The Gold Standard, Bretton Woods, and Other Monetary Policy Regimes

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Gold Standard, Bretton Woods, and Other Monetary Policy Regimes 192 Manfred J. M. Neumann Manfred J. M. Neumann is the director of the Institute tor Inter- national Economics and a professor ot economics at the University of Bonn, I Commentary MICHAEL BORDC) PROVIDES US with a WHICH REGIME PERFORMED comprehensive, scholarly study of the history of BEST? the three main international monetary regimes: the gold standard, the dollar standard, and the It is natural to evaluate the welfare implica- floating exchange rate. lie focuses on two tions of monetary regimes by asking what important questions. First, which regime provided different regimes achieve with respect to the the best performance with regard to the levels level and stability of inflation and real growth. of inflation and real growth? Second, what Any monetary regime can be described as a makes an international monetary regime viable? mechanism or device that delivers an average rate of monetary expansion and a variance of Because I am not a historian, I will limit my money growth. With respect to economic per- comments to two areas, I will first discuss the formance, the essential difference is whether a comparative evidence on the performance of particular m-egime pr’ovides governments with the three monetary regimes and use Bordo’s more or less freedom to manipulate the aver- statistics to infer a little more information on age rate of and the variance of monetat-y expan- the role of demand shocks under the different sion. It follows that regime differences should regimes. Thereafter I will concentrate on the be reflected in inflation levels and variances of important issue of determining a monetary inflation and per capita growth. system’s credibility. I find Bordo’s thoughtful Table I draws from Bot-do’s tables I and 4. 1 discussion of the issue useful. I should add, consider the Group of Seven countries as a however, that sometnnes he takes the literatui-e whole, the United States, Germany and Fi-ance too seriously—especially the affirmative litera- and concentrate on the three major periods: the ture on the European Monetary System (EMS). pre-World War I gold standard, the Bret ton \‘evertheless, Bordo forces us to consider which Woods system of the 1950s and 1960s, and the monetary system or standard, if any, can solve floating exchange rate in place since the the credibility problem in terms of firml inid~197Os.’Note that, in contrast to Bordo, 1 do anchoring market expectations about its not separate out the favorable performance of viability. the Bretton Woods convertible subperiod ‘The Group of Seven countries are Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, the United Kingdom and the United States. FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST, LOUIS 193 / fl__ ~ / ~ _/ -I ~r _, /_ ~-~-c — ~:- / ~-~c ~~ ~ ~_-t~ ,___ ~ ~ ~ - w~ ~ v~~Asc/ / ~~ ~ A ~rir4~ ~ ~‘ / ~ ~ ~ / c’~ ~ ‘A ~~\\ N~ ~tr~: —~r~-Jra -~ t~- -- - * ~ - —— -::~~---~~-‘ \t~ ~ - ~~~~/~\_ ~~ ~ rj~t;/~ ~ ~‘t~1~r~tç~ ~t~c~:4;~ ~ / ~ ~ :~~ ~ N ~ ~- V~ ~ S~A*~~ ~ ~ t~a~:c~~~~ p ~ ~s~/ ~ ~‘ \ ~___-c_ , c~~ ~ ~ -,~-- ~ r’-~-~-°~~ 4 ~ ~ ‘~ -7 / /~ -~ ~-\ 4 ~- ~~ ~ \ ~,, ~ / \\~‘~~ ~ ~-/ \-t- a>/ ~ //1-~ ~ ~ — ~ \ ~ ~:~-s-~> - ~ac~~_s~~s~:/~ / /~t~sJ~-~ \ \ t- 4 - ~~~~~ ; -~--~ $-/\ :~- ~tt-’ ~ c~r~ \ç/~ ~ ~ - ~s~iie~ ~: : ~ c:~ ~ - ~ ~H: ~1 t~- c~ ~\/Y\~ a-~ ~ \~C ~- ~~ ~ ‘7 i-.~ 7 7 ~//p tc ,~/ ~ 7~-/’~~’ ~ — -,,~ / ~, f 7 7 - / -, - ‘7 4 ~7’ 7/ :4-- - — - ‘7 -‘7”-? -- - /7- / ‘7 \- ‘7 /-//~/,/ ~ ‘7 ‘7’- “7?“ 4, -~ -~ - - ‘7 - ‘-~ ,,7”’7 -‘ --i’~~~ ‘7~ ~r —~ ~ ~ >-~- ‘ ~-~“ ‘‘-‘77/- (1 959-197(J) in terms of inflation and output. • Third, the Bretton Woods regime exhibited The subperiod looked good on the surface; how- the highest variability of inflation, whereas ever, it was in fact the period when the break- output variability was closer to its level down of Bretton Woods was programmed. More under the float than under the gold generally speaking, for- ant’ i-egime we nught standard. find ey post a good looking suhperiod.2 The first observation on average inflation per- As Bordo and others have pointed out, the formance is well known and understood. It is data permit the following observations: widely accepted that the classical gold standard • First, average inflation was negligible under prevented the manipulation of monetary expan- the gold standard and highest under the sion by enforcing a direct link between the base floating exchange rate. money stock, the national stock of gold and the balance of payments. Though devaluation was • Second, the variabihtv of inflation, as possible by raising the gold parity in national well as that of real growth, was higher currency, it was rare. Thus the gold standard dcliv- under the gold standard than under the wed the lowest average rate of inflation, given that floating exchange i-ate. the available gold stock did not grow much. 2As Anna Schwartz pointed out in the discussion, an evalu- when the EMS came close to collapse, would be seriously ation of the EMS that bypasses the most recent period, misleading. MARCH/APRIL 1993 194 member country of the European snake or EMS. At the other extreme, fiat money cum floating does not put any external constraint on domes- Checking the empirical validity of these con- tic money production. ‘I’hus governments are jectures requires estimating the variance of ft-ce to use money production to collect inflation nominal demand shocks. Bordo’s study pi-ovides tax and to dampen the business cycle. The addi- us with some valuable information in this nonal advantage to governments of the floating respect. Following Blanchard and Quah (19891 exchange rate is that the regime spares them and liavoumi and Eichengr-een (I 99Z) in particu- the political cost of negotiating devaluation. In lar, he has estimated for each country andl each sum, the floating exchange rate is the monetary monetary regime a bivariate vector autoregres- regime most conducive to inflationary policies. sion (VAR) for the rates of change of the price Finally, the I3retton Woods system was in level and output. The lower panel of table I between the gold standat-d and the floating provides the variances of the estimated aggregate exchange rate in that it started as a gold supply and demand shocks? Under the straight- exchange standard but was permitted to forward assumption that the distribution of real degenerate into a pure fiat money standard (the demand shocks was the same over the different dollat- standardl dut-ing the early 1960s when monetary regimes, differences in demand shock the United States gold stock fell short of the variability can he attributed to the operational value of outstanding dollar liabilities. differences of the regimes. More interesting than the average inflation The empirical findings are mixed. The data performance is the observed difference in the reject our I’irst conjecture. For the Group of volatility of inflation and output growth among Seven countries demand shock variability was regimes. But to what extent can this volatility he highest under the gold standard and lowest attributed to the operation of the different under the potentially permissive floating exchange monetary systems? rate regime. The most puzzling aspect is the high demand variability during the gold stand- EXPLORING THE ROLE OF ard period because not only was monetary pol- icy discretion constrained by the rules of the DEMAND SHOCKS regime, but also fiscal discretion was negligible, Apart from determining the level of inflation, at least by today’s standards. monetary regimes differ with respect to nomi- Our second conjecture, in contrast, is con- nal demand shock variability. I propose the firmed. Demand shock vai-iability was lowest in following conjectures. the United States during the Bretton Woods First, nominal demand shock variability is period and in Germany during the float. More- highest under the floating exchange rate and over, it can be shown for Germany using an lowest under the gold standard. This reflects F-test that the demand shock variance of the the diffeiences in the limits to monetary discre- float differed significantly from its value under tion. Because the degree of monetary discretion Bretton Woods at the 1 percent level of sig- is close to zero under the gold standard and nificance. In the United States the level of unlimited under the floating exchange rate, we significance was 10 percent. should observe that the variance of inflation Though we have not seen any test statistics of was caused predominantly by nominal demand Bordo’s VAR estimates, let us assume that the shocks under the floating exchange rate but by estimates are clean. On this assumption we may supply shocks under the gold standard. use them to investigate the contribution of the aggregate demand shocks to the variability of Second, in a fixed-exchange rate system the inflation and output growth under the different system leader sets the floor for nominal demand monetary regimes. To do so requires a model of shock variability. Consequently, for the Bretton aggregate supply and demand to determine the Woods period we should observe that nominal unknown price elasticities of aggregate demand demand shock variability was lowest in the and supply. United States. Similarly, during the floating rate period nominal demand shock variability should Table 2 provides the bare bones of such a have been lower in Germany than in any other model. The model is written in logs and has a 3 See Bordo’s table 4. FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS 195 - - ?~~1-‘7~’7o47//<~~~~C <~~J1~,’ ‘7-?-. ‘-4~’71-~ ~ ‘7s~’74 ~ -~ -~‘--41 , 47/-/’~— ‘7/ ft ~ ~ ~: // “7.‘7”t ‘7’7”-’7t’71~‘~ ‘~ —‘7 —--- — : ,- -. ,, ‘1, ~Gs4’S*M4$P*— titslSo4i/ ‘7 ‘ 4 ‘7 ‘72-2— _ a4,~14~ <‘g’ ~a rn.~~4’ :‘7 “-‘7 t~~’I A4ii~Is$~sS 4fl ‘7’ ~‘~“ ~ ~— ,~r ~“7‘ 4 ~ ‘---,~/-C-’7’ 4/___ ~ - --‘7/--?-, — / / ~7/~~-~ ~/4/~/_ ~ / -/ “7 a’,-, / 4’ 4 — ‘7 / ‘7<’ ‘7< —a - <-‘7--’7 <‘7 ?~ - ,~.
Recommended publications
  • The Gold Standard and the Great Depression: a Dynamic General Equilibrium Model
    The Gold Standard and the Great Depression: a Dynamic General Equilibrium Model L. Pensieroso and R. Restout Discussion Paper 2018-16 The Gold Standard and the Great Depression: a Dynamic General Equilibrium Model⇤ Luca Pensieroso† Romain Restout‡ December 3, 2018 Abstract Was the Gold Standard a major determinant of the onset and the protracted character of the the Great Depression of the 1930s in the United States and Worldwide? In this paper, we model the ‘Gold- Standard hypothesis’ in a dynamic general equilibrium framework. We show that encompassing the international and monetary dimen- sions of the Great Depression is important to understand what hap- pened in the 1930s, especially outside the United States. Contrary to what is often maintained in the literature, our results suggest that the vague of successive nominal exchange rate devaluations coupled with the monetary policy implemented in the United States did not act as a relief. On the contrary, they made the Depression worse. Keywords: Gold Standard, Great Depression, Dynamic General Equi- librium JEL Classification: N10, E13, N01 ⇤Paper presented at the EEA 2017 meeting in Lisbon, at the CEF 2017 conference in New York, at the ASSET 2016 conference in Thessaloniki, at the Workshop in Macroeconomics on the occasion of the Honorary Doctorate awarded to Olivier Blanchard in Ghent in 2017 and at the 2015 Macro-Dynamics Workshop in Bilbao. We thank participants to these meetings, as well as participants to seminars at the Universities of Louvain and Strasbourg for their feedback. Charlotte de Montpellier and Giulio Nicoletti made interesting remarks on an earlier version.
    [Show full text]
  • The Swiss Economy During the Great Depression
    Gold Standard, Deflation and Depression: The Swiss Economy during the Great Depression Mathias Zurlinden Research, Swiss National Bank SNB 86 Quarterly Bulletin 2/2003 The Great Depression of the 1930s was the most Today, it is generally agreed that there was no serious economic crisis of the 20th century. The USA single cause for the Great Depression. The stock mar- and Germany were the two epicentres, but no country ket crash, bank failures, and growing trade protec- integrated into the global economy was spared. In tionism all played a role. However, monetary factors Switzerland, industrial production fell by 20% – most notably the role of the international gold between 1929 and 1932 and, other than in 1937 and standard – were of particular importance. The fixed 1939, remained below the 1929 level until the end of exchange rates of the gold standard transmitted the decade (and, indeed, the end of World War II). It deflation around the world. And by sticking to the is not surprising, therefore, that people have worried gold standard, central banks allowed a relatively nor- ever since about the possibility of the Great Depres- mal recession to turn into a full-scale depression. sion being repeated. Although Cassel (1936) and Hawtrey (1939) had The international economy of the interwar period expressed similar views in the 1930s, this interna- was shaped by developments in the USA, Germany, tional monetary view of the Great Depression has the UK and France. Hence, most of the literature on found general acceptance only in the last two the Great Depression focuses on these four countries decades.
    [Show full text]
  • The Great Depression: an Overview by David C
    Introduction The Great Depression: An Overview by David C. Wheelock Why should students learn about the Great Depression? Our grandparents and great-grandparents lived through these tough times, but you may think that you should focus on more recent episodes in Ameri- can life. In this essay, I hope to convince you that the Great Depression is worthy of your interest and deserves attention in economics, social studies and history courses. One reason to study the Great Depression is that it was by far the worst economic catastrophe of the 20th century and, perhaps, the worst in our nation’s history. Between 1929 and 1933, the quantity of goods and services produced in the United States fell by one-third, the unemployment rate soared to 25 percent of the labor force, the stock market lost 80 percent of its value and some 7,000 banks failed. At the store, the price of chicken fell from 38 cents a pound to 12 cents, the price of eggs dropped from 50 cents a dozen to just over 13 cents, and the price of gasoline fell from 10 cents a gallon to less than a nickel. Still, many families went hungry, and few could afford to own a car. Another reason to study the Great Depression is that the sheer magnitude of the economic collapse— and the fact that it involved every aspect of our economy and every region of our country—makes this event a great vehicle for teaching important economic concepts. You can learn about inflation and defla- tion, Gross Domestic Product (GDP), and unemployment by comparing the Depression with more recent experiences.
    [Show full text]
  • Stability Under the Gold Standard in Practice
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Money, History, and International Finance: Essays in Honor of Anna J. Schwartz Volume Author/Editor: Michael D. Bordo, editor Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-06593-6 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/bord89-1 Conference Date: October 6, 1987 Publication Date: 1989 Chapter Title: Stability Under the Gold Standard in Practice Chapter Author: Allan Meltzer, Saranna Robinson Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c6739 Chapter pages in book: (p. 163 - 202) 4 Stability Under the Gold Standard in Practice Allan H. Meltzer and Saranna Robinson During her active career as a monetary economist and historian, Anna Schwartz returned to the history of monetary standards many times. In the famed A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960 (Friedman and Schwartz 1963), in her work as executive director of the 1981-82 U.S. Gold Commission (Commission on the Role of Gold in the Domestic and International Monetary Systems 1982), in her introduction to the National Bureau volume A Retrospective on the Classical Gold Standard, 1821-1931 (Bordo and Schwartz 1984), and in books and papers on British and U.S. monetary history before and after these volumes, she has both summarized past knowledge with careful attention to detail and added important pieces to our under- standing of the way monetary systems work in practice. One issue to which she and others have returned many times is the relative welfare gain or loss under alternative standards.
    [Show full text]
  • From Bimetallism to Monetarism: the Shifting Political Affiliation of the Quantity Theory*
    From Bimetallism to Monetarism: the Shifting Political Affiliation of the Quantity Theory* by David Laidler Abstract: The quantity theory of money was associated with the politics of the right in the ‘70s and ‘80s, but a century earlier, particularly in America, it had played an important part in the proposals of the Progressive left. These political associations are examined, and it is argued that a crucial factor in the quantity theory’s apparent migration from left to right was its newly-forged links to the case for monetary policy rules in the interwar years. It was also in the 1930s that the endogenous-money Banking School doctrines deployed by anti-quantity theorists during the monetarist controversy first became mainly associated with the case for discretionary policy, rather than with support for the gold- standard rule, as they had been in earlier times. More generally, shifting scientific opinion about the causes of the Great Depression moved the political centre of gravity of monetary economics to the left from the 1930s onwards, and then back towards the right beginning in the ‘60s, creating an illusion of movement on the quantity theory’s part. ___________________________ *The opening lecture delivered at the 2001 conference of the European History of Economic Thought Society, on “The Influence of Politics on Economic Thought”, held at the Technical University of Darmstadt. This lecture had its origins in an email correspondence with Robert Leeson about post-war Chicago economics, and why the quantity theory should be regarded as a right-wing doctrine. I am grateful to him for the intellectual stimulation, and to Perry Mehrling, Bill Robson, Rick Szostak and Michael Trautwein made many useful comments on an earlier draft.
    [Show full text]
  • Blast from the Past: Hayek, Gold, and Money
    Blast from the Past: Hayek, Gold, and Money Nikhil Sridhar Richard Salsman, Faculty Advisor 1 Acknowledgements I would like to thank Professor Richard Salsman for his invaluable guidance in the writing of this paper and his incredible mentorship throughout my undergraduate career. I would also like to express my gratitude George Selgin of the Cato Institute’s Center for Monetary and Financial Alternatives for recommending many of the sources used in this paper. Finally, there is little chance that this paper would have been completed without the endless debates on monetary economics with my dear friends Gaurav Sharma, Alexander Frumkin, and Aditya Paruchuri. 2 Abstract The resurgence of Austrian economics and the development of market monetarism as a school of thought since the Global Financial Crisis has brought NGDP targeting into the mainstream political economic discourse. This paper will discuss a close cousin of nominal income targeting, Hayek’s rule for monetary policy, and explore its relationship with the classical gold standard, as many advocates of a stable nominal income pathway have also expressed support for some form of a gold standard in the past. This paper offers a theoretical and historical exposition of Hayek’s rule and the classical gold standard before offering a comparative institutional analysis of these two monetary regimes with special consideration given to political economic considerations. 3 Table of Contents Introduction ....................................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • The Gold Standard, Deflation and Fascism in Polanyi's Great
    The gold standard, deflation and fascism in Polanyi’s Great Transformation. A multidisciplinary analysis ERNESTO CLAR Introduction In 1944 Karl Polanyi published a work that would become a milestone in 20th-century social science, The Great Transformation. He was among the first to explain the economic and political catastrophe of the inter-war period as the final stage of a long-term process that reigned in Western Europe (and the United States) in the wake of the Napoleonic wars, market liberalism. Polanyi considered those ‘one hundred years’ to be a coherent period covering the rise and fall of 19th-century civilization. Polanyi characterized the 19th-century civilization that was destined to die with the Great Depression of the 20th century by four institutions: the balance-of-power system, the gold standard, the self-regulating market and the liberal state. Of these institutions, Polanyi asserts that the gold standard was the only one to survive both the Long Depression (previously known as the Great Depression) of 1873-1886 and the Great War. However, its ultimate failure delivered the death blow for market liberalism and, in some places, also swept liberal democracy away with it. The final part of Polanyi’s book gives a historical account of this process. However, early on in the book, Polanyi warns us that he is not conducting historical research: «what we are searching for is not a convincing sequence of outstanding events, but an explanation of their trend in terms of human institutions»1. This statement should be understood as a declaration of intent; Polanyi’s analysis was not limited to a single subject, such as history or economics, and he made this very clear by saying «we shall encroach upon the field of several disciplines in the pursuit of a single aim»2.
    [Show full text]
  • The Gold Standard Loses Luster
    The Gold Standard Loses Luster KEY POINTS The gold standard eliminated the need for a discretionary central bank to control the money supply. Even so, central banks were known to work around the “rules” of the gold standard according to their needs, and in the process undermined the standard’s credibility. The gold standard proved too inflexible during the crisis conditions that prevailed during World War I and the Great Depression. It was abandoned in stages around the globe thereafter, setting the stage for a new era in central banking. When Congress established the Federal Reserve Gold’s Heyday System in 1913, the concept of monetary policy as we understand it today did not exist. Here is how the gold standard is supposed to work: Governments define their currencies in terms of gold, Instead of central bankers actively influencing the level agree to freely exchange their currencies for gold at that of bank reserves in pursuit of low inflation and full official price, and allow the unfettered import and export employment, the job of keeping the money supply in of gold. Countries’ official gold prices then establish balance was left to the gold standard, a time-tested fixed exchange-rate parities among national currencies. system. Money backed by commodities, including gold, When, for example, Britain set an ounce of gold equal had been the norm for millennia. Between 1870 and to £4.24, and the United States fixed it equal to $20.67, 1914, in fact, most of the world, including the United they automatically established an exchange-rate parity States, was on a gold standard.
    [Show full text]
  • The Gold Standard: the Traditional Approach
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: A Retrospective on the Classical Gold Standard, 1821-1931 Volume Author/Editor: Michael D. Bordo and Anna J. Schwartz, editors Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-06590-1 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/bord84-1 Publication Date: 1984 Chapter Title: The Gold Standard: The Traditional Approach Chapter Author: Michael D. Bordo Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c11126 Chapter pages in book: (p. 23 - 120) 1 The Gold Standard: The Traditional Approach Michael D. Bordo 1.1 Introduction What was the traditional approach to the gold standard? In this paper, I try to provide an answer to the question by examining the works of major writers on the subject since the eighteenth century. 1 The choice of writers and works surveyed is based on my judgment that the works encompassed a significant share ofthe content ofthe traditional approach and that the writers played a significant role in the history of economic thought. Six major themes formed the traditional approach, and five major schools of thought may be identified. 1.2 Major Themes in the Literature The first theme, which runs from Cantillon to present-day writers, was that gold (the precious metals) was an ideal monetary standard, domesti­ cally and internationally, because of its unique qualities both as a stan­ dard of value and a medium of exchange. A stable price level in the long run that an automatically operated gold standard produced, in line with the commodity theory of money, was invariably contrasted to the evils of inconvertible fiduciary money.
    [Show full text]
  • The Gold Standard and the Transmission of Business Cycles, 1833-1932" (1984)
    Economics Presentations, Posters and Proceedings Economics 1984 The Gold tS andard and the Transmission of Business Cycles, 1833-1932 Wallace E. Huffman Iowa State University, [email protected] James R. Lothian Citicorp Investment Bank Follow this and additional works at: http://lib.dr.iastate.edu/econ_las_conf Part of the Economic History Commons, Economic Theory Commons, International Business Commons, and the International Economics Commons Recommended Citation Huffman, Wallace E. and Lothian, James R., "The Gold Standard and the Transmission of Business Cycles, 1833-1932" (1984). Economics Presentations, Posters and Proceedings. 23. http://lib.dr.iastate.edu/econ_las_conf/23 This Conference Proceeding is brought to you for free and open access by the Economics at Iowa State University Digital Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Economics Presentations, Posters and Proceedings by an authorized administrator of Iowa State University Digital Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: A Retrospective on the Classical Gold Standard, 1821-1931 Volume Author/Editor: Michael D. Bordo and Anna J. Schwartz, editors Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-06590-1 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/bord84-1 Publication Date: 1984 Chapter Title: The Gold Standard and the Transmission of Business Cycles, 1833-1932 Chapter Author: Wallace E. Huffman, James R. Lothian Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c11135 Chapter pages in book: (p. 455 - 512) 10 The Gold Standard and the Transmission of Business Cycles, 1833-1932 Wallace E.
    [Show full text]
  • Keynes and the Dollar in 1933
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES KEYNES AND THE DOLLAR IN 1933 Sebastian Edwards Working Paper 23141 http://www.nber.org/papers/w23141 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 February 2017 I thank Michael Poyker for his assistance. I have benefitted from conversations with Michael Bordo and Ed Leamer. The views expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2017 by Sebastian Edwards. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Keynes and the Dollar in 1933 Sebastian Edwards NBER Working Paper No. 23141 February 2017 JEL No. B22,B26,B3,E31,E5,F31,N22 ABSTRACT On December 1933, John Maynard Keyes published an open letter to President Roosevelt, where he wrote: “The recent gyrations of the dollar have looked to me more like a gold standard on the booze than the ideal managed currency of my dreams.” In this paper I use high frequency data to investigate whether the gyrations of the dollar were unusually high throughout this period. My results show that although volatility was pronounced, it was not higher than during October 1931- July 1933. I analyze Keynes writings on the international monetary system in an effort to understand what he meant in his letter.
    [Show full text]
  • An Anchor of Gold
    FEDERALRESERVE An Anchor of Gold BY STEPHEN SLIVINSKI ome modern critics of the That doesn’t mean that prices How the gold Federal Reserve suggest that it wouldn’t change under a gold stan- Scould be eliminated and replaced dard. In practice, the price level of standard works in with a gold standard. They claim that nations would tend to move in tandem monetary policymakers are apt to under this arrangement. The mecha- theory and practice bend under pressure to inflate the nism that drives the movement in the currency. A gold standard, on the price level is the balance of payments other hand, can serve as an anchor for that results from trade between the currency that puts a limit on the nations. For example, assume that a growth rate of the money supply. technological innovation increases There are benefits to a gold stan- economic growth in the United States. dard, but there are costs too. The Since the supply of gold, and therefore history of the gold standard provides the money stock, is fixed, prices in the important context for the suggestion United States will fall since it is cheap- that the United States should return er to produce goods domestically as a to a commodity-backed monetary result of the innovation. Prices of U.S. system — gold historically being exports to other countries would fall the most commonly used commodity. too. That leads to lower demand for Additionally, policymakers and the U.S. imports — which are now rela- public could benefit from a greater tively more expensive — and increased understanding of how the gold stan- demand for U.S.
    [Show full text]