Downloadable File 53

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Downloadable File 53 A. A. Cournot Exposition of the Theory of Chances and Probabilities A. A. Cournot, Exposition de la théorie des chances et des probabilités. Paris, 1843, 1984 Translated by Oscar Sheynin Oscar Sheynin, 2013 Berlin, 2013 NG Verlag The more difficult it seems to establish logically what is variable and obeys chance, the more delightful is the science that determines the results Huygens1 1 Contents Note by Translator Preface 1. Combinations and order 2. Chances and mathematical probability 3. The laws of mathematical probability of the repetition of events 4. Randomness. Physical possibility and impossibility 5. Sale prices of chances and probabilities. The market of chances and games in general 6. Laws of probability. Mean values and medians 7. Variability of chances 8. Posterior probabilities 9. Statistics in general and experimental determination of chances 10. Experimental determination of mean values by observations and formation of tables of probabilities 11. Means of measurements and observations 12. Application to problems in natural philosophy 13. Application to problems in demography and duration of life 14. On insurance 15. Theory of probability of judgements. Applications to judicial statistics of civil cases 16. Theory of probability of judgements, continued. Applications to judicial statistics of criminal cases. Probability of testimonies 17. On the probability of our knowledge and on judgements based on philosophical probabilities. Summary 2 Note by Translator Antoine Augustin Cournot (1801 – 1877) was a mathematician, philosopher, economist and educator (Feller 1961; Etudes 1978). Here, I discuss his contribution of 1843 reprinted in 1984 (Paris, Libraire J. Vrin) as vol. 1 of his Oeuvres Complètes complete with an Introduction and Commentary by B. Bru. In this Introduction, Bru remarked that in 1828 and 1829 Cournot had published two notes on the calculus of chances and combinations. In 1834, Cournot translated J. Herschel’s astronomical treatise and appended a discussion of cometary orbits which constitutes here a large part of Chapter 12. A long paper on the application of the theory of probability to judicial statistics followed in 1838 and was largely reprinted here, in Chapters 15 and 16. Bru’s commentary certainly demanded great efforts; by his permission, I quoted some of them adding his initials (B. B.). Regrettably, many of his comments are too short and for the same reason some of his references are not readily understandable. He repeatedly mentions Condorcet, Lacroix, and certainly Laplace and Poisson as the main authors from whom Cournot had issued and he also notes (see p. 318, comment to p. 108, line 12) that Cournot had seldom indicated them. Cournot reprinted Kramp’s table of the normal distribution appended to his book (1799); it is not included in the translation. There exist translations of Cournot’s book into German (1849) by C. H. Schnuse, who also translated, in 1841, Poisson (1837), and into Russian (Moscow, 1970) by N. S. Chetverikov, the closest student of Chuprov. A few of Cournot’s terms ought to be explained. Element is parameter; philosophical criticism apparently means philosophical discussion; a commensurable number is rational. And the same randomness is the same random variable. See explanation of Bernoulli theorems in § 30. And, finally, I have introduced the then still n unknown notation Cm and n! The Preface begins by an explanation: Cournot wished to make assessable his subject to those unacquainted with the higher chapters of mathematics. In § 123 he even repeated the formulation of the Pythagorean proposition (excluded in the translation) and in § 69 he says that he adduced a table (Kramp’s table) of a certain function (of the exponential function of a negative square) but he did not provide its analytical expression. I doubt that that was good enough, but then, his Chapter 12 was certainly beyond the reach of ordinary readers. As Bru noted in his Introduction, the book was not understood in its entirety either by mathematicians or other scientists [!], frequently quoted […] but rarely read. Cournot’s sentences are long-winded, up to 12 and 13 lines (§§ 117 and 240/4). In many cases, perhaps copying Poisson (1837), he connected the parts of complex sentences by semicolons rather than words which is not easy to understand. Demonstrative pronouns are often lacking, but unnecessary repetitions are plentiful. 3 [1] Cournot was obviously ignorant of precise observations (measurements) and he ignored Gauss. His Chapter 11 is therefore barely useful. [2] Cournot (§ 145) considered himself a pioneer in applying statistics to astronomy, but he forgot to mention William Herschel, and he certainly had no means for studying the starry heaven. [3] He did not study the application of statistics to meteorology although Humboldt, in 1817, had introduced isotherms, cf. Cournot’s definition of the aims of statistics in § 103! [4] While discussing statistics of population (Chapter 13), Cournot had not mentioned Daniel Bernoulli’s classical study of prevention of smallpox published in 1766, and Gavarret’s contribution (1840) escaped his notice. For many decades, in spite of the work of Graunt, Süssmilch and Daniel B., later statisticians had avoided medical statistics. [5] Many elementary calculations (in §§ 13. 70, 165 – 167, 170, 182, 203, 204) are wrong which had not, however, affected Cournot’s general conclusions. [6] Cournot’s description of the Bayes rule (§ 88) is superficial: he did not notice that Bayes had treated an unknown constant as a random variable. True, he (§ 89) remarked that without prior information that rule leads to a subjective result, and he (§ 95) attempted to prove that with a large number of observations that result becomes objective. Cf. Note 9 to Chapter 8. His treatment of the Petersburg game is interesting, but he failed to refer to Condorcet (1784, p. 714) who had remarked that the possibly infinite game nevertheless only provided one trial so that many such games should have been discussed. Freudenthal (1951) expressed the same opinion and provided pertinent recommendations. Poisson’s law of large numbers is ignored; during Poisson’s lifetime, Cournot (1838) had, however, at least twice mentioned it. It is generally known that the reason of that about-face was Bienaymé’s attitude. Cournot’s description of tontines (§ 52) was completely wrong; see also Note 17 to Chapter 14. Poisson (see Preface) indicated that Cournot discern[ed] the difference between chances and probabilities. However, in § 12, see also § 240/3, the latter stated that probability was the ratio of the pertinent chances. And he almost indifferently applied the terms theory, or doctrine, of probability, and of chances. Now, however, I turn to other points whose positive aspect much prevail over the negative sude. [1] Probability. Cournot’s subjective philosophical probabilities (§§ 43, 233 and 240/8) can be related to expert opinions whose study undoubtedly belongs to mathematical statistics. Laplace (1812, Chapter 2) had introduced them, noted their possible application to decisions of tribunals and elections, but did not introduce any special term. In § 18 Cournot offered a definition of probability covering both the discrete and continuous cases (i. e., and geometric probability). He appropriately introduced the ratio of the extents (étendue) of the 4 pertinent chances; nowadays, we would have said of the measures. In § 45 he objected to Laplace’s belief that probability is relative in part to our ignorance and in part to our knowledge. Poisson’s letter to Cournot (see Preface) indicates that the latter discern[ed] the […] difference between the words chance and probability […]. However, in § 12, see also § 240/3, Cournot called probability the ratio of the pertinent chances and thus contradicted Poisson’s inference. And, see above, he almost indifferently applied the terms theory or doctrine of probability; or of chances. [2] Probability density. In 1709 Niklaus Bernoulli introduced a continuous distribution (and its density) and many later scholars, including Laplace and Gauss, applied such distributions and densities. Cournot (§§ 64 – 65, see also § 31) followed suit. His term was curve of probability; it appropriately represented […] the law of probabilities of different values of a variable magnitude. Indeed, in § 73, although after Poisson (1837, § 53), Cournot introduced a grandeur fortuitously taking a series of distinct values. True, in 1756 and 1757 Simpson, in an error-theoretic context, had effectively applied such variables. Cournot (§ 73) also described the determination of the density of a function u of a magnitude x which takes a series of various fortuitous values. Actually, he (§ 74) considered the case of a function of two independent variables and a linear function of many variables. Supposing that u = |x − y|, he concluded that for 0 ≤ a ≤ 1 P(u ≥ a) = (1 − a)2. The probability of the contrary event would have described the once-popular encounter problem (Whitworth 1886 and possibly 1867; Laurent P. H. (1873, pp. 67 – 69): two persons are to meet during a specified time interval but their arrivals are independent and occur at random and the first to arrive only waits a specified time. Before Cournot Bessel (1838, §§ 1 and 2) determined the densities of two functions of a continuous and uniformly distributed variable and Laplace solved such problems even earlier. In § 81 Cournot studied a mixture of densities. Let n1, n2, … observations have densities f1(x), f2(x), …, then the mixture of those observations will have a density equal to the weighted arithmetic mean of f1(x), f2(x), … [3] Median. It was Cournot (§ 34) who introduced this important parameter. [4] Randomness. Cournot (§ 40) defined a random event as an intersection of (two) independent chains of other events and thus revived an ancient idea (Aristotle). In § 45 he mentioned the mathematical theory of randomness acting in the proper field of science and declared that randomness has a notable role […] in governing the world. Lacking was the dialectical link between randomness and necessity which Kant (1781/1911, p.
Recommended publications
  • Antoine-Augustine Cournot: His Duopoly Problem with a Re- Appraisal of His Duopoly Price and His Influence Upon Leon Alrw As
    University of Montana ScholarWorks at University of Montana Graduate Student Theses, Dissertations, & Professional Papers Graduate School 1968 Antoine-Augustine Cournot: His duopoly problem with a re- appraisal of his duopoly price and his influence upon Leon alrW as David M. Dodge The University of Montana Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarworks.umt.edu/etd Let us know how access to this document benefits ou.y Recommended Citation Dodge, David M., "Antoine-Augustine Cournot: His duopoly problem with a re-appraisal of his duopoly price and his influence upon Leon alrW as" (1968). Graduate Student Theses, Dissertations, & Professional Papers. 8753. https://scholarworks.umt.edu/etd/8753 This Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the Graduate School at ScholarWorks at University of Montana. It has been accepted for inclusion in Graduate Student Theses, Dissertations, & Professional Papers by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks at University of Montana. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Al'îTCINS-AUGUSTINE COÜRKOTi HIS DUOPOLY PROBLEM ra'IH A RS-APPPAI3AL OF HIS DUOPOLY PRICE AND HIS INFLUENCE UPON LEON WALRAS By David M. Dodge B.A. j, University of Montana, 1968 Presented in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Arts UNIVERSITY OF MONTAÎSA 1968 Approved bys Cî^cii ZTOsn ard of Examiners Air X ] Date Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. UMI Number: EP39554 All rights reserved INFORMATION TO ALL USERS The quality of this reproduction is dependent upon the quality of the copy submitted. In the unlikely event that the author did not send a complete manuscript and there are missing pages, these will be noted.
    [Show full text]
  • Intermediate Microeconomics
    Intermediate Microeconomics IMPERFECT COMPETITION BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD PURDUE UNIVERSITY No, not the BCS Oligopoly: A market with few firms but more than one. Duopoly: A market with two firms. Cartel: Several firms collectively acting like a monopolist by charging a common price and dividing the monopoly profit among them. Imperfect Competition: A market in which firms compete but do not erode all profits. Perfect competition with only 2 firms Assume the following model: ◦ 2 firms that produce the same good (call the firms “Kemp’s Milk” and “Dean’s Milk”). ◦ They both have the same marginal cost (c), and it is constant (so constant AC, too). ◦ The Demand for their good is downward-sloping, but does not have to have a particular shape. ◦ The firms simultaneously choose their prices ( and ). ◦ The firm with the lower price captures the whole market, and the other firm gets nothing. ◦ If both firms set the same price, they split the market demand evenly. Bertrand competition The profit for each firm is given by: = , [ ] and = ( , )[ ]. Π − This model is calledΠ the Bertrand model− of Duopoly—after 19th Century economist, Joseph Louis Francois Bertrand. To find the equilibrium, however, we’re not going to use calculus—just reason. Equilibrium in the Bertrand model Say that you’re Kemp’s dairy. If Dean’s is charging any price that is greater than your own c, then you can choose from among three intervals for your own price: > , = , < . If you go with the first one, ≤ you get no sales because Dean’s undercut your price. If you go with the second one, you get: 1 , .
    [Show full text]
  • B21-2015 Memorial Resolution
    B21-2015 MEMORIAL RESOLUTION PROFESSOR EMERITUS IRVIN MILLMAN GROSSACK (April 25, 1927 – March 4, 2013) Professor Irvin Grossack was born in 1927 in the city of New York. After completing his secondary education at the Bronx High School of Science, he entered the City University of New York where he received a bachelors degree in economics in 1952. After graduation, he worked as a research assistant at the National Bureau of Economic Research in New York City (1954), as an Economic Statistician at the Bureau of the Census in Suitland, Maryland (1955-59) and as a Senior Economist at C.E.I.R., Inc. in Arlington, Virginia (1959-62). He completed his PhD in economics at Columbia University in 1962, and in the same year he moved with his young family to Bloomington, Indiana to join the Department of Business Economics and Public Policy at the Indiana University School of Business, where he taught until his retirement. On a leave of absence from IU, he spent three years (1966-68) in New Delhi, India as a Program Economist for the US-AID Mission (1966-68). Professor Grossack’s research centered in microeconomics and the history of economic thought. His best work was on industrial organization. Here is a selected sample of his most significant writing. In the “The Concept and Measurement of Permanent Industrial Organization” (Journal of Political Economy, 1972, 80:745-760), Grossack argues that the monopoly power of large firms should be judged by their ability to stop smaller firms from entering the market rather than by static and backward-looking measures of concentration.
    [Show full text]
  • Antoine Augustin Cournot: the Pioneer of Modern Economic Ideas
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive Antoine Augustin Cournot: The Pioneer of Modern Economic Ideas Hossain, Md. Mobarak and Chowdhury, Md Niaz Murshed University of Nevada, Reno, Department of Economics, 1664 N. Virginia Street, Reno, NV 89557, USA. 24 December 2018 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/90829/ MPRA Paper No. 90829, posted 31 Dec 2018 14:30 UTC Antoine Augustin Cournot: The Pioneer of Modern Economic Ideas Md. Mobarak Hossain 1 Md Niaz Murshed Chowdhury 2 Abstract Augustin Cournot, an unsung pioneer of many economic ideas during his time, who has written the book, Theory of Wealth, where he developed many economic ideas including the oligopoly theory, doupoly model, the ideas of function and probability into economic analysis. This paper discusses the way he thought the economics should be analyzed as well as his life cycle. Introduction Antoine Augustin Cournot (28 August 1801 – 31 March 1877) was a French philosopher and mathematician who also has great contribution to the development of economic theory [4]. His theories on monopolies and duopolies are still famous in economics. In 1838 the book Researches on the Mathematical Principles of the Theory of Wealth was published, in which he used the applications of the formulas and symbols of mathematics in economic analysis. This 1Corresponding address: University of Nevada, Reno, Department of Economics, 1664 N. Virginia Street, Reno, NV 89557, USA. Email: [email protected] 2University of Nevada, Reno, Department of Economics, 1664 N. Virginia Street, Reno, NV 89557, USA. book was highly criticized and not very successful during Cournot’s lifetime, and he did try to rewrite it twice, but it still has influence in economics today.
    [Show full text]
  • Considerations on the Fundamental Principles of Pure Political Economy
    Considerations on the Fundamental Principles of Pure Political Economy Considerations on the Fundamental Principles of Pure Political Economy (Considerazioni sui principi fondamentali dell’economia pura) was originally published as a series of five articles in the Giornale degli Economisti between May 1892 and October 1893. They were the first systematic representation of Vilfredo Pareto’s contribution to pure economics and their publication in this volume in English closes a serious gap in the knowledge of the work of one of the founders of modern economic science. In the book, Pareto deals with an impressively wide range of subjects including the nature and the limits of the new theories of marginalist econ- omics, the use of mathematics in economics, the problem of method and the hedonistic hypothesis, the concept of homo œconomicus and, last but not least, the concept of final degree of utility. These reflections make the Considerations an assessment of the state of the new economic theories expounded in a mathematical form at the beginning of the 1890s. These papers have exerted a great deal of influence in the sub- sequent development of economic theory. As such, the volume can be con- sidered required reading for all serious economists across the world. Roberto Marchionatti is Professor of Economics at the University of Torino, Italy. He has been a Visiting Scholar in Economics at New York University and at the University of Cambridge, UK. Fiorenzo Mornati is Assistant Professor of Economics at the University of Torino, Italy. He has been Assistant de Recherche at the University of Lausanne (Centre Walras-Pareto), Switzerland.
    [Show full text]
  • Marshallian Cross Diagrams and Their Uses Before Alfred Marshall: the Origins of Supply and Demand Geometry
    Marshallian Cross Diagrams and Their Uses before Alfred Marshall: The Origins of Supply and Demand Geometry ThonaasM. Humphrey And Karl Rau (184 l), Jules Dupuit (1844), Hans von Mangoldt (1863), and Fleeming Jenkin (1870) thor- Undoubtedly the simplest. and most frequently oughly developed it years before Marshall presented used tool of microeconomic analysis is the conven- it in his Pzm Theory of Domestic Vafues (1879) and tional partial equilibrium demand-and-supply-curve later in his Pnitciples of fionomics (1890). Far from diagram of the textbooks. Economics professors merely introducing the diagram, these writers applied and their students put the diagram to at least six it to derive many of the concepts and theories often main uses. They use it to depict the equilibrium or attributed to Marshall or his followers. The notions market-clearing price and quantity of any particular of price elasticity of demand and supply, of stability good or factor input. They employ it to show how of equilibrium, of the possibility of multiple equilibria, (Walrasian) price or (Marshallian) quantity adjust- of comparative statics analyses involving shifts in the ments ensure this equilibrium: the first by eliminating curves, of consumers’ and producers’ surplus, of con- excess supply and demand, the second by eradicating stant, increasing and decreasing costs, of pricing of disparities between supply price and demand price. joint and composite products, of potential benefits They use it to illustrate how parametric shifts in of price discrimination, of tax incidence analysis, of demand and supply curves induced by changes in deadweight-welfare-loss triangles and the allocative tastes, incomes, technology, factor prices, and prices inefficiency of monopoly: all find expression in of related goods operate to alter a good’s equilibrium early expositions of the diagram.
    [Show full text]
  • Notes and References
    Notes and References Note: The term 'loc. cit.' is used when a text has just been mentioned and the term 'op. cit.' is used when a text has been referenced some distance back. 1 The Classical Legacy 1. For a recent critical survey of classical trade theory, including the debate on the Corn Laws and the BuUionist and Banking/Currency school controversies, see Leonard Gomes, Foreign Trade and the National Economy: Mercantilist and Classical Perspectives (London: Macmillan, 1987) part II. Part I of the same book surveys the foreign trade doctrines of the mercantilists. 2. Joan Robinson, 'Reflections on the Theory of International Trade', in her Collected Economic Papers, vol. 5 (Oxford: Blackwell, 1979) p. 130. 2 Early Neoclassical Contributions 1. A. A. Cournot, Recherches sur les Principes Mathematiques de la Theorie des Richesses (Paris: Hachette, 1838). Translated by Nathaniel T. Bacon as Researches into the Mathematical Principles of the Theory of Wealth (London: Macmillan, 1897) p. 117. 2. Cournot's arithmetical example is in Principes, pp. 314-15. 3. See Edgeworth, 'The Theory of International Values', Economic Jour­ nal, 1894, p. 627. 4. Researches, p. 157. 5. Researches, p. 156. 6. Ibid. pp. 162-3. 7. The 1844 criticism was by Carl Heinrich Hagen, in his book, Die Nothwendigkeit der Handelsfreiheit fur das Nationaleinkommen, mathe- matisch nachgewiesen (Konigsberg, 1844) pp. 30-1. Samuelson praises Cournot's treatment of interspatial price equilibrium as being 'marvel­ lously modern and fruitful', but adds, 'his analysis of tariff protection appears to be ambiguous and of doubtful validity'. P. A. Samuelson, The Way of An Economist', in Paul Samuelson (ed.), International Economic Relations (London: Macmillan, 1969) p.
    [Show full text]
  • Charles S. Peirce, Economics, and Scientific Method
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Hoover, Kevin D.; Wible, James R. Working Paper Ricardian inference: Charles S. Peirce, economics, and scientific method CHOPE Working Paper, No. 2017-10 Provided in Cooperation with: Center for the History of Political Economy at Duke University Suggested Citation: Hoover, Kevin D.; Wible, James R. (2017) : Ricardian inference: Charles S. Peirce, economics, and scientific method, CHOPE Working Paper, No. 2017-10, Duke University, Center for the History of Political Economy (CHOPE), Durham, NC This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/172302 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Ricardian Inference: Charles S. Peirce, Economics, and Scientific Method by Kevin D.
    [Show full text]
  • “Fred Schweppe Meets Marcel Boiteux and Antoine- Augustin Cournot: Transmission Constraints and Strategic Underinvestment in Electric Power Generation »
    IDEI-796 September 2013 “Fred Schweppe meets Marcel Boiteux and Antoine- Augustin Cournot: transmission constraints and strategic underinvestment in electric power generation » Thomas-Olivier Léautier 7 Fred Schweppe meets Marcel Boiteux and Antoine-Augustin Cournot: transmission constraints and strategic underinvestment in electric power generation Thomas-Olivier Léautier Toulouse School of Economics (IAE, IDEI, University of Toulouse) 21 allée de Brienne F31 000 Toulouse [email protected] and +33 6 33 34 60 68 September 19, 2013 Abstract This article examines imperfectly competitive investment in electric power generation in the presence of congestion on the transmission grid. Under simple yet realistic assumptions, it precisely derives the technology mix as a function of the capacity of the transmission interconnection. In particular, it …nds that, if the interconnection is congested in one direction only, the cumulative capacity is not a¤ected by the congestion, while the baseload capacity is simply the uncongested baseload capacity, weighted by the size of its domestic market, plus the interconnection capacity. If the interconnection is successively congested in both directions, the peaking capacity is the cumulative uncongested capacity, weighted by the size its domestic market, plus the capacity of the interconnection, while the baseload capacity is the solution of a simple …rst-order condition. The marginal value of interconnection capacity is shown to generalize the expression obtained under perfect competition. It includes both a short-term component, that captures the reduction in marginal cost from substituting cheaper for more expensive power, but also a long-term component, that captures the change in installed capacity. Finally, increasing interconnection is shown to have an ambiguous impact on producers’pro…ts.
    [Show full text]
  • Cournot in English
    Cournot in English Glenn Shafer Rutgers Business School [email protected] The Game-Theoretic Probability and Finance Project Working Paper #48 First posted April 16, 2017. Last revised January 1, 2018. Project web site: http://www.probabilityandfinance.com Abstract Trained as a mathematician, the French scholar Antoine Augustin Cournot (1801{1877) is remembered as a philosopher and economist. Unfortunately, his 1843 book on the philosophy of probability and statistics was never translated into English. Here I provide English translations of a few passages from Cournot's books. To provide context, I also quote a few earlier and later scholars. A complete translation of Cournot's 1843 book by Oscar Sheynin is available at http://sheynin.de/download/cournot.pdf. 1 Introduction 1 2 Before Cournot 2 2.1 Jacob Bernoulli (1655{1705) . .2 2.2 David Hume (1711{1776) . .4 2.3 Pierre Simon Laplace (1749{1827) . .4 3 Passages from Cournot 5 3.1 Cournot's principle . .6 3.2 Multiple testing . .7 3.3 Cournot's superior intelligence . .9 3.4 Independent causal chains . 11 3.5 Bernoulli and Bayes . 12 3.6 What is Statistics?.......................... 14 3.7 Large-sample confidence limits . 15 3.8 Philosophical probability . 16 3.9 Summarizing in 1843 . 17 3.10 Determinism . 20 4 After Cournot 22 4.1 James Clerk Maxwell (1831{1879) . 22 4.2 Charles Sanders Peirce (1839{1914) . 22 4.3 Andrei Kolmogorov (1903{1987) . 23 4.4 Abraham Wald (1902{1950) . 24 4.5 Trygve Haavelmo (1911{1999) . 25 References 26 1 Introduction Cournot sought to understand the relation between pure and applied mathematics|how mathematics can describe the natural and social worlds.
    [Show full text]
  • Mastering Economic Thinking Skills
    AP® Economics 2006–2007 Professional Development Workshop Materials Special Focus: Mastering Economic Thinking Skills connect to college success™ www.collegeboard.com ��������������������������������������������������������� The College Board is a not-for-profit membership association whose mission is to connect students to college success and opportunity. Founded in 1900, the association is composed of more than 5,000 schools, colleges, universities, and other educational organizations. Each year, the College Board serves seven million students and their parents, 23,000 high schools, and 3,500 colleges through major programs and services in college admissions, guidance, assessment, financial aid, enrollment, and teaching and learning. Among its best-known programs are the SAT®, the PSAT/NMSQT®, and the Advanced Placement Program® (AP®). The College Board is committed to the principles of excellence and equity, and that commitment is embodied in all of its programs, services, activities, and concerns. ����������������������� ���������������������������������������������������������������������������� ������������������������������������������������������������������������������������� ����������������������������������������������������������������������������������������� ��������������������������������������������������������������������������������������� ������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������ ���������������������������������������������������������������������������������� �����������������������������������������������������������������������������������������
    [Show full text]
  • An Introductory Course on Mathematical Game Theory
    An Introductory Course on Mathematical Game Theory Julio González-Díaz Ignacio García-Jurado M. Gloria Fiestras-Janeiro Graduate Studies in Mathematics Volume 115 American Mathematical Society Real Sociedad Matemática Española http://dx.doi.org/10.1090/gsm/115 An Introductory Course on Mathematical Game Theory An Introductory Course on Mathematical Game Theory Julio González-Díaz Ignacio García-Jurado M. Gloria Fiestras-Janeiro Graduate Studies in Mathematics Volume 115 American Mathematical Society Real Sociedad Matemática Española Editorial Board of Graduate Studies in Mathematics David Cox (Chair) Rafe Mazzeo Martin Scharlemann Gigliola Staffilani Editorial Committee of the Real Sociedad Matem´atica Espa˜nola Guillermo P. Curbera, Director Luis Al´ıas Alberto Elduque Emilio Carrizosa Rosa Mar´ıa Mir´o Bernardo Cascales Pablo Pedregal Javier Duoandikoetxea Juan Soler 2010 Mathematics Subject Classification. Primary 91–01; Secondary 90C05, 05C57. For additional information and updates on this book, visit www.ams.org/bookpages/gsm-115 Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Gonz´alez-D´ıaz, Julio, 1978– An introductory course on mathematical game theory / Julio Gonz´alez-D´ıaz, Ignacio Garc´ıa- Jurado and M. Gloria Fiestras-Janeiro. p. cm. — (Graduate studies in mathematics ; v. 115) Includes biblographical references and index. ISBN 978-0-8218-5151-7 (alk. paper) 1. Game theory. I. Garc´ıa-Jurado, I. (Ignacio) II. Fiestras-Janeiro, M. Gloria, 1962– III. Title. QA269.G66 2010 519.3—dc22 2010000501 Copying and reprinting. Individual readers of this publication, and nonprofit libraries acting for them, are permitted to make fair use of the material, such as to copy a chapter for use in teaching or research.
    [Show full text]