider is tj = j ∆t where ∆t = t/N. Consider the quantity N−1 S (α)= (1 α) F (t )+ α F (t ) W (t ) W (t ) , (3.12) N − j j+1 j+1 − j j=0 X h ih i where α [0, 1]. Note that the first term in brackets on the RHS can be approximated as ∈ F (τ )=(1 α) F (t )+ α F (t ) , (3.13) j − j j+1 where τ (1 α) t + αt [t ,t ]. To abbreviate notation, we will write F (t )= F , W (t )= W , etc. We j ≡ − j j+1 ∈ j j+1 j j j j may take t 0 and W 0. The quantities ∆W W W are independently and Gaussianly distributed with 0 ≡ 0 ≡ j ≡ j+1 − j zero mean for each j. This means ∆Wj =0 and 2 ∆Wj ∆Wk = (∆Wj ) δjk = ∆tj δjk , (3.14) where ∆t t t . Wick’s theorem then tells us j ≡ j+1 − j ∆Wj ∆Wk ∆Wl ∆Wm = ∆Wj ∆Wk ∆Wl ∆Wm + ∆Wj ∆Wl ∆Wk ∆Wm + ∆Wj ∆Wm ∆Wk ∆Wl = ∆tj ∆tl δjk δ lm + ∆tj ∆tk δjl δkm + ∆tj ∆ tk δjm δkl . (3.15) 4 CHAPTER 3. STOCHASTIC CALCULUS 2 4 2 EXERCISE: Show that WN = t and WN =3t . The expression in Eqn. 3.12 would converge to the integral t S = dW (s) F (s) (3.16) Z0 independent of α were it not for the fact that ∆W /∆t has infinite variance in the limit N . Instead, we will j j → ∞ find that S (α) in general depends on the value of α. For example, the Itˆointegral is defined as the N limit N → ∞ of S (α) with α =0, whereas the Stratonovich integral is defined as the N limit of S (α) with α = 1 . N → ∞ N 2 We now define the stochastic integral t N−1 dW (s) F (s) ms lim (1 α) F (tj )+ α F (tj+1) W (tj+1) W (tj ) , (3.17) α ≡ −N→∞ − − Z j=0 0 X h ih i where ms-lim stands for mean square limit. We say that a sequence SN converges to S in the mean square if lim (S S)2 =0. Consider, for example, the sequence S = N−1(∆W )2. We now take averages, using N→∞ N − N j=0 j (∆W )2 = t t ∆t . Clearly S = S = t. We also have j j+1 − j ≡ j h N i P N−1 N−1 2t2 S2 = (∆W )2 (∆W )2 = (N 2 +2N)(∆t)2 = t2 + , (3.18) N j k N j=0 k=0 X X where we have used Eqn. 3.15. Thus, (S S)2 =2t2/N 0 in the N limit. So S converges to t in the N − → → ∞ N mean square. Next, consider the case where F (t)= W (t). We find N−1 N−1 S (α)= (1 α) W (t )+ α W (t ) W (t ) W (t ) = W + α ∆W ∆W N − j j+1 j+1 − j j j j j=0 j=0 X h ih i X (3.19) N−1 N−1 2 2 2 = 1 W + ∆W W 2 + (2α 1) ∆W = 1 W 2 + (α 1 ) ∆W . 2 j j − j − j 2 N − 2 j j=0 j=0 X h i X Taking the average, N−1 S (α) = 1 t + (α 1 ) (t t )= α t . (3.20) N 2 N − 2 j+1 − j j=0 X Does S converge to S = αt in the mean square? Let’s define Q N−1(∆W )2, which is the sequence we N h N i N ≡ j=0 j analyzed previously. Then S = 1 W 2 + (α 1 ) Q . We then have N 2 N − 2 N P S2 = 1 W 4 + (α 1 ) W 2 Q + (α 1 )2 Q2 , (3.21) N 4 N − 2 N N − 2 N with N−1 N−1 N−1 N−1 4 2 2 WN = ∆Wj ∆Wk ∆Wl ∆Wm =3N (∆t) j=0 k=0 l=0 m=0 X X X X N−1 N−1 N−1 2 2 2 2 WN QN = ∆Wj ∆Wk (∆Wl) = (N +2N)(∆t) (3.22) j=0 k=0 l=0 X X X N−1 N−1 2 2 2 2 2 QN = (∆Wj ) (∆Wk) = (N +2N)(∆t) .
Recommended publications
  • Stochastic Differential Equations with Applications
    Stochastic Differential Equations with Applications December 4, 2012 2 Contents 1 Stochastic Differential Equations 7 1.1 Introduction . 7 1.1.1 Meaning of Stochastic Differential Equations . 8 1.2 Some applications of SDEs . 10 1.2.1 Asset prices . 10 1.2.2 Population modelling . 10 1.2.3 Multi-species models . 11 2 Continuous Random Variables 13 2.1 The probability density function . 13 2.1.1 Change of independent deviates . 13 2.1.2 Moments of a distribution . 13 2.2 Ubiquitous probability density functions in continuous finance . 14 2.2.1 Normal distribution . 14 2.2.2 Log-normal distribution . 14 2.2.3 Gamma distribution . 14 2.3 Limit Theorems . 15 2.3.1 The central limit results . 17 2.4 The Wiener process . 17 2.4.1 Covariance . 18 2.4.2 Derivative of a Wiener process . 18 2.4.3 Definitions . 18 3 Review of Integration 21 3 4 CONTENTS 3.1 Bounded Variation . 21 3.2 Riemann integration . 23 3.3 Riemann-Stieltjes integration . 24 3.4 Stochastic integration of deterministic functions . 25 4 The Ito and Stratonovich Integrals 27 4.1 A simple stochastic differential equation . 27 4.1.1 Motivation for Ito integral . 28 4.2 Stochastic integrals . 29 4.3 The Ito integral . 31 4.3.1 Application . 33 4.4 The Stratonovich integral . 33 4.4.1 Relationship between the Ito and Stratonovich integrals . 35 4.4.2 Stratonovich integration conforms to the classical rules of integration . 37 4.5 Stratonovich representation on an SDE . 38 5 Differentiation of functions of stochastic variables 41 5.1 Ito's Lemma .
    [Show full text]
  • Chaotic Decompositions in Z2-Graded Quantum Stochastic Calculus
    QUANTUM PROBABILITY BANACH CENTER PUBLICATIONS, VOLUME 43 INSTITUTE OF MATHEMATICS POLISH ACADEMY OF SCIENCES WARSZAWA 1998 CHAOTIC DECOMPOSITIONS IN Z2-GRADED QUANTUM STOCHASTIC CALCULUS TIMOTHY M. W. EYRE Department of Mathematics, University of Nottingham Nottingham, NG7 2RD, UK E-mail: [email protected] Abstract. A brief introduction to Z2-graded quantum stochastic calculus is given. By inducing a superalgebraic structure on the space of iterated integrals and using the heuristic classical relation df(Λ) = f(Λ+dΛ)−f(Λ) we provide an explicit formula for chaotic expansions of polynomials of the integrator processes of Z2-graded quantum stochastic calculus. 1. Introduction. A theory of Z2-graded quantum stochastic calculus was was in- troduced in [EH] as a generalisation of the one-dimensional Boson-Fermion unification result of quantum stochastic calculus given in [HP2]. Of particular interest in Z2-graded quantum stochastic calculus is the result that the integrators of the theory provide a time-indexed family of representations of a broad class of Lie superalgebras. The notion of a Lie superalgebra was introduced in [K] and has received considerable attention since. It is essentially a Z2-graded analogue of the notion of a Lie algebra with a bracket that is, in a certain sense, partly a commutator and partly an anticommutator. Another work on Lie superalgebras is [S] and general superalgebras are treated in [C,S]. The Lie algebra representation properties of ungraded quantum stochastic calculus enabled an explicit formula for the chaotic expansion of elements of an associated uni- versal enveloping algebra to be developed in [HPu].
    [Show full text]
  • Selim S. Hacısalihzade Control Engineering and Finance Lecture Notes in Control and Information Sciences
    Lecture Notes in Control and Information Sciences 467 Selim S. Hacısalihzade Control Engineering and Finance Lecture Notes in Control and Information Sciences Volume 467 Series editors Frank Allgöwer, Stuttgart, Germany Manfred Morari, Zürich, Switzerland Series Advisory Boards P. Fleming, University of Sheffield, UK P. Kokotovic, University of California, Santa Barbara, CA, USA A.B. Kurzhanski, Moscow State University, Russia H. Kwakernaak, University of Twente, Enschede, The Netherlands A. Rantzer, Lund Institute of Technology, Sweden J.N. Tsitsiklis, MIT, Cambridge, MA, USA About this Series This series aims to report new developments in the fields of control and information sciences—quickly, informally and at a high level. The type of material considered for publication includes: 1. Preliminary drafts of monographs and advanced textbooks 2. Lectures on a new field, or presenting a new angle on a classical field 3. Research reports 4. Reports of meetings, provided they are (a) of exceptional interest and (b) devoted to a specific topic. The timeliness of subject material is very important. More information about this series at http://www.springer.com/series/642 Selim S. Hacısalihzade Control Engineering and Finance 123 Selim S. Hacısalihzade Department of Electrical and Electronics Engineering Boğaziçi University Bebek, Istanbul Turkey ISSN 0170-8643 ISSN 1610-7411 (electronic) Lecture Notes in Control and Information Sciences ISBN 978-3-319-64491-2 ISBN 978-3-319-64492-9 (eBook) https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-64492-9 Library of Congress Control Number: 2017949161 © Springer International Publishing AG 2018 This work is subject to copyright. All rights are reserved by the Publisher, whether the whole or part of the material is concerned, specifically the rights of translation, reprinting, reuse of illustrations, recitation, broadcasting, reproduction on microfilms or in any other physical way, and transmission or information storage and retrieval, electronic adaptation, computer software, or by similar or dissimilar methodology now known or hereafter developed.
    [Show full text]
  • A Stochastic Fractional Calculus with Applications to Variational Principles
    fractal and fractional Article A Stochastic Fractional Calculus with Applications to Variational Principles Houssine Zine †,‡ and Delfim F. M. Torres *,‡ Center for Research and Development in Mathematics and Applications (CIDMA), Department of Mathematics, University of Aveiro, 3810-193 Aveiro, Portugal; [email protected] * Correspondence: delfi[email protected] † This research is part of first author’s Ph.D. project, which is carried out at the University of Aveiro under the Doctoral Program in Applied Mathematics of Universities of Minho, Aveiro, and Porto (MAP). ‡ These authors contributed equally to this work. Received: 19 May 2020; Accepted: 30 July 2020; Published: 1 August 2020 Abstract: We introduce a stochastic fractional calculus. As an application, we present a stochastic fractional calculus of variations, which generalizes the fractional calculus of variations to stochastic processes. A stochastic fractional Euler–Lagrange equation is obtained, extending those available in the literature for the classical, fractional, and stochastic calculus of variations. To illustrate our main theoretical result, we discuss two examples: one derived from quantum mechanics, the second validated by an adequate numerical simulation. Keywords: fractional derivatives and integrals; stochastic processes; calculus of variations MSC: 26A33; 49K05; 60H10 1. Introduction A stochastic calculus of variations, which generalizes the ordinary calculus of variations to stochastic processes, was introduced in 1981 by Yasue, generalizing the Euler–Lagrange equation and giving interesting applications to quantum mechanics [1]. Recently, stochastic variational differential equations have been analyzed for modeling infectious diseases [2,3], and stochastic processes have shown to be increasingly important in optimization [4]. In 1996, fifteen years after Yasue’s pioneer work [1], the theory of the calculus of variations evolved in order to include fractional operators and better describe non-conservative systems in mechanics [5].
    [Show full text]
  • A Short History of Stochastic Integration and Mathematical Finance
    A Festschrift for Herman Rubin Institute of Mathematical Statistics Lecture Notes – Monograph Series Vol. 45 (2004) 75–91 c Institute of Mathematical Statistics, 2004 A short history of stochastic integration and mathematical finance: The early years, 1880–1970 Robert Jarrow1 and Philip Protter∗1 Cornell University Abstract: We present a history of the development of the theory of Stochastic Integration, starting from its roots with Brownian motion, up to the introduc- tion of semimartingales and the independence of the theory from an underlying Markov process framework. We show how the development has influenced and in turn been influenced by the development of Mathematical Finance Theory. The calendar period is from 1880 to 1970. The history of stochastic integration and the modelling of risky asset prices both begin with Brownian motion, so let us begin there too. The earliest attempts to model Brownian motion mathematically can be traced to three sources, each of which knew nothing about the others: the first was that of T. N. Thiele of Copen- hagen, who effectively created a model of Brownian motion while studying time series in 1880 [81].2; the second was that of L. Bachelier of Paris, who created a model of Brownian motion while deriving the dynamic behavior of the Paris stock market, in 1900 (see, [1, 2, 11]); and the third was that of A. Einstein, who proposed a model of the motion of small particles suspended in a liquid, in an attempt to convince other physicists of the molecular nature of matter, in 1905 [21](See [64] for a discussion of Einstein’s model and his motivations.) Of these three models, those of Thiele and Bachelier had little impact for a long time, while that of Einstein was immediately influential.
    [Show full text]
  • Informal Introduction to Stochastic Calculus 1
    MATH 425 PART V: INFORMAL INTRODUCTION TO STOCHASTIC CALCULUS G. BERKOLAIKO 1. Motivation: how to model price paths Differential equations have long been an efficient tool to model evolution of various mechanical systems. At the start of 20th century, however, science started to tackle modeling of systems driven by probabilistic effects, such as stock market (the work of Bachelier) or motion of small particles suspended in liquid (the work of Einstein and Smoluchowski). For us, the motivating questions are: Is there an equation describing the evolution of a stock price? And, perhaps more applicably, how can we simulate numerically a seemingly random path taken by the stock price? Example 1.1. We have seen in previous sections that we can model the distribution of stock prices at time t as p 2 St = S0 exp (µ − σ =2)t + σ tY ; (1.1) where Y is standard normal random variable. So perhaps, for every time t we can generate a standard normal variable, substitute it into equation (1.1) and plot the resulting St as a function of t? The result is shown in Figure 1 and it definitely does not look like a price path of a stock. The underlying reason is that we used equation (1.1) to simulate prices at different time points independently. However, if t1 is close to t2, the prices cannot be completely independent. It is the change in price that we assumed (in “Efficient Market Hypothesis") to be independent of the previous price changes. 2. Wiener process Definition 2.1. Wiener process (or Brownian motion) is a random function of t, denoted Wt = Wt(!) (where ! is the underlying random event) such that (a) Wt is a.s.
    [Show full text]
  • Lecture Notes on Stochastic Calculus (Part II)
    Lecture Notes on Stochastic Calculus (Part II) Fabrizio Gelsomino, Olivier L´ev^eque,EPFL July 21, 2009 Contents 1 Stochastic integrals 3 1.1 Ito's integral with respect to the standard Brownian motion . 3 1.2 Wiener's integral . 4 1.3 Ito's integral with respect to a martingale . 4 2 Ito-Doeblin's formula(s) 7 2.1 First formulations . 7 2.2 Generalizations . 7 2.3 Continuous semi-martingales . 8 2.4 Integration by parts formula . 9 2.5 Back to Fisk-Stratonoviˇc'sintegral . 10 3 Stochastic differential equations (SDE's) 11 3.1 Reminder on ordinary differential equations (ODE's) . 11 3.2 Time-homogeneous SDE's . 11 3.3 Time-inhomogeneous SDE's . 13 3.4 Weak solutions . 14 4 Change of probability measure 15 4.1 Exponential martingale . 15 4.2 Change of probability measure . 15 4.3 Martingales under P and martingales under PeT ........................ 16 4.4 Girsanov's theorem . 17 4.5 First application to SDE's . 18 4.6 Second application to SDE's . 19 4.7 A particular case: the Black-Scholes model . 20 4.8 Application : pricing of a European call option (Black-Scholes formula) . 21 1 5 Relation between SDE's and PDE's 23 5.1 Forward PDE . 23 5.2 Backward PDE . 24 5.3 Generator of a diffusion . 26 5.4 Markov property . 27 5.5 Application: option pricing and hedging . 28 6 Multidimensional processes 30 6.1 Multidimensional Ito-Doeblin's formula . 30 6.2 Multidimensional SDE's . 31 6.3 Drift vector, diffusion matrix and weak solution .
    [Show full text]
  • Introduction to Stochastic Calculus
    Introduction Conditional Expectation Martingales Brownian motion Stochastic integral Ito formula Introduction to Stochastic Calculus Rajeeva L. Karandikar Director Chennai Mathematical Institute [email protected] [email protected] Rajeeva L. Karandikar Director, Chennai Mathematical Institute Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 1 Introduction Conditional Expectation Martingales Brownian motion Stochastic integral Ito formula A Game Consider a gambling house. A fair coin is going to be tossed twice. A gambler has a choice of betting at two games: (i) A bet of Rs 1000 on first game yields Rs 1600 if the first toss results in a Head (H) and yields Rs 100 if the first toss results in Tail (T). (ii) A bet of Rs 1000 on the second game yields Rs 1800, Rs 300, Rs 50 and Rs 1450 if the two toss outcomes are HH,HT,TH,TT respectively. Rajeeva L. Karandikar Director, Chennai Mathematical Institute Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 2 Introduction Conditional Expectation Martingales Brownian motion Stochastic integral Ito formula Rajeeva L. Karandikar Director, Chennai Mathematical Institute Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 3 Introduction Conditional Expectation Martingales Brownian motion Stochastic integral Ito formula A Game...... Now it can be seen that the expected return from Game 1 is Rs 850 while from Game 2 is Rs 900 and so on the whole, the gambling house is set to make money if it can get large number of players to play. The novelty of the game (designed by an expert) was lost after some time and the casino owner decided to make it more interesting: he allowed people to bet without deciding if it is for Game 1 or Game 2 and they could decide to stop or continue after first toss.
    [Show full text]
  • Stochastic Calculus of Variations for Stochastic Partial Differential Equations
    JOURNAL OF FUNCTIONAL ANALYSIS 79, 288-331 (1988) Stochastic Calculus of Variations for Stochastic Partial Differential Equations DANIEL OCONE* Mathematics Department, Rutgers Universiiy, New Brunswick, New Jersey 08903 Communicated by Paul Malliavin Receved December 1986 This paper develops the stochastic calculus of variations for Hilbert space-valued solutions to stochastic evolution equations whose operators satisfy a coercivity con- dition. An application is made to the solutions of a class of stochastic pde’s which includes the Zakai equation of nonlinear filtering. In particular, a Lie algebraic criterion is presented that implies that all finite-dimensional projections of the solution define random variables which admit a density. This criterion generalizes hypoelhpticity-type conditions for existence and regularity of densities for Iinite- dimensional stochastic differential equations. 0 1988 Academic Press, Inc. 1. INTRODUCTION The stochastic calculus of variation is a calculus for functionals on Wiener space based on a concept of differentiation particularly suited to the invariance properties of Wiener measure. Wiener measure on the space of continuous @-valued paths is quasi-invariant with respect to translation by a path y iff y is absolutely continuous with a square-integrable derivative. Hence, the proper definition of the derivative of a Wiener functional considers variation only in directions of such y. Using this derivative and its higher-order iterates, one can develop Wiener functional Sobolev spaces, which are analogous in most respects to Sobolev spaces of functions over R”, and these spaces provide the right context for discussing “smoothness” and regularity of Wiener functionals. In particular, functionals defined by solving stochastic differential equations driven by a Wiener process are smooth in the stochastic calculus of variations sense; they are not generally smooth in a Frechet sense, which ignores the struc- ture of Wiener measure.
    [Show full text]
  • Itô Calculus
    It^ocalculus in a nutshell Vlad Gheorghiu Department of Physics Carnegie Mellon University Pittsburgh, PA 15213, U.S.A. April 7, 2011 Vlad Gheorghiu (CMU) It^ocalculus in a nutshell April 7, 2011 1 / 23 Outline 1 Elementary random processes 2 Stochastic calculus 3 Functions of stochastic variables and It^o'sLemma 4 Example: The stock market 5 Derivatives. The Black-Scholes equation and its validity. 6 References A summary of this talk is available online at http://quantum.phys.cmu.edu/QIP Vlad Gheorghiu (CMU) It^ocalculus in a nutshell April 7, 2011 2 / 23 Elementary random processes Elementary random processes Consider a coin-tossing experiment. Head: you win $1, tail: you give me $1. Let Ri be the outcome of the i-th toss, Ri = +1 or Ri = −1 both with probability 1=2. Ri is a random variable. 2 E[Ri ] = 0, E[Ri ] = 1, E[Ri Rj ] = 0. No memory! Same as a fair die, a balanced roulette wheel, but not blackjack! Pi Now let Si = j=1 Rj be the total amount of money you have up to and including the i-th toss. Vlad Gheorghiu (CMU) It^ocalculus in a nutshell April 7, 2011 3 / 23 Elementary random processes Random walks This is an example of a random walk. Figure: The outcome of a coin-tossing experiment. From PWQF. Vlad Gheorghiu (CMU) It^ocalculus in a nutshell April 7, 2011 4 / 23 Elementary random processes If we now calculate expectations of Si it does matter what information we have. 2 2 E[Si ] = 0 and E[Si ] = E[R1 + 2R1R2 + :::] = i.
    [Show full text]
  • Introduction to Supersymmetric Theory of Stochastics
    entropy Review Introduction to Supersymmetric Theory of Stochastics Igor V. Ovchinnikov Department of Electrical Engineering, University of California at Los Angeles, Los Angeles, CA 90095, USA; [email protected]; Tel.: +1-310-825-7626 Academic Editors: Martin Eckstein and Jay Lawrence Received: 31 October 2015; Accepted: 21 March 2016; Published: 28 March 2016 Abstract: Many natural and engineered dynamical systems, including all living objects, exhibit signatures of what can be called spontaneous dynamical long-range order (DLRO). This order’s omnipresence has long been recognized by the scientific community, as evidenced by a myriad of related concepts, theoretical and phenomenological frameworks, and experimental phenomena such as turbulence, 1/ f noise, dynamical complexity, chaos and the butterfly effect, the Richter scale for earthquakes and the scale-free statistics of other sudden processes, self-organization and pattern formation, self-organized criticality, etc. Although several successful approaches to various realizations of DLRO have been established, the universal theoretical understanding of this phenomenon remained elusive. The possibility of constructing a unified theory of DLRO has emerged recently within the approximation-free supersymmetric theory of stochastics (STS). There, DLRO is the spontaneous breakdown of the topological or de Rahm supersymmetry that all stochastic differential equations (SDEs) possess. This theory may be interesting to researchers with very different backgrounds because the ubiquitous DLRO is a truly interdisciplinary entity. The STS is also an interdisciplinary construction. This theory is based on dynamical systems theory, cohomological field theories, the theory of pseudo-Hermitian operators, and the conventional theory of SDEs. Reviewing the literature on all these mathematical disciplines can be time consuming.
    [Show full text]
  • Lecture 2: Itô Calculus and Stochastic Differential Equations
    Lecture 2: Itô Calculus and Stochastic Differential Equations Simo Särkkä Aalto University, Finland (visiting at Oxford University, UK) November 14, 2013 Simo Särkkä (Aalto) Lecture 2: Itô Calculus and SDEs November 14, 2013 1 / 34 Contents 1 Introduction 2 Stochastic integral of Itô 3 Itô formula 4 Solutions of linear SDEs 5 Non-linear SDE, solution existence, etc. 6 Summary Simo Särkkä (Aalto) Lecture 2: Itô Calculus and SDEs November 14, 2013 2 / 34 SDEs as white noise driven differential equations During the last lecture we treated SDEs as white-noise driven differential equations of the form dx = f(x; t) + L(x; t) w(t); dt For linear equations the approach worked ok. But there is something strange going on: The use of chain rule of calculus led to wrong results. With non-linear differential equations we were completely lost. Picard-Lindelöf theorem did not work at all. The source of all the problems is the everywhere discontinuous white noise w(t). So how should we really formulate SDEs? Simo Särkkä (Aalto) Lecture 2: Itô Calculus and SDEs November 14, 2013 4 / 34 Equivalent integral equation Integrating the differential equation from t0 to t gives: Z t Z t x(t) − x(t0) = f(x(t); t) dt + L(x(t); t) w(t) dt: t0 t0 The first integral is just a normal Riemann/Lebesgue integral. The second integral is the problematic one due to the white noise. This integral cannot be defined as Riemann, Stieltjes or Lebesgue integral as we shall see next. Simo Särkkä (Aalto) Lecture 2: Itô Calculus and SDEs November 14, 2013 6 / 34 Attempt 1: Riemann integral In the Riemannian sense the integral would be defined as Z t X ∗ ∗ ∗ L(x(t); t) w(t) dt = lim L(x(t ); t ) w(t )(tk+1 − tk ); n!1 k k k t0 k ∗ where t0 < t1 < : : : < tn = t and tk 2 [tk ; tk+1].
    [Show full text]