Sismondi and His French Contemporaries

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Sismondi and His French Contemporaries 1 SISMONDI AND HIS FRENCH CONTEMPORARIES HELMUT O. PAPPE I If Marx, himself an outstanding historian of economic doctrines, regarded Sismondi in 1848 as the head of a school of thought established in both France and England and, if Lenin still dreaded the influences of Sismondi's disciples half a century later, it does not appear evidently convincing that his work should have been completely neglected in the France of his day. On the contrary, there is, in the contemporaneous literature, ample attestation of the fact that he was deemed to be a very important figure indeed. Political economy as a scholarly discipline was still in its early stages at the time, primarily concerned with the school of the Physiocrats or 'Economists' from Quesnay and Turgot to Dupont de Nemours, and with the classical political economy of the followers of Adam Smith. There were soon attempts at taking stock of what had been achieved by precursors and recent writers. In England, John McCulloch sketched an historical account in 1824 which was soon translated into French by Sismondi's teacher Pierre Prevost.1 In France, after some early sketches in the 1770s, by Dupont de Nemours in his brilliant periodical Éphémérides du Citoyen, Jean-Baptiste Say gave an historical account in his Cours complet d'economie pretique of 1829.2 However, it was left to an Italian writer, Count Guiseppe Pecchio, to write the most systematic and influential History of Political Economy in Italy3 which was to serve as model to the French writers on the subject in the late 1830s. The publication of such a pioneering work in Italy was not fortuitous. Pecchio was able to make use of the collection in 50 volumes of the works of Italian classical economists by Custodi between 1803 and 1816, containing reprints of their works as well as biographical sketches; J-B. Say's historical precis was based upon Custodi as well; in particular, the study of the Neapolitan Antonio Serra, claimed to be the founder of the science of political economy, may have brought home, or at least confirmed, to Say the significance of the productive power of industry as compared with agriculture and commerce.4 Another Italian author, given special attention by Pecchio was Giammaria Ortes (1713-1790), an author who condemned the 'science of enrichment' as being fraudulent as well as inefficient because of its neglect of an equitable distribution. These were ideas close to Sismondi's thinking. In point of fact, Pecchio was a 1 J.R.McCulloch A Discourse on the rise, Progress, Peculiar Objects and Importance of Political Economy, 1824 2 'Histoire abregee des progres de l'economie politique'. 3 Storia della economia publica in Italia, 1829; French translation: Histoire de l'economie en Italie - Abrege critique des economistes Italiens, Paris 1830 2 devoted follower of Sismondi whose Nouveaux Principes he had closely analysed as early as 1819 in three review articles published in Italy before he had to seek refuge as an exile in Spain, Greece and, finally in 1828, in Brighton, England, where he died in 1835.5 Pecchio gave more than a mere history of doctrines; he took account of their historical context as well. He contrasted the socio-political conditions prevailing in Italy and England respectively; in the latter, the achievement of civil liberty preceded the science of political economy, whereas in the former, political economy was called upon to help bring about modern liberty. Italian economists had the edge on monetary questions, Free Ports and banking, all of which were part of their national heritage. On the other hand, English authors had immediate experience of the division of labour and of colonies. It was in England that a precise methodology and vocabulary was evolved as well as a hypothetical treatment of purely economic phenomena. On the debit side, however, was the pursuit of mere riches and personal profit as the decisive criteria, contrasted with the wider, if more vague, perspectives of Italian economists who took into account extra-economic considerations such as public welfare, la felicita pubbica, actually a blend of the scholastic Public Good with utilitarian happiness. Italian economists had to adapt their teaching to the less advanced conditions of the Italian economy. They were more concerned with creating a political and structural framework, within which the initiative of entrepreneurs could be released, than with the finer details of laissez- faire as it was practically feasible under the sway of already existing British legal and commercial traditions. There was a distinctively neo-mercantilist element in Pecchio's theory of development which was in keeping with the teaching of his great Italian precursors Pietro Verri and Cesare Beccaria. In his analysis, Pecchio did not do justice to the political economy of the Scottish eighteenth century.6 What he meant to expose was the English doctrine of Ricardo and his followers, especially John McCulloch; he overrated the significance of the Ricardians who represented a minority among British economists. Pecchio's History made a momentous impact on French writing of the 1830s, that is, soon after Sismondi's Nouveaux Principes had seen their second edition in 1827. The pre-eminent French economic historians of the 1830s were the Viscount Alban de Villeneuve-Bargemont and Adolphe Blanqui. 4 Breve Trattato delle cause che possono far abondare li regni d'oro e argente... etc, Napoli 1613. McCulloch, on the other hand, deprecated Serra, probably because he knew only the (misleading) title of the book, see Pecchio, op.cit.p.76, also Schumpeter, op.cit. on Serra. 5 More about Pecchio will be said in the chapter dealing with Sismondi's role in the Italian intellectual Risorgimento. 6 Hutcheson and Hume, in the Stoic tradition, regarded beneficence and benevolence as the motives of virtuous action; Adam Smith distinguished between natural and artificial virtues which were motivated by benevolence and justice respectively. 3 Both published Histories of Political Economy in the second half of the decade. However, Villeneuve-Bargemont expressed views on the history of economic thought first in his massive 3- volume work Christian Political Economy, Studies of the nature and causes of Pauperism in France and Europe and of the measures to alleviate and to prevent it.7 In his eyes, Christian Political Economy epitomized 'a new school' which had come into being under the leadership primarily of Malthus and Sismondi, a school which was made distinctive by a general similarity of principles and, in particular, a common hostile reaction to the most important principles of Adam Smith. The members of this school were said to be the first to have brought to light the pernicious consequences of laissez faire for the labouring classes. Villeneuve-Bargemont's political History of Political Economy appeared in 1839; though it was preceded in 1837 by Adolphe Blanqui's History of Political Economy in Europe, a more penetrating and systematic work, it met with sufficient success to justify a second edition in 1841.8 Setting out from Bacon, Locke, the Encyclopedie, and Rousseau, and using Burke for his motto, the author employed his narrative to foster his ideal of a harmonic consensus of the principles of morality, legislation and political economy (agriculture, commerce, and industry). Following Pecchio, he found the English classical school wanting in this respect. He censored it as the product of 'harsh Machiavellianism', an 'inhuman act of calculation', leading to disastrous consequences for the general welfare of the people, unless corrected by legislative intervention. Instead of taking moral and religious considerations into account, Adam Smith was said to have based his thought on the theory of the production of riches and the egoistic self-interest of individuals. He had left out of consideration the question of equal distribution which had come to present the central problem of the new French school of political economy. A reaction recognising the weaknesses inherent in Smith's theory had become inevitable in the light of the economic crises experienced by the emerging industrial society. While most leading French economists were followers of Jean-Baptiste Say, who had adapted Smith's thought to industrial reality, Villeneuve said that 'it was Sismondi (an author equally acclaimed by France, Italy and Switzerland) who had opened up a vaster horizon than Smith by defining political economy as the study of the means by which the greatest number of people, in a given state, can participate to the highest degree in physical well-being as far as it depends on government... Switzerland can rightly take pride in a political economist whose works have made the most important contribution to the revelation of, and the fight against, the dire consequences of 7 M.le Vic. Alban de Villeneuve-Bargemont, Economie Politique Chretienne. Recherches sur la nature et les causes du Pauoerisme en France et en Europe et sur les moyens de soulager et le prevenir. 3 tomes, Paris 1834 8 Histoire de l'economie politique, Bruxelles 1839; 2nd ed. 2 vols. Paris 1841 4 the English political economy, we are speaking of M. Simonde de Sismondi'.9 According to this new conception, Sismondi holds 'that two elements must always be taken together into consideration: the increase of happiness in depth, and its diffusion among all classes. He set his sight on wealth because it profits the population; he examines population because it participates in wealth... it is thus that political economy becomes foremost the theory of beneficence... A new political school has constituted itself... which has detached itself in several important points from the abstract theories of Adam Smith and his disciples.' Villeneuve-Bargemont's image of Smith was evidently that of Pecchio. It did not do justice to Smith's own conception of benevolence as the motive force, together with justice, of the human virtues.10 However, it bears witness of the towering influence in France of the teaching of Sismondi and J-B.
Recommended publications
  • Industrial Society and the State: French and German Perspectives
    Thomas HopkinsThomas Hopkins Page 1 [email protected] Between Restoration and Revolution, National Constitutions and Global Law: an alternative view on the European century 1815-1914. Thomas Hopkins Research Proposal Industrial Society and the State: French and German Perspectives The project I wish to outline is concerned on a general level with the problems involved in fitting together the concept of an exchange economy, potentially bounded by nothing save the projected extent of a global market, with that of the nation-state. This I take to be one way of formulating what is at stake in confronting the ‘language of economic efficiency’ with that of ‘social solidarity’, the second of the fields of tension identified for investigation as part of the overall research agenda. More particularly, I would like to re-examine some of the difficulties involved in framing the ‘social question’ in the 1830s and 1840s, and in so doing to ask why the concept of class should have proved so disruptive for political, social, legal and economic theory. My aim is not to rehearse the history of labour movements or to retread the well-worn path following the development of Marxism. Rather it is to place under scrutiny the apparent elective affinity between certain ways of thinking about economic development and the idea of representative government. This, I hope, should yield a more nuanced sense of what is in play in debates about the role of social legislation and the prospects for effective political management of the economy. I envisage two points of departure for the project.
    [Show full text]
  • Bibliography on World Conflict and Peace
    DOCUMENT RESUME ED 097 246 SO 007 806 AUTHOR Boulding, Elise; Passions, J. Robert TITLE Bibliography on World Conflict and Peace. INSTITUTION American Sociological Association, Washington, D.C.; Consortium on Peace Research, Education, and Development, Boulder, Colo. PUB DATE Aug 74 NOT? 82p. AVAILABLE FROMBibliography Project, c/o Dorothy Carson, Institute of Behavioral Science, University of Colorado, Boulder, Colorado 80302 ($2.50; make checks payable to Boulding Projects Fund) EDRS PRICE MF-$0.75 BC Not Available from !DRS. PLUS POSTAGE DESCRIPTORS Bibliographies; *Conflict Resolution; Development; Disarmament; Environment; *Futures (of Society); *Global Approach; Instructional Materials; International Education; international Law; International Organizations; *Peace; Political Science; Social Action; Systems Approach; *World Affairs IDENTIFIERS *Nonviolence ABSTRACT This bibliography is compiled primarily in response to the needs of teachers and students in the new field of conflict and peace studies, defined as the analysis of the characteristics of the total world social system which make peace more probable. The introduction includes some suggestions on how to use the bibliography, sources of literature on war/peace studies, and a request to users for criticisms and suggestions. Books, monographs, research reports, journal articles, or educational materials were included when they were:(1) related to conflict management at every social level,(2) relevant to nonviolence, and (3) classic statements in an academic specialization, such as foreign policy studies when of particular significance for conflict studies. A subject guide to the main categories of the bibliography lists 18 major topics with various numbered subdivisions. Th%. main body of the bibliography lists citations by author and keys this to the topic subdivisions.
    [Show full text]
  • 1. the Damnation of Economics
    Notes 1. The Damnation of Economics 1. One example of vice-regal patronage of anti-economics is Canada’s ‘Governor General’s Award for Non-Fiction’. In 1995 this honour was bestowed upon John Raulston Saul’s anti-economic polemic The Unconscious Civilization (published in 1996). A taste of Saul’s wisdom: ‘Over the last quarter-century economics has raised itself to the level of a scientific profession and more or less foisted a Nobel Prize in its own honour onto the Nobel committee thanks to annual financing from a bank. Yet over the same 25 years, economics has been spectacularly unsuc- cessful in its attempts to apply its models and theories to the reality of our civili- sation’ (Saul 1996, p. 4). See Pusey (1991) and Cox (1995) for examples of patronage of anti-economics by Research Councils and Broadcasting Corporations. 2. Another example of economists’ ‘stillness’: the economists of 1860 did not join the numerous editorial rebukes of Ruskin’s anti-economics tracts (Anthony, 1983). 3. The anti-economist is not to be contrasted with the economist. An economist (that is, a person with a specialist knowledge of economics) may be an anti- economist. The true obverse of anti-economist is ‘philo-economist’: someone who holds that economics is a boon. 4. One may think of economics as a disease (as the anti-economist does), or one may think of economics as diseased. Mark Blaug: ‘Modern economics is “sick” . To para- phrase the title of a popular British musical: “No Reality, Please. We’re Economists”’ (Blaug 1998, p.
    [Show full text]
  • Antonio Rosmini on Property It Showed Itself As a Part of God’S Calling
    Journal of Markets & Morality Volume 7, Number 1 (Spring 2004): 63–97 Copyright © 2004 A Sphere Around Alberto Mingardi Policy Director the Person: Istituto Bruno Leoni (Turin, Italy) Antonio Rosmini and Visiting Fellow Centre for the New Europe on Property* (Brussels, Belgium) Father Antonio Rosmini-Serbati (1797–1855) is an author of growing interest and curiosity to his fellow churchmen, as well as to secular intellectuals, as a philosopher who successfully reconciled reason and faith. Nevertheless, the political nuances of his thought have barely been explored by English-speaking scholars, and even among his Italian followers these have not been fully appre- ciated. This article attempts to present an overview of Rosmini’s political philoso- phy, focusing on his concern for the protection of private property rights and arguing that it is precisely his advocacy of private property that determines his attitude toward the general organization of associated life, government, and democracy. The organization of this investigation consists of four parts. The first pro- vides a brief biographical sketch of Antonio Rosmini. The second tentatively enlists the main influences in the development of Rosmini’s thought as far as politics and economics are concerned. The third is devoted to examining his approach toward property. The fourth examines his definition of social justice in the light of his justification of property. Introduction In this article, I introduce the reader to the figure of Antonio Rosmini, provide a biographical sketch, and subsequently approach his thought on private prop- erty. As a priest and a devout Catholic, religious faith was central to every aspect of Rosmini’s philosophy.
    [Show full text]
  • The Order of the Prophets: Series in Early French Social Science and Socialism
    Hist. Sci., xlviii (2010) THE ORDER OF THE PROPHETS: SERIES IN EARLY FRENCH SOCIAL SCIENCE AND SOCIALISM John Tresch University of Pennsylvania Everything that can be thought by the mind or perceived by the senses is necessarily a series.1 According to the editors of an influential text in the history of social science, “in the first half of the nineteenth century the expression series seemed destined to a great philosophical future”.2 The expression itself seems to encourage speculation on destiny. Elements laid out in a temporal sequence ask to be continued through the addition of subsequent terms. “Series” were particularly prominent in the French Restoration and July Monarchy (1815–48) in works announcing a new social science. For example, the physician and republican conspirator J. P. B. Buchez, a former fol- lower of Henri de Saint-Simon who led a movement of Catholic social reform, made “series” central to his Introduction à la science de l’histoire. Mathematical series show a “progression”, not “a simple succession of unrelated numbers”; in human history, we discover two simultaneous series: “one growing, that of good; one diminishing, that of evil.” The inevitability of positive progress was confirmed by recent findings in physiology, zoology and geology. Correlations between the developmental stages of organisms, species, and the Earth were proof that humanity’s presence in the world “was no accident”, and that “labour, devotion and sacrifice” were part of the “universal order”. The “great law of progress” pointed toward a socialist republic in fulfilment both of scripture and of the promise of 1789.
    [Show full text]
  • Ralph Raico: Champion of Authentic Liberalism Daniel P
    State University of New York College at Buffalo - Buffalo State College Digital Commons at Buffalo State History Theses History and Social Studies Education 12-2012 Ralph Raico: Champion of Authentic Liberalism Daniel P. Stanford [email protected] Advisor Gary Marotta, Ph.D., Professor of History First Reader Gary Marotta, Ph.D., Professor of History Second Reader John D. Abromeit, Ph.D., Assistant Professor of History Department Chair Andrew D. Nicholls, Ph.D., Professor of History To learn more about the History and Social Studies Education Department and its educational programs, research, and resources, go to http://history.buffalostate.edu/. Recommended Citation Stanford, Daniel P., "Ralph Raico: Champion of Authentic Liberalism" (2012). History Theses. Paper 13. Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.buffalostate.edu/history_theses Part of the European History Commons, Intellectual History Commons, and the United States History Commons Ralph Raico: Champion of Authentic Liberalism by Daniel P. Stanford An Abstract of a Thesis in History Submitted in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of Master of Arts December 2012 College at Buffalo State University of New York Department of History 1 ABSTRACT OF THESIS Ralph Raico: Champion of Authentic Liberalism This paper explores the intellectual life and writings of Professor Emeritus in History at Buffalo State College, Ralph Raico. The central thesis seeks to portray Professor Raico as the great modern libertarian revisionist historian, and the great modern champion of historical, classical liberalism. More broadly, the work attempts to solidify Professor Raico’s reputation as a major figure in the modern American libertarian movement. Raico’s intellectual foundations are fully developed, beginning from grade school at Bronx High School of Science, to his attendance of Ludwig von Mises’s New York University seminar, to his P.h.D.
    [Show full text]
  • A More Elevated Patriotism
    Martti Koskenniemi & Ville Kari Revised draft 03-03-2017 A MORE ELEVATED PATRIOTISM The Emergence of International and Comparative Law (19th century) Martti Koskenniemi & Ville Kari Contents I. Introduction: L’esprit d’internationalité in 1873 ............................................. 2 II. Local traditions of legal cosmopolitanism ........................................................ 3 A. Germany: Die Naturgesetze der bürgerlichen Gesellschaft....................................................5 B. France: Comparison as reform ................................................................................................. 7 C. Britain: The view from Empire ............................................................................................... 11 III. Attitudes towards the Non-European World ................................................ 13 A. European colonialism ............................................................................................................. 13 B. Non-European reception ........................................................................................................ 15 IV. International Disciplines in 1900 ................................................................. 17 A. International Law .................................................................................................................... 18 B. Comparative Law .................................................................................................................... 20 Conclusion ..........................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Classical Liberalism and the Austrian School
    Classical Liberalism and the Austrian School Classical Liberalism and the Austrian School Ralph Raico Foreword by Jörg Guido Hülsmann Preface by David Gordon LvMI MISES INSTITUTE The cover design by Chad Parish shows the Neptune Fountain, at the Schönbrunn Palace, in Vienna. Copyright © 2012 by the Ludwig von Mises Institute. Permission to reprint in whole or in part is gladly granted, provided full credit is given. Ludwig von Mises Institute 518 West Magnolia Avenue Auburn, Alabama 36832 mises.org ISBN: 978-1-61016-003-2 Dedicated to the memory of the great Ludwig von Mises Table of Contents Foreword by Jörg Guido Hülsmann . ix Preface by David Gordon . xiii Introduction . .xxv 1. Classical Liberalism and the Austrian School . .1 2. Liberalism: True and False . .67 3. Intellectuals and the Marketplace. 111 4. Was Keynes a Liberal? . .149 5. The Conflict of Classes: Liberal vs. Marxist Theories. .183 6. The Centrality of French Liberalism . .219 7. Ludwig von Mises’s Liberalism on Fascism, Democracy, and Imperalism . .255 8. Eugen Richter and the End of German Liberalism. .301 9. Arthur Ekirch on American Militarism . .331 Index. .339 vii Foreword “History looks backward into the past, but the lesson it teaches concerns things to come. It does not teach indolent quietism; it rouses man to emulate the deeds of earlier generations.” Ludwig von Mises1 The present book contains a collection of essays written through- out the past twenty years. I read virtually all of them when they were first published. They have been a central part of my education in the history of liberalism and of the Austrian School of economics, and I consider myself privileged indeed to have encountered Professor Raico and his work early on in my intellectual development.
    [Show full text]
  • French Historians in the Nineteenth Century
    French Historians in the Nineteenth Century French Historians in the Nineteenth Century: Providence and History By F.L. van Holthoon French Historians in the Nineteenth Century: Providence and History By F.L. van Holthoon This book first published 2019 Cambridge Scholars Publishing Lady Stephenson Library, Newcastle upon Tyne, NE6 2PA, UK British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library Copyright © 2019 by F.L. van Holthoon All rights for this book reserved. No part of this book may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise, without the prior permission of the copyright owner. ISBN (10): 1-5275-3409-X ISBN (13): 978-1-5275-3409-4 To: Francisca van Holthoon-Richards TABLE OF CONTENTS Acknowledgments ...................................................................................... ix Chapter One ................................................................................................. 1 Introduction Part 1 Chapter Two .............................................................................................. 10 Under the Wings of Doctrinaire Liberalism Chapter Three ............................................................................................ 12 Germaine de Staël on Napoleon Chapter Four .............................................................................................. 23 Le Moment Guizot, François Guizot Chapter Five .............................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Areas of Expertise and Scholarly Activity (PDF)
    Areas of my Expertise and Scholarly Activity David M. Hart Date: 23 Oct. 2019 Summary I have expertise in the following areas: I. Website Design and the display of Digital Texts: 1. the design of a sophisticated, award-winning academic website for the storage, manipulation, and distribution of complex texts 2. the design of search and citation tools to assist scholars in making use of the online texts in their research 3. the creation of metadata to organise the online material and to show the interconnections between the texts and authors 4. the creation of educational resources to assist teachers and students in understanding the texts II. The Great Books of Liberty: 1. the organisation and presentation of texts which are part of the “great books”, in particular the subset of these which are known as “the great books of liberty” 2. the creation of teaching and study guides in order to help readers understand the texts 3. the creation of a forum for academic experts in the great books to discuss these texts and make this discussion available to professors and students in multiple formats III. The History of the Classical Liberal Tradition I am an active researcher in several fields, including 1. the history of the classical liberal tradition with a focus on the 17th century English Levellers, 19th century French political economy, and American radical individualists 2. the history of economic thought 3. classical liberal class analysis 4. the politics of art and film This research has produced the following: 1. several collections of the works of unjustly neglected political and economic thinkers, including Frédéric Bastiat, Gustave de Molinari, James Mill, Lysander Spooner, Thomas Gordon, and a multi-volume collection of 17th century Leveller tracts 2.
    [Show full text]
  • Jeffrey Lionel Gossman
    1 JEFFREY LIONEL GOSSMAN Born in Glasgow, Scotland, 1929. U.S. Citizen. Married to Eva Reinitz. One child: Janice Gossman- Coppola, art teacher, Clark N.J. High School Education 1946-51 University of Glasgow. M.A. Hons (1st Class) in French and German 1951-52 University of Paris. Diplôme d'études supérieures. Thesis directed by Jean Frappier 1954-57 St. Antony's College, Oxford. D. Phil. (awarded 1958). Thesis directed by Jean Seznec National Service 1952-54 Royal Navy, then Army. Joint Services School for Languages (Cambridge). 1st Class Interpretership in Russian Scholarships and Fellowships 1946-51 Awarded University Bursary, University of Glasgow (5th place in General Bursary Competition) 1951-52 Boursier du gouvernement français 1954-57 Faulds Fellowship from University of Glasgow to St.Antony's College, Oxford 1969-70 American Council of Learned Societies Study Fellowship 1978-79 National Endowment for the Humanities Fellowship. Visitor, Institute for Advanced Study, Princeton 1983 Visitor, Institute for Advanced Study, Princeton (Spring) 1983 Pro Helvetia Society grant for summer research in Basle (Summer) 1986-87 National Endowment for the Humanities Fellowship Teaching 1948-49 Assistant d'anglais, Collège Diderot, Lille 1948 Lecteur d'anglais, University of Lille (fall term) 1957-58 Assistant Lecturer, Department of French Studies, University of Glasgow 1958-62 Assistant Professor, Department of Romance Languages, The Johns Hopkins University 1962-66 Associate Professor, JHU 1966-76 Professor, JHU 1976-99 Professor, Department of Romance Languages and Literatures, Princeton University (retired June 1999) 1984 Seminar director, Folger and Newberry Libraries (fall semester) 1991 Visiting Professor, University of Pennsylvania (spring semester) 1992 Director, Alumni College on “The Idea of Europe,” Princeton University.
    [Show full text]
  • Jules Michelet: National History, Biography, Autobiography1
    JULES MICHELET: NATIONAL HISTORY, BIOGRAPHY, AUTOBIOGRAPHY1 By Lionel Gossman Echoes of lived experience are to be found in the work of many historians. Writing about the past is usually also, indirectly, a way of writing about the present. The past is read through the present and the present through a vision of the past. It has often been noted, for instance, that the author’s reaction to the world around him is reflected in the work of Jacob Burckhardt, the great nineteenth-century Swiss historian, who was born into one of the leading patrician families of the old free city of Basel at a moment when these merchant families, rulers of the little city-state since the Renaissance, were coming under increasingly uncomfortable pressure from the political movements of the time. As examples of such reflections of personal experience one could cite Burckhardt’s often severe criticism, in the Griechische Kulturgeschichte, of the ancient Greek polis and in particular of ancient democracy, and his portraits of talented and distinguished citizens who either fled their city after the coming of democratic rule or, like Diogenes and Epicurus, took the path of inner exile. In Burckhardt’s writing, however, the personal experience is not intentional or programmatic. With Michelet, in contrast – whose work, as it happens, Burckhardt knew and admired – history is explicitly presented, in the historian’s reflection on his craft, not only as a form of bio-graphy, of writing about a living being (France), but of auto-bio-graphy, of writing about a living being that is identified as oneself.
    [Show full text]