Wyatt Wells RHETORIC of the STANDARDS: the DEBATE OVER GOLD and SILVER in the 1890S

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Wyatt Wells RHETORIC of the STANDARDS: the DEBATE OVER GOLD and SILVER in the 1890S The Journal of the Gilded Age and Progressive Era 14 (2015), 49–68 doi:10.1017/S153778141400053X Wyatt Wells RHETORIC OF THE STANDARDS: THE DEBATE OVER GOLD AND SILVER IN THE 1890S Abstract In the 1890s, questions about whether to base the American currency upon gold or silver dominated public discourse and eventually forced a realignment of the political parties. The matter often con- fuses modern observers, who have trouble understanding how such a technically complex—even arcane—issue could arouse such passions. The fact that no major nation currently backs its curren- cy with precious metal creates the suspicion that the issue was a “red herring” that distracted from matters of far greater importance. Yet the rhetoric surrounding the “Battle of the Standards” indi- cates that the more sophisticated advocates of both sides understood that, in the financial context of the 1890s, the contest between gold and silver not only had important economic implications but would substantially affect the future development of the United States. In the 1890s, the Battle of the Standards convulsed American politics. One of the chief combatants, William Jennings Bryan, wrote, “Business partnerships were dissolved on account of political differences; bosom friends became estranged; families were divided—in fact we witnessed such activity of mind and stirring of heart as this nation has not witnessed before for thirty years.”1 At the heart of this bitter conflict was a tech- nical, even arcane financial question: should the United States maintain the gold standard or go to “free silver” at sixteen-to-one, in effect adopting a silver standard? From later perspectives, the focus on such a narrow issue seems strange, and some dismiss it alto- gether. Historian Lawrence Goodwyn describes the Battle of the Standards as a “triumph of form over substance.”2 Yet hindsight is not infallible. The people of the day considered the issue central, and in many cases, their concerns still resonate. THE FINANCIAL CONTEXT Under the gold standard, the United States redeemed dollars on demand, in gold, at the rate of $20.64 to the ounce. Americans thereby anchored their currency to those of other gold standard countries—France; Germany; and most important, Britain—which were their chief trading partners and a major source of investment capital.3 To maintain the gold standard, however, the United States pursued a restrictive monetary policy that forced prices down. Between 1873 and 1896, prices fell by roughly one-third. This decline particularly hurt farmers, who were often in debt and saw the prices of their Wyatt Wells, Auburn University at Montgomery; email: [email protected] © Society for Historians of the Gilded Age and Progressive Era 50 Wells crops sink even more than average—in the case of the most important crops, cotton and wheat, by 50 percent. Persistent deflation kept the currency issue at the forefront of pol- itics. Initially, inflationists focused on greenbacks, the paper currency issued during the Civil War.4 Yet the discovery of huge deposits of silver in the American West made it an increasingly attractive vehicle for inflation. By the 1880s, those squeezed by falling prices were demanding the “free coinage” of silver at $1.29 an ounce. Because the market price of silver was well below $1.29, free coinage would almost certainly lead to a substantial increase in the money supply, inflation, and devaluation. The results would probably help farmers but might well disrupt international trade and investment.5 The currency issue cut across party lines. Democrats from the South and Republicans from the Great Plains, who represented cotton and wheat farmers, respectively, were amenable to inflation. Democrats from New York and Republicans from Massachusetts, centers of commerce and industry, preferred gold. An all-out fight over the currency threatened to splinter both parties, giving political leaders a strong incentive to compro- mise. In the late 1870s, the government forged a workable accommodation between gold and silver. In 1879, the United States adopted the gold standard, replacing the paper cur- rency forced upon it by the Civil War; but at the same time, it began to coin a limited but significant amount of silver.6 This policy expanded the money supply, even as buoyant growth and a substantial federal budget surplus allowed the government to keep silver money at par with gold. This compromise failed to mollify the most committed partisans of either metal, popularly known as silverites and goldbugs, but most Americans seemed satisfied with it as long as the compromise worked financially, which it did for almost a decade. This equilibrium began to unravel in the late 1880s when, after several years of rel- ative stability, farm prices began falling again, generating new calls for inflation. Deflation encouraged the rise of the Farmers’ Alliance and the People’s Party (the Pop- ulists)—both of which challenged the existing political structure. Once again, politi- cians devised a compromise, having the government purchase all the silver mined in the United States with Treasury Bills that it promised to redeem, on demand, in gold. This expedient collapsed in 1893. A devastating financial crisis and an alarming drop in the U.S. government’s gold reserve convinced President Grover Cleveland that compromise was no longer realistic, and he rammed through Congress legislation ending the purchase of silver. Victory came at a high price, however. The president’s policy alienated much of his own Democratic Party, and he had to rely on Republicans to get his measure through the Senate. Cleveland believed that the affirmation of the gold standard would dispel the financial panic, but instead depression settled on the country, lasting into 1897.7 Between them, the bitter debate over silver coinage in 1893 and the Depression destroyed the middle ground and inaugurated the Battle of the Standards, which dominated national politics through the 1896 presidential elec- tion, when Republican William McKinley’s victory over Democrat William Jennings Bryan settled the matter in favor of gold. Yet the question remains: why did free silver and the gold standard arouse such pas- sions? As William Dillon, a prominent Chicago journalist and lawyer, put it, “This is a question of enormous complexity about which men of the highest capacity, who have made a special study of the subject, are still at variance. But to read the gold papers in the country one would conclude that no man who was not a born idiot could see any Rhetoric of the Standards 51 merit on the silver side. And to read the silver papers one would suppose that no man not fit subject for the penitentiary could advocate the single gold standard.”8 THE CRIME OF ‘ 73 According to silverites, the course of American history pivoted on events in 1873. As they saw it, silver coinage constituted part of the fabric of the American Republic. In 1792, at the urging of Alexander Hamilton, Congress authorized the free coinage of both gold and silver. As Senator John Daniel (D-VA) insisted, “The great men who framed our institutions were bimetallists. Our system was designed by Hamilton and Jefferson and approved by Washington; and it existed, flourished, and fulfilled its func- tion from 1793 to 1873 … We flourished as no one nation has ever flourished since time began.”9 Even the Civil War could not permanently halt the country’sprogress.After that conflict, as one silverite wrote, “hope sang is the hearts of America’smillions;the nation, despite the terrible ravages of the late war, was springing in unparalleled prosperity.” The reason was simple: “Money was plentiful.” Unfortunately, “there were … two classes disturbed over the prosperity of the people. One was England’s capitalists, and the other was the usurer class in our country—the drones in the hive of civilization.”10 In 1873, Congress demonetized silver. An otherwise routine piece of legislation stan- dardizing the coinage dropped the silver dollar from the list of authorized coins. Because this coin was the only silver money subject to free coinage, the omission effectively left gold as the sole basis for the currency. At the time, few commented on the measure, and many then in Congress would later insist that they did not recall the bill. The record clearly shows that the measure went through the usual procedures and that some senators and congressmen did discuss it, but most lawmakers probably paid little attention to what was apparently a technical measure without policy implications.11 The country was still on a paper standard—neither silver nor gold coins circulated in the normal course of busi- ness.12 Given the many issues competing for the attention of legislators, it is easy to imagine that few studied the bill carefully. Silverites considered this measure an epic piece of deceit. In Seven Financial Conspir- acies Which Have Enslaved the American People, one of the seminal texts of the Populist movement, Sarah Emery claimed, “In 1872, silver being demonetized in France, England, and Holland, a capital of $500,000 was raised, and Ernest Seyd of London was sent to this country with the fund, as agent of the foreign bond holders and capitalists, to effect the same object (demonetization of silver), which was accomplished.”13 Al- though few other silverites were as specific as Emery, a large portion of them saw the 1873 act as the product of conspiracy. A report issued in 1890 by silverite members of the House of Representatives asserted, “The conspiracy formed in the Old World, planned and so successfully carried through there and here, was aimed to confine the debt-paying medium of the nations concerned to the single metal, gold … Gold decreed to rapidly rise in value, thus adding fifty percent to the value of credits, enriching creditors, public and private, at the expense of debtors and taxpayers.”14 This was the “Crime of ‘73.” The results were disastrous.
Recommended publications
  • A Model of Bimetallism
    Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department A Model of Bimetallism François R. Velde and Warren E. Weber Working Paper 588 August 1998 ABSTRACT Bimetallism has been the subject of considerable debate: Was it a viable monetary system? Was it a de- sirable system? In our model, the (exogenous and stochastic) amount of each metal can be split between monetary uses to satisfy a cash-in-advance constraint, and nonmonetary uses in which the stock of un- coined metal yields utility. The ratio of the monies in the cash-in-advance constraint is endogenous. Bi- metallism is feasible: we find a continuum of steady states (in the certainty case) indexed by the constant exchange rate of the monies; we also prove existence for a range of fixed exchange rates in the stochastic version. Bimetallism does not appear desirable on a welfare basis: among steady states, we prove that welfare under monometallism is higher than under any bimetallic equilibrium. We compute welfare and the variance of the price level under a variety of regimes (bimetallism, monometallism with and without trade money) and find that bimetallism can significantly stabilize the price level, depending on the covari- ance between the shocks to the supplies of metals. Keywords: bimetallism, monometallism, double standard, commodity money *Velde, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago; Weber, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and University of Minne- sota. We thank without implicating Marc Flandreau, Ed Green, Angela Redish, and Tom Sargent. The views ex- pressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, the Fed- eral Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, or the Federal Reserve System.
    [Show full text]
  • Virtual Currencies in the Eurosystem: Challenges Ahead
    STUDY Requested by the ECON committee Virtual currencies in the Eurosystem: challenges ahead Monetary Dialogue July 2018 Policy Department for Economic, Scientific and Quality of Life Policies Authors: Rosa María LASTRA, Jason Grant ALLEN Directorate-General for Internal Policies EN PE 619.020 – July 2018 Virtual currencies in the Eurosystem: challenges ahead Monetary Dialogue July 2018 Abstract Speculation on Bitcoin, the evolution of money in the digital age, and the underlying blockchain technology are attracting growing interest. In the context of the Eurosystem, this briefing paper analyses the legal nature of privately issued virtual currencies (VCs), the implications of VCs for central bank’s monetary policy and monopoly of note issue, and the risks for the financial system at large. The paper also considers some of the proposals concerning central bank issued virtual currencies. This document was provided by Policy Department A at the request of the Committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs. This document was requested by the European Parliament's Committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs. AUTHORS Rosa María LASTRA, Centre for Commercial Law Studies, Queen Mary University of London Jason Grant ALLEN, Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin Centre for British Studies, University of New South Wales Centre for Law Markets and Regulation ADMINISTRATOR RESPONSIBLE Dario PATERNOSTER EDITORIAL ASSISTANT Janetta CUJKOVA LINGUISTIC VERSIONS Original: EN ABOUT THE EDITOR Policy departments provide in-house and external expertise to support EP committees
    [Show full text]
  • Free Silver"; Montana's Political Dream of Economic Prosperity, 1864-1900
    University of Montana ScholarWorks at University of Montana Graduate Student Theses, Dissertations, & Professional Papers Graduate School 1969 "Free silver"; Montana's political dream of economic prosperity, 1864-1900 James Daniel Harrington The University of Montana Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarworks.umt.edu/etd Let us know how access to this document benefits ou.y Recommended Citation Harrington, James Daniel, ""Free silver"; Montana's political dream of economic prosperity, 1864-1900" (1969). Graduate Student Theses, Dissertations, & Professional Papers. 1418. https://scholarworks.umt.edu/etd/1418 This Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the Graduate School at ScholarWorks at University of Montana. It has been accepted for inclusion in Graduate Student Theses, Dissertations, & Professional Papers by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks at University of Montana. For more information, please contact [email protected]. "FREE SILVER MONTANA'S POLITICAL DREAM OF ECONOMIC PROSPERITY: 1864-19 00 By James D. Harrington B. A. Carroll College, 1961 Presented in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Arts UNIVERSITY OF MONTANA 1969 Approved by: Chairman, Board of Examiners . /d . Date UMI Number: EP36155 All rights reserved INFORMATION TO ALL USERS The quality of this reproduction is dependent upon the quality of the copy submitted. In the unlikely event that the author did not send a complete manuscript and there are missing pages, these will be noted. Also, if material had to be removed, a note will indicate the deletion. UMT Disaartation Publishing UMI EP36155 Published by ProQuest LLC (2012). Copyright in the Dissertation held by the Author.
    [Show full text]
  • Final Years of the Silver Standard in Mexico: Evidence of Purchasing Power Parity with the United States
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive Final Years of the Silver Standard in Mexico: Evidence of Purchasing Power Parity with The United States Bojanic, Antonio N. 2 May 2011 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/45535/ MPRA Paper No. 45535, posted 27 Mar 2013 02:12 UTC final years of the silver standard in mexico: evidence of purchasing power parity with the united states Antonio N. Bojanic* Professor of Economics / CENTRUM – Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú Urbanización – Los Alamos de Monterrico – Surco, Perú ABSTRACT RESUMO This paper focuses on the use of silver as Este artigo enfoca o uso da prata como padrão a monetary standard in Mexico during monetário no México, durante aproximada- approximately the last three decades of the mente as três últimas décadas do século XIX nineteenth century and the first decade of e primeira década do século XX. Durante the twentieth century. During this period, esse período, vários eventos ocorreram no several events occurred in the market for mercado de prata, que afetaram os países silver that affected those countries attached atrelados a este metal. Estes eventos causa- to this metal. These events caused some ram alguns destes países a abandonar a prata of these countries to abandon silver for para o bem e adotar outros tipos de regime good and adopt other types of monetary monetário. México e alguns outros, preferiu arrangements. Mexico and a few others ficar com ele. As razões desta decisão são chose to stay with it.The reasons behind this analisados. Além disso prova, que apoia a decision are analyzed. Additionally, evidence teoria da paridade do poder de compra entre that supports the theory of purchasing power o México e os Estados Unidos são também parity between Mexico and the United States apresentados e analisados.
    [Show full text]
  • The Case for a 100 Percent Gold Dollar by Murray N
    The Case for a 100 Percent Gold Dollar By Murray N. Rothbard Publication history: Leland Yeager (ed.), In Search of a Monetary Constitution. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1962, pp. 94-136. Reprinted as The Case For a 100 Percent Gold Dollar. Washington, DC: Libertarian Review Press, 1974, and Auburn, Ala: Mises Institute, 1991, 2005. © Mises Institute, 2005. Preface When this essay was published, nearly thirty years ago, America was in the midst of the Bretton Woods system, a Keynesian international monetary system that had been foisted upon the world by the United States and British governments in 1945. The Bretton Woods system was an international dollar standard masquerading as a “gold standard,” in order to lend the well- deserved prestige of the world’s oldest and most stable money, gold, to the increasingly inflated and depreciated dollar. But this post-World War II system was only a grotesque parody of a gold standard. In the pre-World War I “classical” gold standard, every currency unit, be it dollar, pound, franc, or mark, was defined as a certain unit of weight of gold. Thus, the “dollar” was defined as approximately 1/20 of an ounce of gold, while the pound sterling was defined as a little less than 1/4 of a gold ounce, thus fixing the exchange rate between the two (and between all other currencies) at the ratio of their weights.1 Since every national currency was defined as being a certain weight of gold, paper francs or dollars, or bank deposits were redeemable by the issuer, whether government or bank, in that weight of gold.
    [Show full text]
  • The Gold Standard and the Great Depression: a Dynamic General Equilibrium Model
    The Gold Standard and the Great Depression: a Dynamic General Equilibrium Model L. Pensieroso and R. Restout Discussion Paper 2018-16 The Gold Standard and the Great Depression: a Dynamic General Equilibrium Model⇤ Luca Pensieroso† Romain Restout‡ December 3, 2018 Abstract Was the Gold Standard a major determinant of the onset and the protracted character of the the Great Depression of the 1930s in the United States and Worldwide? In this paper, we model the ‘Gold- Standard hypothesis’ in a dynamic general equilibrium framework. We show that encompassing the international and monetary dimen- sions of the Great Depression is important to understand what hap- pened in the 1930s, especially outside the United States. Contrary to what is often maintained in the literature, our results suggest that the vague of successive nominal exchange rate devaluations coupled with the monetary policy implemented in the United States did not act as a relief. On the contrary, they made the Depression worse. Keywords: Gold Standard, Great Depression, Dynamic General Equi- librium JEL Classification: N10, E13, N01 ⇤Paper presented at the EEA 2017 meeting in Lisbon, at the CEF 2017 conference in New York, at the ASSET 2016 conference in Thessaloniki, at the Workshop in Macroeconomics on the occasion of the Honorary Doctorate awarded to Olivier Blanchard in Ghent in 2017 and at the 2015 Macro-Dynamics Workshop in Bilbao. We thank participants to these meetings, as well as participants to seminars at the Universities of Louvain and Strasbourg for their feedback. Charlotte de Montpellier and Giulio Nicoletti made interesting remarks on an earlier version.
    [Show full text]
  • Gold Democrats and the Decline of Classical Liberalism, 1896–1900
    SUBSCRIBE NOW AND RECEIVE CRISIS AND LEVIATHAN* FREE! “The Independent Review does not accept “The Independent Review is pronouncements of government officials nor the excellent.” conventional wisdom at face value.” —GARY BECKER, Noble Laureate —JOHN R. MACARTHUR, Publisher, Harper’s in Economic Sciences Subscribe to The Independent Review and receive a free book of your choice* such as the 25th Anniversary Edition of Crisis and Leviathan: Critical Episodes in the Growth of American Government, by Founding Editor Robert Higgs. This quarterly journal, guided by co-editors Christopher J. Coyne, and Michael C. Munger, and Robert M. Whaples offers leading-edge insights on today’s most critical issues in economics, healthcare, education, law, history, political science, philosophy, and sociology. Thought-provoking and educational, The Independent Review is blazing the way toward informed debate! Student? Educator? Journalist? Business or civic leader? Engaged citizen? This journal is for YOU! *Order today for more FREE book options Perfect for students or anyone on the go! The Independent Review is available on mobile devices or tablets: iOS devices, Amazon Kindle Fire, or Android through Magzter. INDEPENDENT INSTITUTE, 100 SWAN WAY, OAKLAND, CA 94621 • 800-927-8733 • [email protected] PROMO CODE IRA1703 Gold Democrats and the Decline of Classical Liberalism, 1896–1900 —————— ✦ —————— DAVID T. BEITO AND LINDA ROYSTER BEITO n 1896 a new political party was born, the National Democratic Party (NDP). The founders of the NDP included some of the leading exponents of classical I liberalism during the late nineteenth century. Few of those men, however, fore- saw the ultimate fate of their new party and of the philosophy of limited government that it championed.
    [Show full text]
  • Hong Kong's Currency Board and Changing Monetary Regimes
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HONG KONG’S CURRENCY BOARD AND CHANGING MONETARY REGIMES Yum K. Kwan Francis T. Lui Working Paper 5723 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 August 1996 This paper was presented at NBER’s East Asian Seminar on Economics, and the NBER conference “Universities Research Conference on the Determination of Exchange Rates.” This work is part of NBER’s project on International Capital Flows which receives support from the Center for International Political Economy. We are grateful to the Center for International Political Economy for the support of this project and to Barry Eichengreen and Zhaoyong Zhang for helpful and constructive comments. Any opinions expressed are those of the authors and not those of the National Bureau of Economic Research. O 1996 by Yum K. Kwan and Francis T. Lui. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including @ notice, is given to the source. NBER Working Paper 5723 August 1996 HONG KONG’S CURRENCY BOARD AND CHANGING MONETARY REGIMES ABSTRACT The paper discusses the historical background and institutional details of Hong Kong’s currency board. We argue that its experience provides a good opportunity to test the macroeconomic implications of the currency board regime. Using the method of Blanchard and Quah (1989), we show that the parameters of the structural equations and the characteristics of supply and demand shocks have significantly changed since adopting the regime. Variance decomposition and impulse response analyses indicate Hong Kong’s currency board is less susceptible to supply shocks, but demand shocks can cause greater short-term volatility under the system.
    [Show full text]
  • The Populist Movement
    The populist movement Item Type text; Thesis-Reproduction (electronic) Authors Montgomery, Winona Publisher The University of Arizona. Rights Public Domain: This material has been identified as being free of known restrictions under U.S. copyright law, including all related and neighboring rights. Download date 29/09/2021 21:06:34 Item License http://creativecommons.org/publicdomain/mark/1.0/ Link to Item http://hdl.handle.net/10150/627573 THE POPULIST MOVEMENT WINONA MONTGOMERY LIBRAIO UNIV. OF ARIZONA T HE P 0 P U.L 1ST OVEMENT A THESIS SUBMITTED TO THE FACULTY OF THE UNIVERSITY OF ARIZONA in PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE R _IQUIREMENTS- FOR THE DEGREE OF MASTER of ARTS BY WINONA MONTGOMERY MAY 15 1923 E929/ // ACKUOWLEDGEMENT The writer wishes to acknowlede her indebted- ness to Professor H. A. Hubbard Associate Professor Ida C. Reid under whose direction this thesis was written, for their interest and advice. THE POPULIST MOVEMENT FORCES THAT CAUSED THE POPULIST mnv:TTET2 Chapter I Situation of the Farmer. A. EzTDansion of the West. 1. Increased agricultural production. Fall in „prices of agriraltural -)roducts. 3. Increased demand for money. B. Railroads. 1. 7elcomed 137 farmers. 2. Farmers objected to hi7h freight rates. 3. Farmers opposed Railroad ownership of land. C. Period of Depression. 1. Poor crops. 2. Low prices of cotton. D. Organization. 1. Grange 2. Farmer' l o c a l organizations. 3. Farmers' Alliance and Cobr- - ati7re Union. 4. Farmers' and Laborers' Union of America. 5. National Farmers' Alliance. Chapter II American Labor. A. Low Wao:es. 1. Table of wages. 2• City caused laborers;' expenses to increase.
    [Show full text]
  • International Bimetallism
    STATEMENT RESPECTING THE WORK OF THE RECENT INTERNATIONAL BIMETALLIC COMh!ISSION HON.EDWARD 0.WOLCOTTa I I OF COLORADO, IN THE SENATE OF THE UNITED STATES, JANUARY 17, 1898. P WASHINGTON. 1898. r .C m: e* 4'~tatementRespecting the Work of the Recent Internationel Bimetallic Conkmission, BY I4UN. EDWAED 0. WOLGOTT, OF COLORADO, INTIIE SENATEOF TIIE UNITEDSTATES, Jaizunry 17, 1538. Mr. WOLCOTT s3id: Mr. PRESIDENT:In the statement which I am glad to make respecting certain phases of the work of the recent bimetallic com- mission. I must s-vealc, of course, entirely unoficiallv and as not committing my associates in the slightest degree &ither to my opinions or deductions. Later in the session we are certain to have ample discussion on the subject of silver, and it will proba- bly be acrid and bitter enough. In my remarks to-day, however, I mean to avoid, as far as possible, anything which may give rise to controversy, and while the account of our negotiations must necsssarily seem bare and colorless, the subject of them is one of surpassing interest and importance to every member of the Senate and to every citizen of our country. When Congress met a year ago, soon after the national election, there was a universal expression by the Republican membei-ship &nthe Senate that the pledge of the party in its St. Louis platform to promote international bimetallism by every aeans in its power was an undertaking to be faithfully carried out without evasion or delay. As a result of this sentiment, and growing out of the action of the Republican menibers of the Senate, I spent the monthsof Jan- uary and February last in London and Paris, with a day or two at Berlin, inquiring unofficially as to the apparent prospects of securing bimetallism by international agreement.
    [Show full text]
  • Rules Versus Discretion at the Federal Reserve: on to the Second Century
    Rules versus Discretion at the Federal Reserve: On to the Second Century The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters Citation Friedman, Benjamin Morton. 2012. Rules versus discretion at the Federal Reserve System: On to the second century. Journal of Macroeconomics 34(3): 608-615. Published Version dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jmacro.2012.05.009 Citable link http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:10886842 Terms of Use This article was downloaded from Harvard University’s DASH repository, and is made available under the terms and conditions applicable to Open Access Policy Articles, as set forth at http:// nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:dash.current.terms-of- use#OAP For: Journal of Macroeconomics April, 2012 RULES VERSUS DISCRETION AT THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM: ON TO THE SECOND CENTURY Benjamin M. Friedman Harvard University A look back over the soon-to-be-completed first century of the U.S. Federal Reserve System immediately highlights the continuing importance of a fundamental tension: between the desire, often on different grounds in diverse quarters, for rule-based policymaking, and the practicalities that, inevitably or not, lead central bankers to preserve an essential role for discretion in actual policy decisions. Such key episodes during this hundred years as the initial debate over the new central bank’s structure, the exploration of how it might conduct open market operations and the creation of the Federal Open Market Committee, the confused
    [Show full text]
  • Walter Nugent COMMENTS on WYATT WELLS, “RHETORIC OF
    The Journal of the Gilded Age and Progressive Era 14 (2015), 69–76 doi:10.1017/S1537781414000541 Walter Nugent COMMENTS ON WYATT WELLS, “RHETORIC OF THE STANDARDS: THE DEBATE OVER GOLD AND SILVER IN THE 1890S” I. SOME THOUGHTS ON THE WELLS PAPER Wyatt Wells redirects our attention to the “battle of the standards,” the central issue of the 1896 Bryan-McKinley campaign but with roots going back to the Civil War and Recon- struction. He contrasts opposing sides, labeled “goldbugs” and “silverites.” Often these labels identify Republicans on one side, Democrats and Populists on the other. Goldbugs concentrated in the Northeast, silverites in the South and West. Goldbugs included many bankers, merchants (especially in international trade), and bondholders, while silverites were often agrarians—not only farmers but rural businesspeople who shared the farmers’ ups and downs. And agrarians, both in where they lived and what they did, were still the majority of the American people during the decades in question. There were exceptions to all of these categorizations, but in general they identify the groups for which “gold- bugs” and “silverites” are surrogate terms. The consistent policies and laws affecting money—from the Public Credit Act of 1869 to the 1893 repeal of the Sherman Silver Purchase Act—effected “persistent deflation” (p. 1). That benefited goldbugs and disadvantaged silverites.1 Whether “urban workers” (p. 10) would have been harmed by moderate inflation is arguable. It might have raised wages more than consumer prices; wages may lag more than prices but could have caught up. Arguable too is the proposition that keeping the silver standard would have ruined foreign investment.
    [Show full text]