Microeconomics Monopoly and Monopsony

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Microeconomics Monopoly and Monopsony Microeconomics Monopoly and monopsony Harald Wiese Leipzig University Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 1 / 53 Structure Introduction Household theory Theory of the firm Perfect competition and welfare theory Types of markets Monopoly and monopsony Game theory Oligopoly External effects and public goods Pareto-optimal review Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 2 / 53 Definition monopoly and monopsony Monopoly: one firm sells Monopsony: one firm buys Monopoly: Price setting Quantity setting p X Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 3 / 53 Price versus quantity setting p II I p demand p M MC AC y y M y III IV Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 4 / 53 Overview Definitions Price setting Revenue and marginal revenue with respect to price Profit Profit maximization (without price differentiation) Quantity setting Revenue and marginal revenue with respect to price (?) Profit Profit maximization without price differentiation Profit maximization with price differentiation Quantity and profit taxes Welfare analysis Monopsony Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 5 / 53 Revenue and marginal revenue with respect to price Revenue for demand function X (p): R(p) = pX (p) Marginal revenue (= MR, here MRp): dR dX MR = = X + p (product rule) p dp dp If the price increases by one unit, on the one hand, revenue increases by X (for every sold unit the firm obtains one Euro) dX on the other hand, revenue decreases by p dp (the price increase decreases demand that is valued at price p) Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 6 / 53 Profit in the linear model Definition Let X be the demand function. Then P (p) := R (p) − C (p) | {z } | {z } | {z } profit revenue cost is profit depending on price p and P(p) = p (d − ep) − c ((d − ep)) , d c, d, e ≥ 0, p ≤ e profit in the linear model. Functions: price 7! quantity 7! cost Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 7 / 53 Revenue, cost and a question I R,C cd C R p ? p Problem What is the economic meaning of the prices with question mark? Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 8 / 53 Revenue, cost and a question II R,C cd C R p p0 p Rmax pmax p X CR0 Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 9 / 53 Marginal cost with respect to price and with respect to quantity dC dX : marginal cost (with respect to quantity) dC dp : marginal cost (with respect to price) dC dC dX = < 0. dp dX dp |{z} |{z} >0 <0 Chain rule: differentiate C (X (p)) with respect to p means: first, differentiate C with respect to X ) marginal cost then, differentiate X with respect to p ) slope of demand function Functions: price 7! quantity 7! cost Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 10 / 53 Profit maximization Profit condition dP dR dC =! 0 or − =! 0 or dp dp dp dR dC =! dp dp Problem Confirm: The profit-maximizing price in the linear model is M d+ce p = 2e . Which price maximizes revenue? Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 11 / 53 Profit maximization Comparative static We have d + ce pM = . 2e How does pM change if c increases? Differentiation: dpM 1 = dc 2 Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 12 / 53 Exercises Problem 1 Consider a monopolist with cost function C (X ) = cX , c > 0, and demand function X (p) = ap#, # < −1. 1 Determine price elasticity of demand marginal revenue with respect to price 2 Express the monopoly price as a function of #! dpM 3 Determine and interpret dj#j ! Problem 2 The demand function is given by X (p) = 12 − 2p and the cost function of the monopolist by C (X ) = X 2 + 3. Determine the profit-maximizing price! Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 13 / 53 The linear model A reminder p a a 1 X , p 1 b a 2b 2 pX 1 p(X ) MR a a X 2b b a a X 2b b Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 14 / 53 Marginal revenue Marginal revenue and elasticity (Amoroso-Robinson relation) dR dp MR = = p + X (product rule) dX dX 1 1 = p 1 + = p 1 − > 0 for j#X ,pj > 1 #X ,p j#X ,pj dp Marginal revenue equals price MR = p + X · dX = p in three cases: dp dp horizontal (inverse) demand, dX = 0: MR = p + X · dX = p =0 first small\ unit, X = 0: MR = p + X · dp = p = R(X ) " =0 dX X first-degree price differentiation, MR = p + X · dp =0 dX ) see below Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 15 / 53 Profit Definition For X ≥ 0 and inverse demand function p monopoly profit depending on quantity is given by P (X ) := R (X ) − C (X ) = p (X ) X − C (X ) | {z } | {z } | {z } profit revenue cost Linear case: a P(X ) = (a − bX ) X − cX , X ≤ b Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 16 / 53 Profit Average and marginal definition profit for X¯ : p P (X¯ ) = p(X¯ )X¯ − C (X¯ ) a D = [p(X¯ ) − AC (X¯ )] X¯ E G (average definition) pX F pX MR H X¯ AC Z C MC = [MR (X ) − MC (X )] dX c B A 0 X X −F (if appropriate) (marginal definition) Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 17 / 53 Quantity setting with uniform price We have: inverse demand function for the monopolist: p(X ) total cost: C (X ) Monopolist's profit P : P(X ) = R(X ) − C (X ) = p(X )X − C (X ). Necessary condition for profit maximization: dP dR dC = − =! 0 dX dX dX or, equivalently, MR =! MC Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 18 / 53 Quantity setting with uniform price p MC AC Cournot point p M demand MR X M X Problem Inverse demand function p (X ) = 27 − X 2. Revenue-maximizing and profit-maximizing price for MC = 15? Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 19 / 53 Clever man: Antoine Augustin Cournot Antoine Augustin Cournot (1801-1877) was a French philosopher, mathematician, and economist. In his main work \Recherches sur les principes math´ematiquesde la th´eorie des richesses", 1838, Cournot presents essential elements of monopoly theory (this chapter) and oligopoly theory (next chapter) Inventor (?) of the Nash equilibrium Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 20 / 53 Quantity setting with uniform price The linear model p p MC AC X , p c D a X ,p 1 a 0 E M X , p p M pX pX MR c MR A B F X M X PC X X ( 1 (a−c) , c ≤ a X M = X M (c, a, b) = 2 b 0, c > a Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 21 / 53 Quantity setting with uniform price Maximum profit p MC AC Cournot point p M profit ACX M demand MR X M X Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 22 / 53 Quantity setting with uniform price Comparative statics I M 1 (a−c) ¶X M ¶X M ¶X M X (a, b, c) = 2 b , where ¶c < 0; ¶a > 0; ¶b < 0, M 1 ¶pM ¶pM ¶pM p (a, b, c) = 2 (a + c), where ¶c > 0; ¶a > 0; ¶b = 0, 2 M 1 (a−c) ¶PM ¶PM ¶PM P (a, b, c) = 4 b , where ¶c < 0; ¶a > 0; ¶b < 0. Problem 2 M 1 (a−c) dPM Show P (c) = 4 b and determine dc ! Hint: Use the chain rule. Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 23 / 53 Quantity setting with uniform price Comparative statics I Solution 1 (a−c)2 dPM d 4 b = dc dc 1 = 2(a − c) (−1) 4b a − c = − 2b Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 24 / 53 Alternative expressions for profit maximization 1 MC =! MR = p 1 − j#X ,pj ! 1 j#X ,pj p = 1 MC = MC 1 − j#X ,pj − 1 j#X ,p j p − p 1 − 1 p − MC j#X ,p j 1 =! = p p j#X ,pj Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 25 / 53 Monopoly power perfect competition: Profit maximization implies \price = marginal cost" Explanation: With perfect competition every firm is \small" and has no influence on price. Inverse demand is then horizontal, hence MR = p. Monopoly: The optimal price is in general above marginal cost. Definition (Lerner index) p − MC p Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 26 / 53 Monopoly power Lerner index ! p−MC ! Perfect competition: p = MC and hence p = 0 Monopoly: MC =! MR = p 1 − 1 and hence j#X ,p j p − p 1 − 1 p − MC p − MR j#X ,p j 1 =! = = p p p j#X ,pj Interpretation: If demand reacts strongly to price increases, the monopolist wants to choose a price close to marginal cost. Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 27 / 53 Monopoly power, but zero monopoly profit p AC Cournot pM point MC p(X ) MR X X M C X M p > MC, but AC X M = = pM X M Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 28 / 53 Forms of price differentiation First-degree price differentiation: Every consumer pays his willingness to pay =) complete absorption of consumer surplus Second-degree price differentiation: The firm requires different prices for different quantities (e.g., quantity discount) =) different prices for high-intensity users and low-intensity users Third-degree price differentiation: Consumers are grouped in different categories. =) uniform price only within a category Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 29 / 53 First-degree price differentiation Every consumer pays his willingness to pay: dp MR = p + X · = p =0 dX A price decrease resulting from an extension of output concerns only the marginal consumer, but not inframarginal consumers (those with a higher willingness to pay) Harald Wiese (Leipzig University) Monopoly and monopsony 30 / 53 First-degree price differentiation Formally: Take the derivative of revenue with respect to quantity d R y p (q) dq MR = 0 = p (y) dy Hint: Differentiating an integral with respect to the upper bound of integration yields the value of the integrand (here p (q)) at the upper bound.
Recommended publications
  • Microeconomics Exam Review Chapters 8 Through 12, 16, 17 and 19
    MICROECONOMICS EXAM REVIEW CHAPTERS 8 THROUGH 12, 16, 17 AND 19 Key Terms and Concepts to Know CHAPTER 8 - PERFECT COMPETITION I. An Introduction to Perfect Competition A. Perfectly Competitive Market Structure: • Has many buyers and sellers. • Sells a commodity or standardized product. • Has buyers and sellers who are fully informed. • Has firms and resources that are freely mobile. • Perfectly competitive firm is a price taker; one firm has no control over price. B. Demand Under Perfect Competition: Horizontal line at the market price II. Short-Run Profit Maximization A. Total Revenue Minus Total Cost: The firm maximizes economic profit by finding the quantity at which total revenue exceeds total cost by the greatest amount. B. Marginal Revenue Equals Marginal Cost in Equilibrium • Marginal Revenue: The change in total revenue from selling another unit of output: • MR = ΔTR/Δq • In perfect competition, marginal revenue equals market price. • Market price = Marginal revenue = Average revenue • The firm increases output as long as marginal revenue exceeds marginal cost. • Golden rule of profit maximization. The firm maximizes profit by producing where marginal cost equals marginal revenue. C. Economic Profit in Short-Run: Because the marginal revenue curve is horizontal at the market price, it is also the firm’s demand curve. The firm can sell any quantity at this price. III. Minimizing Short-Run Losses The short run is defined as a period too short to allow existing firms to leave the industry. The following is a summary of short-run behavior: A. Fixed Costs and Minimizing Losses: If a firm shuts down, it must still pay fixed costs.
    [Show full text]
  • Economics of Competition in the U.S. Livestock Industry Clement E. Ward
    Economics of Competition in the U.S. Livestock Industry Clement E. Ward, Professor Emeritus Department of Agricultural Economics Oklahoma State University January 2010 Paper Background and Objectives Questions of market structure changes, their causes, and impacts for pricing and competition have been focus areas for the author over his entire 35-year career (1974-2009). Pricing and competition are highly emotional issues to many and focusing on factual, objective economic analyses is critical. This paper is the author’s contribution to that effort. The objectives of this paper are to: (1) put meatpacking competition issues in historical perspective, (2) highlight market structure changes in meatpacking, (3) note some key lawsuits and court rulings that contribute to the historical perspective and regulatory environment, and (4) summarize the body of research related to concentration and competition issues. These were the same objectives I stated in a presentation made at a conference in December 2009, The Economics of Structural Change and Competition in the Food System, sponsored by the Farm Foundation and other professional agricultural economics organizations. The basis for my conference presentation and this paper is an article I published, “A Review of Causes for and Consequences of Economic Concentration in the U.S. Meatpacking Industry,” in an online journal, Current Agriculture, Food & Resource Issues in 2002, http://caes.usask.ca/cafri/search/archive/2002-ward3-1.pdf. This paper is an updated, modified version of the review article though the author cannot claim it is an exhaustive, comprehensive review of the relevant literature. Issue Background Nearly 20 years ago, the author ran across a statement which provides a perspective for the issues of concentration, consolidation, pricing, and competition in meatpacking.
    [Show full text]
  • Labor Demand: First Lecture
    Labor Market Equilibrium: Fourth Lecture LABOR ECONOMICS (ECON 385) BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD Extension: the minimum wage revisited •Here we reexamine the effect of the minimum wage in a non-competitive market. Specifically the effect is different if the market is characterized by a monopsony—a single buyer of a good. •Consider the supply curve for a labor market as before. Also consider the downward-sloping VMPL curve that represents the labor demand of a single firm. • But now instead of multiple competitive employers, this market has only a single firm that employs workers. • The effect of this on labor demand for the monopsony firm is that wage is not a constant value set exogenously by the competitive market. The wage now depends directly (and positively) on the amount of labor employed by this firm. , = , where ( ) is the market supply curve facing the monopsonist. Π ∗ − ∗ − Monopsony hiring • And now when the monopsonist considers how much labor to supply, it has to choose a wage that will attract the marginal worker. This wage is determined by the supply curve. • The usual profit maximization condition—with a linear supply curve, for simplicity—yields: = + = 0 Π where the last term in parentheses is the slope ∗ of the −labor supply curve. When it is linear, the slope is constant (b), and the entire set of parentheses contains the marginal cost of hiring labor. The condition, as usual implies that the employer sets marginal benefit ( ) equal to marginal cost; the only difference is that marginal cost is not constant now. Monopsony hiring (continued) •Specifically the marginal cost is a curve lying above the labor supply with twice the slope of the supply curve.
    [Show full text]
  • Application of Game Theory in Swedish Raw Material Market Rami Al-Halabi 2020-06-12
    Application of game theory in Swedish raw material market Rami Al-Halabi 2020-06-12 Application of game theory in Swedish raw material market Investigating the pulpwood market Rami Al-Halabi Dokumenttyp – Självständigt arbete på grundnivå Huvudområde: Industriell organisation och ekonomi GR (C) Högskolepoäng: 15 HP Termin/år: VT2020 Handledare: Soleiman M. Limaei Examinator: Leif Olsson Kurskod/registreringsnummer: IG027G Utbildningsprogram: Civilingenjör, industriell ekonomi i Application of game theory in Swedish raw material market Rami Al-Halabi 2020-06-12 Sammanfattning Studien går ut på att analysera marknadsstrukturen för två industriföretag (Holmen och SCA) under antagandet att båda konkurrerar mot varandra genom att köpa rå material samt genom att sälja förädlade produkter. Produktmarknaden som undersöks är pappersmarknaden och antas vara koncentrerad. Rå materialmarknaden som undersöks är massavedmarknaden och antas karaktäriseras som en duopsony. Det visade sig att Holmen och SCA köper massaved från en stor mängd skogsägare. Varje företag skapar varje månad en prislista där de bestämmer bud priset för massaved. Priset varierar beroende på region. Både SCA och Holmen väljer mellan två strategiska beslut, antigen att buda högt pris eller lågt pris. Genom spelteori så visade det sig att båda industriföretagen använder mixade strategier då de i vissa tillfällen budar högt och i andra tillfällen budar lågt. Nash jämviktslägen för mixade strategier räknades ut matematiskt och analyserades genom dynamisk spelteori. Marknadskoncentrationen för pappersmarknaden undersöktes via Herfindahl-Hirschman index (HHI). Porters femkraftsmodell användes för att analysera industri konkurrensen. Resultatet visade att produktmarknaden är koncentrerad då HHI testerna gav höga indexvärden mellan 3100 och 1700. Det existerade dessutom ett Nash jämviktsläge för mixade strategier som gav SCA förväntad lönsamhet 1651 miljoner kronor och Holmen 1295 miljoner kronor.
    [Show full text]
  • Monopoly Monopoly Causes of Monopolies Profit Maximization
    Monopoly • market with a single seller • Firm demand = market demand Monopoly • Firm demand is downward sloping • Monopolist can alter market price by adjusting its ECON 370: Microeconomic Theory own output level Summer 2004 – Rice University Stanley Gilbert Econ 370 - Monopoly 2 Causes of Monopolies Profit Maximization •Created by law ⇒ US Postal Service • We assume profit maximization • a patent ⇒ a new drug • Earlier we noted – profit maximization • sole ownership of a resource ⇒ a toll highway ⇒ – Marginal Revenue = Marginal Cost • formation of a cartel ⇒ OPEC • With monopolies, that is the relevant test • large economies of scale ⇒ local utility company (natural monopoly) Econ 370 - Monopoly 3 Econ 370 - Monopoly 4 1 Mathematically Significance dp(y) dc(y) p()y + y = π ()y = p ()y y − c ()y dy dy At profit-maximizing output y*: • Since demand is downward sloping: dp/dy < 0 – So a monopoly supplies less than a competitive market dπ ()y d dc(y) would = ()p()y y − = 0 – At a higher price dy dy dy • MR < Price because to sell the next unit of output it has to lower its price on all its product dp()y dc(y) p()y + y = – Not just on the last unit dy dy – Thus further reducing revenue Econ 370 - Monopoly 5 Econ 370 - Monopoly 6 Linear Demand Linear Demand Graph • If demand is q(p) = f – gp • Then the inverse demand function is p – p = f / g – q / g –Let a = f / g, and a –Let b = 1 / g – Then p = a – bq p(y) = a – by • Since output y = demand q, the revenue function is – p(y)·y = (a – by)y = ay – by2 y • Marginal Revenue is a / 2b a / b –MR
    [Show full text]
  • Buyer Power: Is Monopsony the New Monopoly?
    COVER STORIES Antitrust , Vol. 33, No. 2, Spring 2019. © 2019 by the American Bar Association. Reproduced with permission. All rights reserved. This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or stored in an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association. Buyer Power: Is Monopsony the New Monopoly? BY DEBBIE FEINSTEIN AND ALBERT TENG OR A NUMBER OF YEARS, exists—or only when it can also be shown to harm consumer commentators have debated whether the United welfare; (2) historical case law on monopsony; (3) recent States has a monopoly problem. But as part of the cases involving monopsony issues; and (4) counseling con - recent conversation over the direction of antitrust siderations for monopsony issues. It remains to be seen law and the continued appropriateness of the con - whether we will see significantly increased enforcement Fsumer welfare standard, the debate has turned to whether the against buyer-side agreements and mergers that affect buyer antitrust agencies are paying enough attention to monopsony power and whether such enforcement will be successful, but issues. 1 A concept that appears more in textbooks than in case what is clear is that the antitrust enforcement agencies will be law has suddenly become mainstream and practitioners exploring the depth and reach of these theories and clients should be aware of developments when they counsel clients must be prepared for investigations and enforcement actions on issues involving supply-side concerns. implicating these issues. This topic is not going anywhere any time soon.
    [Show full text]
  • Product Differentiation and Economic Progress
    THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF AUSTRIAN ECONOMICS 12, NO. 1 (2009): 17–35 PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION AND ECONOMIC PROGRESS RANDALL G. HOLCOMBE ABSTRACT: In neoclassical theory, product differentiation provides consumers with a variety of different products within a particular industry, rather than a homogeneous product that characterizes purely competitive markets. The welfare-enhancing benefit of product differentiation is the greater variety of products available to consumers, which comes at the cost of a higher average total cost of production. In reality, firms do not differentiate their products to make them different, or to give consumers variety, but to make them better, so consumers would rather buy that firm’s product rather than the product of a competitor. When product differentiation is seen as a strategy to improve products rather than just to make them different, product differentiation emerges as the engine of economic progress. In contrast to the neoclassical framework, where product differentiation imposes a cost on the economy in exchange for more product variety, in real- ity product differentiation lowers costs, creates better products for consumers, and generates economic progress. n the neoclassical theory of the firm, product differentiation enhances consumer welfare by offering consumers greater variety, Ibut that benefit is offset by the higher average cost of production for monopolistically competitive firms. In the neoclassical framework, the only benefit of product differentiation is the greater variety of prod- ucts available, but the reason firms differentiate their products is not just to make them different from the products of other firms, but to make them better. By improving product quality and bringing new Randall G.
    [Show full text]
  • A Primer on Profit Maximization
    Central Washington University ScholarWorks@CWU All Faculty Scholarship for the College of Business College of Business Fall 2011 A Primer on Profit aM ximization Robert Carbaugh Central Washington University, [email protected] Tyler Prante Los Angeles Valley College Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.cwu.edu/cobfac Part of the Economic Theory Commons, and the Higher Education Commons Recommended Citation Carbaugh, Robert and Tyler Prante. (2011). A primer on profit am ximization. Journal for Economic Educators, 11(2), 34-45. This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the College of Business at ScholarWorks@CWU. It has been accepted for inclusion in All Faculty Scholarship for the College of Business by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks@CWU. 34 JOURNAL FOR ECONOMIC EDUCATORS, 11(2), FALL 2011 A PRIMER ON PROFIT MAXIMIZATION Robert Carbaugh1 and Tyler Prante2 Abstract Although textbooks in intermediate microeconomics and managerial economics discuss the first- order condition for profit maximization (marginal revenue equals marginal cost) for pure competition and monopoly, they tend to ignore the second-order condition (marginal cost cuts marginal revenue from below). Mathematical economics textbooks also tend to provide only tangential treatment of the necessary and sufficient conditions for profit maximization. This paper fills the void in the textbook literature by combining mathematical and graphical analysis to more fully explain the profit maximizing hypothesis under a variety of market structures and cost conditions. It is intended to be a useful primer for all students taking intermediate level courses in microeconomics, managerial economics, and mathematical economics. It also will be helpful for students in Master’s and Ph.D.
    [Show full text]
  • Profit Maximization and Cost Minimization ● Average and Marginal Costs
    Theory of the Firm Moshe Ben-Akiva 1.201 / 11.545 / ESD.210 Transportation Systems Analysis: Demand & Economics Fall 2008 Outline ● Basic Concepts ● Production functions ● Profit maximization and cost minimization ● Average and marginal costs 2 Basic Concepts ● Describe behavior of a firm ● Objective: maximize profit max π = R(a ) − C(a ) s.t . a ≥ 0 – R, C, a – revenue, cost, and activities, respectively ● Decisions: amount & price of inputs to buy amount & price of outputs to produce ● Constraints: technology constraints market constraints 3 Production Function ● Technology: method for turning inputs (including raw materials, labor, capital, such as vehicles, drivers, terminals) into outputs (such as trips) ● Production function: description of the technology of the firm. Maximum output produced from given inputs. q = q(X ) – q – vector of outputs – X – vector of inputs (capital, labor, raw material) 4 Using a Production Function ● The production function predicts what resources are needed to provide different levels of output ● Given prices of the inputs, we can find the most efficient (i.e. minimum cost) way to produce a given level of output 5 Isoquant ● For two-input production: Capital (K) q=q(K,L) K’ q3 q2 q1 Labor (L) L’ 6 Production Function: Examples ● Cobb-Douglas : ● Input-Output: = α a b = q x1 x2 q min( ax1 ,bx2 ) x2 x2 Isoquants q2 q2 q1 q1 x1 x1 7 Rate of Technical Substitution (RTS) ● Substitution rates for inputs – Replace a unit of input 1 with RTS units of input 2 keeping the same level of production x2 ∂x ∂q ∂x RTS
    [Show full text]
  • Antoine-Augustine Cournot: His Duopoly Problem with a Re- Appraisal of His Duopoly Price and His Influence Upon Leon Alrw As
    University of Montana ScholarWorks at University of Montana Graduate Student Theses, Dissertations, & Professional Papers Graduate School 1968 Antoine-Augustine Cournot: His duopoly problem with a re- appraisal of his duopoly price and his influence upon Leon alrW as David M. Dodge The University of Montana Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarworks.umt.edu/etd Let us know how access to this document benefits ou.y Recommended Citation Dodge, David M., "Antoine-Augustine Cournot: His duopoly problem with a re-appraisal of his duopoly price and his influence upon Leon alrW as" (1968). Graduate Student Theses, Dissertations, & Professional Papers. 8753. https://scholarworks.umt.edu/etd/8753 This Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the Graduate School at ScholarWorks at University of Montana. It has been accepted for inclusion in Graduate Student Theses, Dissertations, & Professional Papers by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks at University of Montana. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Al'îTCINS-AUGUSTINE COÜRKOTi HIS DUOPOLY PROBLEM ra'IH A RS-APPPAI3AL OF HIS DUOPOLY PRICE AND HIS INFLUENCE UPON LEON WALRAS By David M. Dodge B.A. j, University of Montana, 1968 Presented in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Arts UNIVERSITY OF MONTAÎSA 1968 Approved bys Cî^cii ZTOsn ard of Examiners Air X ] Date Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. UMI Number: EP39554 All rights reserved INFORMATION TO ALL USERS The quality of this reproduction is dependent upon the quality of the copy submitted. In the unlikely event that the author did not send a complete manuscript and there are missing pages, these will be noted.
    [Show full text]
  • Intermediate Microeconomics
    Intermediate Microeconomics IMPERFECT COMPETITION BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD PURDUE UNIVERSITY No, not the BCS Oligopoly: A market with few firms but more than one. Duopoly: A market with two firms. Cartel: Several firms collectively acting like a monopolist by charging a common price and dividing the monopoly profit among them. Imperfect Competition: A market in which firms compete but do not erode all profits. Perfect competition with only 2 firms Assume the following model: ◦ 2 firms that produce the same good (call the firms “Kemp’s Milk” and “Dean’s Milk”). ◦ They both have the same marginal cost (c), and it is constant (so constant AC, too). ◦ The Demand for their good is downward-sloping, but does not have to have a particular shape. ◦ The firms simultaneously choose their prices ( and ). ◦ The firm with the lower price captures the whole market, and the other firm gets nothing. ◦ If both firms set the same price, they split the market demand evenly. Bertrand competition The profit for each firm is given by: = , [ ] and = ( , )[ ]. Π − This model is calledΠ the Bertrand model− of Duopoly—after 19th Century economist, Joseph Louis Francois Bertrand. To find the equilibrium, however, we’re not going to use calculus—just reason. Equilibrium in the Bertrand model Say that you’re Kemp’s dairy. If Dean’s is charging any price that is greater than your own c, then you can choose from among three intervals for your own price: > , = , < . If you go with the first one, ≤ you get no sales because Dean’s undercut your price. If you go with the second one, you get: 1 , .
    [Show full text]
  • Monopsony Power, Pay Structure and Training
    IZA DP No. 5587 Monopsony Power, Pay Structure and Training Samuel Muehlemann Paul Ryan Stefan C. Wolter March 2011 DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor Monopsony Power, Pay Structure and Training Samuel Muehlemann University of Bern and IZA Paul Ryan King’s College Cambridge Stefan C. Wolter University of Bern, CESifo and IZA Discussion Paper No. 5587 March 2011 IZA P.O. Box 7240 53072 Bonn Germany Phone: +49-228-3894-0 Fax: +49-228-3894-180 E-mail: [email protected] Any opinions expressed here are those of the author(s) and not those of IZA. Research published in this series may include views on policy, but the institute itself takes no institutional policy positions. The Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) in Bonn is a local and virtual international research center and a place of communication between science, politics and business. IZA is an independent nonprofit organization supported by Deutsche Post Foundation. The center is associated with the University of Bonn and offers a stimulating research environment through its international network, workshops and conferences, data service, project support, research visits and doctoral program. IZA engages in (i) original and internationally competitive research in all fields of labor economics, (ii) development of policy concepts, and (iii) dissemination of research results and concepts to the interested public. IZA Discussion Papers often represent preliminary work and are circulated to encourage discussion. Citation of such a paper should account for its provisional character. A revised version may be available directly from the author.
    [Show full text]