Church Provision of Club Goods and Community Redevelopment in New Orleans East

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Church Provision of Club Goods and Community Redevelopment in New Orleans East Working Paper Church Provision of Club Goods and Community Redevelopment in New Orleans East * EMILY CHAMLEE-WRIGHT Abstract This paper examines how the church pro vision of club goods, or quasipublic goods, can foster community rebound in the wake of disaster. In particular, the swift return of the com munity surrounding the Mary Queen of Vietnam Catholic Church in N ew Orleans East is examined here. This paper argues that the church provision of valuable club goods not easily replicable outside of New Orleans East is a driving force in drawing people back to the community. The club goods under consideration are 1) a distinct ethnic-religious-language community, 2) a capacity for communitywide social coordination, and 3) a capacity for political action. This paper concludes by considering the broader relevance this case has for understanding the role club goods can play in rendering individual agency more effective. Key Words: religious provision of club goods, community redevelopment, social resilience, post-disaster recovery * WORKING PAPER Emily Chamlee-Wright is Professor of Economics at Beloit College and Affiliated Senior Scholar at The Mercatus Center, George Mason University. She would like to thank the members of the research team who helped us conduct the interviews for this project, including Lenore Ealy, Dan Rothschild, Anthony Skriba, and Adam Martin. She would also like to thank Kathryn Linnenberg for her assistance in training the interview team and developing the interview instrument; the Vietnamese interpreters Khai Hoang and Vu Nguyen; Skyler Treat for her research assistance; and Peter Boettke, Virgil Storr, Scott Beaulier, Josh Hall, and Charles Westerberg for their insightful comments on earlier drafts. Finally, she would like to thank the Mercatus Center for their generous financial support. The usual caveat applies. The ideas presented in this research are the author's and do not represent official positions of the Mercatus Center at George Mason University. Church Provision of Club Goods and Community Redevelopment in New Orleans East Introduction [The] perpetual consumption and reproduction of capital affords the explanation of what has so often excited wonder, the great rapidity with which countries recover from a state of devastation; the disappearance, in a short time, of all traces of the mischiefs done by earthquakes, floods, hurricanes, and the ravages of war. n enemy lays waste a country by fire and sword, and destroys or carries away nearly all the moveable wealth existing in it: all the inhabitants are ruined, and yet in a few years after, everything is much as it was before. — John Stuart Mill, The Principles of Political Economy. Book I, Chapter V, paragraph I.5.19. Quoted in Hirshlei er (2002) Hurricane Katrina might have given even John Stuart Mill reason to doubt whether Gul Coast communities would recover rom the devastation that ollowed in her path. Indeed, at the present writing (two years a ter the storm), some communities appear as though they might stand as shocking e-ceptions to Mill.s optimistic thesis.1 And yet, in some communities, Mill.s e-pectations o swi t recovery have indeed been born out. 0he community surrounding the Mary Queen o Vietnam (MQV1) Catholic Church in 1ew 2rleans East is widely considered to be a post4Katrina success story. But, despite Mill.s e-planation, its success still presents something o a pu55le. 6 hy was it this community that achieved such early success, and how was this success won7 According to the 8rban 9and Institute (89I), the principal consulting group advising the Bring 1ew 2rleans Back Commission, :0he 1ew 2rleans East area e-perienced some o the city.s most severe looding, with lood depths ranging rom ive to more than twelve eet,; (89I 200WORKING6: 43). Early recommendations in the redevelopment pl annPAPERing process suggested that its pro-imity to the Bayou Sauvage 1ational 6 ildli e Re uge made 1ew 2rleans East a good candidate or conversion to open space (ibid). But with the e-ception o the Arench Quarter, Church Provision o Club Goods and Community Redevelopment in 1ew 2rleans East 1 Garden Cistrict, and 8ptown (which incurred little to no lood damage due to higher elevations), the MQV1 neighborhood came back aster and more robustly than virtually all other neighborhoods in 2rleans Parish, even those with similar levels o lood damage and those that were considerably more a luent. Si-teen months a ter the storm, or e-ample, only ten percent o the residents living in the a luent 9akeview neighborhood had returned, but the MQV1 community had achieved this threshold within weeks o the storm (Bohrer 2007). By April 2006, 1,200 o the 4,000 residents who lived within a one4mile radius o the church had returned. 6 ithin a year o the storm, more than 3,000 residents had returned. By the summer o 2007, appro-imately 90 percent o the MQV1 residents were back, while the rate o return in 1ew 2rleans overall remained at only 45 percent.2 Aurther, within a year o the storm, 70 o the 75 Vietnamese4owned businesses in the MQV1 neighborhood were up and running. Again, why this community, and what were the mechanisms that drove their success7 A ull response to this Euestion would include an e-amination o the wide array o social resources embedded within the MQV1 community.3 6 hat is e-amined here is the critical role played by the MQV1 church in the redevelopment e ort. By providing valuable club goods the MQV1 church has e-erted considerable leverage in drawing people back to the community. :Club goods; are those :Euasi4public; resources that lie between purely private and purely public goods. Commercial society regularly provides club goods, such as itness clubs and gol courses. Civil society also has the ability to provide club goods, such as community centers and amateur team sports clubs. E-amples are so common, we rarely think o club goods as being vitaWORKINGl to a community.s e-istence. But in the a termath o Ka triPAPERna, it was the provision o essential club goods that served as a driving orce in recreating one 1ew 2rleans neighborhood. 0he club goods e-amined here are 1) a highly speci ic ethnic4religious identity and language community, 2) the capacity to coordinate both religious and secular civic li e be ore and a ter Church Provision o Club Goods and Community Redevelopment in 1ew 2rleans East 2 Katrina, and 3) the in rastructure necessary or political action in the post4Katrina environment. By providing such goods, the MQV1 church has ostered the sense that its 1ew 2rleans East neighborhood (a neighborhood that might look Euite ordinary to the outsider) represents something Euite special to the insider—a :second homeland; that is worth rebuilding. 0he analysis presented here seeks to complement the already well4developed theoretical treatment o the religious provision o club goods with a case study o how this phenomenon is playing out in a post4disaster setting. In addition to complementing the literature on the religious provision o club goods, this analysis makes a contribution to the literature e-amining the role social capital plays in post4disaster conte-ts (Beggs et al. 1996a, 1996bF Hulbert et al. 2001). 6 hile much o the e-isting literature ocuses on how individuals deploy their social networks to meet the immediate challenges o a natural disaster, this analysis ills an important gap by e-amining the role socially embedded resources play in long term recovery o an entire community. Ainally, this case study makes a contribution to the burgeoning literature e-ploring issues o agency and structure in the post4Katrina recovery process (Colten 2006F Elliott G Pais 2006F Henkel et al. 2006F Hartman G SEuires 2006F Herring 2006). As will be discussed below, the church provision o club goods o ers a use ul lens or understanding how, in some circumstances, social structure makes e ective agency possible. Club Goods as a Theoretical Lens 0he analysis presented here builds out o Buchanan.s (1965) insight that many valuable goods and services are provided somewhere between the yawning gap o purely private and purely public goods. Buchanan points out that common e-perience suggests that people o ten pre WORKINGer club goods (e.g., membership at a community swimm ingPAPER pool) over purely private goods (e.g., a swimming pool in the backyard). Buchanan also points out that ew goods meet the strict criteria o a purely public good along the lines that Samuelson (1954) suggests in his classic Church Provision o Club Goods and Community Redevelopment in 1ew 2rleans East 3 article on the subHect. Instead, many goods possess a degree o :publicness; that distinguishes them rom either o the two e-tremes in ways that deserve special attention. 0hough Buchanan.s principal concern was to develop a general theory o clubs, others have applied this theoretical lens to e-plain historical patterns o social change. Kuran (2001), or e-ample, describes how Middle Eastern Islamic waqfs provided water services, light houses, hospitals, orphanages, and public spaces as a means o acEuiring a credible commitment rom the state to en orce property rights and not predate against immobile private assets. In their study o the economic organi5ation o the medieval church, Ekelund, et al. (1996) note that in addition to providing many private goods, the Church also provided essential public goods, such as a system o law and courts, and e-erted its :transnational in luence to limited armed con lict among petty warlords who dominated the political landscape o western Europe; (Ekelund et al. 1996: 25). Aurther, the Church supplied Euasi4public goods, such as ormal education and norms and institutions that aided the poor, both o which served as crucial contributions to the development o human capital (Ekelund et al.
Recommended publications
  • Club Good Intermediaries∗
    Club Good Intermediaries∗ Simon Loertscher† Leslie M. Marx‡ September 4, 2016 Abstract The emergence and ubiquitous presence in everyday life of digital goods such as songs, movies, and e-books give renewed salience to the problem of providing public goods with exclusion. Because digital goods are typically traded via inter- mediaries like iTunes, Amazon, and Netflix, the question arises as to the optimal pricing mechanism for such club good intermediaries. We derive the direct Bayesian optimal mechanism for allocating club goods when the mechanism designer is an intermediary that neither produces nor consumes the goods, and we develop an indirect mechanism that implements this mechanism. We also derive sufficient con- ditions for the intermediary-optimal mechanism to be implementable with revenue sharing contracts, which are widely used in e-business. Keywords: revenue maximization, excludable public goods, two-sided platforms, optimal pricing, digital goods JEL Classification: C72, D82, L13 ∗We thank seminar participants at the 34th Australasian Economic Theory Workshop, C´edric Wasser, and an anonymous referee for helpful comments. †Department of Economics, Level 4, FBE Building, 111 Barry Street, University of Melbourne, Victoria 3010, Australia. Email: [email protected]. ‡The Fuqua School of Business, Duke University, 100 Fuqua Drive, Durham, NC 27708, USA: Email: [email protected]. 1 Introduction The issue of optimal public goods provision has achieved new salience with the emergence of digital goods like e-books, downloadable songs, and movies along with new technologies that make exclusion and distribution possible at negligible marginal costs. An aspect not present in the analysis of excludable public goods or “club goods” in the age of the internet is that consumers gain access to these digital goods via an intermediary such as Amazon, iTunes, Spotify, or Netflix rather than contracting directly with the producer of the club good as they might with the owner of a country club.
    [Show full text]
  • “Free Riding” in Civil Wars? Violence, Insurgency, and the Collective Action Problem
    NÚMERO 139 STATHIS N. KALYVAS MATTHEW ADAM KOCHER How Free is “Free Riding” in Civil Wars? Violence, Insurgency, and the Collective Action Problem JUNIO 2006 www.cide.edu Las colecciones de Documentos de Trabajo del CIDE representan un medio para difundir los avances de la labor de investigación y para permitir que los autores reciban comentarios antes de su publicación definitiva. Se agradecerá que los comentarios se hagan llegar directamente al (los) autor(es). • D.R. ® 2006. Centro de Investigación y Docencia Económicas, carretera México-Toluca 3655 (km 16.5), Lomas de Santa Fe, 01210, México, D.F. Tel. 5727•9800 exts. 2202, 2203, 2417 Fax: 5727•9885 y 5292•1304. Correo electrónico: [email protected] www.cide.edu Producción a cargo del (los) autor(es), por lo que tanto el contenido como el estilo y la redacción son su responsabilidad. Acknowledgements Thanks to Abbey Steele for research assistance, and to Zeynep Bulutgil, Eddie Camp, Sergio Galaz García, Adria Lawrence, Nicholas Sambanis, Jonah Schulhofer-Wohl, Justin Fox. Versions of this paper were presented at the Sawyer Seminar on Mass Killing, Center for Advanced Study in the Behavioral Science (CASBS); the Comparative Politics Workshop, Department of Political Science, Yale University; and the Laboratory on Comparative Ethnic Processes (LiCEP). Thanks to all the participants for their generous attention and thoughful commentary. Abstract That rebels face a collective action problem is one of the most widely shared assumptions in the literature on civil wars. We argue that the collective action paradigm can be both descriptively inaccurate and analytically misleading as applied to civil wars —which are uniquely characterized by large-scale violence.
    [Show full text]
  • Of Clubs and Conflict: the Dissolvant Power of Social Capital in Kivu (D.R.Congo)
    Of clubs and conflict: the dissolvant power of social capital in Kivu (D.R.Congo) Frank Van Acker (University of Antwerp, Faculty of Applied Economics and Development Studies, Antwerp, Belgium) Written for the 8th IASCP Conference, Bloomington, Indiana 31 May to 4 June 2000 1. Introduction Stretched out over 500 km along the borders of the Democratic Republic of Congo with the republics of Uganda, Rwanda, and Burundi, lie the Congolese provinces of North and South Kivu. These provinces consist of highlands and volcanoes to the East, and lowlands to the West. As such, they mirror the conditions of the crowded and fertile highlands of Rwanda to one side, and those of the underpopulated Congo basin to the other. Currently the Kivu is notorious as a hotbed of problems and conflicts, where rebellious armies and peasant militias hold sway. Yet this kind of turmoil is not new; as far back as the 1920’s, conflicts regularly erupted. Clearly, the particular location and history of the provinces are pertinent in looking for an explanation. The colonial history of the region is one in which Rwandan and Burundian peasants were resettled in the Kivu to supply labor to the large coffee and tea estates and cattle ranches situated in the highlands there. After Congolese independence in 1960, the nature of the problem changed but not the problem itself; peasants of neighboring countries continued to flock to Kivu to escape the crowded conditions of their own homelands. Consequently, the biggest post-independence bone of content in the Kivu is that of nationality. In various political seesaw movements, nationality was granted to these immigrants and repealed again according to political convenience.
    [Show full text]
  • Public Goods and Club Goods
    0750 PUBLIC GOODS AND CLUB GOODS Patrick McNutt Chairperson, Competition Authority, Dublin and Research Associate, Department of Political Science, University of Dublin © Copyright 1999 Patrick McNutt Abstract Public goods contrast with private goods. Pure public goods have the unique characteristics of non-excludability and non-rivalry in consumption while private goods are sold to those who can afford to pay the market price. The under-supply equilibrium of a public goods provision is an important aspect of the provision of public goods. The economic theory of clubs represents an attempt to explain the under-supply equilibrium of a public goods provision. It raises many different and controversial issues which impinge on government policy in the public sector. In many respects, a club provision proffers an alternative to a central government provision of local public goods. The salient characteristic of a club, the excludability factor, may militate against an equal and democratic distribution of the club good. At the level of voluntary clubs, with which Buchanan was originally concerned, club theory can critically appraise the efforts at achieving optimal membership of the club and the maximum utility of club members. As the literature introduces increasing problems with cooperation then it behoves law and economics scholars to research and develop non-market and/or non-cooperative solutions to an optimal provision of public goods. JEL classification: D60, D71, K00. Keywords: Free Rider, Pareto Optimality, Club Goods, Excludability and Non-rivalry, Coase Theorem, Homogeneity 1. Introduction Pure public goods as originally defined by Samuelson (1954) have the unique characteristics of non-excludability and non-rivalry in consumption.
    [Show full text]
  • Zbwleibniz-Informationszentrum
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Engerer, Hella Working Paper Security Economics: Definition and Capacity Economics of Security Working Paper, No. 5 Provided in Cooperation with: German Institute for Economic Research (DIW Berlin) Suggested Citation: Engerer, Hella (2009) : Security Economics: Definition and Capacity, Economics of Security Working Paper, No. 5, Deutsches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung (DIW), Berlin This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/119331 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Economics of Security Working Paper Series Hella Engerer Security Economics: Definition and Capacity January 2009 Economics of Security Working Paper 5 This publication is an output of EUSECON, a research project supported by the European Commission’s Seventh Framework Programme.
    [Show full text]
  • Agricultural and Food Value Chains As Clubs 1
    Available online at www.centmapress.org INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL ON FOOD SYSTEM Proceedings in DYNAMICS System Dynamics and Innovation in Food Networks 2018 Consciously Pursued Joint Action: Agricultural and Food Value Chains as Clubs 1 Euan Fleming, Garry Griffith, Stuart Mounter and Derek Baker The authors are all with the Centre for Agribusiness, UNE Business School, University of New England, Armidale, Australia [email protected]; [email protected]; [email protected]; [email protected] ABSTRACT Certain members of a population consciously and deliberately decide to take joint action to provide particular types of goods or services that are at least partly excludable and at least partly congestible because it is too costly to provide such goods individually. These goods are called club goods or collective goods. We first define some key concepts in club theory and public choice. This includes the prospects for determining the optimal level of membership of a club, how to determine the optimal level and range of provision of services by a club, and consideration of the dynamics of club membership. Then we examine the ways in which club theory can help provide an alternative approach to recognising and overcoming market failure in agricultural and food value chains. We note that useful insights can be gained by considering value chains as ‘latent clubs’. That is, they are systems that exist but which are either inactive or have not been fully developed, but which have the potential for improvement through collective action. If value chain members do exploit an opportunity to reap the rewards of collective action, then forming a club that comprises the whole chain or a subset of chain members offers an efficient organisation design to do so.
    [Show full text]
  • 0750 Public Goods and Club Goods
    0750 PUBLIC GOODS AND CLUB GOODS Patrick McNutt Chairperson, Competition Authority, Dublin and Research Associate, Department of Political Science, University of Dublin © Copyright 1999 Patrick McNutt Abstract Public goods contrast with private goods. Pure public goods have the unique characteristics of non-excludability and non-rivalry in consumption while private goods are sold to those who can afford to pay the market price. The under-supply equilibrium of a public goods provision is an important aspect of the provision of public goods. The economic theory of clubs represents an attempt to explain the under-supply equilibrium of a public goods provision. It raises many different and controversial issues which impinge on government policy in the public sector. In many respects, a club provision proffers an alternative to a central government provision of local public goods. The salient characteristic of a club, the excludability factor, may militate against an equal and democratic distribution of the club good. At the level of voluntary clubs, with which Buchanan was originally concerned, club theory can critically appraise the efforts at achieving optimal membership of the club and the maximum utility of club members. As the literature introduces increasing problems with cooperation then it behoves law and economics scholars to research and develop non-market and/or non-cooperative solutions to an optimal provision of public goods. JEL classification: D60, D71, K00. Keywords: Free Rider, Pareto Optimality, Club Goods, Excludability and Non-rivalry, Coase Theorem, Homogeneity 1. Introduction Pure public goods as originally defined by Samuelson (1954) have the unique characteristics of non-excludability and non-rivalry in consumption.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 8: Externalities and Public Goods
    Chapter 8 Externalities and Public Goods 8.1 What is an Externality? We just showed that competitive markets result in Pareto optimal allocations — that is the market acts to make sure that those who value goods the most receive them, and those that can produce goods at the least cost produce them, and there is no way that everybody in society could be made better off. Thisgaveusthefirst and second welfare theorems — the market allocates commodities efficiently, and any efficient allocation can be derived by a market with suitable ex ante transfers of wealth. Now we will take a look at one important circumstance where the welfare theorems do not hold. When we talked about commodities in the past, they were always what are called “private goods.” That is, they were such that they were consumed by only one person, and that person’s consumption of the good had no effect on other people’s utility. But, this is not true of all goods. Think, for example, of a local bakery that produces bread. Earlier, we said that each person purchases the quantity of bread where the marginal benefit of consuming an additional loaf is just equal to the price of a loaf, and each firm produces bread up to the point where the marginal cost of producing the loaf is just equal to its price. In equilibrium, then, the marginal benefitofeating an additional loaf of bread is just equal to the marginal cost of producing an additional loaf. But, think about the following. People who walk by the bakery get the benefit from the pleasant smell of baking bread, and this is not incorporated into the price of bread.
    [Show full text]
  • ECONOMICS Public Goods and Common Resources
    10/22/2017 N. GREGORY MANKIW Look for the answers to these questions: PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS • What are public goods? Eight Edition • What are common resources? Give examples of each. • Why do markets generally fail to provide the CHAPTER Public Goods and efficient amounts of these goods? • How might the government improve market 11 Common Resources outcomes in the case of public goods or common resources? Premium PowerPoint Slides by: V. Andreea CHIRITESCU Modified by Joseph Tao-yi Wang Eastern Illinois University © 2018 Cengage Learning®. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly accessible website, in whole or in part, except for use © 2018 Cengage Learning®. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly accessible website, in whole or in part, except for use 2 as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website or school-approved learning 1 as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website or school-approved learning management system for classroom use. management system for classroom use. Introduction The Different Kinds of Goods • We consume many goods without paying: • Excludability – Parks, national defense, clean air & water – Property of a good whereby a person can be prevented from using it – When goods have no prices, the market – Excludable : MOS rice burgers, Wi-Fi access forces that normally allocate resources are Not excludable absent – : radio signals, national defense • Rivalry in consumption – The private market may fail to provide the socially efficient quantity of such goods – Property of a good whereby one person’s use diminishes other people’s use • ‘Governments can sometimes improve – Rival : MOS rice burgers market outcomes’ – Not rival : An MP3 file of David Tao’s latest single © 2018 Cengage Learning®.
    [Show full text]
  • University of Hawai`I at Mānoa Department of Economics Working Paper Series
    University of Hawai`i at Mānoa Department of Economics Working Paper Series Saunders Hall 542, 2424 Maile Way, Honolulu, HI 96822 Phone: (808) 956 -8496 www.economics.hawaii.edu Working Paper No. 20-7 Clubs, Coase, and the Role of Government By James Roumasset March 2020 Clubs, Coase, and the Role of Government James Roumasset1 Abstract As Ronald Coase and others have shown, deducing the appropriate role of government in the economy requires a comparative institutions approach. Trying to generalize from oversimplified specifications regarding transaction costs, according to whether exclusion is possible or not, is a futile exercise. An alternative to the Ostrom matrix is to distinguish private, club, and collective consumption goods according to their technical characteristics, specifically their degree of congestabiilty. The other box of the Ostrom matrix, “common pool” resources, can also be usefully analyzed from a club perspective. Spillover goods are spatial clubs. Lastly, a version of the Coase theorem is offered that provides the foundation of comparative institutional analysis JEL classification: H4 Keywords: Public goods, club goods, congestability, Ostrom matrix, comparative institutions Public goods and the Coase Theorem are two of the most confusing parts of any text or curriculum about public economics. At least some of the confusion can be resolved by applying the concept of the shrinking core and by more clearly separating first-best efficiency conditions from second-best matters of implementation. The resulting framework helps to clarify the role of government in an economy. Public Goods It is commonplace to define public goods by the characteristics of non-rivalry and non- excludability.
    [Show full text]
  • Greed Versus Grievance: a Useful Conceptual Distinction in the Study
    Anke Hoeffler: ‘Greed’ versus ‘Grievance’: A Useful Conceptual Distinction in the Study of Civil War? ‘Greed’ versus ‘Grievance’: A Useful Conceptual Distinction in the Study of Civil War? Anke Hoeffler* University of Oxford I. Introduction Since the end of World War II, civil war has been the most common form of large-scale violent conflict; in total, this type of armed confrontation has killed about sixteen million people (Regan 2009). Over the past decade, there has been a pronounced increase in the civil war literature. Economists, among other social scientists, have tried to investigate the causes of large-scale violent conflict by using economic theory, as well as empirical tests, which had hitherto been impos- sible due to lack of data. These analytical searches are driven by the hope that if we can gain a better understanding of the causes of civil war, we may be able to prevent future violent conflict and help to resolve ongoing wars. In this article I discuss whether ‘greed’ versus ‘grievance’ is a useful conceptual distinction to help us understand and prevent civil wars. I argue that the theory of collective action provides some useful insights into the organisation of rebellion. Group interests (e.g., common grievances) can only be addressed by collective action. One way of understanding how this collective action can be achieved is to frame rebellion as the production of a public good. Collective action theory suggests that in order to overcome the problem of ‘free riding’, participants have to receive private rewards. Thus, ‘greed’ may be an important factor in the organisation of rebellion.
    [Show full text]
  • Financing and Providing Global Public Goods
    Financing and Providing Global Public Goods This study was commissioned by the Development Financing 2000 project within the Swedish Ministry for Financing and Foreign Affairs. The purpose of the project is to increase awareness, knowledge and international commitment to a strong, effective and well-funded multilateral system for Providing Global development. The study aims at bridging the academic discussion on Public Goods global public goods with ongoing international policy processes. A conceptual framework for assessing financing and institutional arrangements for the provision of global Expectations and Prospects public goods is suggested. Some of the key issues brought forward are: • A global public goods delivery system • A decision tree for evaluating financing options for global public goods • A possible division of labour for the international community • Case studies on climate change, biodiversity, financial stability, peace and security, and HIV/AIDS ryckeri Omslag: Rolf Hernegran, Graphium Norstedts T DEVELOPMENT FINANCING 2000 Ministry for Foreign Affairs Sweden S-103 39 Stockholm Tel: +46-8-405 10 00, Fax: +46-8-723 11 76 Study 2001:2 Web site: www.utrikes.regeringen.se Ministry for Foreign Affairs ISBN 91-7496-269-8 Sweden inancing and Providing Global Public Goods Expectations and Prospects Prepared for the Ministry for oreign Affairs Sweden rancisco Sagasti and Keith Bezanson on behalf of: November 2001 For further information about the project Development Financing 2000 please go to www.utrikes.regeringen.se/inenglish/policy/devcoop/financing.htm
    [Show full text]