The Social Analysis of Three Early 19Th Century French Liberals: Say, Comte, and Dunoyer*

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Social Analysis of Three Early 19Th Century French Liberals: Say, Comte, and Dunoyer* THE SOCIAL ANALYSIS OF THREE EARLY 19TH CENTURY FRENCH LIBERALS: SAY, COMTE, AND DUNOYER* MARK WEINBURG Ueporlment of Hislory. University ofChica,?o The topic of this paper is the class theory of It was a vast social-historical treatise shaped and Jean-Baptiste Say (1767-1832). Charles Comte informed by the principles of political economy. (1782-1838) and Charles Dunoyer (1786-1862). It would be impossible to discuss the class However, in order to be fully accurate, this title theories of these men without examining their should be qualified in several respects. First, the view of history, their political ideas and most thinking of these men can not be examined in importantly their economic thought. In fact, the complete isolation, divorced from traditional main thesis of this paper is that a cogent, liberal ideas, the works of their contemporaries cohesive and vastly powerful social analysis was and the intellectual currents of the day. created with the fusion of liberal historical and Secondly, their class theories strictly speaking political thought with the economic orthodoxy cannot be separated from what we might now of Jean-Baptiste Say. consider the separate specializations of econom- An examination of any group of critical ics, history and political theory. This is the radicals, such as the French liberals of the nature of the times as well as in the nature of the Restoration and July Monarchy periods, subject. In the early 19th century, the social necessarily must address itself to three basic sciences had not developed in the sense which we questions. First, what was the primary liberal know them today. With the exceptions of view of the origins and history of the class history and political economy, real special- structure of their society? Secondly, how did izations had not yet become established among they envision the structure of a truly just the "political and moral sciences", as they were society? And finally, by what means was the just then known. In this group, Say is the exception, society to be attained? From this derives the a true specialist, perhaps the first professional basic organization of the paper. In the first economist of the 19th century. Comte is closest section, 1 will present a brief and by no means to Say in this regard, a professor of law and a exhaustive examination of some aspects of the publicist. He wished to apply in his own field the revolutionary liberal tradition in which these scientific methods of J. B. Say. His Trait6 de men shared and some of the contemporaneous legislation involved a meticulous examination of intellectual climates which influenced their the history and social organizations of the work. The second section will deal with the human race based upon the principles of utility development of the doctrines of industrielisme and political economy. Dunoyer, who is which was the synthesis of traditional liberal remembered primarily as a political economist, views on history and politics and the new science was somewhat more ambitious in his endeavors. of economics. The final section of the paper will Trained as a lawyer, he was a publicist, a examine the vitally important concepts of professor of political economy, and he wrote his anarchy and social evolution as' they were chief work, La Libert6 du travail as a history of developed in the later writings of Say, Comte the growth of liberty in civilization, which to and Dunoyer. Dunoyer meant the history of civilization itself. The original version of this paper was delivered at the Fourth Libertarian Scholars Conference, October, 1976, One of the most important themes in the New York City. historical thought of thelate 18th and early 19th 46 MARK WEINBURG centuries was the concept of the evolution of 18th century found the ideological grounds for civilization through various stages. Perhaps the revolution. first among the French to develop this was In his revolutionary tract, Paine distinguished Bossuet in his Discours sur I'histoire universelle radically between society and government, one, (1681). In 1750, Turgot set out in his Plan de always a blessing arising from our wants, the deux discours sur I'histoire universelle the other, a necessary evil, arising from our division of civilization into the stages of wickedness.131 Paine realized, of course, that in hunting, pastoral and agricultural societies a developed and civilized society brute force which was to be so influential among later alone would not suffice to support a political liberal theorists. It was within this evolutionary order.141 A successful revolutionary must first framework that the liberals of the Restoration break the bonds of conviction and emotion period developed their ideas concerning the which attach men even to bad governments. structure of modern society.lll This was the role of natural law and social The fundamental liberal notion of the origin contract theories, to sap the legalist and of the pre-revolutionary and restoration class theological foundations of monarchical govern- structure of France was based upon what we ment. Thus, rather than the anointed of God, might most simply call the Conquest Theory. the king became merely the descendant of the This concept was hardly a novelty in the "principal ruffian of some restless gang" who at post-Napoleonic era. It was, rather, a common- one time managed to usurp the natural rights of place of 18th century liberal radicalism. Thomas men. Paine employed it to attack the legitimacy of the Similar notions were developed just prior to British monarch in his Common Sense of 1776. the outbreak of the French Revolution by Abbe Paine's wry comments about French bastards Sieyes in his tract, What is the Third Estate? and armed banditti may have lacked scholarly Amid the breakdown of the late medieval and restraint, but they were an effective piece of absolutist order in France, Sieyes appealed to propaganda in the American Revolutionary the growing sense of nationhood within French struggle.lZ1 society. Sieyes defined the essence of this Briefly, the conquest theory traced the origin nationhood as the existence of a community of contemporary European class structure to the living in a common order under a common barbarian invasions which swept over the law.lS1This emphasis upon a common order and Roman Empire and imposed upon the indige- a common law was in stark contradiction to the nous peoples of western Europe and the political theory and practices of absolutism. In Mediterranean world a barbarian military the theory of the absolutist state, society hierarchy from whence there developed the consisted of innumerable legally autonomous royal and noble classes of medieval and modern groups variously called estates, corps, orders or Europe. Coincidental with this was the rise of classes. Society was divided vertically and Christianity and the consequent elaboration of a horizontally into these particular groups, each religious hierarchy, the higher orders of which having its own functional monopoly, its own were rapidly co-opted by the secular aristocracy. status, and its own privileges @rivatae Ieges or For centurie~,the servile masses groaned under private laws); hence the opposition between the tyranny of the feudal system; however, the "particular orders" and "common order", various rivalries of kings and lords and religious "private laws" and "common law". Over all and secular factions allowed opportunities for the king enjoyed absolute power, at least in the growth and reassertion of the productive theory. Each particular corps or group had the classes. In France, the growing importance of right to counsel the king in matters which were these classes received legal sanction in the germane to its interests. In turn the king recognition of the Third Estate as one of the dispensed justice.161 three great orders of the realm. It was in a It was the obvious breakdown of this critical examination of these origins of the particularist and feudal view of society towards structure of their society that the radicals of the which Sieyes aimed his arguments. He noted 1 THE SOCIAL ANALYSIS OFTHREE EARLY 19TH CENTURY FRENCH LIBERALS 47 that it was the Third Estate which performed all development of those faculties across the course the essential functions of society, meaning here of human history would reveal those laws and production and commerce. The feudal view make it possible to trace the probable future perhaps fit the time when the Third Estate was course of the race.lgl Both Condorcet's emphasis merely the servile horde which existed only to on the scientific method and his general scheme provide the sustenance of the warrior and for the development of civilization were to have clerical classes. However, with the growth of great influence among the liberals of - the arts, of industry and of commerce, the Third post-Napoleonic era. Estate had grown to become the largest, the In the period stretching from the American strongest, and most vital portion of society. revolution to the restoration of the Bourbons in French society was no longer the medieval France, there was general recognition, through- commonwealth of knights and priests and serfs, out the Western world, of the great progress but a modern nation based upon industry and which had been attained through the develop- commerce, and the Third Estate was that ment of the physical sciences and technology. nation; nothing outside the Third Estate could There was also, after the style of Condorcet, a share in that nationhood. "The Third Estate growing confidence that those same methods which had been reduced to nothing, has when applied to the phenomena of society and reacquired, through its industry, a part of what government would bring about a great flowering the injustice of the stronger had taken from it." of the social sciences and a consequent ration- The nobility was no longer the "monstrous alization of society.
Recommended publications
  • Industrial Society and the State: French and German Perspectives
    Thomas HopkinsThomas Hopkins Page 1 [email protected] Between Restoration and Revolution, National Constitutions and Global Law: an alternative view on the European century 1815-1914. Thomas Hopkins Research Proposal Industrial Society and the State: French and German Perspectives The project I wish to outline is concerned on a general level with the problems involved in fitting together the concept of an exchange economy, potentially bounded by nothing save the projected extent of a global market, with that of the nation-state. This I take to be one way of formulating what is at stake in confronting the ‘language of economic efficiency’ with that of ‘social solidarity’, the second of the fields of tension identified for investigation as part of the overall research agenda. More particularly, I would like to re-examine some of the difficulties involved in framing the ‘social question’ in the 1830s and 1840s, and in so doing to ask why the concept of class should have proved so disruptive for political, social, legal and economic theory. My aim is not to rehearse the history of labour movements or to retread the well-worn path following the development of Marxism. Rather it is to place under scrutiny the apparent elective affinity between certain ways of thinking about economic development and the idea of representative government. This, I hope, should yield a more nuanced sense of what is in play in debates about the role of social legislation and the prospects for effective political management of the economy. I envisage two points of departure for the project.
    [Show full text]
  • Bibliography on World Conflict and Peace
    DOCUMENT RESUME ED 097 246 SO 007 806 AUTHOR Boulding, Elise; Passions, J. Robert TITLE Bibliography on World Conflict and Peace. INSTITUTION American Sociological Association, Washington, D.C.; Consortium on Peace Research, Education, and Development, Boulder, Colo. PUB DATE Aug 74 NOT? 82p. AVAILABLE FROMBibliography Project, c/o Dorothy Carson, Institute of Behavioral Science, University of Colorado, Boulder, Colorado 80302 ($2.50; make checks payable to Boulding Projects Fund) EDRS PRICE MF-$0.75 BC Not Available from !DRS. PLUS POSTAGE DESCRIPTORS Bibliographies; *Conflict Resolution; Development; Disarmament; Environment; *Futures (of Society); *Global Approach; Instructional Materials; International Education; international Law; International Organizations; *Peace; Political Science; Social Action; Systems Approach; *World Affairs IDENTIFIERS *Nonviolence ABSTRACT This bibliography is compiled primarily in response to the needs of teachers and students in the new field of conflict and peace studies, defined as the analysis of the characteristics of the total world social system which make peace more probable. The introduction includes some suggestions on how to use the bibliography, sources of literature on war/peace studies, and a request to users for criticisms and suggestions. Books, monographs, research reports, journal articles, or educational materials were included when they were:(1) related to conflict management at every social level,(2) relevant to nonviolence, and (3) classic statements in an academic specialization, such as foreign policy studies when of particular significance for conflict studies. A subject guide to the main categories of the bibliography lists 18 major topics with various numbered subdivisions. Th%. main body of the bibliography lists citations by author and keys this to the topic subdivisions.
    [Show full text]
  • 1. the Damnation of Economics
    Notes 1. The Damnation of Economics 1. One example of vice-regal patronage of anti-economics is Canada’s ‘Governor General’s Award for Non-Fiction’. In 1995 this honour was bestowed upon John Raulston Saul’s anti-economic polemic The Unconscious Civilization (published in 1996). A taste of Saul’s wisdom: ‘Over the last quarter-century economics has raised itself to the level of a scientific profession and more or less foisted a Nobel Prize in its own honour onto the Nobel committee thanks to annual financing from a bank. Yet over the same 25 years, economics has been spectacularly unsuc- cessful in its attempts to apply its models and theories to the reality of our civili- sation’ (Saul 1996, p. 4). See Pusey (1991) and Cox (1995) for examples of patronage of anti-economics by Research Councils and Broadcasting Corporations. 2. Another example of economists’ ‘stillness’: the economists of 1860 did not join the numerous editorial rebukes of Ruskin’s anti-economics tracts (Anthony, 1983). 3. The anti-economist is not to be contrasted with the economist. An economist (that is, a person with a specialist knowledge of economics) may be an anti- economist. The true obverse of anti-economist is ‘philo-economist’: someone who holds that economics is a boon. 4. One may think of economics as a disease (as the anti-economist does), or one may think of economics as diseased. Mark Blaug: ‘Modern economics is “sick” . To para- phrase the title of a popular British musical: “No Reality, Please. We’re Economists”’ (Blaug 1998, p.
    [Show full text]
  • Antonio Rosmini on Property It Showed Itself As a Part of God’S Calling
    Journal of Markets & Morality Volume 7, Number 1 (Spring 2004): 63–97 Copyright © 2004 A Sphere Around Alberto Mingardi Policy Director the Person: Istituto Bruno Leoni (Turin, Italy) Antonio Rosmini and Visiting Fellow Centre for the New Europe on Property* (Brussels, Belgium) Father Antonio Rosmini-Serbati (1797–1855) is an author of growing interest and curiosity to his fellow churchmen, as well as to secular intellectuals, as a philosopher who successfully reconciled reason and faith. Nevertheless, the political nuances of his thought have barely been explored by English-speaking scholars, and even among his Italian followers these have not been fully appre- ciated. This article attempts to present an overview of Rosmini’s political philoso- phy, focusing on his concern for the protection of private property rights and arguing that it is precisely his advocacy of private property that determines his attitude toward the general organization of associated life, government, and democracy. The organization of this investigation consists of four parts. The first pro- vides a brief biographical sketch of Antonio Rosmini. The second tentatively enlists the main influences in the development of Rosmini’s thought as far as politics and economics are concerned. The third is devoted to examining his approach toward property. The fourth examines his definition of social justice in the light of his justification of property. Introduction In this article, I introduce the reader to the figure of Antonio Rosmini, provide a biographical sketch, and subsequently approach his thought on private prop- erty. As a priest and a devout Catholic, religious faith was central to every aspect of Rosmini’s philosophy.
    [Show full text]
  • The Order of the Prophets: Series in Early French Social Science and Socialism
    Hist. Sci., xlviii (2010) THE ORDER OF THE PROPHETS: SERIES IN EARLY FRENCH SOCIAL SCIENCE AND SOCIALISM John Tresch University of Pennsylvania Everything that can be thought by the mind or perceived by the senses is necessarily a series.1 According to the editors of an influential text in the history of social science, “in the first half of the nineteenth century the expression series seemed destined to a great philosophical future”.2 The expression itself seems to encourage speculation on destiny. Elements laid out in a temporal sequence ask to be continued through the addition of subsequent terms. “Series” were particularly prominent in the French Restoration and July Monarchy (1815–48) in works announcing a new social science. For example, the physician and republican conspirator J. P. B. Buchez, a former fol- lower of Henri de Saint-Simon who led a movement of Catholic social reform, made “series” central to his Introduction à la science de l’histoire. Mathematical series show a “progression”, not “a simple succession of unrelated numbers”; in human history, we discover two simultaneous series: “one growing, that of good; one diminishing, that of evil.” The inevitability of positive progress was confirmed by recent findings in physiology, zoology and geology. Correlations between the developmental stages of organisms, species, and the Earth were proof that humanity’s presence in the world “was no accident”, and that “labour, devotion and sacrifice” were part of the “universal order”. The “great law of progress” pointed toward a socialist republic in fulfilment both of scripture and of the promise of 1789.
    [Show full text]
  • Classical Liberalism and the Austrian School
    Classical Liberalism and the Austrian School Classical Liberalism and the Austrian School Ralph Raico Foreword by Jörg Guido Hülsmann Preface by David Gordon LvMI MISES INSTITUTE The cover design by Chad Parish shows the Neptune Fountain, at the Schönbrunn Palace, in Vienna. Copyright © 2012 by the Ludwig von Mises Institute. Permission to reprint in whole or in part is gladly granted, provided full credit is given. Ludwig von Mises Institute 518 West Magnolia Avenue Auburn, Alabama 36832 mises.org ISBN: 978-1-61016-003-2 Dedicated to the memory of the great Ludwig von Mises Table of Contents Foreword by Jörg Guido Hülsmann . ix Preface by David Gordon . xiii Introduction . .xxv 1. Classical Liberalism and the Austrian School . .1 2. Liberalism: True and False . .67 3. Intellectuals and the Marketplace. 111 4. Was Keynes a Liberal? . .149 5. The Conflict of Classes: Liberal vs. Marxist Theories. .183 6. The Centrality of French Liberalism . .219 7. Ludwig von Mises’s Liberalism on Fascism, Democracy, and Imperalism . .255 8. Eugen Richter and the End of German Liberalism. .301 9. Arthur Ekirch on American Militarism . .331 Index. .339 vii Foreword “History looks backward into the past, but the lesson it teaches concerns things to come. It does not teach indolent quietism; it rouses man to emulate the deeds of earlier generations.” Ludwig von Mises1 The present book contains a collection of essays written through- out the past twenty years. I read virtually all of them when they were first published. They have been a central part of my education in the history of liberalism and of the Austrian School of economics, and I consider myself privileged indeed to have encountered Professor Raico and his work early on in my intellectual development.
    [Show full text]
  • Sismondi and His French Contemporaries
    1 SISMONDI AND HIS FRENCH CONTEMPORARIES HELMUT O. PAPPE I If Marx, himself an outstanding historian of economic doctrines, regarded Sismondi in 1848 as the head of a school of thought established in both France and England and, if Lenin still dreaded the influences of Sismondi's disciples half a century later, it does not appear evidently convincing that his work should have been completely neglected in the France of his day. On the contrary, there is, in the contemporaneous literature, ample attestation of the fact that he was deemed to be a very important figure indeed. Political economy as a scholarly discipline was still in its early stages at the time, primarily concerned with the school of the Physiocrats or 'Economists' from Quesnay and Turgot to Dupont de Nemours, and with the classical political economy of the followers of Adam Smith. There were soon attempts at taking stock of what had been achieved by precursors and recent writers. In England, John McCulloch sketched an historical account in 1824 which was soon translated into French by Sismondi's teacher Pierre Prevost.1 In France, after some early sketches in the 1770s, by Dupont de Nemours in his brilliant periodical Éphémérides du Citoyen, Jean-Baptiste Say gave an historical account in his Cours complet d'economie pretique of 1829.2 However, it was left to an Italian writer, Count Guiseppe Pecchio, to write the most systematic and influential History of Political Economy in Italy3 which was to serve as model to the French writers on the subject in the late 1830s.
    [Show full text]
  • French Historians in the Nineteenth Century
    French Historians in the Nineteenth Century French Historians in the Nineteenth Century: Providence and History By F.L. van Holthoon French Historians in the Nineteenth Century: Providence and History By F.L. van Holthoon This book first published 2019 Cambridge Scholars Publishing Lady Stephenson Library, Newcastle upon Tyne, NE6 2PA, UK British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library Copyright © 2019 by F.L. van Holthoon All rights for this book reserved. No part of this book may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise, without the prior permission of the copyright owner. ISBN (10): 1-5275-3409-X ISBN (13): 978-1-5275-3409-4 To: Francisca van Holthoon-Richards TABLE OF CONTENTS Acknowledgments ...................................................................................... ix Chapter One ................................................................................................. 1 Introduction Part 1 Chapter Two .............................................................................................. 10 Under the Wings of Doctrinaire Liberalism Chapter Three ............................................................................................ 12 Germaine de Staël on Napoleon Chapter Four .............................................................................................. 23 Le Moment Guizot, François Guizot Chapter Five .............................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Jeffrey Lionel Gossman
    1 JEFFREY LIONEL GOSSMAN Born in Glasgow, Scotland, 1929. U.S. Citizen. Married to Eva Reinitz. One child: Janice Gossman- Coppola, art teacher, Clark N.J. High School Education 1946-51 University of Glasgow. M.A. Hons (1st Class) in French and German 1951-52 University of Paris. Diplôme d'études supérieures. Thesis directed by Jean Frappier 1954-57 St. Antony's College, Oxford. D. Phil. (awarded 1958). Thesis directed by Jean Seznec National Service 1952-54 Royal Navy, then Army. Joint Services School for Languages (Cambridge). 1st Class Interpretership in Russian Scholarships and Fellowships 1946-51 Awarded University Bursary, University of Glasgow (5th place in General Bursary Competition) 1951-52 Boursier du gouvernement français 1954-57 Faulds Fellowship from University of Glasgow to St.Antony's College, Oxford 1969-70 American Council of Learned Societies Study Fellowship 1978-79 National Endowment for the Humanities Fellowship. Visitor, Institute for Advanced Study, Princeton 1983 Visitor, Institute for Advanced Study, Princeton (Spring) 1983 Pro Helvetia Society grant for summer research in Basle (Summer) 1986-87 National Endowment for the Humanities Fellowship Teaching 1948-49 Assistant d'anglais, Collège Diderot, Lille 1948 Lecteur d'anglais, University of Lille (fall term) 1957-58 Assistant Lecturer, Department of French Studies, University of Glasgow 1958-62 Assistant Professor, Department of Romance Languages, The Johns Hopkins University 1962-66 Associate Professor, JHU 1966-76 Professor, JHU 1976-99 Professor, Department of Romance Languages and Literatures, Princeton University (retired June 1999) 1984 Seminar director, Folger and Newberry Libraries (fall semester) 1991 Visiting Professor, University of Pennsylvania (spring semester) 1992 Director, Alumni College on “The Idea of Europe,” Princeton University.
    [Show full text]
  • Jules Michelet: National History, Biography, Autobiography1
    JULES MICHELET: NATIONAL HISTORY, BIOGRAPHY, AUTOBIOGRAPHY1 By Lionel Gossman Echoes of lived experience are to be found in the work of many historians. Writing about the past is usually also, indirectly, a way of writing about the present. The past is read through the present and the present through a vision of the past. It has often been noted, for instance, that the author’s reaction to the world around him is reflected in the work of Jacob Burckhardt, the great nineteenth-century Swiss historian, who was born into one of the leading patrician families of the old free city of Basel at a moment when these merchant families, rulers of the little city-state since the Renaissance, were coming under increasingly uncomfortable pressure from the political movements of the time. As examples of such reflections of personal experience one could cite Burckhardt’s often severe criticism, in the Griechische Kulturgeschichte, of the ancient Greek polis and in particular of ancient democracy, and his portraits of talented and distinguished citizens who either fled their city after the coming of democratic rule or, like Diogenes and Epicurus, took the path of inner exile. In Burckhardt’s writing, however, the personal experience is not intentional or programmatic. With Michelet, in contrast – whose work, as it happens, Burckhardt knew and admired – history is explicitly presented, in the historian’s reflection on his craft, not only as a form of bio-graphy, of writing about a living being (France), but of auto-bio-graphy, of writing about a living being that is identified as oneself.
    [Show full text]
  • The Formation and Progress of the Tiers État, Or Third Estate in France Vol
    The Online Library of Liberty A Project Of Liberty Fund, Inc. Augustin Thierry, The Formation and Progress of the Tiers État, or Third Estate in France vol. 2 [1856] The Online Library Of Liberty This E-Book (PDF format) is published by Liberty Fund, Inc., a private, non-profit, educational foundation established in 1960 to encourage study of the ideal of a society of free and responsible individuals. 2010 was the 50th anniversary year of the founding of Liberty Fund. It is part of the Online Library of Liberty web site http://oll.libertyfund.org, which was established in 2004 in order to further the educational goals of Liberty Fund, Inc. To find out more about the author or title, to use the site's powerful search engine, to see other titles in other formats (HTML, facsimile PDF), or to make use of the hundreds of essays, educational aids, and study guides, please visit the OLL web site. This title is also part of the Portable Library of Liberty DVD which contains over 1,000 books and quotes about liberty and power, and is available free of charge upon request. The cuneiform inscription that appears in the logo and serves as a design element in all Liberty Fund books and web sites is the earliest-known written appearance of the word “freedom” (amagi), or “liberty.” It is taken from a clay document written about 2300 B.C. in the Sumerian city-state of Lagash, in present day Iraq. To find out more about Liberty Fund, Inc., or the Online Library of Liberty Project, please contact the Director at [email protected].
    [Show full text]
  • Did Marx "Turn" the Original Class Struggle? Prepared for the EEA
    Did Marx "Turn" the Original Class Struggle? Prepared for the EEA 2011 Meetings, Marxist Theory and Philosophy Panels Cameron M. Weber New School for Social Research, FIT/SUNY and St. John‟s University [email protected] cameroneconomics.com Abstract In this paper I compare Marx and Engels‟ theory of the class struggle as being between Capital and Labor with that developed by the French Classical Liberals during the Restoration (1815 - 1830) as being between Free Man and the State. We trace Marx's awareness of, and respect for, some of this earlier work (especially that of Augustin Thierry) as found in Marx and Engels‟ personal correspondence. We also critique examples in Marx and Engels‟ published writings which show that these later writers might have „turned‟ the original classical Liberal social theory due to Marx‟s philosophical pre-disposition towards the Hegelian "Other". I propose that it is these Hegelian roots which require that the classical economists‟ notion of an economic surplus becomes a 'social' surplus in order to give cohesion to a reunification of man with his alienated self. We find many parallels in the two social theories, including historical movement, productive and unproductive labor, exploitation and a march of history towards human freedom. Note: Some of the ideas in this paper were originally presented at the Summer Institute for the Preservation of the History of Economic Thought at University of Richmond, VA, in June 2010. This current version tries to address suggestions made by Duncan Foley, Gary Mongiovi and Mishan Hing at the New School and researches more deeply into the historical context of Le Censeur Européen writers.
    [Show full text]