<<

Armenian Journal of Public Policy Volume3,No.1 March2008

LOOKING FORWARD : THE GLOBAL COMPETITIVENESS OF THE ARMENIAN ECONOMY CONTENTS

David Joulfaian Guest Editor’s Note

Mher Baghramyan and Vahram Ghushchyan Implications of Armenian Dram Appreciation for the Competitiveness of Armenian IT, Tourism, and Food Processing Industries

Vahe Heboyan and Lewell F. Gunter Exchange Rate Dynamics in

Era Dabla-Norris and Holger Floerkemeier Bank Efficiency, Market Structure, and Foreign Ownership: What Determines Banking Spreads in Armenia?

Karen Grigorian and Vahram Stepanyan Productivity and Sources of Enterprise Level Efficiency in Armenia

Manuk Hergnyan, Gagik Gabrielyan, and Anna Makaryan Competitiveness of the Armenian Private Sector: Moving to the Next Stage

Kenneth Fortson, Ester Hakobyan, Petrosyan, Anu Rangarajan, and Rebecca Tunstall Armenia’s Millennium Challenge Account: Assessing Impacts on Economic Growth and Poverty Reduction in Rural Armenia

A journal of the Armenian International Policy Research Group

Armenian Journal of Public Policy AjournaloftheArmenianInternationalPolicyResearchGroup

Guest Editor

DavidJoulfaian USDepartmentofTreasury

Editorial Board

RichardBeilock UniversityofFlorida AraKhanjian VenturaCollege ArmanGrigorian SwissFederalInstituteofTechnology GarbisIradian InternationalInstituteofFinance LucigDanielian AmericanUniversityofArmenia ArmineKhachatryan InternationalMonetaryFund

Managing Editor

HeghineManasyan CRRCArmenia/ EurasiaPartnershipFoundation

Assistant to Managing Editor

ArtakGalyan ArmenianInternationalPolicy ResearchGroup Manuscripts, book reviews, and communication with editors should be sent electronically to [email protected]. Published articles will be available online at www.aiprg.net.TheviewsexpressedintheJournalarenottobeconstruedasthoseof theeditorsorthepublisher,theArmenianInternationalPolicyResearchGroup. ThefinancialsupportofEurasiaPartnershipFoundationinArmeniainpublishingthis issueisgratefullyacknowledged. Copyright©2008AIPRG Printedby TOROSPublishing ,,Armenia.

Armenian Journal of Public Policy Volume3,No.1 March2008

LOOKING FORWARD :

THE GLOBAL COMPETITIVENESS OF THE ARMENIAN ECONOMY

CONTENTS

DavidJoulfaian GuestEditor’sNote………………………………………………………………………... MherBaghramyanandVahramGhushchyan ImplicationsofArmenianDramAppreciationfortheCompetitivenessof ArmenianIT,Tourism,andFoodProcessingIndustries………………………………….. VaheHeboyanandLewellF.Gunter ExchangeRateDynamicsinArmenia…………………………………………………….. EraDablaNorrisandHolgerFloerkemeier BankEfficiency,MarketStructure,andForeignOwnership: WhatDeterminesBankingSpreadsinArmenia?...... KarenGrigorianandVahramStepanyan ProductivityandSourcesofEnterpriseLevelEfficiencyinArmenia…………………….. ManukHergnyan,GagikGabrielyan,andAnnaMakaryan CompetitivenessoftheArmenianPrivateSector:MovingtotheNextStage…………….. KennethFortson,EsterHakobyan,AnahitPetrosyan,AnuRangarajan,and RebeccaTunstall Armenia’sMillenniumChallengeAccount:AssessingImpactsonEconomicGrowth andPovertyReductioninRuralArmenia………………………………………………….

Armenian Journal of Public Policy Volume3,No.1 March2008

GUEST EDITOR’S NOTE TheArmenianeconomyexperiencedrapidgrowthoverthepastdecade,inparticular growingatdoubledigitratessince2001.Atthesametimethecountryexperienceda number of shocksthatmay have implicationsforthe country’s competitiveness and sustainabilityofcontinuedgrowth.TheseincludetherapidappreciationoftheDram, lowfinancialintermediation,andstalledreformsamongothers. This timely volume contains six papers that address various aspects of the competitiveness of the Armenian economy. These include the effects of the appreciationoftheexchangerate,competitioninthebankingsector,productivityatthe firmlevel,theoverallcompetitivenessoftheprivatesector,aswellastheagricultural sectorandtheimpactoffarmertraining. The first paper by Mher Baghramyan and Vahram Ghushchyan addresses the appreciation of the Dram and its implications for the competitiveness of the IT, tourism, and food processing sectors. The authors explore the relationship among exchangerates,technicalefficiency,andexportandprofitabilityoffirmsoperatingin Armenia.Theyfindthatexchangerateappreciationhasseriousimplicationsforfirm profitability. TheappreciationoftheDramalsoraisesthequestionofwhethertheexchangerateis misaligned. The second paper by Vahé Heboyan and Lewell Gunter explores the underlyingfactorsthatexplaintheexchangeratedynamicsinArmenia.Theirresults show that the Armenian is misaligned from its longrun equilibrium path. However, theyalso reportthat the degreeof misalignment is sensitive to the set of variablesusedintheestimationandcallforfurtherwork. Turningtothebankingsector,thethirdpaper,coauthored by Era DablaNorris and Holger Floerkemeier, studies the determinants of banking interest rate spreads and marginsinArmenia.Theyfindthatalargeproportionofthevariationinspreadsand marginscanbe explainedby bank size,liquidity,and market power, aswellas the marketstructurewithinwhichbanksoperate.Theresultssuggestthatthereisalarge potentialtoincreasecostefficiencyandcompetitioninthebankingsystem.

The fourth paper by Karen Grigorian and Vahram Stepanyan examines firm level evidence on the sources of productivity growth in the Armenian economy. They estimatetotalfactorproductivity(TFP)usingasampleoffirmsinthemanufacturing and service sectors, and investigate its variation across industries, time and region. Theyfindthattechnicalefficiencyishighestinthejewelry,furnitureandjuicesectoras wellasmining,andlowestinchemicals,textilesandconstruction;theservicesector operatesatthemeanoftechnicalefficiencyacrosstheeconomy.However,theauthors concludethatArmeniaisnotexperiencinganygrowthintechnicalefficiency. Movingtothebigpicture,thenextpaperbyManukHergnyan,GagikGabrielyan,and Anna Makaryan examines the competitiveness of the Armenian private sector. The paper reviews Armenia’s economic achievements and studies the underlying factors and causal links to the country’s competitiveness. It also advances a set of recommendationstopositionArmeniaintheregionandglobally. Thelastpaper,coauthoredbytheteamofKennethFortson,EsterHakobyan,Anahit Petrosyan,AnuRangarajan,andRebeccaTunstall,reviews the major features of the MillenniumChallengeAccountprogramandlaysoutthemethodologyonhowtostudy the impact of farmer training. The results of the evaluation will assess the farmer trainingprogram’ssuccessinincreasingtheadoptionofeffectiveagriculturalpractices, increasing cultivation of highervalue crops, improving farm productivity, increasing agriculturalprofitsandhouseholdincome,andreducingpovertyrates. GuestEditor DavidJoulfaian

IMPLICATIONS OF ARMENIAN DRAM APPRECIATION FOR THE COMPETITIVENESS OF ARMENIAN IT, TOURISM , AND FOOD PROCESSING INDUSTRIES MherBaghramyan,AIPRG VahramGhushchyan,Ph.D.,AIPRG ∗ Abstract: The Armenian currency appreciated more than 40 percent during 2003 2006.Thissharpchangeinnominalexchangerateisconsideredanegativeshockfor local producers and especially for the exporters. The survey data of fifty eight Armenian companies is used to study how the appreciation has affected the competitivenessofArmeniantourism,IT,andfoodprocessingindustries.Weusethe Stochastic Frontier modeling technique to estimate the level of and changes in the technical efficiency of the companies during 20032006. The technical efficiency parametersarethenincludedintotheregressionmodelinordertorevealthepossible impactofthecurrencyappreciationonprofitsandexportlevelsofthecompanies. Wefindsystematicandstatisticallysignificantimpactsofexchangeratechangesonthe level of technical efficiency of the companies.We also find that work experience is anotherimportantdeterminantofdegreeoftechnicalefficiency. Westudytherelationshipsamongexchangerates,technicalefficiency,andexportand profitabilityofthecompanies.Wefindthataone point appreciation of thenominal exchangeratecausesadecreaseintheexportofanaverageArmenianITcompanyby 66thousanddrams(about200USD)peryear,averagefoodprocessingcompanyby12 thousandDrams(about40USD)peryear,andalossofprofitofanaverageincoming touroperatorandhotelby112thousandAMD(orabout340USDperyear). JELClassification:C1,C3,D2 Keywords:TechnicalEfficiency,ExchangeRate,Appreciation,Competitiveness

∗ Theauthors wishtothank CompetitiveArmenianPrivate Project (CAPS), USAID, and Norwegian InstituteofInternationalAffairs(NUPI)forfinancialsupport,AIPRGstafffortheirdedicatedeffortson conductingthesurvey,andallsurveyrespondentsforprovidingdataandmakingusefulcomments. TheanalysisandviewspresentedinthisstudydonotnecessarilyreflectthoseofAIPRGorUSAIDand arethoseoftheauthorsalone.

I. INDUSTRY OVERVIEW

1.1 IT and Tourism Both Armenian information and communication (ICT) and tourism industries experiencedrapidgrowthduringthelastdecadeandareconsideredtobeamongthe mostdynamicandperspectivesectorsofArmenianeconomy.AccordingtoEnterprise Incubator Foundation (EIF, 2007) and the Ministry of Trade and Economic Development 1ofArmenia,theaverageannualgrowthrateofICTindustrywasabout 30%.165companiesoperatingintheindustryemployabout5000people.Theindustry outputin2006wasabout85millionUSDcomprisingabout2%ofGDPofArmenia, and about 63% of the output was exported. The share of tourism in the GDP of Armeniaisabout67%,beingatthesametimeoneofthemainexportcategories. 2 Table 1 .1 shows the dynamics of international tourist arrivals for 20012006. The industrymaintainshighannualgrowthrates(onaverage25%)andhasbecomeoneof themostimportantanddynamicsectorsoftheArmenianeconomy.Itisestimatedthat, on average, one foreign tourist spends in Armenia about 10 days and about $1,600 USD,notcountinginternationaltravelexpenses. 3

Table 1.1 International Tourist Arrivals to Armenia, 2001-2006 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 Internationaltouristarrivals,thousand 123,262 162,089 206,094 262,685 318,563 381,136 Annualgrowthrateofinternational 31.5 27.2 27.5 21.3 19.6 touristarrivals,percentage Source:MinistryofTradeandEconomicDevelopmentofArmenia. Theoretically,domesticcurrencyappreciationcanhaveextremelynegativeeffectboth for tourism and IT industries. Along with appreciation, domestic prices (when denominatedinforeigncurrency)becomemoreexpensiveforforeignvisitorsandtheir number may decrease in favor of alternative cheaper destinations. According to the recentstudyofECAInternational, 4Yerevanisranked21 st amongmostexpensivecities for visitors and is ahead of Paris (23 rd ), Vienna (25 th ), Berlin (27 th ), and even Manhattan, NY (28 th ). This position of the Armenian capital is, in part, due to the domesticcurrencyappreciation. MostofArmenianITcompanieseitherexporttheirproductsoroperateasoutsourcing contractors.MostoftheircostsaredenominatedinArmeniandrams,laborbeingthe largestcostcategory,whichmakescostcuttingalmostimpossible.Inthecompetitive market,theentireburdenofdramappreciationcan be offset only by an increase of dollar price, if that company operates at the possible highest efficiency level. On anotherside,therealdramwagesinArmenianITsectoraredrivenupbyadeficitof properlyskilledlaborwhichmakesArmenianITcompaniesevenlesscompetitivein theinternationalmarket.

1www.minted.am 2ibid 3ibid 4http://www.ecainternational.com/ASP/ViewArticle2.asp?ArticleID=175

1.2 Food Processing The food processing industry is traditionally one of the important sectors of the Armenianeconomy.Inthemid80s,thesectoraccountedforabout18percentoftotal industrialoutput.Armeniawasalwaysfamousforitsbrandyandwine,cannedfruits andvegetables,traditionalmeatproducts,freshanddriedfruits,etc.Afterthecollapse oftheFSUandthehardtransitionprocess,worsenedbytheeconomicblockadeand war, the food processing industry experienced a dramatic decline. Many companies stopped operating, and others tried to survive, utilizing just 510 percent of their capacity.Aftertheprivatizationin19941999,theindustrystartedreviving,benefitting fromlargevolumesofforeigninvestments(about$60millionUSDby2000(Decay, 2000)) and increased domestic demand driven by import substitution. Table 1.2 summarizesthemainindicatorsofthefoodindustryofArmeniaduring19852006. Table 1.2 Main Indicators of Food Industry of Armenia 1985 1997 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 Numberofenterprises, 135 178 593 670 769 786 782 n/a units Volumeofproduction, 93.7 114.9 126.7 150.8 161.9 185.4 189.4 bln.Drams Volumeofproduction, n/a 190,913 206,990 220,963 260,539 303,468 405,069 455,288 currentUSD,000s Shareintotal IndustrialOutput, 18.4 36.8 37.1 37.1 36.6 31.3 29.5 29.4 percentage Numberofindustrial productionpersonnel, 33.5 15.2 12.1 10.8 11.6 11.6 14.3 n/a persons,000s* FoodExport,current n/a 25,328 50,538 59,212 81,187 82,877 114,112 121,846 USD,000s FoodExport,sharein MerchandiseExport, n/a 10.9 14.8 11.7 11.8 11.5 11.7 12.4 percentage FoodImport,current n/a 277,979 212,405 199,796 223,803 282,659 315,940 343,492 USD,000s FoodImport,shar ein MerchandiseImport, n/a 31.2 24.2 20.2 17.5 20.9 17.5 15.7 percentage Foodtradebalance, 252,651 161,867 140,583 142,616 199,783 201,827 221,646 currentUSD,000s NominalExchange Rate,(annualaverage), 490.8 555.1 573.4 578.8 533.5 457.7 416 dramsperUSD ChangeinNominal ExchangeRate,YOY, 3.3% 0.9% 7.8% 14.2% 9.1% percentage *Withoutsmallandsupersmallorganizations. Source:StatisticalYearbookofArmenia2006,NSS;“Industry”StatisticalCollection,NSS,1997; Authors’calculations.

During the 2000s, the share of the food processing industry has further grown, providing about 30 percent of total industrial output in 2005. At the same time, it becamethethirdlargestexportingindustry,accounting for about 12 percent of total merchandise exports in 2005. The period of 19972005 was characterized by substantial import substitution growth. While domestic food production has almost doubled,foodimportshaveincreasedbyjustabout14percentcomparedto1997,and the share of foods in total merchandise import decreased from 31 to 18 percent. However,in2005,thetradebalanceforfoodswasstillnegativerepresentingabout200 mlnUSDorabout180percentofthesameyearfoodexport.Armeniaisstillhighly dependent on imported food products which is about half of the total food consumption. Despite the increase of the number ofenterprises operating within the industry, the levelofoutputsignificantlydecreasedcomparedtothepretransitionlevel(seeAnnex A).In2006,thevolumeofproductionofalmostall foodproductswas significantly lowerthaninthepretransitionperiod,withtheonlyexceptionbeingwholemilkdairy products. While for some product groups the difference is modest (alcoholfree beverages – 86 percent of 1985 level, meat–75, and brandy77percent), for other productsitisstriking(grapewine–about6percent,sausages7,andcannedproducts– about5percent). II. EXCHANGE RATE : REAL OR IMAGINARY THREAT ? TheArmeniannationalcurrency–theDram–wasintroducedinNovember1993atthe rateof200SovietRoublesperDram.Theensuingfewyearswerecharacterizedby highratesofinflationandcurrencydepreciation.In1996theCentralBankofArmenia (CBA)adoptedthefloatingexchangerateregimeandannouncedlowinflationasthe maintargetofBank’spolicy.Bytheendof1990’stheGovernmentwasabletoachieve macroeconomicstabilizationandtheeconomystartedgrowingathighrates. Table 2.1 AMD/USD Exchange Rate Dynamics, 1997-2007 Oct. 1997 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007* NominalExchangeRate, annual 490.8 555.1 573.4 578.8 533.5 457.7 416 331 average,dramsperUSD ChangeinNominalExchange 3.3 0.9 7.8 14.2 9.1 20.4 Rate,YOY,percentage Source:StatisticalYearbookofArmenia2006,NSS Note:*Exchangerateasof19/10/2007 Starting from 2004, the Armenian currency has been experiencing dramatic appreciation (see Table 2.1). The most common official explanation of that phenomenon are high inflows of remittances from abroad, possible undervalued positionoftherealexchangerateprior2003,rapidgrowthinincomeandproductivity, as well as a process of dedollarization of the economy following new banking and legal regulations and the depreciation of dollar with respect to other major world (, Yuan, Yen, etc). Despite high pressure, Central Bank of Armenia continuestofollowitspolicyofprioritizinglowinflationrateratherthansupporting stableexchangerate.ThecommonreactionofArmenianofficialstothecomplaintsof Armenianproducersandexportersregardingthenegative impact of theappreciation hasbeenadvicetoincreasetheproductivity. 5However,fewappearconcernedwiththe feasibilityofsuchproductivitygrowth.Moreover,accordingtoarecentstudybythe WorldBank(WorldBank,2007)Armeniahasachievedsignificantimprovementinthe laborproductivity.ItisquitepossiblethatmanyArmenianenterprisesthatalreadyhave modernized their technology and have applied effective management and quality control systems, have already completed the catchup process in productivity, and sustainingfurtherproductivitygrowthmightnotbefeasibleforthem. ThisstudywillattempttoestimatethedegreeofthetechnicalefficiencyofArmenian food processing, Information and Communication Technology companies (ICT), hotels,andincomingtouroperatorsandcheckhowthedramappreciationhasaffected theirperformanceandcompetitiveness. 2.1 What do Managers Think? Inordertosupplementthefindingsoftheempiricalanalysisandgainbetterinsightinto the situation, we conducted a series of brief interviews with CEO’sof anumber of companiesfromalltheindustries.Theanswerson6questions(Q)formulatedbelow aresummarizedintheTable2.2.

Table 2.2 Mean results of the Interview answers Sector Numberofcompanies Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q5 Q6 ITcompanies 38 35 503 48 23 77 4 Hotels 21 20 523 30 1 34 5 TourOperators 33 53 460 33 11 76 3 FoodProcessingcompanies 32 47 420 26 2 55 5 Weightedaverageofallcompanies 124 40 474 35 11 64 4 Q1.WhatwouldyouexpectthepercentagedifferenceofCompany’s2006revenueto be,iftheexchangerateremainedatthelevelof2003,i.e.580dramsper1USD? Onaverage,themanagersclaimedthattheirrevenueswouldbeabout40percenthigher if the exchange rate were unchanged, the largest impact being for incoming tour operators – more than 50 percent. IT managers mentioned that the appreciation of Drammakestheircompanieslesscompetitivecomparedtootheroutsourcingcountries, andatleast5firmsbranchesofforeigncompanies,mentionedthattheirheadquarters hadbeenseriouslyconsideringtheoptionofshuttingdowntheirArmenianoffice. For hotels and tour operators, the major problem is the continued appreciation of ArmeniantourismservicewhichcausesArmenialosingthebattleintheglobaltourism market. They argue that it is the flow of tourists of Armenian origin that allows the industrytosurvive,howeverthisgrowthisabouttoslowdown. Food companies selling in domestic markets are concerned with the loss of sales because most of the population is surviving with the flow of remittances, and the

5Seeforexample,VahagnGrigoryan,“TheFutureofExport”(inArmenian),ww.cba.am/verluc/2.9.pdf (lastvisitedonMay10,2008). appreciation of dram is affecting the welfare of remittance recipients and thus the demandforfoodproducts. Q2.WhatAMD/USDexchangeratewouldbethemostfavorableforYourCompany andwouldmakeitcompetitive? Thedesirableexchangerateisattheaverage474dramsperUSdollarwhichisabout 47percenthigherthantherateof335dramsprevailed during the study. Almost all respondentsmentionedthattheyareconcernednotonlywiththerealappreciationof the currency but also with unpredictability of the exchange rates. Sometimes the uncertaintycreatesevenmoreproblemswhentheyneedtomakepricerecalculations, signagreements,printanddistributebooklets,catalogues,etc. Q3.andQ4.WhatisthepercentagechangeofyourCompany’sexportprices(inUSD) anddomesticprices(inAMD)comparedto2003? Bothexportanddomesticpriceshaveincreasedduringthelast4years.However,while domesticpricesincreasedataverage11percent(whichisconsistentwiththeinflation inthecountryforthesameperiod),theexportpriceshavegrownatabout35percent, whichinitsturnisclosetotheappreciationrate for the same period. Evidently the companiesraisetheirexportpricesinordertooffsettheexchangerateeffect,which makesthemlesscompetitiveintheinternationalmarket. Q5.WhatpercentageofyourCompany’scapitalassetsandhumanresourcesisbeing used(rateofutilization),onaverage,duringtheyear? Theanswerstothisquestionrevealseriousefficiencyproblems.Themoststriking,in this regard, is with respect to hotels, with their average occupancy rate of about 35 percent.Whilethetourismindustryhasaseasonalnatureand76percentofworkload canbejustified,fortheITindustrytherateof77percentshouldbeanissueofconcern. Thefoodcompaniesoperateonaverageat50%ortheircapacity. Q6. Please, evaluate State – Your Company interrelations according to 010 point system(0extremelyunfavorable,10themostfavorable). The average ranking of this answer was 4 points. The main reasons for such low evaluations of the relationship with the State are tax and customs administration problems, corruption, lack of business assistance programs, the State’s inability to improvethequalityofeducation,etc. The predominant opinion among managers is that the process of appreciation is irreversible,regardlessthecausesofthisphenomena.However,theyinsistthatifthe CBAfollowssuchamonetarypolicy,thegovernmentshouldtakeadequatemeasures tohelpdomesticcompaniestosurviveinthisunfavorableenvironment. DespitethefactthatboththeITandtourismindustriesareprioritysectorofeconomy for the Armenian Government, these industries have no privileges or advantages comparedtoothersectorsofeconomy.

Themostcommonproblemsidentifiedbytherespondents 6andtheirsuggestionsare presentedbelow: TaxandCustomsAdministration • Currently,allimportedequipmentistaxedwith20percentVATandcustomsduties are applied to the most of them. Usually, the customs value is determined by customs officers without any justification, regardless of the invoice value, and is basedoninternalinstructionsratherthanmarketprices.Itissuggestedthatthese industries should be exempt from VAT tax and customs duties on imported equipmentandondomesticinvestmentsintocapitalassets. • Decreaseprofittaxrateforexporters,fromthecurrent20to10percent; • SimplifytheproceduresandenforcetherefundofoverpaidVATtax; • Providetemporary(12year)taxexemptionfornewlyestablishedICTcompanies. • Hotel Restaurant taxation . Many hotels complained that the hotel restaurants are taxedidenticallytootherrestaurants,taxbeingcalculatedonthesquaremeterbase. Theyclaimthatthisapproachisnotacceptablesincehotelrestaurantsserveonly hotel customers and are marginally profitable while regular restaurants earn high profits on hosting different occasions (weddings, birthday parties, etc.), and the twocategoriescannotbetreatedidentically.Somehotels,especiallyintheregions, were going to close their restaurants and stop providing breakfast to their customers. Finance • Createamechanismforprovidinglowinterest,longtermloanstoexporters; • ImprovetheaccesstothelongtermloansforICTcompanies. Educationandtraining • AshortageofskilledICTspecialistsisobserved,andmanycompaniesconsiderthis asoneofthemostimportantobstaclesforfurtherexpansionoftheindustry; • A shortage of specialized managers (hotel managers, IT managers) is another seriousproblem; • CompaniesneedtheGovernmenttoprovidefreetrainingorcovertrainingcostsof managersandotherkeyemployees; • The Government should cover the costs of participation in various international tradefairs,symposiums,networks,etc. Protection of intellectual property rights. It is wellknown that the protection of intellectual property rights is one of the most important factors stimulating the investment into R&D since the investors are sure that the potential benefits of new inventions or innovations will belong to them only. Many Armenian IT companies mentionedthataslongastheprotectionofintellectualpropertyrightisnotenforced,

6 The suggestions and policy recommendations in this chapter are those of respondents and may be differentfromtheviewsofauthors.

there will be no serious development of the ICT industry and little investment into R&Dshouldbeexpected. Demonopolization. Thisissue is consideredespeciallyimportant by ICT companies. Veryhighpricesandlowqualityofinternetandtelephoneservices,accompaniedwith thenontransparentsystemofstatecontractsonITservices,createsignificantnegative spilloversandmarketdistortions. Themostimportantmessageofthecompanies’officialswasthatthesituationisvery critical, and if the Government wants to preserve the emerging Armenian food processing,IT,andtourismindustries,theyshouldactasquicklyaspossible,otherwise eveninoneyearitmightbetoolate. III. METHODOLOGY AND MODEL SPECIFICATION 3.1 Stochastic Frontier Model ThemethodusedinouranalysisiscalledStochasticFrontierModelwhichwewilluse to estimate the degree of technical efficiency (TE) of Armenian companies. The obtainedlevelsoftechnicalefficiency,then,willberegressedontheexchangerateto see whether the appreciation of the Armenian currency has affected the technical efficiencyandthusthecompetitivenessofthecompanies. WewillassumethatthesurveyedcompanieshaveproductionfunctionswithinputsX andoutputY.Intheperfectlyefficientworld,thei th firmintimetwouldproducethe outputY it (1) Y = f (X ,β ) it ijt , th th andX ijt isthei firm’sj inputattimet.However,asFarrell(Farrell,1957)specifies, in real life two types of efficiencies exist: technical efficiency that allows firms to producethemaximumlevelofoutputgiventhelevelofinputsandallocativeefficiency thatrequiresproductionofgivenlevelofoutputascheaplyaspossible.Tounderstand thelevelofefficiencyofthefirm,weneedtohavethelevelofoutputoftheabsolutely efficientfirm,whichisknownasproductionfrontier,andthencomparetheoutputof thefirmwiththefrontier. The stochastic models for estimating the production frontier and level of efficiency wereintroducedin1977byAigner,LovellandSchmidt(Aigner,1977)andMeeusen andVanDenBroeck(Meeusen,1977).Inthesemodelstheefficiencyismeasuredas ξi suchthat (2) Y = f (X ,β )ξ it ijt i , where ξibelongstotheintervalwithin0and1.Afirmisperfectlyefficientwhen ξi=1, inwhichcasethefirm’sactualproductionisatthehighestpossiblelevelandislocated ontheproductionfrontier(Figure3.1).If ξi<1,thefirmisnotproducingthemaximum

output of the inputs X ijt , given the available technology reflected by the production function f (X ijt , β ) . Figure 3.1 Production Frontier and Technical Efficiency

Productionfrontier

Outputs . . . . . Actualproduction ......

Inputs Inadditiontoinefficiency,eachfirmexperiencesalsosomeexogenousshocksv it that areintroducedintothemodelasstochasticerrorterm.

(3) Yit = f (X ijt ,β )ξi exp(vit )

Takinglogsofbothsidesanddefining ui = −ln(ξi ) gives

(4) lnYit = ln( f (X ijt ,β )) − ui + vit Where vit and utareindependentlyandidenticallydistributed,truncatedatzero,with 2 meanandvariance σ ,and vit and utaredistributedindependentlyofeachother; cov( ui,v i)=0.FollowingBatteseandCoelli(1992),weparameterize utas (5) u = exp(−η(t −T ))u it i i , th whereT iisthelasttimeperiodinthei paneland ηisthedecayparameter.When η>0, thedegreeofinefficiencydecreasesovertime,when η<0 ,thedegreeofinefficiency increases over time. The last period i.e. when t=T i, contains the base level of inefficiencyforthegivenfirm.If η>0, thelevelofinefficiencydecreasestowardthe baselevel,andif η<0 ,thelevelofinefficiencyincreasestothebaselevel. In our study, to estimate the production frontier and inefficiency terms of the companies, we will use two specifications of the production function: Translog productionfunction(6)andCobbDouglasproductionfunction(7).

1 1 1 lnY = β + β lnt + β ln K + β ln L + β (t)2 + β (ln K )2 + β (ln L )2 + (6) it 0 t K it L it 2 tt 2 KK it 2 LL it

+ β KL (ln Kit )(ln Lit ) + β Kt (ln Kit )(lnt) + β Lt (ln Lit )(lnt) − uit + vit and (7) lnY = β + β lnt + β lnK + β lnL −u + v it 0 t K it L it it it , wherecapital(K),labor(L)andtime(t)areinputfactorsusedtoestimatethestochastic frontiermodel,andYistheoutput. Weassumethatbothproductionfunctionshaveconstantreturntoscale:RTS=1,which istestedforbothmodelspecifications. TechnologicalProgress(TP)isthederivativeoftheproductionfunctionwithrespectto time:

(8) TP = βt + βtt t)( + βKt (lnKit ) + βLt (lnLit ) IfTPispositive(negative),thentheproductionfrontiershiftsup(down). For the CobbDouglas production function, TP is constant and is the coefficient of time βt . Change of Technical Efficiency (TE) is the derivative of the negative of the inefficiencymeasurewithrespecttotime: du (9) TE = − it dt IfTEisgreaterthanzero,thenthetechnicalinefficiencydeclinesovertimeandvice versa. IV. DATA The data used for this study was obtained during the survey of Armenian food processingcompanies,ITcompanies,touroperatorsandhotelsconductedduringJune September, 2007. Initially, data of 50 companies from each sector of economy was intendedtobestudied;however,only23foodprocessingcompanies,15incomingtour operators,7hotels,and13ITcompaniesagreedtoprovidetheirfirmleveldata(see AnnexBforthesummarystatistics).ThedataforRevenue,Capital,Wagesandother monetaryvariablesisexpressedinArmeniandrams;itisadjustedfortheinflationby usingGDPDeflatorofArmeniawithbaseyearof1996whichwasobtainedfromIMF WorldEconomicOutlookDatabase.Thedataondomesticinflationandtheexchange rate was obtained fromthe National Statistical Service of Armenia (NSS). We also calculatedameasureofforeigninflation,whichistheaverageinflationrateoftenmain tradepartnersofArmeniaweightedbytheirshareintotalArmeniantrade.Thedataon tradewasobtainedfromNSS,andthedataonpricelevelsfromIMFWorldEconomic OutlookDatabase.ThedataofRealEffectiveExchangeRatewasobtainedfromCBA ofArmenia. V. EMPIRICAL RESULTS Asthenumberofcompaniesfromeachindustrywasinsufficientfor conducting the stochasticfrontieranalysisseparatelyforeachindustry,wedecidedtogroupITand tourismindustriestogetherandincludeanindustrydummyvariableforaccountingfor industryspecificvariation.Thenumberofcompanies(23)wassufficientforanalysisof thefoodprocessingindustry. Wecalculatedthechangeintechnicalefficiencybasedontwoproductionfunctions.In Model1weusedaTranslogproductionfunction(seeequation6)andintheModel2 weusedaCobbDouglasproductionfunction(7).Inbothmodels,theinputsarecapital, labor and time. We assume that technical efficiency varies over time (timevariant, equation 5) and has a truncated normal distribution. We also measured the technologicalprogress(TP).IntheTranslogmodel,eTechnologicalProgress(TP)is calculatedusingequation8,andTEiscalculatedaccordingtoequation9.IntheCobb Douglasmodel,TPisthecoefficientoftimeandTEiscalculatedaccordingtoequation 9. In both models, the null hypothesis of Constant Return to Scale (CRS) is accepted basedonthelikelihoodratiotest. Technical efficiency and technological progress for each firm, for every year were estimated.ThemeanTEandTPbyyeararepresentedintheTable5.1andTable5.2. Table 5.1 Mean of Estimated Parameters: IT, Tour Operators, and Hotels, 2003-2006

Year te1 te2 tp1 tp2 2003 0.4369728 0.4716637 0.2318835 0.0768452 2004 0.4860817 0.5213609 0.0213009 0.0768452 2005 0.5035055 0.5472735 0.1761738 0.0768452 2006 0.4912892 0.5453566 0.2722712 0.0768452 Total 0.4834649 0.5263201 0.0892652 0.0768452 Note:te–technicalefficiency,tp –technologicalprogress ;.1and2refertotheModel1andModel2 respectively. ThepositivesignofTEshowsthatinbothcasesthedegreeoftechnicalinefficiencyis decreasingovertime.Aninterestingobservationisthatinbothmodels,thetechnical efficiency is increasing for 20032005 but the rate is slowing down in 2006. Technological Progress (TP) indicates the direction of change of the production frontier.Inthefirstmodel,startingfrom2004,thefrontierisshiftingup.Inthecaseof secondmodel,theTPisconstantandcanbeinterpretedasanaverageprogressduring thelast4years.

Table 5.2 Mean of Estimated Parameters: Food Processing, 2003-2006

year te1 tp1 2003 0.2632050 0.5384401 2004 0.2599808 0.1620835 2005 0.2679276 0.0995709 2006 0.2666353 0.2382905 Total 0.2646437 0.0580394 Note:te–technicalefficiency,tp=technologicalprogress.1and2refertotheModel1andModel2 respectively. Forthefoodprocessingindustry,Model2didnotprovide economically meaningful results,sowedroptheresults.InTable5.2weseethatthedegreeofTEisfluctuating duringthespecifiedperiod. Table5.3andTable5.4providesummarystatisticsoftheestimatedparametersofTE byindustry.WecanseethatTEindexforthefoodprocessingindustryisthesmallest, andwithinthetourismindustry,hotelsareabout1520percentlessefficientthantour operators.InthecaseofITcompanies,themeanTEisalmostatthesamelevelof about51percentinbothmodels,howeverthisindustryhasthelargestspreadinterms oftechnicalefficiency (with largest standard deviation)showingthat whilesomeIT companiesaresuccessfulinimprovingtheirefficiency,othersarelaggingfarbehind. Table 5.3 Summary Statistics of TE1 by Industry, Average 2003-2006 Industry Obs Mean Std.Dev. Min Max Hotel 22 0.4300364 0.2061671 0.2121916 0.8590048 IT 27 0.4987445 0.2722411 0.0623348 0.8645540 TourOperators 22 0.5181412 0.2335382 0.0999397 0.8691981 FoodProcessing 73 0.2646437 0.2539802 0. 0324986 0.8200656 Table 5.4 Summary Statistics of TE2 by Industry, Average 2003-2006 Obs Mean Std.Dev. Min Max Hotel 22 0.5058211 0.1912658 0.2499393 0.8819743 IT 27 0.5112230 0.2806895 0.0629765 0.8730741 TourOperators 22 0.5653473 0.2485631 0.10 85106 0.8742781 Wewanttoestimatehowthechangeinexchangerateaffectsthetechnicalefficiencyof thefirms.Inregressions,thecalculatedfirmandtimespecifictechnicalefficiency,TE1 and TE2, are dependant variables. Two measures of exchange rate are alternatively considered: i) nominal AMD/USD exchange rate ( exch ) together with domestic inflation rate ( infa ) and trade weighted foreign inflation rate ( inff ), and ii) Real EffectiveExchangeRate 7(reer )calculatedbyCBA.Theforeigninflationrateforeach yeariscalculatedusingaverageoftheinflationratesofthetenlargestArmeniantrade partners,weightedbyshareofthetradeofeachcountryinthetotalforeigntradeof Armenia. 7REERisacompositeindexthatincorporatesnominalexchangerateandpricelevelsofbothArmenia and its trade partners. For additional details on the methodology and calculations of REER refer to websiteoftheCentralBankofArmenia:http://www.cba.am/publications/prog/annex.pdf(lastvisitedon May10,2008).

Since we are trying to estimate the changes in the competitiveness of Armenian producers, in addition to macroeconomic variables we also include firm specific variables, such as marketing expenses in thousands of drams (adjusted by GDP Deflator) and average work experience of the employees expressed in years. Unfortunately,thedataontrainingswasnotreliableandconsistenttoincludeintothe model.TheregressionresultsorrandomeffectmodelsarepresentedinAnnexC(IT andTourismIndustries)andAnnexD(FoodProcessingIndustry). The first model specification provides the following results for IT and Tourism Industries: (10) te1 = 0.3554323 + 0.0002701*exch*** – 0.0011503*infa – 0.0002147*inff + 0.0005063*exp**+5.09e07*marketr+0.0279733*tour–0.0501147*hotel Note:*significantat10%;**significantat5%;***significantat1%. TheregressionresultsusingTE2asameasureoftechnicalefficiencyareidentical: (11) te2 = 0.4780624 +0.0000438*exch*** – 0.0001404*infa + 0.0002289*inff + 0.0000968*exp**+1.24e07*marketr+0.0578764*tour+0.0000625*hotel Note:*significantat10%;**significantat5%;***significantat1%. Theregressionresultsforfoodprocessingindustryarethefollowing: (12) te1 = 0. 2681958+ 0.0000164*exch*** + 0. 0000148*infa + 0. 0003993*inff + 0.000027*exp–4.10e09*marketr Note:*significantat10%;**significantat5%;***significantat1%. Frombothspecifications,forallthreeindustries,wecanseethatthenominalexchange ratehasstatisticallysignificantimpactontheleveloftechnicalefficiency.Thepositive signshowsthattheeffectoftheappreciationofArmeniancurrencyforthetechnical efficiencyandthuscompetitivenessofthecompaniesisnegative.Thepositivesignis robusttochangesinthemodelspecificationandindependentvariable.Forexample,we run similar regressions by using consumer price index (CPIa and CPIf) instead of inflationrateasameasureofdomesticandforeignpricelevels,andwefoundsimilar results. The coefficients for work experience are positive and significant at 5 percent significance level in (10) and (11). This means that work experience is one of the importantdeterminantsoftechnicalefficiencyinITandTourismindustries. Thecoefficientsofthedomesticandforeignpricelevels,aswellasmarketingexpenses arenotsignificantandaresensitivetothemodelspecifications. Theindustrydummiesalsoarehighlyinsignificant,meaningthatthedeterminantsof technicalefficiencydon’tdifferbetweenITandtourismindustries.

Tobetterassessthesituation,inthenexttworegressionsthreeofthepreviouslyused variables ( exch , infa , and inff ) are substituted for by one variable – Real Effective ExchangeRate( reer ). (13) te1 = 0.6885364 – 0.0021411*reer*** + 0.0006226*exp* + 7.91e07*market + 0.0278303*tour–0.0513877*hotel and (14) te2 = 0. 5328573 – 0.0003383*reer*** + 0.0001125*exp** + 1.65e07*marketr + 0.0578545*tour–0.0001084*hotel Note:*significantat10%;**significantat5%;***significantat1%. AndforFoodProcessingIndustry,wehave (15) te1=0.2899901–0.0001198*reer***+0.0000339*exp–7.36e09*marketr Theresultsarecomparablewith(10)–(12).Again,theexchangerateappreciationhas negativeandhighlysignificanteffectsforthedegreeoftechnicalefficiency, 8andwork experiencehaspositiveandsignificantcoefficientsfortheITandTourismindustries, butnotforfoodcompanies. Tocontinueouranalysis,weuseTobitmodelinordertoestimatethepossibleeffectof thechangeinthedegreeoftechnicalefficiency(te1andte2)ontheexportsofITand foodprocessingcompanies(AnnexE).Unfortunately,thedataonnumberofforeign customersobtainedfromtouroperatorsandhotelsisnotconsistentandreliable,andwe cannotconductasimilaranalysisfortourismindustry 9. WefindthatforITindustry (16) export=–64415.22+244478*te1 (17) export=–66121.35+243023.3*te2 andforFoodProcessingindustry (18) export=–147614.9+743663.2*te1 AllcoefficientsofTEaresignificantat1%significancelevel. Theresultsof(16)suggestthat,onaverage,10percentimprovementinthedegreeof technical efficiency of a company brings about 24.5 million dram or 73.9 thousand

8Itisimportanttonotethatwhilethesignof reer isoppositetothesignof exch ,theeffectitsimilar.Itis explainedbythemethodologyof reer calculation:theappreciationmeansanincreaseofvalueof reer butdecreaseofvalueof exch . 9Ifwehadareliabledataonthenumberofforeigncustomersforeachtouroperator,wecouldusea similarmodelandregressthenumberofcustomers on the degree of technical efficiency to find out indirectlythetotalnumberofcustomerslostduetotheexchangerateappreciation.

USD 10 ofadditionalexportsofITproductsand74million(about225thousandUSD)of additionalexportsofprocessedfood. Now we can use our estimates for calculating the effect of each point of dram appreciationonexports.Accordingto(10),appreciationofthenominalexchangerate by1dramiscausingthetechnicalefficiencyofanaverageArmenianITcompanyto decreaseby0.0002701.Ontheotherhand,from(13)weknowthatadecreaseofTEby 10percentwilldecreasetheexportofanaverageITcompanyby24.5millionAMD. Thismeansthataonepointappreciationofthenominalexchangeratewillcausethe export of an average Armenian IT company to go down by 0.0002701* 244,478,000=66,034 drams which is equal about 200 USD (at the rate of 1USD=331AMDasof19October,2007).Ifwewanttoestimatethetotalimpactthat theappreciationduringaspecifiedperiodhadfortheentireindustry,weshouldusethe followingformula: (19) LossinExport IT =66,034*Numberofcompanies*∆exchangerate Similarly,aonepointappreciationofthenominalexchangeratewillcausetheexport of an average Armenian food processing company to go down by 0.0000164 * 743,663,200=12,196 drams which is equal about 37 USD (at the rate of 1USD=331AMD),and (20) LossinExport FOOD =12,196*Numberofcompanies*∆exchangerate WhenwecompareITandfoodindustries,twoimportantobservationscan be made. TheelasticityoftechnicalefficiencyofITcompanieswithrespecttonominalexchange rateismorethantenfoldhigherthaninfoodprocessingindustrywhichmeansthatIT companiesaremoresensitivetotheexchangerateappreciation.Ontheotherhand,the changeintechnicalefficiency has3 time largerimpactfor theexportlevelof food companiesimplyingthatthereturnonTEimprovementsislarger. Table 5.5 presents the estimated export losses of the Armenian IT industry starting from 2004.We found thatstarting from 2004Armenian IT industry has lost export opportunitiesofabout6millionUSDofvalue.Inoursurvey,thetotalexportofthe surveyed IT companies was 1,095 million AMD during 20042006. For the same period,thenominalexchangeratehasappreciatedfrom579AMD/USDin2004to416 AMD/USDin2006.Accordingto(19),thetotalexportslossofour13ITcompanies amounts to 140 million AMD or about 13 percent of total exports. Similarly, food industryhaslostabout45millionAMDofexportopportunitiesorabout3percentof actualexports. Next,weestimatehowthechangeinTEduetothedramappreciationhasaffectedthe profitability of the tourism and food processing industries. We use a random effect regression model (see Annex F). The results suggest that TE has a significant and positiveeffectfor the profitability of tourismcompanies. Onaverage, each point of dramappreciationcausesanaveragetouroperatorandhoteltoloseabout112thousand AMDorabout340USDandtheaveragefoodprocessingcompanytolosejust14USD ofprofitbeforetax. 10 Attherateof331AMDper1USD,asof19October,2007

Table 5.5 Estimated Loss of Exports in IT industry due to dram appreciation, 2003-2006 Total,[95% Oct. 2003* 2004 2005 2006* Total Confidence 2007*** Interval] NumberofOperatingCompanies* 110 125 141 160 165 ITIndustryRevenue,mln.USD* 37.7 49.3 64.4 84.2 ITIndustryaveragerevenue,mln. 0.34 0.39 0.45 0.52 USD* Domesticmarket,mln.USD* 13.5 17.8 23.5 30.9 Exports,mln.USD* 24.2 31.5 41.0 53.3 69.3 Exportloss,mln.AMD** 373 707 441 926 2,446 1,495 3,398 Exportloss,mln.USD** 0.699 1.544 1.059 2.798 6.100 3.727 8.473 RatioofLostExporttothe 2.2 3.8 2.0 4.0 actualExport,%** NominalExchangeRate,AMDper 578.8 533.5 457.7 416.0 331.0 USD,annualaverage,drams Source:*EIF2007;**Authors’calculation. Note:***Exchangerateasof19/10/2007 FromTable5.6weseethatonlyin2006,anaveragetourismcompanyhaslostabout 9.5milliondramofprofitbeforetax(about29thousandUSD), while the total loss startingfrom2004hasamountedto28milliondrams(68thousandUSD). Table 5.6 Estimated Average Loss of Profit per Tour Operator and Hotel Total [95% 2004 2005 2006 Oct.2007 Total ConfidenceInterval] Profitlosspercompany , 5.092 8.521 4.687 9.555 27.855 2.487 53.223 mln.AMD Lossofprofit,per 9,545 18,616 11,268 28,867 68,296 6,098 130,493 company,USD,000s Duringtheperiodof20042006,thelostprofitofallsurveyedtouroperatorsandhotels amountedto401millionAMDor15percentofactualprofit.Forfoodcompanies,the profitlosswasmodestatslightlylessthan1percent. OuranalysisstronglysuggeststhattheITandtourismindustries,andtolesserextent foodprocessingindustry,havebeenseriouslyaffectedbydramappreciation,andsince the appreciation process continues, urgent measures should be undertaken by the governmentforhelpingcompaniestooffsetthisnegativepressureandstaycompetitive indomesticandinternationalmarkets.

VI. POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS AND CONCLUSION Thesurveydataof58Armeniancompaniesareusedtostudyhowtheappreciationhas affectedthecompetitivenessofArmenianITcompanies,hotels,touroperatorsandfood processingindustries.WeusetheStochasticFrontierModelingtechniquetoestimate thelevelandchangesintechnicalefficiencyofArmeniancompaniesfortheperiodof 200306. The technical efficiency parameters are then included into the regression model in order to reveal the possible impact of currency appreciation on export volumesandprofitabilityofthecompanies. The model shows that the level of technical efficiency of Armenian companies has been rapidly growing during the last 3 years, but reversed in 2006. We find a systematicandstatisticallysignificantnegativerelationshipbetweendramappreciation andthedegreeoftechnicalefficiencyofthecompanies.Wealsofind thattechnical efficiencyisanimportantdeterminantofexportlevels.Weestimatethatstartingfrom 2004 ,theArmenianITindustryhaslostabout6millionUSDofexportopportunities. WealsofoundthateachpointofdramappreciationiscausinganaverageITcompany toloseabout66thousandAMD(about200USD)ofexportsperyearandtheaverage foodprocessingcompanytoloseabout12thousandAMD(37USD)peryear. Westudytherelationshipbetweenthedegreeoftechnicalefficiencyandprofitability ofArmeniantouroperatorsandhotels.Wefindthateachpointofdramappreciation causesanaveragetouroperatorandhoteltoloseabout112thousandAMDorabout 340 USD of profit before tax. The profit loss of food processing companies is negligible. We also find strong positive correlation between average work experience of the company’semployeesandthedegreeoftechnicalefficiencyofthatcompany. Intheconditionsofcontinueddramappreciation,theArmeniangovernmentandsenior companymanagementsshouldworktogetherinseekingpossiblewaysforovercoming the negative pressure created by the exchange rate appreciation. According to the model(equation10),oneofthecompanyleveldeterminantsoftechnicalefficiencyis workexperience,oneyearincreaseofaverageworkexperienceofthecompany’sstaff offsettingabout2pointsofdramappreciation.Ifweconsidertrainingsasameansof improvingskillsandaddingexperience,theycanbecomeapowerfultoolforimproving efficiencyandproductivityofthecompany. Accordingtothecurrentlegislation,afirm cannot claim more than the equivalent of 1 percent of total revenue as training expense. This restriction should be removed as it will create incentives for the companiestospendmoremoneyonstafftraining.Also,morefreetrainingshouldbe organizedthroughstatebusinessassistanceprograms. Improving knowledge and making education better targeted is another challenge especiallyinITsector.Manymanagerscomplainedthatnewgraduateshaveverypoor skillsandknowledge,andtheyhavetospendalot ofresourcestotrainandeducate them.Oneoftherecommendationsistocreatealinkbetweeneducationalinstitutions and employers in the area of curriculum development: before confirming a certain course,thecurriculumshouldbereviewedanddiscussedwithpotentialemployers,and onlyaftertheirapprovalthecourseshouldbetaughtinthecollege. Itiswellknown,that20percentVATtaxoninvestmentsandontheimportofcapital assets(suchasequipment,electronics,etc)createsanadditionaltaxburdenandaffects the investmentdecisionofthecompanies. Ofcourse, it wouldbeidealif importof capital assets were exempt from VAT tax and customs duties. However, if it not possible at all, the government could consider adding ICT industry into the list of privilegedcompaniesthatareallowedto paytheVATbyinstallment ,accordingtothe accepteddepreciationschedule.Forexample,ifadepreciationperiodofanimported

serveris3years,thecompanycouldpaythecalculatedVATtaxduring3yearperiod, at3equalinstallments. Alltheseandotherpolicyrecommendationsshouldbeimplementedaspartofastate privatedialogue.Theappreciationcontinues,andthereisnodoubtthatithascreated additional (sometimes almost disastrous) challenges for newly emerged Armenian economy, and all available intellectual, financial, and political resources should be mobilizedtohelpArmeniancompaniesovercomethissituation.

Appendix Annex A. Output of selected products of Food Industry of Armenia 1985 1997 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 Meat,ton,000s 70 32 38 38 41 43 47 53 Sausages,ton 26,200 40 1,108 1,044 998 841 1,053 1,775 Wholemilkdairyproducts(in 177 251 197 207 218 279 299 313 milkequivalent),ton,000s Cheese,ton 26,000 1,500 4,792 4,819 14,257 14,413 14,403 14,487 Animalbutter,ton 390 11 13 29 48 44 105 n/a Vegetableoil,ton 6,792 279 262 1,559 2,204 385 289 2,735 Pastaproducts(macaroni),ton 14,000 400 67 5 1,085 1,196 2,334 2,634 2,981 Groats,ton n/a n/a 16 12 8 22 1,141 291 Confectionery,ton 40,000 1,500 3,085 3,507 3,969 3,964 4,836 7,454 Flour,ton,000s 393 143 114 110 132 147 140 152 Breadandbakeryproducts,ton, 312 373 299 294 294 295 295 295 000s Salt,ton,000s n/a n/a 29 30 32 32 35 37 Cannedproducts,thousandsof 494,000 31,000 38,006 52,571 16,955 7,852 12,103 13,890 conditionalcans/t* ofwhich Meat n/a n/a 582 525 1,347 n/a Fish n/a n/a 323 266 226 144 87 n/a Vegetable n/a n/a 751 2,471 1,673 705 996 n/a Tomato 185,000 11,000 24,441 43,531 12,945 5,396 5,618 n/a Fruit 216,000 19,000 12,491 6,303 1,529 1,082 4,055 n/a ofwhich Jam,Confiture n/a n/a 406 551 877 826 827 n/a Alcoholfreebeverages,liter, 44,830 16,360 27,434 26,817 33,183 36,223 31,981 38,409 000s Naturaljuices,liter,000s n/a n/a 1,812 2,519 4,248 4,588 4,341 5,971 Cigarettes,000000s 11,958 815 1,623 2,815 3,222 2,720 3,020 2,825 Mineralwater,liter,000s 147,500 13,000 20,157 18,286 19,542 19,929 24,115 27,240 Alcoholicbeverages Beer,liter,000s 60,370 5,040 9,975 7,078 7,312 8,834 10,751 12,618 Vodka,liter,000s 15,970 5,920 9,456 10,335 10,122 12,878 13,596 12,801 Brandy(cognac),liter,000s 11,690 3,920 5,026 6,060 7,217 7,333 9,135 9,060 Grapewine,liter,000s 66,460 3,370 6,394 4,008 2,046 6,224 6,740 3,826 Champagne,liter,000s 3,280 1,520 582 622 670 569 519 543 *Since2003productionofcannedproductshavebeencalculatedintons. Source:StatisticalYearbookofArmenia2006,NSS;SocialEconomicSituationinRAJanuary December,2006;"Industry"StatisticalCollection,NSS,1997

Annex B. Mean of Key Variables Obtained during the Survey, 2003-2006

Averagemonthly Revenue, Profit, Capital Labor/ Averagemonthly wageofadminist Year AMD, AMD, assets, employees, wageofproductive rativeworkers, 000s 000s AMD,000s person workers,AMD,000s AMD,000s Food processing companies 2003 413148 54779 163237 43 23 35 2004 494124 39997 189464 51 23 43 2005 466309 48603 202869 63 29 63 2006 559972 64752 173037 71 34 66 Tour Operators 2003 64419 14516 20701 10 45 51 2004 60514 11715 14324 11 52 53 2005 66387 13111 14187 13 63 68 2006 70807 10903 13230 13 72 76 Hotels 2003 316775 107529 413874 58 32 54 2004 402104 120367 514335 61 34 53 2005 316402 89705 644795 68 39 75 2006 316606 126420 1175143 71 46 104 ICT 2003 109591 27133 30523 48 58 128 2004 121564 16629 148931 53 114 106 2005 178755 22780 179223 59 135 148 2006 203816 23906 122773 51 137 158

Annex C. Output of Regression Analysis of TE determinants, IT and Tourism Industries

Model specification 1

Dependent variable: te1 – technical efficiency of IT and Tourism industries obtained from TranslogProductionFunction Independent variable: Nominal exchange rate AMD/USD, domestic inflation rate, weighted foreigninflationrate,averageworkexperience,marketingexpenses,dummyvariablesfortour operatorsandhotels. RandomeffectsGLSregression Numberofobs= 58 Groupvariable(i):id Numberofgroups= 17 Rsq: within= 0.9679 Obspergroup:min= 1 between=0.0001 avg= 3.4 overall= 0.0143 max= 4 Randomeffectsu_i~Gaussian Waldchi2(7) = 1058.48 Corr(u_i,X)=0(assumed) Prob>chi2 = 0.0000 te1 Coef. Std.Err. z P>|z| [95%Conf.Interval] exch .0002701 .0000346 7.81 0.000 .0002024 .0003379 infa .0011503 .001325 0.87 0.385 .0037473 .0014466 inff .0002147 .0077871 0.03 0.978 .0154773 .0150478 exp .0005063 .0002398 2.11 0.035 .0000362 .0009763 marketr .000000509 .000000454 1.12 0.263 .000000381 .0000014 tour .0279733 .1471016 0.19 0.849 .2603406 .3162872 hotel .0501147 .1657391 0.30 0.762 .3749573 .2747279 _cons .3554323 .1186831 2.99 0.003 .1228178 .5880469 sigma_u .2609599 sigma_e .00330753 rho| .99983938 (fractionofvarianceduetou_i) Model specification 2

Dependent variable: te2 – technical efficiency of IT and Tourism industries obtained from CobbDouglasProductionFunction. Independent variable: Nominal bilateral exchange rate AMD/USD, domestic inflation rate, weighted foreign inflation rate, average work experience, marketing expenses, dummy variablesfortouroperatorsandhotels. RandomeffectsGLSregression Numberofobs= 58 Groupvariable(i):id Numberofgroups= 17 Rsq:within= 0.9534 Obspergroup:min= 1 between= 0.0086 Avg= 3.4 overall= 0.0200 Max= 4 Randomeffectsu_i~Gaussian Waldchi2(7)= 742.93 corr(u_i,X)=0(assumed) Prob>chi2= 0.0000 te2 Coef. Std.Err. z P>|z| [95%Conf.Interval] exch .0000438 6.53e06 6.70 0.000 .000031 .0000566

infa .0001404 .0002504 0.56 0.575 .0006312 .0003504 inff .0002289 .0014718 0.16 0.876 .0026557 .0031136 exp .0000968 .0000453 2.14 0.033 .00000795 .0001857 marketr .0000001240 .0000000858 1.44 0.149 .0000000444 .0000002920 tour .0578764 .1562754 0.37 0.711 .2484177 .3641705 Hotel .0000625 .1760605 0.00 1.000 .3450098 .3451349 _cons .4780624 .1068555 4.47 0.000 .2686295 .6874954 sigma_u .28207267 sigma_e .000636 rho .99999492(fractionofvarianceduetou_i) Model specification 3

Dependent variable: te1 – technical efficiency of IT and Tourism industries obtained from TranslogProductionFunction. Independent variable: Real Effective Exchange Rate (REER), average work experience, marketingexpenses,dummyvariablesfortouroperatorsandhotels.

RandomeffectsGLSregression Numberofobs= 58 Groupvariable(i):id Numberofgroups= 17 Rsq:within= 0.9346 Obspergroup:min= 1 Between= 0.0000 Avg= 3.4 Overall= 0.0151 Max= 4 Randomeffectsu_i~Gaussian Waldchi2(5)= 500.10 corr(u_i,X)=0(assumed) Prob>chi2= 0.0000 te1 Coef. Std.Err. z P>|z| [95%Conf.Interval] reer .0021411 .0001045 20.50 0.000 .0023458 .0019363 exp .0006226 .000329 1.89 0.058 .0000222 .0012674 marketr .000000791 .000000636 1.24 0.213 .000000455 .00000204 tour .0278303 .137765 0.20 0.840 .2421841 .2978447 hotel .0513877 .1552333 0.33 0.741 .3556394 .252864 _cons .6885364 .094103 07.32 0.000 .504098 .8729748 sigma_u .23759577 sigma_e .00459649 rho .99962588 (fractionofvarianceduetou_i)

Model specification 4

Dependent variable: te2 – technical efficiency of IT and Tourism industries obtained from CobbDouglasProductionFunction. Independent variable: Real Effective Exchange Rate (REER), average work experience, marketingexpenses,dummyvariablesfortouroperatorsandhotels. RandomeffectsGLSregression Numberofobs= 58 Groupvariable(i):id Numberofgroups= 17 Rsq:within= 0.9220 Obspergroup:min= 1

between= 0.0087 Avg= 3.4 overall= 0.0202 Max= 4 Randomeffectsu_i~Gaussian Waldchi2(5)= 430.25 corr(u_i,X)=0(assumed) Prob>chi2= 0.0000 te2 Coef. Std.Err. z P>|z| [95%Conf.Interval] reer .0003383 .0000179 18.95 0.000 .0003733 .0003033 exp .0001125 .0000563 2.00 0.046 2.24e06 .0002228 marketr 1.65e07 1.09e07 1.52 0.129 4.81e08 3.78e07 tour .0578545 .1462734 0.40 0.692 .2288361 .3445451 hotel .0001084 .1647926 0.00 0.999 .3230959 .3228791 _cons .5328573 .0993873 5.36 0.000 .3380618 .7276527 sigma_u .25720413 sigma_e .00080072 rho .99999031 (fractionofvarianceduetou_i)

Annex D. Output of Regression Analysis of TE determinants, Food Processing Industry

Model specification 1

Dependent variable: te1 – technical efficiency of Food Processing industry obtained from TranslogProductionFunction. Independent variable: Nominal exchange rate AMD/USD, domestic inflation rate, weighted foreigninflationrate,averageworkexperience,marketingexpenses. RandomeffectsGLSregression Numberofobs= 61 Groupvariable(i):id Numberofgroups= 18 Rsq:within= 0.9344 Obspergroup:min= 2 between= 0.0434 Avg= 3.4 overall= 0.0044 Max= 4 Randomeffectsu_i~Gaussian Waldchi2(5)= 564.24 corr(u_i,X)=0(assumed) Prob>chi2= 0.0000 te1 Coef. Std.Err. z P>|z| [95%Conf.Interval] exch .0000164 .00000244 6.70 0.000 .0000116 .0000211 infa .0000148 .0000937 0.16 0.875 .0001688 .0001984 inff .0003993 .0005416 0.74 0.461 .0006623 .0014609 exp .000027 .0000199 1.36 0.175 .000012 .000066 marketr .0000000041 .0000000052 0.79 0.431 .0000000143 .0000000061 _cons .2681958 .0628235 4.27 0.000 .1450639 .3913276 sigma_u .27152788 sigma_e .00025974 rho .99999908 (fractionofvarianceduetou_i) Model specification 2

Dependentvariable: te1–technicalefficiencyofFoodProcessingindustryobtainedfrom TranslogProductionFunction. Independentvariable: RealEffectiveExchangeRate(REER),averageworkexperience, marketingexpenses. RandomeffectsGLSregression Numberofobs= 61 Groupvariable(i):id Numberofgroups= 18 Rsq:within= 0.9121 Obspergroup:min= 2 between= 0.0581 Avg= 3.4 overall= 0.0074 Max= 4 Randomeffectsu_i~Gaussian Waldchi2(3)= 425.23 corr(u_i,X)=0(assumed) Prob>chi2= 0.0000 te1 Coef. Std.Err. z P>|z| [95%Conf.Interval] reer1 .0001198 .00000705 16.99 0.000 .0001337 .000106 exp .0000339 .0000225 1.51 0.131 .0000101 .0000779 marketr .00000000736 .00000000582 1.27 0.206 .0000000188 .00000000404 _cons .2899901 .0613354 4.73 0.000 .1697749 .4102054 sigma_u .26330417

sigma_e .0002929 rho .99999876 (fractionofvarianceduetou_i)

Annex E. Output of Tobit models

IT Industry

1. Dependentvariable: te1–technicalefficiencyofITandTourismindustriesobtained fromTranslogProductionFunction Obtainingstartingvaluesforfullmodel: Iteration0:loglikelihood= 339.19909 Iteration1:loglikelihoo= 338.09634 Iteration2:loglikelihood= 338.02567 Iteration3:loglikelihood= 338.02453 Iteration4:loglikelihood= 338.02453 Fittingfullmodel: Iteration0:loglikelihood= 209.42266 Iteration1:loglikelihood= 209.15759 Iteration2:loglikelihood= 208.49901 Iteration3:loglikelihood= 208.41576 Iteration4:loglikelihood= 208.41301 Iteration5:loglikelihood= 208.413 Randomeffectstobitregression Numberofobs= 27 Groupvariable(i):id Numberofgroups= 8 Randomeffectsu_i~Gaussian Obspergroup:min= 2 Avg= 3.4 Max= 4 Waldchi2(1)= 25.39 Loglikelihood=208.413 Prob>chi2= 0.0000 export Coef. Std.Err. z P>|z| [95%Conf.Interval] te1 244478 48519.54 5.04 0.000 149381.4 339574.5 _cons 64415.22 28943.82 2.23 0.026 121144.1 7686.377 /sigma_u 102806.7 9953.772 10.33 0.000 83297.65 122315.7 /sigma_e 47056.11 8959.238 5.25 0.000 29496.33 64615.89 rho .8267862 .0559387 .6961766 .9146014 Observationsummary:16uncensoredobservations 11leftcensoredobservations 0rightcensoredobservations

2. Dependentvariable: te2–technicalefficiencyofITandTourismindustriesobtained fromCobbDouglasProductionFunction Obtainingstartingvaluesforfullmodel: Iteration0:loglikelihood= 339.15012 Iteration1:loglikelihood= 338.03716 Iteration2:loglikelihood= 337.95508 Iteration3:loglikelihood= 337.9536 Iteration4:loglikelihood= 337.9536 Fittingfullmodel: Iteration0:loglikelihood= 209.21367 Iteration1:loglikelihood= 208.77 Iteration2:loglikelihood= 208.39435 Iteration3:loglikelihood= 208.35855 Iteration4:loglikelihood= 208.35791 Iteration5:loglikelihood= 208.35791 Randomeffectstobitregression Numberofobs= 27 Groupvariable(i):id Numberofgroups= 8 Randomeffectsu_i~Gaussian Obspergroup:min= 2 Avg= 3.4 Max= 4 Waldchi2(1)= 26.37 Loglikelihood=208.35791 Prob>chi2= 0.0000 export Coef. Std.rr. z P>|z| [95%Conf.Interval] te2 243023.3 47327.75 5.13 0.000 150262.6 335784 _cons 66121.35 29029.59 2.28 0.023 123018.3 9224.399 /sigma_u 102511.1 9812.481 10.45 0.000 83278.99 121743.2 /sigma_e 46441.68 8862.952 5.24 0.000 29070.61 63812.75 rho .8297063 .0553546 .7001194 .9164015 Observationsummary:16uncensoredobservations 11leftcensoredobservations 0rightcensoredobservations

Food Processing Industry Dependentvariable: te1–technicalefficiencyofFoodProcessingindustryobtainedfrom TranslogProductionFunction Obtainingstartingvaluesforfullmodel: Iteration0:loglikelihood= 924.25177 Iteration1:loglikelihood= 924.19565 Iteration2:loglikelihood= 924.19544 Fittingfullmodel: Iteration0:loglikelihood= 690.76796 Iteration1:loglikelihood= 687.0899 Iteration2:loglikelihood= 686.42755 Iteration3:loglikelihood= 686.37083 Iteration4:loglikelihood= 686.36997 Iteration5:loglikelihood= 686.36997 Randomeffectstobitregression Numberofobs= 69 Groupvariable(i):id Numberofgroups= 20 Randomeffectsu_i~Gaussian Obspergroup:min= 2 Avg= 3.5 Max= 4 Waldchi2(1)= 20.51 Loglikelihood=686.36997 Prob>chi2= 0.0000 export Coef. Std.Err. z P>|z| [95%Conf.Interval] te1 743663.2 164192.9 4.53 0.000 421851 1065475 _cons 147614.9 68387.89 2.16 0.031 281652.7 13577.11 /sigma_u 156953.4 41315.08 3.80 0.000 75977.33 237929.5 /sigma_e 153072.1 17413.61 8.79 0.000 118942 187202.1 rho .5125175 .14852 .242388 .7767924 Observationsummary:50uncensoredobservations 19leftcensoredobservations 0rightcensoredobservations

Annex F. Output of Regression model

Tourism Industry

Dependentvariable: prof–reportedaccountingprofitoftouroperatorsandhotels Independentvariable: te1–technicalefficiencyobtainedfromTranslogProductionFunction, hoteldummyvariablesforhotels. RandomeffectsGLSregression Numberofobs= 41 Groupvariable(i):id Numberofgroups= 11 Rsq:within= 0.0030 Obspergroup:min= 2 Between= 0.4878 Avg= 3.7 Overall= 0.2743 Max= 4 Randomeffectsu_i~Gaussian Waldchi2(2)= 6.41 corr(u_i,X)=0(assumed) Prob>chi2= 0.0406 prof Coef. Std.Err. z P>|z| [95%Conf.Interval] te1 416177.7 193381.3 2.15 0.031 37157.25 795198.2 hotel 164544.4 85389.84 1.93 0.054 2816.643 331905.4 _cons 232723.9 129731.3 1.79 0.073 486992.5 21544.74 /sigma_u 128448.33 /sigma_e 80894.634 rho .7160107 (fractionofvarianceduetou_i) Dependentvariable: prof–reportedaccountingprofitoftouroperatorsandhotels Independentvariable: te2–technicalefficiencyobtainedfromCobbDouglasProduction Function,hoteldummyvariablesforhotels. RandomeffectsGLSregression Numberofobs= 41 Groupvariable(i):id Numberofgroups= 11 Rsq:within= 0.0032 Obspergroup:min= 2 between= 0.4150 avg= 3.7 overall= 0.2180 max= 4 Randomeffectsu_i~Gaussian Waldchi2(2)= 5.26 corr(u_i,X)=0(assumed) Prob>chi2= 0.0722 prof Coef. Std.Err. z P>|z| [95%Conf.Interval] te2 426704 223108.4 1.91 0.056 10580.43 863988.5 hotel 158213.3 90090.3 1.76 0.079 18360.4 334787.1 _cons 261552.4 157947.1 1.66 0.098 571123 48018.26 /sigma_u 138338.29 /sigma_e 80884.039 rho .74523748 (fractionofvarianceduetou_i)

Food Processing Industry

RandomeffectsGLSregression Numberofobs= 75 Groupvariable(i):id Numberofgroups= 21 Rsq:within= 0.0294 Obspergroup:min= 2 between= 0.2240 Avg= 3.6

overall= 0.2063 Max= 4 Randomeffectsu_i~Gaussian Waldchi2(1)= 5.37 corr(u_i,X)=0(assumed) Prob>chi2= 0.0205 prof| Coef. Std.Err. z P>|z| [95%Conf.Interval] te1| 275796.3 119000.3 2.32 0.020 42559.96 509032.6 _cons 23838 45633.38 0.52 0.601 113277.8 65601.77 sigma_u 138198.63 sigma_e 55290.772 rho .86202027 (fractionofvarianceduetou_i)

REFERENCES AignerD.J.,C.A.K.Lovell,andP.Schmidt(1977), FormulationandEstimationof StochasticFrontierProductionFunctionModels ,JournalofEconometrics6,pp.2137 Battese,G.E.andT.J.Coelli(1992),FrontierProductionFunctions,Technical EfficicencyandPanelData:withApplicationstoPaddyFarmersinIndia,Journalof ProductivityAnalysis,3,153169 EnterpriseIncubatorFoundation(EIF),(2007),ArmenianInformationTechnology Sector,SoftwareandServices, 2006IndustryReport Decaye,J.(2000), FoodProcessingIndustryProfile ,AEPLAC(ArmenianEuropean PolicyandLegalAdviceCentre) M.J.Farrell(1957),TheMeasurementofProductiveEfficiency,JournaloftheRoyal StatisticalSociety,SeriesA(General),Vol.120,No.3,253290 Meeusen,W.andV.D.Broeck(1977),EfficiencyEstimationfromCobbDouglas ProductionFunctionswithComposedError,InternationalEconomicReview18,435 444 STATA StatisticalSoftware:Release9,2005.CollegeStation,TX:StataCorpLP TheWorldBank(2007),Armenia :LaborMarketDynamics ,VolumeII:MainReport. ReportNo.35361AM.HumanDevelopmentSectorUnit,EuropeandCentralAsia Region,TheWorldBank www.armstat.am,NationalStatisticalServiceofArmenia www.cba.am,CentralBankofArmenia www.imf.org,WorldEconomicOutlookDatabase

EXCHANGE RATE DYNAMICS IN ARMENIA VahéHeboyan,PhDCandidate,AppliedEconomics,Universityof Lewell F. Gunter, Professor, Department of Agricultural and Applied Economics, UniversityofGeorgia Abstract: Whileexperiencingimpressiveeconomicgrowth,Armenia’sexchangerate has significantly appreciated with respect to major currencies in nominal and real terms,andthishastriggeredconcernsinvariouspartsofthesociety.TheCentralBank ofArmeniaandthegovernmentononesideandeconomists,businessmen,andpolitical leaders on the other side, provided their own, mostly contrary, interpretations and argumentsoverthecausesoftheappreciation.Thisstudyattemptstounderstandthe underlyingeconomicfundamentalsthatexplainexchange rate dynamics in Armenia. The Behavioral Equilibrium Exchange Rate has been identified as an appropriate approachformodelinglongrunexchangeratedynamicsinArmenia.Resultsshowthat Armenian currency has been misaligned from its longrun equilibrium path. The estimated degree of misalignment is sensitive to the set of economic fundamental variablesusedintheestimation.Eventhough,estimatedmodelspresentedinthisstudy havestrongstatisticalparametersandyieldsimilarmisalignmenttrends,theydifferin themagnitudeoftheestimatedmisalignment.Furtheranalysisarenecessarytostudy the sensitivity ofthe resultsto thechoiceof the variables and given the theoretical ambiguityofthesignsofmajorityofvariables,additionalworkisrequiredtomakethe correctinferenceabouttheresults. JELClassification:E50,F31 Keywords:monetarypolicy,BEER,exchangeratedetermination

I. INTRODUCTION Economicproblemsassociatedwithexchangeratedynamicshavebecomeoneofthe central issues dominating macroeconomic scientific research. Determination of the right exchange rate has been one of the key objectives for international investors, multinational corporations, and scientists (Rosenberg, 2003). Equally, the choice/adoptionoftherightexchangerateregimewasontheagendaduring1980sand 1990stransitionprocessfromcentrallyplannedto market orientedeconomies in the countriesoftheformerSovietUnion(FSU)andCentralandEastern Europe(CEE). Several scientists have blamed economic crises in the developing world as being directly or indirectly caused by the inappropriate exchange rate policies in those countries 1. Understanding of exchange rate behavior, underlying determinants, equilibriumpath,exchangeratemisalignment,andtheimpactontheoveralleconomic performance and competitiveness have always been of great importance in the exchangerateliterature(Edwards,1989;Égertetal.,2005). Overvaluationofexchangerateshasveryimportantmacroeconomicconsequences.It mayalterinternationalcompetitivenessofthecountry,mayaffectinflation,outputand foreign direct investments (FDI) significantly, and may also signal a currency crisis (DiboogluandKutan,2001).However,undervaluationofthecurrencymayalsohave negativeeconomicconsequences.Forexample,itmayleadtohigherinflationandprice instabilityduetodramaticgrowthinexports.Thus,adoptingthe right exchangerate policyandgettingtheexchangerate right becomescrucialfortheoverallsuccessofthe economyduringthetransitionandinthelongrun(Égertetal.,2005). This study is part of a larger study that aims to understand the macroeconomic implications of exchange rate dynamics on transition economies with a focus on Armenia.RepublicofArmeniaisalandlockedcountrysituatedonthesoutheastern edgeoftheEurope.Forover70 yearsitwaspartof the Soviet Union. Before the devastatingearthquakeof1988,whichparalyzedvastpartsoftheeconomyandkilled more than25,000people, Armenia’s scientific instituteswereamong the best in the entireSovietbloc,supportingsomeofthewidelyrecognizedSoviethightechnology andmilitarydevelopments.Itscollectivefarms,kolkhozesandsovkhozes,vineyards, andfactoriesproducedsomeofthehighestquality foodsandconsumergoods fora marketof286millionpeople.“ArmeniawastheCaliforniaofSoviethightechnology, theItalyofSovietshoemanufacturing,theFranceofSovietmadecognac”concludes theNationalGeographic(Viviano,2004). Fueledbyliberalmarketandeconomicreformsthatpromotedinvestorconfidenceand boostedexports,Armeniawasquicktorecoverfromproductiondeclineexperiencedby alltransitioncountriesoftheFSUandCEE(WorldBank,2007).Armenia’seconomic recoverystartedin1994alongwiththecountriesofCEEwhiletherestoftheFSU countries(except)werestillexperiencingnegativegrowth.Armenia’seconomy hasregistereddoubledigiteconomicgrowthsince2001averaging12.3percentannual growthduring20012006(WorldBank,2007;Roland,2000;Iradian,2007).Itsexports grewbyanaverageof20.8percentannuallyduring20002005surpassingallcountries 1Edwards(1989)referstothe1980sdebtcrisis(Cline,1983),failedexperimentswithfreemarket policiesintheSouthernCone(Corboetal.,1986),andthedisappointingperformanceofAfrica’s agriculturalsector(WorldBank,1984).

intheFSUandCEE.Armenia’sinflationhasalsobeensurprisinglylowaveraging2.6 percentannuallyduring 20002005,whichislowerthanothercountriesinFSUand CEE except (0.9%), Czech Republic (2.5%), and Poland (2.5%) (World Bank,2007;Iradian,2007). Suchimpressiveeconomicperformanceinthelastyearshasbeenaccompaniedwitha rapid appreciation ofthe nationalcurrency, theDram (ISO code: AMD), which has triggered alarms in various parts of the society. During 20032007, the dram appreciatedby46,27,and29percentwithrespect toUSdollar,Euro,and Russian respectively(IMF,2008)(seeFigureA.1). The Central Bank of Armenia, prominent economists, businessmen, and politicians offeredtheirowninterpretationofthecausesoftheappreciation,inmanycasescausing furthercontroversiesonthematter.TheCentralBankofArmenia(CBA)hasbacked the official government view that the current appreciation is linked to the drastic growthincashremittancesregularlysenthomebyhundredsofthousandsof workingabroad,mainlyin,andrelativeslivinginothercountries,aswellasby thecontinuousweakeningoftheUSdollarininternationalcurrencymarkets.TheCBA estimates that about 40 percent of households in Armenia receive remittances from abroadandinsiststhatthedrasticincreasesinthedollarremittancesarethemajorcause ofsuchchanges.AccordingtotheCBA,thedollarvalueofremittancesjumpedby50 percentto$760millionin2004fromayearearlier.Comparedtothemonetarybaseof Armenia’s small economy, about $268 million in circulation, the large amounts of remittancesmayindeedcausesuchmajorfluctuationsinthecurrencyexchangemarket. AccordingtoMr.SmbatNasibian,thechairmanofArmenia’smajorcommercialbank, theConverseBank,“therearejusttoomanydollarsincirculationinArmenia.”Tothe contrary,criticsquestionthecredibilityoftheofficialstatisticsontheremittances.In particular,EduardAghajanov,aleadingeconomistandtheformerheadoftheNational Statistical Service(NSS) has argued that“Armenians living in Russia or the United Statescouldnothavegotten50percentwealthierwithinayear”(Danielyan,2005). Whateverthereasonis,theappreciationofthedram has already generated negative reaction from the hundreds of thousands of Armenian families that rely heavily on remittancesfromabroad.TheeconomicdeclinethatfollowedthecollapseoftheSoviet Union has forced nearly one million Armenians, or about 30 percent of Armenia’s current population, to migrate to other countries, primarily to Russia, in search for work.BanaianandRoberts(2007)estimatethatremittancesconstitute80percentofthe totalincome inthe householdsthat receive them. Despite large numbers, the CBA arguesthatdependenceonremittancesisexaggeratedastheyaccountforonlyabout25 percentofincomeinArmenia.CBAgoesfurtherarguingagainstinterventionintothe exchange market, as its primary objective is to ensure low inflation, which it has accomplishedsuccessfully 2(IMF,2007b;WorldBank,2007). The survey of the ArmenianEuropean Policy and Legal Advice Center (AEPLAC) conductedinJanuary2005,foundthatmorethan85percentofrespondentssavemoney in US dollars,that nearly50 percent ofthose surveyed claimto havelost from the dram’sappreciationandthatonly27.6percentclaimedtohavebeenbetteroffasa

2TheCBAhasannouncedarevisionofits2008inflationtargetfrom3to4(±1.5)percent(IMFc,2007). resultofappreciation(Yeghiazaryan,2004).Claimsagainstgovernmentmanipulation havebecomestrongerduetothefactthatvirtuallynoimportedproductbecamecheaper duetotheappreciation.Mr.NasibianoftheConverseBank,believesthat“themain reason for that is a very small number of importers. Each of them seems to have monopolized a particular field, making disproportionate profits” (Danielyan, 2005). Contrary,thegovernmentandtheimportersclaimthatthepriceincreasesintheworld markets offset the potential for decline in the prices for imported goods. The latest InternationalMonetaryFundreview(IMF,2007a)hasconcludedthatfurtheractionis needed in Armenia“ tolookforwaystoreducemonopolisticpracticesinthe import business, with a view to increasing the passthrough of exchange rate changes to domesticprices” . Armenianexportbusinesseshavealsoraisedalarmsregardingcontinuingappreciation ofthedram.Sincelate2006,manyexportershavearticulated for more intervention from the CBA in the currency exchange market. More specifically, the head of the DiamondCompanyofArmenia,andthePresidentoftheInternationalAssociationof ArmenianJewelers,Mr.GagikAbrahamianhassuggestedareturntoafixedexchange rateregimearoundAMD400/US$.TheDirectorGeneral of the Shoghakn diamond cutting company, Mr. Sergey Gasparyan, has also spoken with a similar support (Emerging Markets Monitor, 2006). Despite these calls for intervention, the CBA continues to hold to its primary objective of inflation targeting, and the Emerging Markets Monitor (2006) does not believe that there will be substantial changes in Armenia’smonetarypolicyinthenearfuture.ItforecaststhatAMDwillmovetowards AMD300perUSdollarby2010andbelievesthatAMDappreciationhasalsocreated benefits,suchaslowinflationandlowimpactofinternationalpriceincreasesonthe Armenianmarket. Forexample, dramappreciationhelpedtopreventcompletepass throughofincreasingworldoilpricestothedomesticmarket.TheCBAalsobelieves that appreciation creates unique opportunity for local businesses to boost their competitiveness through acquiring new foreign technologies as AMD appreciation makes foreign technologies cheaper in local currency (Emerging Markets Monitor, 2006). These contradicting arguments and statements continue to dominate publicprivate discussionsinArmenia.Thus,scientificallyrobustexplanationsaretimelyandcrucial to avoid further speculation and accusations around monetary developments in Armeniaandtheiruseforpoliticalmanipulations.

II. OBJECTIVES This studyis part ofalarger research effortto survey, adapt, and extend empirical models from monetary and financial economics to benefit the understanding and practical modeling of exchange rate dynamics and behavior, exchange rate pass throughintopricesofstrategicandimportantconsumergoodsinArmenia.Aspecific objectiveofthispartoftheresearchistoexaminethedynamicsoftherealexchange rateinArmeniaandexplainitsrelationtoeconomicfundamentals. Thestudyaimstoprovidescientificallysupportedexplanationsofrecentdevelopments inthecurrencyexchangemarketandthebehaviorofexchangeratesinArmenia,thus offeringanalternativetospeculativetheoriesandonthecausesandeffectsofexchange ratedynamicsinArmenia.

III. THEORETICAL BACKGROUND

Therealexchangerate(RER)isoneofthemostimportantconceptsininternational economicsandthemostimportantrelativepriceininternationalfinance.Ithasattracted enormousattentionfromleadinginternationalorganizationsandresearcherswhotryto understandthebehaviorofrealexchangeratesandtheirdeterminants.Exchangerate researchhasbeen,forthelastfewdecades,oneofthemost‘popular’theoreticaland empiricalresearchtopicsattheInternationalMonetaryFund. Realexchangerateplaysacrucialroleindeterminingthecompetitivenesspositionofa countryintheglobalmarket.Realexchangeratesdirectlyimpactinflationandoutput in every economy and are more important for the young and fragile economies in transition.Intheseeconomies,oneofthemainmacroeconomicdiscussiontopicsisthe critical role oftherealexchange rateintheeconomic adjustment process. Edwards (1994)believesthatthereisageneralconsensusamongresearchersthatsustainedreal exchangeratemisalignmentwillgenerateseriousmacroeconomicimbalances,andto correct the external imbalances, such as the current account deficit, strong demand managementpoliciesandrealexchangeratedevaluationmayberequired.Additionally, it has been established that much of the economic success in the ‘successful’ developingcountriesareduetosuccessfulexchangeratepolicesthatmaintainedthe realexchangerateatthe‘appropriate’level.Thus,thebehavioroftherealexchange rateisakeycomponentinmacroeconomicpolicyevaluationanddesign. Averyimportantconceptrelatedtorealexchangerateeconomicsisrealexchangerate misalignment .Edwards(1989,p.8)definesitas sustaineddeviationsoftheactualreal exchangeratefromitslongrunequilibriumlevel .Whentheactualrealexchangerate isbelowtheequilibriumvalue,itissaidthattherealexchangerateis overvalued ,and undervalued ifitisaboveitslongrunequilibriummark.Thus,theunderstandingofthe conceptoftheequilibrium,and equilibriumrealexchangerate(ERER) inparticular, becomesthecriticalbuildingblockinthisentirestory. Theconceptofequilibriumitselfhasgeneratedheateddebatesoverdiverserangeof issues,suchasitsexistence,uniqueness,optimality,determination,andevolutionover time.VonNeumannandMorgenstern(1944)believethatwithoutimposingastructure bywhichdifferentmodelsshouldbejudged,onecannotchoosebetweenthemasthe solutiontoallofthemmustsatisfythesameanalyticalthinking.Thereforetheconcept ofequilibriumisnolessimportantwithinthecontextoftheexchangeratesthanitisfor otherfieldsofeconomics(DriverandWestaway,2004). DriverandWestaway(2004)discusstheconceptoftheequilibriumexchangeratein the context of the time horizon, where they identify short, medium, and longrun equilibriumexchangerates: (a) S hortrun equilibrium isdefined astheexchange ratethat resultswhen its fundamentaldeterminantsareattheircurrentsettingsafterremovingtheeffects ofrandomshocks. (b) Mediumrunequilibrium isdefinedastherateatwhichtheeconomyachieves internalandexternalbalance. (c) Longrunequilibrium isachievedatthepointwhenstockpointequilibriumis achievedforallagentsoftheeconomy.

Within the equilibrium setting, it is also important to know which measure of the exchange rate should be used, and why. The choice of the exchange rate measure (nominalversusreal),thepricedeflator,orevenifitisbilateralormultilateralmeasure directly depends on the relevant research agenda. Some choose to use the nominal bilateralexchangerateasdetermineddirectlyinthefinancialmarkets.However,most theories of equilibrium exchange rates refer to the real exchange rate, even though different measures of relevant prices are used. Driver and Westaway (2004) have identified five price measures commonly used to define the real exchange rate: (a) consumer price index, (b) prices of tradable goods or output prices, (c) price of an economy’sexportscomparedtothepriceofitsexports, (d) relativeunit labor costs, and(e)ratiooftradabletonontradableprices. Thereisacommonconsensusintheexchangerateliteraturethatthereisnosinglebest modelingapproachtoexchangeratebehaviorortoidentifyingacommonmeasureof relevantprice.Thechoiceoftheapproachdependsonthequestionofinterestandmore importantlyonthetimehorizonofthestudy.DriverandWestaway(2004)alsobelieve thattheapproachesmaydifferinthetreatmentofdynamicsandthetimeframethey concentrateon.Thesummarizedoverviewofthesedifferent approaches is compiled DriverandWestaway(2004,p.26). Theconceptofexchangeratemisalignmentisperhapsthemostchallengingempirical problem in macroeconomics due to unobservable equilibrium value of the real exchangerate.However,economictheorymodelsERERasafunctionofobservable fundamentalvariablesoftheeconomyassumingthattheactualRERconvergestoits equilibriuminthelongrun(Baffesetal.,1999). Sincetheearly1990s,agrowingnumberofempiricalstudieshaveappliedtheabove relationshiptostudyingequilibriumrealexchangeratesandmisalignmentsassociated withthem.Thebehavioralequilibriumexchangerateapproach(BEER)hasbecomea standardworkhorseinexaminingrealexchangeratesandtheirmisalignmentfromlong run equilibrium. The BEER approach has been popularized by Sebastian Edwards (1994; 1989) and MacDonald (1997) and used by many authors in the empirical literature. This approach has also become a standard approach for exchange rate modelingattheInternationalMonetaryFund. TheinfluentialworksofEdwards(1994;1989)werethefirstsubstantialattemptsto understandthebehavioroftherealexchangerateina transitioneconomy settingin termsofeconomicfundamentals.Edwards’frameworkhasbeenadaptedandextended bymany.KhanandOstry(1991)studytheresponseoftheERERtotherealshocksin thedevelopingcountries.Usingpaneldata,theyestimateERERelasticitiesfortrade shocksandcommercialpolicies.Elbadawy(1994)appliesthesimplifiedversionofthe model to estimating ERER for Chile, Ghana, and India. Faruqee (1995) and Mongardini(1998)examinetheERERin,DeBroeckandSløk(2001)extendthe modeltothetransitioneconomiesoftheCEEandBalticcountries,LaneandMilesi Farretti(2001)forIreland,andMacDonaldandRicci(2003)forSouthAfrica. Chudik and Mongardini (2007) have applied the Autoregressive Distributed Lag (ARDL) modeling techniques pioneered by Pesaran and Shin (1999) to estimate equilibriumrealexchangeratesin39SubSaharanAfrican(SSA)countries.BEERhas notbeensuccessfulwhenappliedtoasinglecountryduetodatalimitations(only26

yearlyobservations),buttheirpaneldataestimateswerestatisticallyandeconomically significantevenwhendifferentestimationtechniqueswereused.Theauthorshavealso developed a user friendly template that automates variable selection and estimation procedures(Chudik,2006a;Chudik,2006b). WidespreadsuccessoftheEdwards’(1994;1989)seminalframeworkanditsextended versionsintherecentdecade ortwo,andmorespecifically its use for studying the behavioranddeterminantsofrealexchangeratesinCEEandFSUcountries,provide anappropriategroundtoadoptitforthepurposesofexaminingthebehaviorofthereal exchangerateinArmeniaandpossibledeviationsfromitslongrunequilibriumpath. Morespecifically,theapproachandtemplateusedbyChudikandMongardini(2007) areadoptedforthisstudy. Edward’s model is an intertemporal general equilibrium model of a small open economy.TheuniqueERERisattainedwhentheeconomy achieves its internal and externalbalance.Themodel’sinternalbalanceisachievedwhenallmarketsfornon tradablegoodsarecleared(staticequilibrium).Externalbalanceisachievedwhenthe netpresentvalueofthefuturecurrentaccountsisnonnegativeatthegivenlevelof exogenouslongruncapitalinflows(dynamicequilibrium).Aformalsummaryofthe modelisprovidedbyEdwards(1994;1989)andMongardini(1998,AppendixII). ThebasicstructureofEdwards’realexchangeratemodelis: * * =logetθ( log e t − log e t−1 ) −−+ λ ( ZZ tt ) (1) +φ()()logStt − log S−1 − ψ PMPR t − PMPR t − 1 where, e is the actual real exchange rate, e* istheequilibriumrealexchangerate(in turnafunctionoffundamentals), Zt isanindexofmacroeconomicpolicies(i.e.therate * ofgrowthofdomesticcredit), Zt isthesustainablelevelofmacroeconomicpolicies

(i.e.therateofincreaseofdemandfordomesticmoney), St isthenominalexchange rate, PMPR is the spread in the parallel market for foreign exchange, and θλψ, , ,and φ arepositiveparametersthatcapturethemostimportantdynamicaspects oftheadjustmentprocess. Equation(1)clearlysuggeststhattherealexchangerateismovingduetothreeforces. First , the actual real exchange rate will tend to independently correct existing * misalignmentthroughthepartialadjustmentterm θ (loget− log e t −1 ) .Thespeedofthe adjustmentisdeterminedbytheparameter θ .Thelargeristheparameter,fasterwill be the speed at which the real exchange rate misalignment will be corrected. The second termthatdeterminestherealexchangeratemovementsisgivenbythetermfor * macroeconomicpolicies, −λ (Zt − Z t ) .AccordingtoEdwards(1994;1989),ifpolicies are “inconsistent” the real exchange rate will become overvalued, ceteris paribus . However,ChudikandMongardini(2007)arguethatitisnotclearwhetherchangesin thesepolicieswillhaveanimpactontheERERinthelongrun.The third elementof the equation is the change in the nominal exchange rate (i.e. nominal devaluation) representedby φ (logSt− log S t −1 ) .Nominaldevaluationwillintheshortruncausethe realexchangeratetodepreciate.Themagnitudewilldependontheparameter φ .The forth elementreferstothechangesintheparallelmarketpremium.Anincreaseinthis termwillcausearealexchangerateappreciation. TheERERin(1)canbewrittenas: * (2) loget=β0 + β i log ( FUND it) + ε t where, FUND it representsasetoffundamentalvariablesthatareassumedtohavea determining effect on the ERER. The choice of the fundamentals varies from one countrytoanother.LikelydeterminantsofERERinadevelopingcountry,asdiscussed forexample,inEdwards(1994;1989),ChudikandMongardini(2007),andRoudetet al.(2007),are: 1. Termsoftradeforgoods(TOT).Isdefinedastheprice ratio of the country’s exportsoverimports.Animprovementinthetermsoftradeimpliesincreasein the international price for exports, which will have a positive impact on the currentaccountandleadtotheERERappreciation. 2. Governmentspending(GOV).Usuallydefinedasthegovernment consumption ofnontradablegoods.Anincreaseintheconsumptionvisàvistradablegoods willimprovethecurrentaccountandleadtoappreciationoftheERER. 3. Marketopenness(OPEN).Thisisaproxyfortradecontrolsorrestrictions.An increase in the openness will lead to an increased trade. The equilibrium response of the ERER will depend on whether this leads to improving or deterioratingcurrentaccount. 4. Technological progress/productivity (TECHPRO).Allowscapturing thefamous BalassaSamuelsoneffectthattheproductivityimprovementswillgenerallybe concentratedinthetradablegoodssector.Technologicalprogressincreasesthe productivityintheeconomyandleadstotheappreciationoftheERERwithout hurtingitscompetitiveness. 5. Investment(INV).UsuallydefinedastheratioofinvestmentstoGDPrelativeto that of foreign partners. Investments in developing countries are usually concentrated in the imports sector, thus have negative impact on the trade balance. But the overall impact on ERER is still ambiguous as it still may capturetechnologicalprogress. 6. Debt service (DS). Is defined as a share of exports. An increase in the debt service payments leads to the deterioration of the external balance and will requirepriceadjustmentstorestoretheequilibrium.Thus,aERERdeprecation shouldbeexpected. 7. Netforeignassets(NFA).Isaproxyforthecountry’snetexternalpositionandis definedasashareofGDP.Animprovementintheposition(increaseincapital inflows)leadstotheappreciationofERER. 8. Aidflows(AID)asashareofexports.Itrepresentsasignificantshareofseveral developing and low income countries. An increase inaidflowsimprovesthe externalbalanceandleadstoERERappreciation. 9. Controls over capital flows (CAPCTRL). Similar to market openness liberalizationwillhaveimpactontheERER.Thedirectionwilldependonthe realinterestratedifferentialandthecountry’sriskprofile.

After substituting (2)into (1), and for convenienceandgeneralization using a single notation of macroeconomic policy variables, say POLICY , and omitting the PMPR term,weobtainareducedformequationthatcould be estimated using conventional methods.

(3) logeti=γ log( FUND it) +−−( 1 θλ) log e ti−1 ( POLICY it) + φε NOMDEV tt + where, NOMDEV stands for nominal devaluation and γ ’s are combinationsof β ’s and θ . Nominal devaluation ( NOMDEV ) has positive sign and can be quite powerful for reestablishingrealexchangerateequilibrium.However,Edwards(1989)believesthat “forthenominaldevaluationtohavealastingeffect,itisnecessarythatthesourcesof theoriginaldisequilibrium–positiveEXCREandDEH 3–beeliminated.Ifthisisnot thecase,soonafterthedevaluationtheRERwillagainbecomeovervalued ”(p.141). IV. DATA AND ESTIMATION METHODOLOGY

Thestudyusesquarterlydatacovering1996:Q12007:Q4.TableA.1providesabrief descriptionofeachvariableanditssource(s). Oneofthemajorproblemsfacedwhenworkingwithtimeseriesdataistheissueof stationarityintheseries.Intheshorttimeseriesthedeterminationofvariables’orderof integration becomes uncertain due to poor performance of unit root tests for small samples(ChudikandMongardini,2007).GregoryandHansen(1996)arguethat“ the standard tests for cointegration are not appropriate, since they presume that the cointegratingvector istimeinvariantunder thealternative hypothesis (p. 100) ” and thatifthereexistsacointegration,thestandardADFtestmaynotrejectthenull,thus wronglyconcludingthatthereisnolongrunrelationship.Gregory,Nason,andWatt (1996) have found that the power of standard ADF test decreases sharply when a structural break is present. Structural breaks occur with technological progress, economic crises, changes in people’s preferences, policy or regime shifts, and institutional developments, which are very typical to developing and transition countries. Thetraditionaleconometriccointegrationapproaches,suchasJohansen’s,requirethe series to be integrated to the same order, thus introducing a further degree of uncertainty into the analysis of level relationships especially in a transition country setting.Pesaran,Shin,andSmith(2001)developedanewapproachfortestingforthe existenceoflevelrelationshipbetweenvariablesirrespectiveofwhethertheunderlying variablesarestationary,integratedtotheorderofone,oramixtureofthetwo.This approachhasbeensuccessfulandsuperiortothetraditionalJohansencointegrationtest inasmallsample(ChudikandMongardini,2007). 3EXCREandDEHareexcesssupplyfordomesticcreditcalculatedastherateofgrowthofdomestic creditminuslaggedrateofgrowthofrealGDPandratiooffiscaldeficittolaggedhighpowermoney respectively.TheymeasuretheroleofmacroeconomicpoliciesintheRERbehavior(Edwards,1989,p. 137).

The estimation is done using an Autoregressive Distributed Lag (ARDL) Modeling approach proposed by Pesaran and Shin (1999). This approach makes estimation independentoftheorderofintegrationinthevariables,thusprovidesstatisticallybetter results(Mongardini,1998).ThegeneralARDLmodelforadependentvariable yt and independentvariables xt withintercept(c)iswrittenas:

py n px (4) yt=∑α iti y− + ∑∑ β jijti xc, − + i=1 j = 1 i = 1 where, py, p x are the orders of lags for dependent and independent variables, respectively, and n refers to the number of regressors. The corresponding error correctionwillberepresentedwith:

n py −1 n px −1 (5) =yytππ yyt−1 +∑ yxjjt , x , −− 1 ++ ∑ θ iti y ∑∑ ψ jijti + xc, − j=1 i = 1 ji == 10 TheboundstestsproposedbyPesaran,Shin,andSmith(2001)usesFstatisticstotests fortheexistenceofthelevelrelationship.Thejointnullhypothesisis:

(6) H0:πyy=∩ 0{ π yx , j = 0, j = 1,2,..., n } Forthepurposesofthisresearch,Chudik’s(2006b;2006a)econometrictemplatefor conductingestimationsusingPesaranandShin's(1999)ARDLapproachwasslightly modified.ItisuserfriendlyandhasanMSExcelandEViewsbasedinterface.Dueto thesmallsamplesize,itisimpossibletoincludeallpotentialexplanatoryvariablesin theestimationprocess,thusthereisaneedforselectingtheappropriatesetofvariables. The empirical literature commonly uses up to four explanatory variables in a small samplesetting.Thetemplateenablestheusertoincorporatethevariableselectioninto theestimationprocess.

V. RESULTS AND CONCLUSIONS Atotalof126modelswith3125possiblespecificationsforeachmodelof9potential explanatoryvariables 4withuptofourlagsinthedependentandindependentvariables are investigated for the best possible combination of four variables, which are then rankedaccordingtothefollowingprinciples: a) existenceoflongruncointegrationusingboundstesting; b) the number of statistically significant variables at 5 percent significance level; and c) the number of correct signs of the parameters as predicted by the economic theory.

4SeeTableA.1forthelistandexplanationofvariablesusedinthisstudy.

Thetwobestmodels(ModelsAandB)withrespectivelongrunparameterestimates and tstatisticsandassociated misalignments are illustrated in Figures A.2A.5. Note thatanincreaseintheexchangeratemeasureshererepresentsanappreciationofthe dram. ModelAwith(2,0,0,0,0) 5quarterlylagstructure (7) ERER=×0.48 GOV −× 0.80 NFA +× 0.05 INV −× 0.63 EXCRE 3.8− 4.5 2.3− 5.0

ModelBwith(1,0,4,2,0)quarterlylagstructure (8) ERERGOVNFAEXCRENOMDEV=×0.28 −×−× 1.61 0.88 +× 0.03 3.5− 7.3 − 8.5 4.6

All coefficients are statistically and economically significant and all except the macroeconomicpolicyvariable( EXCRE ),measuredastherateofgrowthofdomestic creditminuslaggedrateofgrowthofrealGDPassuggestedbyEdwards(1989,1994), have the expected signs. The sign of EXCRE has not been widely discussed in the literature and Edwards (1989, 1994) offers little explanation for the suggested sign. Thus, a further study is necessary for the correct inference. The positive sign on governmentconsumption( GOV ),asashareofGDPrelativetothatofforeigntrading partners,suggeststhatgovernmentconsumptionisbiasedtowardsnontradables.The negativesignonNetForeignAssets( NFA )asashareofGDPsuggeststhathighNFA increasecurrentaccountbyincreasinginvestments,thuscausingdepreciation.Thesign ondirectinvestmentsinthecountry( INV )asashareofGDPrelativetothatofthe trading partners suggests that investments are associated with technological progress and productivity increases, thus cause appreciation. The sign on the nominal devaluationis intuitivehoweverthe magnitudeismuch smaller than what has been foundinotherresearch.

Realexchangeratemisalignment( mt)iscalculatedasthedeviationoftherealexchange ratefromitsestimatedequilibriumvalueexpressedinapercentageterm,asexpressed inequation8: * (9) mt=log e t − log e t * where et and et arerealandrealequilibriumexchangeratesrespectively. Resultsofthestudyshowthatoverthecourseofthestudy,therealexchangeratefor Armenia was misalignedfromitslongrun equilibriumpath. However,the degree of misalignmentissensitivetothesetofeconomicfundamentalvariablesandlagsusedin theestimation.Duetothesmallsamplesize,itisimpossibletoincludeallvariables thataresuggestedbytheeconomictheory,thusasubsetofthosevariablesneedstobe choseninthestudy.Eventhough,bothmodelshavestrongstatisticalparametersand yieldsimilarmisalignmenttrends,theydifferinthemagnitudeofthemisalignment.

5Lagstructureforthedependentvariablefirstthentheexplanatoryvariables.

Furtheranalysesarenecessarytostudythesensitivityoftheresultstothechoiceofthe variableset.Additionally,giventhetheoreticalambiguityofthesignsofmajorityof variables,additionalworkisrequiredtomakebetterinferencesabouttheresults. In the final research report, the feasibility of grouping of several variables and introducingbetterproxieswillbestudiedtoavoidtheneedforlimitingthenumberof variables in the model. Additionally, the short run volatility of the bilateral nominal exchange rate needs to be studied based on changes in monetary aggregates and expectations. An additional expectations defining variable(s) will be introduced to capturethepotentialeffectofmajorpoliticalandeconomiceventsinthecountry. Andfinally,theexchangeratepassthoughintothepriceofimportantproductswillbe examined.Understandingtheimpactofexchangeratefluctuationsonpricesandoutput hasacriticalpolicyimplicationinordertodeterminetheappropriatemonetarypolicy response,whichmayinfluencethefuturedirectionoftheeconomic,social,aswellas politicaldevelopmentsinthecountry.

Appendix

Figure A.1 Exchange Rates Indexes for Armenia, 1996-2007 (2000=100)

Source:owncalculations,(IMF,2008) Note:increasemeansanappreciation.Russiaisrepresentedontherightaxis.

Table A.1 Data Description and Sources Variable Description Logtransformation Datasource REER Real equilibrium exchange rate. Is a multilateral CPI based real effective Yes 2 exchangerate. It is defined interms of ArmenianDram per unit offoreign currency, so that an increase (decrease) in REER r epresents depreciation (appreciation). ToT TermsoftradeforArmeniaisdefinedastheratioofexportpriceindexover Yes 1,3,4 importpriceindex. GOV Governmentconsumption asashareofGDPrelativetothatofforeigntrading Yes 1,2,4 partners. OPEN Opennesstotrade:exportsplusimportsasashareofGDP. Yes 1,2 NFA NetforeignassetsasashareofGDP. No 1,2 INV Directinvestmentsinrep.economyasashareofGDPrelativetothatofthe Yes 1,2,5 tradingpartners. EXCRE Excesssupplyofdomesticcredit.Measuredastherateofgrowthofdomestic No 1,2 creditminusthelaggedrateofgrowthofrealGDP. PROD Measureofproductivity.ProxiedbypercapitarealGDPrelativetothatofthe Yes 1,2,6,7 tradingpartners. DS Debtserviceasashareofexports. No 1,8,9 MONDEV Nominaldevaluation.Nominaleffectiveexchangerateisused. No 2 Sources: (1) owncalculations (9) (CBA,2006) (2) (IMF,2008) (3) (NSS,2003a;NSS,2006;NSS,2007a) (4) (DatastreamInternational,May1,2008) (5) (ArmenianEconomicAssociation,April29,2008) (6) (IMF,May9,2008) (7) (NSS,2001;NSS,2003b;NSS,2007b) (8) (IMF,1998;IMF,1999;IMF,2001;IMF,2002)

Figure A.2 REER and ERER for Armenia, Model A (in natural logarithms)

5 4.9 4.8 4.7 4.6 4.5 4.4 4.3 4.2 4.1 19961 19971 19981 19991 20001 20011 20021 20031 20041 20051 20061 2007

Figure A.3 Real Exchange Rate Misalignment in Armenia, Model A

50%

40%

30%

20%

10%

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

Figure A.4 REER and ERER for Armenia, Model B (in natural logarithms)

5.4

5.2

5

4.8

4.6

4.4

4.2

4 1996 1 1997 1 1998 1 1999 1 2000 1 2001 1 2002 1 2003 1 2004 1 2005 1 2006 1 2007

Figure A.5 Real Exchange Rate Misalignment in Armenia, Model B

60%

40%

20%

0%

20%

40%

60%

80% 1996 1 1997 1 1998 1 1999 1 2000 1 2001 1 2002 1 2003 1 2004 1 2005 1 2006 1 2007

REFERENCES Armenian Economic Association, (April 29, 2008), Balance of Payments [Online]. Available:ArmenianEconomicAssociation/EconomicData(www.aea.am) Baffes,J.,I.A.Elbadawi,andS.A.O'Connell(1999), SingleEquationEstimationof the Equilibrium Real Exchange Rate , in Hinkle, L. E. and Montiel, P. J. (eds.), ExchangeRateMisalignment,ConceptsandMeasurementfor Developing Countries, NewYork,NewYork:OxfordUniversityPress,405464 Banaian, K. and B. Roberts (2007), Remittances in Armenia II: The Impact of Remittances on the Economy and Measures to Enhance Their Contribution to Development ,ArmenianJournalofPublicPolicy2,229257 CBA (2006), Annual Report 2006, Appendix. Central Bank of Armenia, [Online]. Availableat:http://cba.am/publications/anne_2006/appendix.pdf Chudik, A. (2006a), ARDL Approach to Cointegration Econometric Template (availableuponrequest) Chudik,A.(2006b), DocumentationforARDLApproachtoCointegrationEconometric Template, Unpublishedmanual(availableuponrequest) Chudik, A. and J. Mongardini (2007), In Search of Equilibrium: Estimating Equilibrium Real Exchange Rates in SubSaharan African Coountries , International MonetaryFundWorkingPaper Danielyan, E. (2005), Armenian Government Under Fire Over ContinuingCurrency Appreciation, www.EurasiaNet.org. Accessed on 14 Dec 2006. Available at: http://eurasianet.org/departments/business/articles/eav050205_pr.shtml Datastream International, (May 1, 2008), [Online]. Available: Datastream International/Economics De Broeck, M. and T. Slø, (2001), Interpreting Real Exchange Rate Movements in TransitionCountries, InternationalMonetaryFundWorkingPaper Dibooglu,S.andA.M.Kutan(2001), SourcesofRealExchangeRateFlactuationsin Transition Economies: The Case of Poland and Hungary, Journal of Comparative Economics29,257275 Driver, R. L. and P. F. Westaway (2004), Concepts of EquilibriumExchangeRates, BankofEnglandWorkingPaper248 Edwards, S. (1989), Real Exchange Rates, Devaluation, and Adjustment: Exchange RatePolicyinDevelopingCountries ,MassachusettsInstituteofTechnology Edwards, S. (1994), Real and Monetary Determinants of Real Exchange Rate Behavior: Theory and Evidence from Developing Countries , in Williamson, J. (ed.) Estimating Equilibrium Exchange Rates , Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics

Égert,B.,L.Halpern,andR.MacDonald(2005), EquilibriumExchangeRatesinthe TransitionEconomies:TakingStockoftheIssues, WilliamDavidsonInstituteWorking Paper Elbadawy, I. (1994), Estimating LongRun Equilibrium Real Exchange Rates, in EstimatingEquilibriumExchangeRates ,inWilliamson,J.(ed.)EstimatingEquilibrium ExchangeRates, Washington,DC:InstituteforInternationalEconomics Emerging Markets Monitor (2006), Armenia: IsAMD Strength Starting To Hurt? In EmergingMarketsMonitor,Vol.12.13 Faruqee,H.(1995),LongRunDeterminantsoftheRealExchangeRate:AStockFlow Perspective, IMFStaffPapers42,80107 Gregory, A. W. and B. E. Hansen (1996), Residualbased tests for cointegration in modelswithregimeshift, JournalofEconometrics70,99126 Gregory, A. W., J. M. Nason, and D. Watt (1996), Testing for structural breaks in cointegratedrelationships, JournalofEconometrics71,321341 IMF (1998), Republic of Armenia Recent Economic Developments, IMF Country ReportNo.98/22. Washington,D.C.:InternationalMonetaryFund IMF (1999), Armenia: Recent Economic Developments and Selected Issues, IMF CountryReportNo.99/128. Washington,D.C.:InternationalMonetaryFund IMF (2001), Republic of Armenia: Recent Economic Developments and Selected Issues, IMF Country Report No. 01/78. Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund IMF(2002), RepublicofArmenia:StatisticalAnnex, IMFCountryReportNo.02/225. Washington,D.C.:InternationalMonetaryFund IMF (2007a), Statement at the Conclusion of an IMF Mission to Armenia, Press ReleaseNo.07/214.InternationalMonetaryFund IMF (2007b), World Economic Outlook: Globalization and Inequality, Washington, DC:InternationalMonetaryFund IMF(2008), InternationalFinanceStatistics, InternationalMonetaryFund IMF (May 9, 2008), Direction of Trade Statistics , [Online]. International Monetary Fund Iradian, G. (2007), Rapid Growth in Transition Economies:GrowthAccounting Approach. InternationalMonetaryFundWorkingPaper Kahn,M.andJ.Ostry(1991), ResponseoftheEquilibriumRealExchangeRatetoReal DisturbancesinDevelopingCountries, InternationalMonetaryFundWorkingPaper

Lane, P. R. and G. M. MilesiFerretti (2001), The External Wealth of Nations: MeasuresofForeignAssetsandLiabilitiesforIndustrial and Developing Countries, JournalofInternationalEconomics55(December),263294 MacDonald,R.(1997), WhatDeterminesRealExchangeRates?TheLongandShort ofIt, WorkingPaperNo97/21. Washington,DC:InternationalMonetaryFund MacDonald,R.andL.Ricci(2003), EstimationoftheEquilibriumRealExchangeRate forSouthAfrica, InternationalMonetaryFundWorkingPaper Mongardini, J. (1998), Estimating Egypt's Equilibrium Real Exchange Rate, InternationalMonetaryFundWorkingPaper NSS (2001), StatisticalYearbook of Armenia.Yerevan, Armenia : National Statistical Service NSS (2003a), Prices and Price Indexes in The Republic of Armenia 19922002 (in Armenian).Yerevan,Armenia :NationalStatisticalService NSS(2003b), StatisticalYearbookofArmenia.Yerevan,Armenia: NationalStatistical Service NSS (2006), Prices and Price Indexes in The Republic of Armenia 20012005 (in Armenian),Yerevan,Armenia: NationalStatisticalService NSS (2007a), Prices and Price Indexes in The Republic of Armenia 20022006 (in Armenian),Yerevan,Armenia: NationalStatisticalService NSS(2007b), StatisticalYearbookofArmenia.Yerevan,Armenia: NationalStatistical Service Pesaran, M. H. and Y. Shin (1999), An Autoregressive Distributed Lag Modeling Approach to Cointegration Analysis .inStrom,S.(ed.), Econometrics and Economic Theoryinthe20thCentury:TheRagnarFrischCentennial Symposium, Cambridge, England:CambridgeUniversityPress Pesaran, M. H., Y. Shin, and R. J. Smith (2001), Bounds Testing Approaches to the AnalysisofLevelRelationships, JournalofAppliedEconometrics16,289326 Roland,G.(2000), TransitionandEconomics:politics,markets,andfirms ,Cambridge, Massachusetts:MassachusettsInstituteofTechnology Rosenberg, M. R. (2003), Exchangerate determination: models and strategies for exchangerateforecasting, NewYork:McGrawHill Roudet,S.,M.Saxegaard,andC.G.Tsangarides(2007), Estimation of Equilibrium ExchangeRatesintheWAEMU:ARobustnessAnalysis,InternationalMonetaryFund WorkingPaper

Viviano,F.(2004), TheRebirthofArmenia, inTheNationalGeographic,Vol.March 2004 .2849 Von Neumann, J. and O. Morgenstern (1944), Theory of Games and Economic Behavior, PrincetonUniversityPress WorldBank(2007), WorldDevelopmentIndicators2007 ,CDROM. Washington,DC: WorldBank Yeghiazaryan,A.(2004), TheLatestDevelopmentsintheForeignExchangeMarket: AnAttempttoMakeaQuantitativeAnalysis, ArmenianTrendsQ3,1416

BANK EFFICIENCY , MARKET STRUCTURE , AND FOREIGN OWNERSHIP : WHAT DETERMINES BANKING SPREADS IN ARMENIA ? EraDablaNorris,InternationalMonetaryFund HolgerFloerkemeier,InternationalMonetaryFund* Abstract: Despite farreaching banking sector reforms and a prolonged period of macroeconomic stability and strong economic growth, financial intermediation in Armeniahaslaggedbehindothertransitioncountries,andinterestratespreadshave remainedhigherthaninmostCentralandEasternEuropeantransitioncountries.This paperexaminestheroleofbankcharacteristics,marketstructure,foreignownership, and macroeconomic factors in determining interest rate spreads and margins in Armenia.Wefindthatbankspecificfactors,suchasbanksize,liquidity,andmarket power, as well as the market structure within which banks operate, explain a large proportionofcrossbank,crosstimevariationinspreadsandmargins.Incontrastto the experience of other transition countries, foreign bank ownership is not directly associatedwithlowerspreadsandmargins.However,wefindthatforeignbankorigin mattersforbankingefficiency. JELClassificationNumbers:E43,G21,C13 Keywords:Bankingsystem,interestratespreads,foreignownership,Armenia

*TheviewsofthispaperrepresentthoseoftheauthorsanddonotreflecttheviewsoftheInternational MonetaryFund.

I. INTRODUCTION As in other transition countries, the structure of Armenia’s banking system has undergone significant changes. Bank restructuring and privatization has been accompanied byconsolidation, marketentryof newbanks, an overhaul of the legal framework, and a strengthening of prudential regulation and supervision. However, despitethesereformsandaprolongedperiodofmacroeconomicstabilityandeconomic growth,financialintermediationremainslowbyregionalstandards(Table1.1).Atthe sametime,interestratespreadshaveremainedpersistentlyhighandwellabovethose inmosttransitioncountries,averagingover12percentsince2003(Figure1.1). Table 1.1 Financial Intermediation in Selected Transition Countries, 2005

BroadMoney PrivateCredit BankAssets BankDeposits /GDP /GDP /GDP /GDP Armenia 16.4 8.2 20.2 10.7 Azerbaijan 15.4 9.7 25.5 11.7 50.1 60.0 108.2 44.8 Georgia 16.6 14.8 26.3 12.7 26.6 26.7 63.3 25.6 Latvia 45.4 59.9 115.9 22.4 Lithuania 40.7 34.9 59.9 32.1 Russia 33.4 23.9 44.8 25.0 Ukraine 45.5 33.4 52.3 31.6 Source:WEOandIFSdatabases

Figure 1.1 Regional Comparison of Interest Rate Spreads

Source:IMFIFS. Thespreadbetweenlendinganddepositratesiswidelyregardedasanindicatorofthe efficiencyoffinancialintermediation.Highinterestratespreadsareanimpedimentto financial intermediation, as they discourage potential savers with low returns on deposits and increase financing costs for borrowers, thus reducing investment and growth opportunities. This is of particular concern for the lessadvanced transition countrieswherefinancialsystemsarelargelybankbasedandtendtoexhibithighand persistent spreads. Understanding the determinants of high spreads in Armenia is, therefore,importanttoinformpolicyforimprovingbankingefficiencyandachieving financialdeepening. Highintermediationspreadsinmanycountriesareattributed to a variety of factors. Bankspecificfactors,suchasoverheadcosts,banksize,riskassessmentcapacity,and investmentmanagement,influencebankingefficiency(DemirgüçKuntandHuizinga, 1999;Dell’ArricciaandMárquez,2004).Thelegalandinstitutionalenvironmentcan contributetotheefficiencyofintermediationthroughitsimpactonloanrecoveryrates, enforceabilityofforeclosures,andcollateralcollection,aswellasmarkettransparency and information sharing on borrowers (DemirgüçKunt et al., 2004, Haselmann and Wachtel, 2006). Atthesame time,themarketstructure within which banks operate (ownership structure, market concentration, competition) can have important implicationsfortheincentivesofbankstoovercome market frictionsand efficiently intermediatetheeconomy’ssavingstoborrowers.Inparticular,foreignbankentry,by imposingcompetitivepressureandbringinginexpertiseinriskmanagement,canplay animportantroleindeterminingtheoverallefficiencyandprofitabilityofthebanking sector(MartinezPeriaandMody,2004;Claessens etal. ,2001,VanHoren,2007). This paper has two objectives. First we analyze the determinants of banking sector efficiency,asmeasuredbyspreadsandnetinterestmargins,intheArmenianbanking

systemusingabanklevelpaneldatasetovertheperiod20022006. 1Inparticular,we examinewhetherbankmarketsharesandmarketpower,concentration,andoperational efficiencyplayanimportantroleindeterminingspreadsandmargins.Thedatasetalso includesinformationonbanks’loanportfoliocomposition whichallowsus toassess whether varying risk premiums across sectors and variations in market segments accountfordifferencesinspreadsandmarginsacrossbanks.Second,inlightofthe financialsectorreformsandchangesinmarketstructureandownershipthathavetaken place in Armenia, we investigate the impact of foreign bank entry in determining interest rate spreads and margins. In particular, we examine whether foreign banks operate with lower spreads and margins relative to domesticallyowned banks and whetherforeignbankoriginmattersforbankingefficiency. Previous studies on transition countries have typicallyfocusedon the importance of financialreforms,foreignownership,andcompetition in determining banking sector efficiencyinthemoreadvancedtransitioncountries(seeFriesetal.,2002;Friesand Taci, 2005 for an overview). Claeys and Vander Vennet (2004) find that bank concentration,operationalefficiency,andcapitaladequacyareimportantdeterminants ofbankinterestmarginsinCentralandEasternEuropean(CEE)countries.Usingdata forbanksineleventransitioncountries,Bonin etal. (2005)showthatmajorityforeign ownedbankstendtobemoreefficientandhaveapositiveimpactonbankcompetition intransitioncountries. 2Veryfewstudieshaveexaminedtheeffectoffinancialsector reforms and changes in market structure on banking system efficiency in the CIS countriesoftheCaucasusandCentralAsia.Thispapercontributestotheliteratureby investigating the determinants of banking system efficiency in relatively financially underdevelopedCIScountry. Our results show the importance of bankspecific characteristics in explaining the variationofinterestratespreadsandmarginsacrossbanksandacrosstimeinArmenia. We find that larger and more liquid banks with less exposure to agricultural and consumer loans are associated with lower spreads. Banks exhibiting higher market power,asmeasuredbyindividualmarketshares,areassociatedwithhigherspreadsbut withlowermargins.Moreprofitablebanksareassociatedwithhighermargins,while highercapitaladequacyandliquidityratiosareassociatedwithlowermargins.Higher concentrationinloananddepositmarketshasapositiveandeconomicallysignificant effectonbothspreadsandmargins.However,macroeconomicvariableswerefoundto haveonlyaminimalimpactonbothspreadsandmargins. Incontrasttotheexperienceofothertransitioncountries,thepresenceofforeignbanks doesnotdirectlyseemtohavecontributedtolowerspreadsandmargins,reflectingthe limited presence of firsttier international banks in the Armenian banking sector. However,wefindthatforeignbankoriginmattersforbankingefficiency,withfirsttier

1Expostinterestratespreadsarethedifferencebetweentheimplicitinterestrateschargedtoborrowers andpaidtodepositors,whilenetinterestmargins capturethedifferencebetweenbank’stotalinterest incomeandtotalinterestexpenses. 2Severalsinglecountrystudieshaveinvestigatedtherelationshipbetweenforeignownershipandbank efficiency in transition countries. Jemric and Vujcic (2002, Croatia), Hasan and Marton (2003) for Hungary,andWeill(2003)fortheCzechRepublicandPoland,findthatforeignownedbanksaremore efficientthandomesticallyownedbanks.

(western)foreignbankshavingaspillovereffectoninterestratespreads.Thepresence ofbanksfromothercountries,however,isassociatedwithhigherspreads. Theremainderofthepaperisorganizedasfollows.SectionIIgivesanoverviewofthe Armenian banking sector and provides a regional comparison. Section III discusses methodologyanddata.SectionIVpresentsthemainresultsanddiscussesrobustness tests.SectionVIconcludesanddiscussespolicyimplications. II. THE ARMENIAN BANKING SYSTEM TheArmenianbankingsystemhasexperiencedsubstantialconsolidationoverthepast decade.Asinothertransitioncountries,liberallicensingandregulationpoliciesledto thecreationofalargenumberofbanksduringtheearly1990s.Thegradualtightening ofprudentialregulationssincethemid1990sandanumberofbankfailuresbetween 2000 and 2002 reduced the number of banks from 74 in 1994 to 21 currently. Strengthening of the regulatory and supervisory framework also resulted in improvementsinsystemwideassetquality,capitalization,andprofitability,whichare high in comparison with other transition countries (Floerkemeier, 2006). However, mostbanksarestillverysmall,exhibitinglowindicatorsofbankingproductivity,such astheamountofdepositsandassetsperemployee. The Armenianbanking system hasalso undergonesignificant changes in its market structure.Since2001,allbankshavebeenprivatelyowned.Foreignparticipationinthe bankingsystemincreasedfollowingtheremovaloflimitsonforeignownershipinthe mid1990s.Foreignbanksnowaccountfor60percentand70percentofsystemwide loans and deposits,respectively. However, with one key exception, foreigninvestors were mainly Armenian Diaspora individuals without the benefit of international banking expertise and reputation. Some banks from other CIS countries have also enteredtheArmenianmarketbytakingoverlocalbanks,butuntilmid2006,onlyone firsttierinternationalbankoperatedinArmenia. Market concentration, as measured by the HerfindahlHirshman Index (HHI) and concentrationratios(shareofthetopthreebanks)inloansanddeposits,hasbeenlow or moderate. 3 The top three banks account for about 3540 percent of the system’s assetsandloans.MarketconcentrationasmeasuredbytheHHIfordepositsishigher thanthatforloans(Figure2.1)mainlyduetothedominantpositionoftheonlyfirsttier international bank in demand deposits, with a market share in this segment of more than50percent. However,asaresultofmarketsegmentation,concentrationofcredit onindividualeconomicsectorsandondemanddepositsissignificantlyhigherthanthe overall concentration measures suggest. Market concentration is high in agricultural andmortgageloansandmoderateinlendingtothetransportandcommunication,and construction sectors. Most banks are only active in two to four of the nine main economic sectors, resulting in generally high HHI credit portfolio specialization indices.

Figure 2.1 Market Concentration in the Armenian Banking Sector

3TheU.S.DepartmentofJusticeconsidersmarketsinwhichtheHHIisbetween1000and1800points tobemoderatelyconcentrated,andthoseinwhichtheHHIisinexcessof1800pointsconcentrated.

Sources:CentralBankofArmeniaandARKA Asmentionedearlier,interestratespreadsinArmeniaaresignificantlyhigherthanin othertransitioncountries.Onereasonforthisisthesmallsizeofthefinancialsector, suggesting unrealized economies of scale. Other factors explaining high spreads include low intermediation activity (as measured by loantodeposit ratios). Competitive pressures appear to be limited, which possibly allows banks to charge abovemarketspreads,resultingininternationallyhighreturnsonassets.Problemswith asset quality, on the other hand, are less likely to play an important role, as nonperformingloanratiosarelowbyregionalcomparison(Figure2.2). Figure 2.2 Regional Comparison of Determinants of Interest Rate Spreads, 2005

Source:IMF Focusing solely on the aggregate banking sector indicators may, however, be misleading as bank activities, market shares, banking productivity, profitability, and financial soundness indicators vary greatly among individual banks. Banks differ greatlyinsize,andcustomerbase.AroundhalfofallArmenianbanksareverysmall withlimitedmarketsharesindepositsandloans .Anumberofthesebanksconcentrate theiractivitiesintradefinancing,moneytransfers,andinvestmentbanking,ratherthan in deposittaking and loanmaking. Anecdotal evidence suggests that several small banksserveas“pocketbanks”ofenterprisegroupsorwealthyindividuals,whichuse themfortreasuryoperations,orassourcesofcheapliquidity,andequityinvestment. Otherbanksserveaverylargenumberofsmallscaledepositorsandborrowers.While theymayhavecomparativelylargesharesoftheoveralldepositandcreditmarkets,the size of the average financial service per customer is extremely small, with average loansanddepositsofUS$200percustomer.

III. METHODOLOGY AND DATA We utilizeapanel dataset of20 commercialbanks’ spreads and interest margins to empirically investigate which bankspecific, market structure, and macroeconomic characteristics are the main determinants of bankingspreads in Armenia. 4 Following DemirgüçKunt and Huizinga (1999), DemirgüçKunt et al., (2004), and others, we estimateageneralclassofregressionsforspreadsandnetinterestmarginoftheform: (1) Ii,t = α+ β1Bi,t + β2Ct+ β3Mt+ εi,t Iit isthedependentvariable(eitherspreadormargin)forbank iattime t;B i,t isavector ofbankspecificvariablesforbank iandtime t;Ctisavectoroftimevarying,industry specific variables such as measures of concentration and ownership structure in the bankingsystem;Mtisavectoroftimevaryingmacroeconomicvariables;and εi,t is the residual.Wecontrolfortimeeffectsbyincludingquarterlyandyearlytimedummies. ThespreadandmarginequationsareestimatedwithbothpooledOLSandfixedeffects

4Weomitbanksthatwereundercentralbankadministrationand/orwent out of business duringthe sampleperiod.Ofthefivebanksthatareexcludedfromthesample,twowentoutofbusiness,onewas acquiredbyanotherbank,onebecameacreditorganization,andoneemergedfromtemporarycentral bankadministrationundernewownership.

regression. The latter controls for timeinvariant bankspecific effects. Table 3.1 and 3.2providesummarystatisticsandcorrelationsfortheemployedvariables. Table 3.1 Summary Statistics

Variable Observations Mean Median StdDev. Min. Max. Spread 307 3.63 3.7 1.10 0.10 7.70 Margin 307 1.48 1.4 0.69 0.70 4.00 Spread2 279 12.58 12.7 4.18 4.20 27.50 Overhead 307 6.71 5.5 4.89 0.3 36.48 Non interestincome 307 0.90 0.54 1.27 0.18 9.80 Banksize 307 7.11 7.07 0.38 6.03 7.88 Marketsharedeposits 307 5.04 3.2 6.02 0.1 32.20 CapitalAdequacy 309 58.28 32.4 51.24 11.2 326.50 ROA 310 2.02 2.45 5.41 38.6 24.20 Currentliquidity 305 157.02 115 109.20 75.5 804.90 Liquidassetsratio 308 42.95 39.8 14.94 17 90.60 Portfolioindustry 310 23.66 18.96 17.84 0 98.53 Portfolioagriculture 310 4.81 0.31 11.03 0 58.11 Portfolioconsumer 310 23.55 21.14 17.18 0 84.20 Marketshareindustry 310 5.13 4.10 5.47 0 32.65 Marketshareagriculture 310 5.16 0.13 14.78 0 73.65 Marketshareconsumer 310 5.16 3.85 5.23 0 31.94 Foreignbankshareloans 310 56.80 62.05 10.63 38.3 68.50 Foreignbanksharedeposits 310 69.87 71.45 6.95 58.4 78.30 Herfindahlloans 16 798.75 797.10 54.70 696.7 864.20 Herfindahldeposits 16 1182.61 1154.10 104.97 1055.8 1417.30 Concentrationratio(3)loans 16 0.35 0.35 0.02 0.33 0.38 Concentrationratio(3)deposits 16 0.48 0.49 0.03 0.43 0.52 Exchangerate 16 2.54 1.65 3.07 8.9 1.30 RealGDPgrowth 16 12.46 11.7 3.44 7.5 18.40 Inflation 16 3.57 3.19 3.22 1.05 8.76 Realmoneymarketrate 16 1.57 2.27 3.76 4.57 11.20

Table 3.2 Correlation Matrix Non share share share ROA share Spread Market Capital Market Market interest income Margin dummy Current Foreign Market industry deposits industry Spread2 liquidity Portfolio Portfolio Portfolio adequacy consumer Overhead Banksize agriculture agriculture consumer

Spread 1 Margin 0.527 1 Spread2 0.444 0.361 1 Overhead 0.217 0.189 0.122 1 Noninterest 0.177 0.097 0.097 0.814 1 income Banksize 0.062 0.064 0.068 0.166 0.008 1 Marketshare 0.101 0.176 0.167 0.171 0.036 0.777 1 deposits Capital 0.325 0.226 0.209 0.088 0.207 0.478 0.273 1 adequacy ROA 0.247 0.384 0.123 0.116 0.221 0.108 0.075 0.036 1 Current 0.058 0.149 0.089 0.126 0.062 0.435 0.346 0.392 0.001 1 liquidity Foreign 0.247 0.407 0.205 0.208 0.266 0.037 0.225 0.297 0.231 0.148 1 dummy Portfolio 0.307 0.196 0.069 0.085 0.021 0.247 0.271 0.200 0.006 0.011 0.203 1 industry Portfolio 0.208 0.324 0.253 0.070 0.137 0.158 0.102 0.201 0.029 0.101 0.227 0.209 1 agriculture Portfolio 0.286 0.036 0.104 0.087 0.157 0.024 0.002 0.443 0.047 0.267 0.173 0.494 0.116 1 consumer Marketshare 0.174 0.082 0.029 0.050 0.031 0.616 0.487 0.281 0.019 0.249 0.215 0.628 0.027 0.177 1 industry Marketshare 0.231 0.358 0.260 0.028 0.118 0.208 0.076 0.164 0.053 0.149 0.246 0.191 0.953 0.121 0.010 1 agriculture Marketshare 0.195 0.132 0.135 0.056 0.159 0.361 0.234 0.538 0.044 0.248 0.014 0.183 0.072 0.641 0.324 0.117 consumer 1 Observations:303 Foreign Foreign Real Herfindahl Herfindahl CR3 Exchange RealGDP bankshare bankshare CR3loans Inflation money loans deposits deposits rate growth loans deposits marketrate Foreignbankshare 1 loans Foreignbankshare 0.965 1 deposits Herfindahlloans 0.908 0.960 1 Herfindahldeposits 0.220 0.418 0.461 1 Top3banksloans 0.764 0.855 0.901 0.448 1 Top3banksdeposits 0.760 0.830 0.911 0.561 0.816 1 Exchangerate 0.405 0.343 0.365 0.031 0.217 0.270 1 RealGDPgrowth 0.507 0.552 0.604 0.428 0.582 0.450 0.243 1 Inflation 0.209 0.108 0.097 0.547 0.061 0.108 0.241 0.156 1 Realmoneymarket 0.387 0.459 0.493 0.632 0.394 0.412 0.440 0.537 0.743 1 rate Observations:16

Two measures of intermediation efficiency used in the study are spreads and net interest margins. 5 Spread isthedifferencebetweentheexpostimplicitinterest rate chargedonloansandtheimplicitinterestpaidondeposits. Netinterestmargin isthe differencebetween totalinterestincomeandtotalinterestexpensedividedbyaverage assets. 6Thisvariablemeasuresthegapbetweentheamountabankpaystheproviders offundsandwhatitreceivesfromusersofbankcredit.Theaverageexpostinterest spread in our sample is 3.6 percent, while the net interest margin is 1.5 percent, comparedtoanaverageexanteinterestratespreadof12.7percent.Thevariationof spreadsandmarginsacrossbanksisabouttwiceaslargeasthevariationovertime. Althoughthenetinterestmargincanbeinterpretedasanindicatorofbankefficiency, changes in margins could also be due to unrelated factors. A reduction in the net interestmargincan,forexample,reflectareductioninbanktaxationor,alternatively,a higherloandefaultrate.Inaddition,crossbankdifferencesinnetinterestmarginsmay reflect differences in bank activity, asset allocations, and risk tastes, rather than differencesinefficiency.Theseissuesemphasizetheneedtocontrolforbankspecific characteristics, to conduct robustness tests, and to use alternative measures of bank efficiency and performance. We use a variety of control variables and sensitivity checkstomitigateproblemswithinterpretingthenetinterestmarginvariable. Weuseavarietyofbankspecificvariablestoexplainthevariationininterestmargins and spreads. Overhead costs refer to the ratio of administrative expenses (including payrollandfixedassets)tototalbankassets.Weusethisvariabletocapturecrossbank differences in the organization and operation of the bank. If banks incur high administrative costs in theprocess of providing their servicesas intermediaries,they are likely to increase their interest spreads. Bank size isthe logarithmoftotalbank assets. Sizemaybeanimportantdeterminant of net interest margins and spreads if there any scalerelated cost or revenue advantages. Noninterest income equals non interest operating income divided by total assets. Typically banks have different productmixes,whichmayinfluencethepricingofloanproducts.Therefore,bankswith welldevelopednoninterestincomesources mayhavelowerinterestmarginsdueto crosssubsidizationofbankactivities. Capitaladequacy isdefinedastheratioofregulatorycapitaltoriskweightedassets. This variable captures banks’ overall financial soundness. Banks with higher capital adequacyratiosmaybeabletowithstandshockstotheirbalancesheets,buttheyalso giveup financialleveragewhichmaylead to lower interest margins and returns on equity. Returnonassets (ROA)isdefinedasprofitsovertotalassets. Moreprofitable banks may be able to charge lower interest rate spreads, or the higher spreads and margins could themselves constitute a mechanism through which banks generate profits. Current liquidity istheratioofhighlyliquidassetstodemandliabilitiesand measurestheextenttowhichdeposittakerscouldmeetawithdrawaloffunds.Banks

5Intherobustnesssection,weconsideranalternativemeasureofexanteinterestspreads–thedifference betweentheweightedaveragelendinganddepositratesforeachbank, wheretheweightsaretherelative amounts of deposits or loans contracted at the specific interest rate. However, this data series is incomplete as it only includes information on depositsandloans made duringthelastweek ofeach quarter. 6Duetodataunavailability,weuseaveragetotalassetsinsteadofearningassetsinthedenominator. with high levels of liquid assets (e.g. cash and government securities) may receive lowerinterestincomethanbankswithlessliquidassets(e.g.loans).Ifthemarketfor deposits is reasonably competitive, greater liquidity will tend to be negatively associatedwithspreadsandnetinterestmargins. Depositmarketshare istheratioofindividualbanks’depositstototalbankingsystem deposits.Totheextentthatmarketsharesgettranslatedintomarketpower,bankswith higher market shares may be able to charge higher spreads. Therefore, a bank that dominatesthebankingsystemmayenjoyhigherspreadsandnetinterestmarginsthana smaller bank, after controlling for bank sizerelated economies of scale. Following BeckandHesse(2006),wealsodistinguishbetweenbankportfoliosharesofindustry , agriculture, and consumer loans . Lending rates and thus spreads could reflect risk premiums that may vary across sectors, while interest margins are affected by loan losses which could again vary across sectors. In addition, we include bank market shares in industry, agriculture, and consumer loans. These variables account for market segmentation and the potential for market power in specific sectors of the economy. Thedummyvariable foreign indicatesforeignownership,whereabankischaracterized asforeignifatleast50percentofitscapitalisheldbyforeigners.Byintroducingthis variable,wecantestwhethertheaveragespreadsandmarginsforforeignbanksare significantlydifferentfromtheaveragespreadfordomesticallyownedbanks. We include several measures of market structure, some of which do not vary significantlyovertime. Foreignbankparticipation istheshareofloansordepositsin the hands offoreignbanks.AsinMartinez Periaand Mody (2004), this variable is includedtotestwhetherthereisaspillovereffectarisingfromthepresenceofforeign banksinthesystem. 7Wealsostudytheimpactofbankconcentrationonspreadsand margins by including several measures of market concentration in our estimations. Specifically, we include the HerfindahlHirshman indexforboththedepositandthe lendingmarketas wellastheshareof loansand deposits held by the top 3 largest banks. We interpret a positive association between concentration measures and the margin and spread variables as an indication of greater market power and less competitioninthebankingsystem. Given that the level of bank spreads and margins can be affected by the macro environment in which banks operate, we control for variables such as real GDP growth , inflation ,the realmoneymarketrate andthe changeinthenominalexchange rate .Inflationcanaffectspreadsifmonetaryshocksarenotpassedthroughtothesame extenttodepositandlendingratesoriftheadjustmentoccursatdifferentspeeds.The shortterm money market rate proxies the marginal cost of funds faced by banks. Finally, exchange rate risk, as measured by changes in the exchange rate, resulting fromcurrencymismatchesbetweendollardenominatedassetsandliabilitiescouldbe important,asArmeniaisahighlydollarizedeconomy. 7Forinstance,itcouldbearguedthatforeignbankentrywouldforcedomesticbankstolowerspreads, eitherbecauseincreasedcompetitiondrivesthemtobecomemoreefficientortorelinquishsomeofthe margins they were able to charge before. Alternatively, Dell’Ariccia and Marquez (2004) argue that whenfacedwithforeignbankcompetition,domesticbanksmayredirecttheirlendingtosegmentsthat aremoreopaque,wheretheyhavegreatermarketpowerandaninformationadvantagevisàvisforeign marketentrants,allowingthemtochargehigherspreads.

Weusequarterlybankbalancesheetandincomestatementdatacompiledby ARKA NewsAgency andtheCentralBankofArmeniafortheperiodbetweenthelastquarter of2002andthethirdquarterof2006.Dataoninflation,outputgrowth,andthereal shortterminterestratearefromtheIMF’sIFSdatabase.Appendixcontainsadetailed descriptionofthevariablesusedinthispaper.

IV. EMPIRICAL RESULTS ThefirstsectionpresentsthemainresultsforbankspecificvariablesusingpooledOLS andfixedeffectsregressions.Thenextsectiondiscussestheimpactofmarketstructure andmacroeconomicvariables;robustnesstestsarepresentedinthelastsection.Inall tables, the standard errors shown are clustered by banks to allow for potential unobservedfactorsthatcauseacorrelationoferrortermsforindividualbanksacross time. We also include but do not report quarterly andannualtimedummiesinmost regressions. 4.1 Basic Results Table4.1showstherelationshipbetweenbanklevelcharacteristicsandinterestspreads andmargins. Columns1–3reportregressionsofinterestratespreads,whilecolumns4– 6 report regressions of net interest margins. Column 1 presents a pooled OLS regression, while in columns 2 and 3 banklevel fixed effects are included. The contributionofbankspecificfixedeffectsislarge,accountingforroughly50percent and 40 percent ofthe totalexplainedvariation in the spreadandmargin regressions, respectively. Table 4.1 Interest Rate Spreads and Margins and Bank Characteristics ExpostInterestSpread NetInterestMargin (1) (2) (3) (1) (2) (3) Overhead 0.079 0.000 0.009 0.058 0.008 0.008 (0.037)** (0.030) (0.025) (0.022)** (0.014) (0.014) Noninterestincome 0.199 0.010 0.058 0.236 0.068 0.079 (0.148) (0.097) (0.093) (0.084)** (0.056) (0.057) Banksize 1.657 2.444 1.909 0.365 0.042 0.201 (0.853)* (0.715)*** (0.676)** (0.333) (0.395) (0.427) Marketshare 0.070 0.100 0.058 0.025 0.078 0.070 (0.031)** (0.042)** (0.040) (0.011)** (0.017)*** (0.016)*** Capitaladequacy 0.011 0.007 0.005 0.004 0.003 0.003 (0.003)*** (0.005) (0.004) (0.001)*** (0.001)* (0.001)** ROA 0.047 0.025 0.028 0.064 0.025 0.024 (0.019)** (0.026) (0.026) (0.021)*** (0.012)** (0.012)* Liquidity 0.000 0.003 0.003 0.001 0.0005 0.0004 (0.001) (0.001)*** (0.001)*** (0.000)*** (0.000)** (0.000)** Foreignbank 0.163 0.335 0.356 0.364 0.011 0.005 (0.306) (0.293) (0.276) (0.163)** (0.226) (0.280)

Agriculture 0.043 0.004 (0.006)*** (0.003) Industry 0.007 0.005 (0.012) (0.004) Consumer 0.014 0.003 (0.005)** (0.006) Constant 15.296 21.837 17.068 0.820 3.037 4.492 (5.905)** (5.128)*** (4.834)*** (2.413) (2.830) (3.131) Fixedeffects NO YES YES NO YES YES Observations 303 303 303 303 303 303 Rsquared 0.284 0.605 0.648 0.481 0.777 0.781 Quarterlyandannualtimedummiesareincl udedbutnotreported.Clusteredstandarderrorsin parenthesis ***,**,and*denotessignificanceatthe1%,5%,and10%levels,respectively. 1/Timedummiesnotincludedinallequationsbecauseofmulticollinearityproblems. Banksizeanddepositmarketsharearethemainbanklevelcharacteristicsexplaining variation in ex post interest spreads . Larger banks generally have lower interest rate spreads than smaller banks, reflecting economies of scale. At the same time, bank spreadsincreasewiththeirmarketshares. 8Thissuggeststhatwhilelargerbanksenjoy scale economies, to the extent that market shares get translated into market power, banks with largermarketshares charge higher spreads.Theimpactofbanksizeand market shares on spreads is not only statistically significant, but also economically important. On average, a one standard deviation increase in bank size results in a reduction of spreads by about 0.8 percentage points, while a one standard deviation increaseinthemarketsharevariableincreasesspreadsby0.5percentagepoints. Thecurrentliquidityratioisfoundtobenegativelyandsignificantlyassociatedwithex postspreads,reflectingtheneedofbankswithavolatilefundingbasetoholdmore liquid assets. A one standard deviation increase in liquidity reduces spreads by 0.3 percentagepoints.Overheadcosts,noninterestincome,capitaladequacy,andROAare notsignificantoncebankspecificfixedeffectsareincludedintheregressions. The foreign ownership dummy does not have a statistically significant impact on spreads, suggesting that foreignowned banks do not charge lower spreads than domesticbanks.Thisresultcontradictstheusualfindingsintheliteratureregardingthe importanceofforeignbankpresence inloweringspreads. Column 3 indicates that a highershareofagriculturalandconsumerloansinabank’sloanportfolioisassociated withhigherspreads,suggestingthattheseloansareperceivedasbeingriskier.Interms of economic magnitudes, banks with a 10 percent higher loan portfolio share in agricultureandconsumer loanscharge 0.4 and0.1 percentage points higher spreads relativetotheaverage,respectively. Themaindeterminantof netinterestmargins isthedepositmarketshare.Incontrastto the spread regressions, the market share of banks enters negatively in the margin

8Themarketshareofloans(resultsnotreported),ontheotherhand,doesnothaveasignificanteffecton spreadsandmargins.Resultsareavailablefromtheauthorsuponrequest.

regressions. This result could possibly reflect individual banks’ aggressive pricing strategies to gain market share in the deposit market. The effect of this variable is economicallyimportant,asaonestandarddeviationincreaseinmarketsharereduces marginsby0.4percentagepoints.Incontrasttothespreadregressions,theimpactof banksizeonmarginsisnotsignificant. As in thecase ofthe spread regressions, overhead costsandnoninterestincomeare insignificant once bankspecific fixed effects are included. Higher capital adequacy ratios lead to a significant reduction of margins, reflecting the tradeoff between keeping greater safety cushions and reaching higher margins by increasing financial leverage and investing in longerterm assets. The association between margins and ROA is significant and positive. However, we also acknowledge the possibility of reverse causation, that is, banks that realize higher margins are likely to be more profitable.Theliquidityvariableisnegativelyandsignificantlyassociatedwithhigher marginsinthefixedeffectsregressions.TheimpactofcapitaladequacyandROAis modest:onestandarddeviationincreaseincapitaladequacyreducesspreadsbyabout 0.2 percentagepoints,whilevariationsinROAofthesamemagnitudechangemargins onlyby0.1percentagepoint.Incontrasttothespreadregressions,theloanportfolio variablesdonothaveasignificanteffectonmargins. Finally, theforeign ownership dummyisinsignificantwiththeinclusionofbankspecificfixedeffects. 4.2 Market Structure and Macroeconomic Characteristics Tables 4.2 and 4.3 report results for interest spreads and margins, respectively, includingmarketstructureandmacroeconomiccharacteristics.Columns1–7intables 4.2and4.3examinetheeffectofbankconcentrationandforeignparticipationinthe loananddepositmarkets.Again,weemployclusteredstandarderrorsandfixedeffects but quarterly and yearly time dummy variables are not included in all regressions becauseofmulticollinearityissues.Wecontinuetofindthatbankspreadsdeclinewith sizeandliquidityandincreasewithbankmarketshares,whilemarginsdecreasewith bankmarketshares,liquidity,andcapitaladequacy,andincreasewithROA.

Table 4.2 Ex post spreads, banking structure and macro variables

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) Overhead 0.001 0.006 0.001 0.012 0.021 0.013 0.028 0.019 0.024 (0.030) (0.0 28) (0.029) (0.028) (0.770) (0.029) (0.039) (0.029) (0.024) Non interestincome 0.005 0.000 0.005 0.005 0.017 0.003 0.004 0.043 0.047 (0.100) (0.108) (0.102) (0.101) (0.063) (0.101) (0.100) (0.105) (0.078) Banksize 2.452 2.562 2.615 1.742 1.313 1.732 1.737 1.597 1.391 (0.711) 3 (0.676) 3 (0.691) 3 (0.673) 2 (0.673) 2 (0.677) 2 (0.678) 2 (0.688) 2 (0.539) 2 Marketshare 0.099 0.078 0.092 0.072 0.043 0.073 0.069 0.074 0.052 deposits (0.041) 2 (0.031) 2 (0.038) 2 (0.044) (0.052) (0.045) (0.045) (0.032) 2 (0.045) Capitaladequacy 0.007 0.010 0.009 0.007 0.005 0.007 0.006 0.008 0.004 (0.005) 1 (0.004) 2 (0.004) 2 (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.004) 1 (0.005) ROA 0.025 0.026 0.025 0.027 0.026 0.027 0.027 0.033 0.026 (0.027) (0.025) (0.026) (0.027) (0.025) (0.028) (0.028) (0.029) (0.025) Liquidity 0.003 0.003 0.003 0.003 0.003 0.003 0.003 0.003 0.003

(0.001) 3 (0.001) 3 (0.001) 3 (0.001) 3 (0.001) 3 (0.001) 3 (0.001) 3 (0.001) 2 (0.001) 3 Foreignbank 0.348 0.332 0.313 0.339 0.321 0.523 0.299 (0.283) (0.285) (0.262) (0.281) (0.297) (0.340) (0.314) Foreignparticipation 0.0390.041 loans (0.025) (0.026) Foreignparticipation 0.033 deposits (0.023) Origin1 0.061 0.087 (0.009) 3 (0.015) 3 Origin2 0.011 0.007 (0.006) 1 (0.003) 2 HHI(loans) 0.003 (0.002) 2 HHI(deposits) 0.001 (0.000) 2 CR3(loans) 7.016 (3.069) 2 CR3(deposits) 5.547 (2.487) 2 Marketshare 0.064 (industry) (0.027) 2 Marketshare 0.009 (agriculture) (0.034) Marketshare 0.010 (consumer) (0.028) Exchangerate 0.004 (0.022) RGDP 0.000 (0.011) Inflation 0.018 (0.029) Moneymarketrate 0.0004 (0.000) 2 Constant 21.520 22.354 22.339 15.755 17.154 15.733 15.615 19.193 15.253 (5.335) 3 (5.145) 3 (5.380) 3 (5.221) 3 (5.058) 3 (5.094) 3 (5.078) 3 (4.482) 3 (3.921) 3 Fixedeffects YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES Timedummies1/ YES YES YES NO NO NO NO YES NO Observations 303 303 303 303 303 303 303 303 303

Rsquared 0.608 0.632 0.625 0.593 0.567 0.591 0.594 0.602 0.557 Clustered standarderrorsinparenthesis. 3, 2,and 1denotesignificanceatthe1 ,5 ,and1 0percent levels,respectively. 1/Timedummiesnotincludedinallequationsbecauseofmulticollinearityproblems. Table 4.3 Net Interest Margin, Banking Structure and Macro Variables (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) Overhead 0.007 0.006 0.005 0.011 0.010 0.011 0.001 0.003 0.009 (0.012) (0.012) (0.011) (0.013) (0.015) (0.250) (0.011) (0.014) (0.014) Non interest 0.058 0.061 0.044 0.072 0.064 0.037 0.025 0.049 0.051 income (0.049) (0.054) (0.045) (0.051) (0.055) (0.042) (0.043) (0.056) (0.048) Banksize 0.154 0.170 0.340 0.080 0.069 0.468 0.504 0.219 0.209 (0.377) (0.384) (0.398) (0.368) (0.366) (0.386) (0.393) (0.448) (0.375) Marketshare 0.080 0.077 0.072 0.083 0.084 0.068 0.067 0.094 0.076 de posits (0.016) 3 (0.017) 3 (0.017) 3 (0.017) 3 (0.017) 3 (0.016) 3 (0.017) 3 (0.022) 3 (0.015) 3 Capitaladequacy 0.003 0.003 0.003 0.003 0.003 0.003 0.004 0.003 0.003 (0.002) 1 (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) 1 (0.002) 1 (0.002) 2 (0.002) 2 (0.002) 1 (0.002) 2 ROA 0.022 0.022 0.021 0.025 0.025 0.021 0.021 0.022 0.024 (0.011) 1 (0.011) 1 (0.011) 1 (0.012) 2 (0.012) 2 (0.011) 1 (0.011) 1 (0.010) 2 (0.012) 1 Liquidity 0.001 0.001 0.0005 0.0004 0.0003 0.0004 0.0004 0.0004 0.000 (0.000) 3 (0.000) 3 (0.000) 2 (0.000) 2 (0.000) 2 (0.005) 1 (0.005) 1 (0.000) 2 (0.000) Foreignbank 0.027 0.011 0.013 0.060 0.067 0.009 0.055 (0.249) (0.227) (0.232) (0.231) (0.201) (0.169) (0.207) Foreign 0.0090.010 participation (0.003) 3 (0.003) 2 Foreign 0.009 participation (0.004) 2 Origin1 0.0060.006 (0.004) (0.005) Origin2 0.000 0.001 (0.003) (0.003) HHI(loans) 0.000 (0.001) HHI(deposits) 0.0004 (0.000) 1 CR3(loans) 3.462 (1.331) 2 CR3(deposits) 0.624 (0.802) Marketshare 0.019 (industry) (0.006) 3 Marketshare 0.002 (agriculture) (0.018) Marketshare 0.032 (consumer) (0.018) 1 Exchangerate 0.017 (0.207) RGDP 0.017

(0.007) 2 Inflation 0.021 (0.015) Moneymarket 0.011 rate (0.013) Constant 4.639 4.623 6.096 2.513 2.167 7.635 2.135 4.623 4.243 (2.735) (3.774) (2.906) 2 (2.960) (2.710) (2.572) 2 (2.771) (3.774) (2.727) Fixedeffects YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES Timedummies YES YES YES NO NO NO NO YES NO Observations1/ 303 303 303 303 303 303 303 303 303 Rsquared 0.756 0.775 0.749 0.786 0.777 0.749 0.741 0.786 0.760 Clusteredstandarderrorsinparenthesis. 3, 2,and 1denotesignificanceatthe1%,5%,and10%levels, 1/Timedummiesnotincludedinallequationsbecauseofmulticollinearityproblems. Wefirstexaminewhetherchangesinthemarketstructureofthebankingsystemhave hadanimpactonbankspreadsandmargins.Asinthepreviousregressions,wedonot findthatforeignbanks,onaverage,havelowerspreadsormargins.However,wefind thatforeignbankshaveanindirect“spillovereffect”ontheoveralllevelofspreadsand margins.Column1inTable4.2and4.3suggeststhatforeignbankparticipationinthe loanmarket(i.e.,theshareofloansheldbybanksthatareatleast50percentforeign owned)doesnothaveastatisticallysignificantnegativeeffectoninterestspreadsbut resultsinlowermargins. To examinethisfurther, weincludetwo interaction terms between the origin of the bank and foreign market share in loans in column 2.9 The origin 1 variable is the interaction between the firsttier international bank and the foreign market share variable, while origin 2 is the interaction between other types of foreign banks and foreign market share. We find that the interaction term between the firsttier internationalbankandtheforeignmarketsharevariableisnegativelyandsignificantly associatedwithinterestspreads,whiletheinteractiontermbetweenotherforeignbanks and foreign market share is positively and significantly associated with spreads. ConsistentwithVanHoren(2007),thisresultsuggeststhatbankorigincouldmatterfor bankingefficiency,with only the western foreignbank having a spillover effect in lowering interest rate spreads. However, the presence of other foreign banks is associated with higher spreads. In the margin regressions, this effect is found tobe insignificant(column2,Table4.3). A similar result is obtained when we consider the foreign market share in deposits (column3ofTables4.2and4.3).Foreignbankparticipationinthedepositmarketdoes not have a statistically significant effect on interest spreads but results in lower margins, again providing evidence of the spillover effect. However, as before, the interactiontermsbetweenthebankoriginandforeignmarketsharevariableareagain significant in the spread regressions, suggesting that the presence of firsttier internationalbanksisimportantforbankingefficiency.

9Wedonotincludetheforeignbankdummyintheregressionsincolumns2and3duetopotential multicollinearitywiththeoriginvariables.

Higher bank concentration, as measured by the HerfindahlHirshman index (HHI) (columns4and5inTables4.2and4.3)inboththeloananddepositmarkets,raises spreads significantly, while a higher HHI in the deposit market is positively and significantlyassociatedwithmargins. 10 AonestandarddeviationincreaseintheHHI for loans results in an 0.2 percentage point increase in spreads, while one standard deviationincreaseintheHHIfordepositsresultsina0.1percentagepointincreasein spreads.Similarresultsareobtainedwhenweconsiderthesharesofloansanddeposits heldbythetop3banksinthecaseofspreads,andtheshareofloansheldbythetop3 banksinthecaseofmargins. Bankmarketsharesinloanstotheindustrialsectorarefoundtobesignificantlyand negatively associated with lower spreads, consistent with lower risks of loans to a sector with “easy” collateral. At the same time, industrial loan market shares are positivelyassociatedwithmargins(column8inTables4.2and4.3),possiblyreflecting lack of competition due to market segmentation within the industrial loan market. Finally, market shares in consumer loans are significantly and positively associated withhighermargins.Thiscouldbeanindicationofmarketsegmentationandhighbank switchingcostsinacreditmarketthatischaracterizedbyrelationshipbanking. Next,weextendthemodelspecificationwithfourkeymacroeconomicvariables.The results in column 9 of Tables 4.2 and 4.2 indicate that higher real GDP growth is positivelyandsignificantlyassociatedwithhighermargins,reflectingbetterinvestment opportunitiesandlowerdefaultrisksinahighgrowthenvironment,butthiseffectis insignificant in the spread regressions. Likewise, the inflation rate has a small but significanteffectonmargins.Theexchangerateenterspositivelyandsignificantlyin themarginregression,suggestinganarrowingofmarginsinperiodsoftheexchange rate appreciation. The coefficient of the inflationadjusted money market rate is significant and weakly positive in the spread regression, indicating some effect of fundingcosts.Overall,theeconomiceffectsofthemacroeconomiccharacteristicson spreadsandmarginsareverysmall.

4.3 Robustness Inthissection,webrieflydiscusswhetherthereportedfindingsarerobusttoalternative definitionofspreads,thetreatmentofoutliers,andtheinclusionofothervariables.As discussedinfootnote9, spread2 isthedifferencebetweenexantecontractedloanand depositinterestrates,andiscomputedasthedifferencebetweentheweightedaverage lendingandweightedaveragedepositrates.Ascanbeseenfromcolumn1inTable4.4 theresultsareconsistentwiththosefoundfortheexpostspreadvariable.Wecontinue tofindthatlargerbankshavelowerspreads,whilegreatermarketpower,asmeasured by a higher market share of deposits, is positively and significantly associated with higher spreads. In contrast to the regressions for spreads and margins, the foreign ownershipdummyisnowsignificantandenterstheequationwithanegativesign,that is,majorityforeignownedbanksappeartohavelowerexantespreads.However,this resultisnotrobustinalternativespecifications.

10 WedonotincludetheHHIforloansanddepositsvariableswiththerelevantforeignparticipation variables simultaneously in the same regression as they are highly correlated with each other, with correlationcoefficientsof0.9fortheloanmarket.

Table 4.4 Robustness Test

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Dependentvariable Spread2 Spread Margin Spread2 Spread Margin Overhead 0.059 0.029 0.010 0.029 0.002 0.007 (0.088) (0.070) (0.020) (0.156) (0.031) (0.012) Noninterestincome 0.089 0.022 0.027 0.162 0.012 0.065 (0.279) (0.183) (0.051) (0.435) (0.130) (0.056) Banksize 7.568 2.214 0.472 9.417 2.303 0.052 (2.349) 3 (1.115) 1 (0.420) (2.120) 3 (0.735) 3 (0.386) Marketsharedeposits 0.351 0.085 0.059 0.419 0.103 0.073 (0.114) 3 (0.052) (0.017) 3 (0.115) 3 (0.041) 2 (0.017) 3 Capitaladequacy 0.002 0.008 0.003 0.004 0.004 0.001 (0.018) (0.005) (0..001) 1 (0.015) (0.005) (0.001) ROA 0.024 0.059 0.035 0.051 0.009 0.017 (0.042) (0.015) 3 (0.014) 2 (0.029) 1 (0.031) (0.012) 1 Currentliquidity(LR2) 0.004 0.006 0.001 0.011 (0.004) (0.003) 2 (0.001) (0.013) Liquidassetsratio(LR1) 0.005 0.015 (0.009) (0.004) 3 Foreignbank 1.269 0.435 0.023 0.522 0.269 0.126 (0.666) 1 (0.291) (0.218) (0.695) (0.253) (0.114) Constant 71.375 22.443 6.622 88.108 21.351 3.754 (17.877) 3 (8.232) 2 (3.060) 1 (17.227) 3 (5.352) 3 (2.747) Fixedeffects YES YES YES YES YES YES Timedummies YES YES YES YES YES YES Observations 274 269 269 249 305 305 Rsquared 0.462 0.637 0.812 0.452 0.564 0.794 Clusteredstandarderrorsinparenthesis. 3, 2,and 1denotesignificanceatthe1%,5%,and10%levels, respectively. To test the sensitivity of our results to outliers, we estimate the basic fixedeffects regressionsreportedinTable4.1byexcluding3ofthesmallestbanksinouroriginal sample. These institutions are among the smallest banks in the sector. In contrast to other banks, these banks focus on feegenerating investment and private banking activitiesratherthandeposittakingandloanmaking.Columns2,3,and4,reportthe results for all three independent variables. 11 The basic thrust of our results remains unchanged. Incolumns5and6,wereplacethecurrentliquidityratiovariablewiththeliquidasset ratio(ratioofliquidassetstototalassets).Inbothequations,thecoefficientshavethe expected negative sign, indicating that more liquid banks receive lower returns on holdingcashorsecuritiesthanbanksthatinvestahighershareoftheirfundsinloans. However,asopposedtothecurrentliquidityvariable,theliquidassetsratiohasonlya significantimpactonmargins,butnotonspreads.

11 Wealsoranregressionswiththe shareofnonperformingloans aswellas loanlossprovisions insome specifications. However,these variables were foundto have noimpact onspreadsandmargins. The resultsarenotreportedhere,butareavailableuponrequest.

V. CONCLUSIONS Inthispaper,weuseabanklevelpaneldatasettoexaminethedeterminantsofexpost interestratespreadsandnetinterestmarginsinArmeniaovertheperiod2002–06.Our results provide evidence of the important role that bankspecific characteristics and marketstructureplayinexplainingthevariationofinterestratespreadsandmargins.In contrast to findings from other transition and developing countries, the presence of foreign banks was notfound to directly contribute to lower spreads and margins in Armenia.However,wefindevidenceofaspillovereffectofforeignbankpresenceon interestspreadsandmargins.Specifically,wefindthatforeignbankoriginmattersfor banking efficiency, with the presence of the firsttier western foreign bank having a spillovereffectinloweringspreads.Banksfromdevelopingcountriesorothertypesof foreignbankstendtochargehigherspreads.Theresultssuggestthatthereisalarge potentialtoincreasecostefficiencyandcompetitioninthebankingsystem,including byencouragingfurtherwesternbankentry. The large explanatory power of timeinvariant banklevel fixed effects in the panel analysismaybeanindicationofhighmarketsegmentationandlowcompetitioninthe bankingsector.Improvinginformationonbothsidesofthemarket,thatis,information about borrowers for banks and information about banks for depositors, is likely to contributetoamorecompetitivebankingmarketanddecliningmarketsegmentation. Theintroductionofacreditregistryin2003andtheestablishmentofaprivatecredit bureau, which became operational in 2007, have been important steps towards improvinginformationsharingonthecreditworthinessofborrowersinArmenia.These willservetoincreaseborrowerdisciplinebyreducingmoralhazard,andatthesame timemitigatetheinformationmonopolythatbankshaveovertheirexistingclients,thus reducingbankswitchingcosts.Atthesametime,increasedpublicinformationabout banks as well as bank ratings by international rating companies in Armenia could contribute to improving market transparency, the functioning of market forces, and depositorconfidence.

Appendix Variable Definitions

VariableName Description Differencebetweentotalinterestincomereceivedinquarter dividedbyaverageloansforthequarterandtotalinterest Spread expensesinquarterdividedbyaveragedepositsforthe quarter. Differencebetweentotalinterestincomeandexpensesover Margin averageassets Differencebetweentheweightedaveragelendingrateandthe weightedaveragedepositrateforeachbankandeachquarter Spread2 wheretheweightsaretherelativeamountsofdepositsor loanscontractedatspecificinterestrates. Overhead Administrativecostsovertotalassets Non interestincome Non interestoperatingincomedividedbytotalassets Banksize Logoftotalbankassets Bankdepositsdividedbytotalcommercialbankdepositsin Marketsharedeposits economy Capitaladequacy Ratioofregulatorycapitaltorisk weightedassets ROA Profitsovertotalassets Currentliquidity Liquidassetsoverdemandliabilities Portfolio(i ndustry,agriculture, Bankloanstosectoroveritstotalloanportfolio consumer) Foreign Equals1forforeignownedbank;0otherwise Foreignbankparticipation Shareofloans/depositsinthehandsofforeignbanks loans/deposits Herfindahlindexloans/deposits Sumofsquaredloan/depositmarketsharesofbanks Concentrationratio(3)loans/deposits Shareofthreelargestbanksinloans/deposits Marketshare(industry,agriculture, Bankloanstosectordividedbytotalcommercialbankloans consumer) tosector GDPgrowth QuarterlyrealGDPgrowth Inflation QuarterlychangeoftheCPIindex Realmoneymarketrate Quarterlymoneymarketrateadjustedforinflation Changeintheexchangerate QuarterlychangeinDramperUS$

REFERENCES Beck,T.,andH.Hesse(2006), BankEfficiency,OwnershipandMarketStructure.Why areInterestRateSpreadssoHighinUganda? ,WorldBankWorkingPaperNo.4027, Washington:WorldBank Bonin,J.,I.HasanandP.Wachtel(2005),Bank Performance,Efficiencyand OwnershipinTransitionCountries ,JournalofBankingandFinance,29,31–53 Claessens,S.,A.DemirgüçKuntH.andHuizinga(2001),HowDoesForeignEntry AffectDomesticBankingMarkets?JournalofBankingandFinance,25,891–911 Claeys,S.andR.VanderVennet(2005), DeterminantsofBankInterestMarginsin CentralandEasternEurope:AComparisonwiththeWest ,GhentUniversityWorking PaperNo. 316, Belgium:GhentUniversity Dell’Ariccia,G.andR.Marquez(2004),InformationandBankCreditAllocation , JournalofFinancialEconomics,72,185–214 DemirgüçKunt,A.andH.Huizinga(1999), DeterminantsofCommercialBank InterestMarginsandProfitability:SomeInternationalEvidence ,WorldBank EconomicReview,13,379–408 DemirgüçKunt,A.,L.LaevenandR.Levine(2004),Regulations,MarketStructure, Institutions,andtheCostofFinancialIntermediation ,JournalofMoney,Creditand Banking,36,593–622 Floerkemeier,H.(2006), Armenia’sFinancialSystem:WhyisitSmall,andWhat ReformsareNeeded? ,IMFSelectedIssuesPapers,SM/06/434,Washington: InternationalMonetaryFund Fries,S.,D.NaevenandP.Seabright(2002), BankPerformanceinTransition Countries ,EBRD,London:EconomicBankforReconstructionandDevelopment Fries,S.,andA.Taci(2005), CostEfficiencyofBanksinTransition:Evidencefrom 289Banksin15PostcommunistCountries ,JournalofBankingandFinance,29,55– 81 Hasan,I.andK.Marton(2003), DevelopmentandEfficiencyoftheBankingSectorina TransitionalEconomy:HungarianExperience ,JournalofBankingandFinance,27, 22492271 MartinezPeria,M.andA.Mody(2004), HowForeignParticipationandMarket ConcentrationImpactBankSpreads:EvidencefromLatinAmerica ,JournalofMoney, Credit,andBanking,36,511–537 VanHoren,N.(2007), ForeignBankinginDevelopingCountries:OriginMatters , EmergingMarketsReview,8,81105 PRODUCTIVITY AND SOURCES OF ENTERPRISE LEVEL EFFICIENCY IN ARMENIA

KarenGrigorian,Ph.D,Economist,WorldBank VahramStepanyan,Ph.D,Economist,WorldBank *

Abstract: This study reviews in detail the sources of productivity growth in the Armenian economy and suggests policies to encourage sustainable growth in the future. It summarizes the theoretical frameworks and empirical findings on the determinants of enterprise productivity in developed and transition economies, highlightedbyanumberofkeyfactorsincludingcompetition,foreigndirectinvestment andtheinstitutionalenvironment.Thecentralpartofthestudycomprisestheempirical analysisofasamplesurveyof300Armenianfirmsinthemanufacturingandservice sectorsduring20032005toprovideestimatesoftotalfactorproductivity(TFP). The study suggests thatArmenia is not experiencing significant growth in technical efficiency,andpossiblyinTFP,contrarytotheargumentsofmacroeconomicpapers. Technical progress at the level of firms seems to be playing no major part in the Armenian growth process. The results suggest no significant difference in TFP on average between the industrial and service industries. The study finds virtually no differenceinaveragelevelsofTFPbetweenfirmsthatexportandthosethatdonot, indicating that competitive pressures in export markets have not acted to raise productivity in Armenian firms. This indicates the urgent need for policy to ensure fasterdisseminationofnewtechnologiesandknowhowandtheimprovementoflabor skills.ThemeanestimatedvaluesofTFParevirtuallyidenticalinforeignownedand domesticfirms,suggestingseriousweaknessesintheinstitutionalenvironmentwhich prevent foreign owned firms from transferring their technology and knowhow to Armenian companies. There is at best mixed evidence that competition is having a positive effect on TFP because competitive pressures are not yet strong enough in Armeniatoinfluencemanagerialdecisions. ThestrongmacroeconomicperformanceoftheArmenianeconomyisprobablybased primarilyonthesuccessfulimplementationofreformsatthestartoftransition,notably priceliberalization,openingtheeconomytotradeandrelianceontheprivatesector. However,thetimehascomeforasecondphaseofreformstoenhancetheinstitutional environment,increasecompetitionintheeconomyandencouragedeeperpenetration offoreigndirectinvestment.

JELClassification:D24,O47,C3,O43, Keywords:Armenia,productivity,stochasticfrontieranalysis *TheauthorsaregratefultoProf.S.Estrin(LSE)forhisvaluableguidanceandusefulsuggestions.

I. INTRODUCTION

Armenian firms have, for some years, been operating in an environment where widespread economic reforms have been implemented, and this has laid the foundationsforastrongmacroeconomicperformance.Asaresult,theeconomyhas maintainedstrongeconomicgrowthformorethanadecade,thoughemployment(inthe formal sector) has not been rising and investment rates have been moderate. This suggeststhatefficiencygainsmayhavebeenoneoftheimportantenginesofeconomic growth(e.g., The WorldBank,2007,henceforthThe Caucasian Tiger) via both the reallocationoflaborfromlowtohighproductivityuseswithinandbetweensectorsand fromtechnicaladvancewhichmayhaveincreasedtechnicalefficiency of production over time. In this study, we try to understand in detail the sources of productivity growth in the Armenian economy, in order to be able to develop policies which encouragesustainablegrowthinthefuture. InthispaperweexploreindetailthesourcesofproductivitygrowthintheArmenian economy.First,wereviewthegrowingliterature,boththeoreticalandempirical,onthe potentialdeterminantsoffirmlevelproductivity.Wesurveythisliteraturefocusingon findings of potential relevance to Armenia. We thenmovetoconsidertheeconomic situation in Armenia at the aggregate level with respect to these determinants, in particular,competition,ownershipandforeigndirectinvestment. Next we examine a sample survey of approximately 300 Armenian firms in the manufacturingandservicesectorsintheyears2003 to 2005 to provideestimates of totalfactorproductivity(TFP).Wewillusetheseestimatestoexplorethedeterminants ofproductivityandtoseehowthesedifferfromothereconomies.Wealsoinvestigate the pattern ofvariationinTFP in firmsacross industries, time and region over this period.Thefindingscanbeusedtoidentifytheareasofgreatestpotentialintermsof productivity,andthosewheregreatereffortswillberequiredtobringthefirmstothe productive frontier. We base our formulations on studies of productivity in other transition economies, including those of Central and Eastern Europe (CEE) and the former Soviet Union. This will allow us to compare and contrast our findings concerningthefactorsinfluencingproductivityinArmeniawiththepathsfollowedin comparableeconomieselsewhere. The paper has five further sections. In the following section we survey the large literature concerning the definition and the determinants of productivity growth. The formerhelpsustoidentifyappropriateestimationmethodsforcalculatingproductivity, namelyestimationofTFPviastochasticfrontiers.Thelatterprovidesuswithanumber of hypotheses concerning the possible determinants of productivity differentials in Armenia, in particular, with respect to competition and theimpact of foreign direct investment.Inthethirdsectionwepresentinformationonthemovementsofthekey determinantsofproductivityinArmenia,beforeoutlininginthefourththeestimation methodsusedinthisstudyandthedataemployedinourempiricalwork.Theresultsof ourestimationsarereportedinthefifthsection,whichprovidesestimatesofTFPby year, industry and region as well as explores the principal determinants of company level total factor productivity in Armenia. We bring together the findings and draw policyconclusionsinthesixthsection.

The strengths of this study are its ability to derive analytically advanced and robust measures of company efficiency across different industries and time, as well as the abilitytoexplore,basedonthetheoreticalliteratureandtheplethoraofstudiesforother transitioneconomies,carefullydevelopedhypotheses concerning the determinants of differential productivity performance in Armenian firms. This work can provide a sound basis for the development of policy to encourage the enhancement of productivityinArmenianfirms.However,itisalsousefultonotethelimitationsofthis Paper.Ourresearchisbasedonarelativelyshortsample(threeyears)andhenceisnot wellsuitedtotheevaluationoflongtermtrends.Moreover,thestrengthofthePaper– itsabilitytoidentifyfirmlevelproductivityanditsdeterminantsisalsoitsweakness. Becauseitisbasedonasurveyofexistingenterprises, it is not designed to explore some of the issues which have been given stress in the productivity literature, for example,theroleofsocalled“creativedestruction”asproposedbyJosephSchumpeter (1942) whereby productivity within a sector is increased by the entry of new and relativelymoreefficientfirms.Becauseoursampleisconstructedtocoveragroupof firmsthatsurvivethroughoutthesampleperiod,weexcludeallentrantsandexitersand hencecannotexploretheimpactof“creativedestruction”onproductivitygrowth. II. MEASURING COMPANY PRODUCTIVITY AND ITS DETERMINANTS

2.1 Estimating Total Factor Productivity

TherearetwoapproachestoestimatingTFPintheliterature,andweemploybothin thisPaper.ThefirstisbasedontheSolowproductionfunctionanddevelopsTornquist indexesbyconstructingtheresidualinaproductionfunctioncalculatedatthemeanof thesample.HenceonedirectlyestimatesTFPbyestimatingaproductionfunction.The TFP is the residual in this function, calculated for example for the Cobb Douglas specificationasthedifferencebetweenactualoutput(valueadded)andpredictedoutput usingthefactorsharesoflaborandcapitalastheweightsforthetwoinputs.Anearly exampleofthisapproachisbyJorgenson,GollopandFraumeni(1987)fortheUS.For developingcountries,theworkwasextendedbyChenery, Robinson and Syrquin, in their path breaking 1986 book, "Industrialization and Growth". For transition economies,theapproachhasbeenusedespeciallytoanalyzetheimpactofprivatization and therearewellover100 studiesusing some sort of production function method (e.g.,DjankovandMurrell,2002). The secondapproachtoidentifying TFP is viatheestimation of frontier production functions. The idea here is to compare the efficiency of firms, on average, with a constructedcompositerepresentingthemostefficientproducer.Thusoneestimatesthe relativedistanceforafirmbetweenitsactualcombinationofinputsandthepredicted inputcombinationforagivenlevelofoutputthatwouldberequiredbytheestimated “mostefficient”firm.Theapproachistocalculate,usinginformationabouttheinput output combinations of the most efficient firms, the technology frontier and then measuringTFPinotherfirmsasadistancefromthis,controllingforcapitalintensity. Estimation is usually undertaken using nonparametric estimation methods (e.g., Schmidt,1985;Cornwall,Schmidt,andSickles,1990).This approachhas beenused lessfrequentlyintheanalysisofdevelopingandemergingmarkets,perhapsbecauseof data limitations, but it provides aclear picture of the dispersion of efficiency within eachsector.

Usingeitherapproach,butmorecommonlywiththeSolowmethod,onecanidentify the factors that influence TFP. Using the Solow approach, one can estimate simultaneouslyasecondroundregressionwhichincludespotentialdeterminantsonthe righthandside.Inthefrontiermethod,onecaneithercomparetheestimatesofmean (median) TFP in subsamples defined across determinants or include these as independentvariablesinthe“augmented”frontierproductionfunctionestimates.We usedbothapproaches in thisstudy,buthave tended to reportthefindingsfrom the former method because given the sample size these are probably more reliable for inference. 2.2 Determinants of TFP The Western literature on the determinants of enterprise productivity has tended to focus on the role of competition, organizational factors (notably ownership and the effects of foreign direct investment) and institutional environment, including governmentregulations.Thesefactorshavealsoprovedtobeimportantintransition,so itisupontheseandthefindingsofthehugeliteratureonthedeterminantsofTFPin transitioneconomiesthatthisbriefsurveywillconcentrate.Onecanthereforeidentify threefactorsinthetransitionliteraturethatareexpectedtoinfluencethelevelandrate of change of total factor productivity: competition, ownership (notably foreign ownership),andcharacteristicsofthefirm(oftenproxiedbytheageofthefirm).

A. Competition It is usually hypothesized that company efficiency will be positively affected by the competitiveness of the market in which the firm operates. The argument is that monopolypowerprovidesfirmswithamarginofcomfortwhichtheyexploitbyfailing to undertake the organizational changes necessary to maintain and increase TFP. Competition puts pressure on management because they have to work harder to maintaintheirprofitsagainsttheencroachmentsofotherfirmsandpotentialentrants. This leads them to undertake more efficiency enhancing activities, for example, innovationintroducingnewproductionmethodsandnewproducts,andrearranging organizationalstructuressoastokeepperformanceaheadofotherfirmsinthemarket. These pressures are necessarily reduced in a less competitive environment, where managers, because they do not face the same “struggle for survival”, may become complacentorindolent. Inaclosedeconomy,theforcesofcompetitionderive principally from thedomestic market.Inthisstudy,weproxythesebuyindustrydummyvariables.Theymayalso derivefrominternationalcompetition.Thusfirmswhichoperateprimarilyinoverseas markets,exportingthebulkoftheiroutput,mayfacemuchgreatercompetitivepressure and this may force them to enhance their TFP relative to firms facing competitive pressures only in their domestic markets. Finally, firms that are innovating new products may also be more productive,inthat their lower cost base allows them to successfully bring to market new products. Alternatively, high rates of product innovationmayinsteadindicatefirmsthatarestrugglingtosurvivegiventheircurrent levelsofTFP,andrepresentmoreasignalofdesperationthanefficiency.

B. Private Ownership The privatization policies of transition economies are based on the hypothesis that privately owned firms will have higher TFP than state owned ones, because of their superiorcorporategovernance.Thereisveryconsiderableevidenceforthisargument (e.g.,DjankovandMurrell,2002).Thehigherlevelsofefficiencyarisebecauseitis easierinaprivatelyownedfirmtoaligntheinterestsofownersandmanagersandto reducetheproblemsofasymmetricinformationbetweenownersandmanagerswhich lieattheheartofthecorporategovernanceproblem(e.g.,Estrin,2002).Withprivate ownership,monitoringcanbeefficientandtheflowsofinformationtransparenteither viadirectownerrepresentationonboardsorthroughthecompetitivepressureofthe stockmarket.Moreover,bankruptcylawsimpactonprivatebutnotstatefirms,andthe absence of a bankruptcy threat can lead to “soft budget constraints” that distort managerialincentives.Thestructureofownershipisinprincipleaveryimportantissue inArmeniaasinalltransitioneconomies,butisnotofdirectempiricalrelevancefor ourstudybecauseallthefirmsinoursurveyareprivatelyowned. C. Foreign Direct Ownership

Inthetransitioncontextforeignownershiphasprovedtobethemostsignificantsource ofproductivitygains.Onecanconsidertheimpactatthreelevels: • Onthemacroeconomy • Onthefirmswhichhavebeenboughtbynewforeignowners • Onotherfirmsintheeconomy,througheitherhorizontalorverticalspillovers. Sincethisissuchanimportantarea,wewillconsider eachofthese impacts in turn. TheimpactofFDIonhosteconomiesiscomplexasforeigninvestorsinteractwith,and thusinfluence,manylocalindividuals,firmsandinstitutions.However,onaverage,the net effectmaywellbelessthanmanyobserversexpect. Figure 2.1 outlines various channelsofimpact.AnyFDIprojectcloselyinteractswithlocalbusinesses;mostofthe impactonthehosteconomyistransmittedthroughthisinteraction.Beyondthis,FDI alsoimpactsonotheraspects,includingmacroeconomicvariables,thehosteconomy’s institutional framework as wellas the naturaland social environment. Most of these interactions are bilateral. On the one hand, foreign investors adapt to the local institutional,socialandnaturalenvironmentindesigningtheirstrategies.Ontheother hand, they would – intentionally or not – influence the environment through, for instance,politicallobbying,settinggoodexamplesoflaborstandards,orpollutingthe environment. The FDI project in turn is designed by a Multi National Enterprise (MNE)locatedoutsidethecountry.ThestructureandstrategiesofthisMNEthusshape theprojectanditsinteractionswiththelocalenvironment. Macro Effects

FDI is argued to influence the main macroeconomic variables of concern to policy makers: balance of payments, employment, and gross domestic investment. FDI is commonlybelievedtohaveapositiveeffectoneachofthesevariables. At the country level, scholars have attempted to relate the inflow of FDI to macroeconomicgrowthintermsofGDPonthebasisofendogenousgrowthmodels (e.g. Borensztein, Gregorio and Lee 1998). They find a complementary effect of

countries’ absorptive capacity, measured by proxies for human capital, which positively moderates the relationship between FDI inflows and GDP growth. In particular, a minimum threshold level of human capital is required to benefit from inwardFDI.Balasubramanyan,SalisuandSapsford(1996) differentiate countries by theirtradeopenness,andfindthatFDIhasamorepositiveeffectoneconomicgrowth of countries with exportoriented trade regime compared to countries with import substitutiontypetraderegimes. Figure 2.1 Channels of Impact of FDI ParentMNE FDIProject Knowledge LocalFirms =countryoforigin =subsidiaryrole Linkage =intraindustryspillovers =industry =modeofentry =interindustryspillovers =organizational =centralization Competition =absorptivecapacity centralization =knowledge =entrepreneurship =clusters =size&experience management

Natural SocialIssues Institutions Macroeconomy environment =’ethical’business =policyframework =balanceof =pollutionhavens practices =FDIlaws payment =globalstandards =labourstandards =competitionlaws =capitalstock ... =wages =educationalsystem =employment ... ... ... Source:Meyer(2004)

More recently, Li and Liu (2005) examine the macroeconomic relationship taking accountoftheendogeneityofFDI,thatisforeigninvestorsarelikelytoseeklocations withhighereconomicgrowthaswellascontributetothisgrowth.Theirempiricalstudy showsthatsuchanendogenousrelationshiphasincreasedoverthetimeperiodoftheir studyfrom1970to1999.Thisendogeneityreinforcesthecomplementaryrelationship betweenFDIandlocalhumancapitalinpromotingeconomicgrowth. Horizontal spillover effects to local firms Hirschman(1958)arguesthatpoorcountrieswouldbenefitfrompursuingunbalanced industrial growth promoting, in particular, the developing of industries with strong backwardandforwardlinkages. Thebenefitsthatlocalfirmsmayattainarisethroughseveralchannels: • Demonstrationeffectsworkthroughthedirectcontactbetweenlocalagentsand MNEsoperatingatdifferentlevelsoftechnology.Afterobservinganinnovation adaptedtolocalconditions,localentrepreneursmayrecognizetheirfeasibility, and thus strive to imitate them. As local businesses observe existing users,

information about new technologies and business practices is diffused, uncertaintyisreduced,andimitationincreases. • Foreigninvestorsaffectlocalbusinessesnotonlythroughproductivityeffects, butinavarietyofotherways.Forexample,scholarshaveinvestigatedmarket access benefits generated by foreign investors (e.g., Aitken, Hanson and Harrison, 1997; Greenaway, Sousa and Wakelin, 2004). The rationale of this literatureisthatMNEswoulddirectlyorindirectlyshareknowledgeonhowto operateininternationalmarkets,bybuildingtradechannels,andbyenhancing thecountryoforiginreputation. • FDI contributes to human capital formation, especially through training and labormobility.Trainedlocalemployeesmaymovetolocally ownedfirms or setupownentrepreneurialbusinesses.MNEstypicallypaysalariesabovelocal standards to discourage highly trained employees from leaving, yet they may notopposesuchmovementsifthenewfirmsbecomebusinesspartners.Many successfullocalfirmstracetheiroriginstoentrepreneursortopmanagersthat hadpriorlinkstoMNEs(e.g.,Altenburg,2000).Even where fewemployees move,thosethatmovemaymakeasubstantivecontributiontolocalbusiness. • FDImayhelplocalfirmstoaccessexportmarkets.MNEsaremorelikelyto sharegeneraltradeknowledge,asitislessindustryspecificandnotpartoftheir corecapabilitiesanditsdiffusiontolocalbusinessesdoes notendanger their own competitive advantage. Moreover, foreign investors may help building tradechannelsandacountryoforiginreputationthatlocalfollowersmayuse fortheirexports(e.g.,Altenburg,2000). • Foreign investors may support local supplier industries and markets for specializedinputs,suchaslaborandmaterials.Beyondthequalityofphysical products this may enhance in particular the quality of services provided by suppliers, such as justintime delivery and low default rates. With these improvedinputs,localfirmsinturnmayenhancetheirproductivity. Negative spillovers on local firms are also possible, notably through crowding out effects. Foreign investors may gain market share at the expense of local firms. This wouldleavethelocalfirms,atleastintheshortrun,withexcessproductioncapacity and thus low productivity and low profitability. Moreover, foreign investment may source internationally and thus weaken the local industry’s domestic supplier base. TheseseemlesslikelytoberelevantthanthepositiveeffectsinthecaseofArmenia whichisarelativelysmallandopeneconomywithlowlevelsofFDI. Perez(1997)offersanevolutionarymodeloftechnologyspilloversthatdependonthe absorptivecapacityoflocalfirmsandareinverselyrelatedtothetechnologicalgap;yet received spillovers influence the market share dynamics between local and foreign competitors.Hethussuggeststhatstronglocalfirmswouldbenefitfromcompetition from foreign investors, while weak firms are likely to be crowded out completely. MarkusenandVenables(1999)analysetherelationshipbetweenthenumberofforeign owned firms and the number of domestic firms under a range of assumptions and scenarios.Theyarguethat,undercertainconditions,entryofforeigninvestorswould triggerentryofnewdomesticfirmsinverticallyrelatedindustries. Theresearchquestionthathasprobablyattractedmost empirical researchishorizontal spillovers, in particular the productivity benefits that local firmsattract from foreign investmentintheirindustry.Thisliteraturebypassesthefactthatknowledgeflowsare

notmeasurabledirectlybyestimatinglocalfirms’productivityasafunctionof,among otherfactors,thepresenceofforeigninvestorsintheindustry.Thisstreamofresearch was initiated by Caves (1974), and in 2007 we counted over 60 studies using this approach(e.g.,MeyerandSinani,2007). Thisliteraturehasevolvedinseveralstages,notablytoemploymorecomplexdatasets andmoresophisticatedanalyticaltechniques,andtoincorporatemoderatingvariables that may influence this relationship. Important references include Caves (1974), BlomströmandPersson(1983),HaddadandHarrison,(1993)andAitkenandHarrison (1999). Görg and Strobl (2001) review this literature using a Metaanalysis of 21 studiesandfindthatthesemethodologicalissuessubstantiallyaffecttheresults,such that early crosssectional studies may have overstated the actual effects of FDI. Moreover,theypointtoimportantvariationsofspilloversacrosscountries.

Vertical spillover effects to local firms Local firms may benefit from vertical linkages in a supply chain, benefiting from knowledgetransferstosuppliersandcustomers.MNEsmaymakeadeliberateeffortto improvethequalityoflocalsuppliers,especiallyforcomponentsthatcannotbecost efficientlyimportedduetohightransportationcostsorwherethelocalindustryhasa naturalcostadvantage(e.g.forlaborintensivecomponents).Theseeffectsbenefitalso firmsinotherindustries,forinstanceprovidersofbusinessservices,suchasaccounting orlegalservices.Similarlytheymaysupporttheircustomers,forinstancebyproviding traininginsalesandmarketing. Wehavelessempiricalevidenceonthismatter,mainlybecausethedatasetsrequiredto analyze vertical interactions along the supply chain are fairly complex and hard to obtain. Lall (1980) provides the first major study on vertical spillovers. Building on Hirschman(1958),Lalldevelopsthetheoreticalargumentsonwhybackwardlinkages wouldemerge,andheprovidesprobablythefirstsystematicempiricalevidence. Javorcik (2004) employs industrylevel inputoutput data from Lithuania, and finds higher productivity in industries which are suppliers to industries with high foreign presence. This productivity effect is larger when the foreign investors are domestic marketorientedratherthanexportoriented.Atthesametime,shefindsnoevidenceof spilloverswithinthesameindustry. Sources of Variation in FDI Impact

Multinationalsvaryintheirinternaloperations,includingforinstancethecentralization of decision making, organizational cultures, and human resource management practices. Consequently, subsidiaries in emerging economies would vary in their interactions with other business units of the parent’s network. This in turn affects interactions with local businesses, for instance, the development of local supply networks,investmentinhumancapital,employeemobility,andthestagesofthevalue chainlocatedinthehosteconomy.

Some of these variations are due to industryspecific features (e.g., Grosse 2005). InfrastructureFDIforinstanceintransportortelecommunicationcangreatlyenhance productivity in other sectors of the economy, yet at the risk of foreign control – possiblyevenmonopoly–ifthesectorisnotappropriatelyregulated.Similarbenefits and risk arise from financial sector investment. Services such as information technologyoperateinmorecompetitivemarketsandmaybenefitawiderangeofother business. In manufacturing, major variations arise from the need or opportunity to produceclosetothemarketduetohightransportationcostsorlowscaleeconomies. AnaspectofparticularrelevanceforMNEspilloversis intrafirmknowledgetransfer. Knowledge sharing within the MNE is a precondition for knowledge spillovers. Typicallyinvestorswouldtransfer‘knowhow’totheiraffiliatestoenhanceefficiency andproductivity.Yettheywouldkeeptightercontrolovertheir‘knowwhy’,because suchknowledgecould–ifdiffusedtootherfirms–threatentheinternationalmarket position of the firm. Knowledge spillovers would also rise with higher value added activities, such as complex manufacturing processes like making customized machinery,ratherthanmassassemblyof,forexample,garmentsorshoes. In particular, research and development (R&D) is commonly believed to generate positivespillovers.Traditionally,MNEwouldkeeptheirR&Dactivitiesclosetotheir homebase,orlocateitinleadingedgeclusterssuchasSiliconValley.However,recent data show that R&D is increasingly located in countries such as China, India, SingaporeandBrazil(UN2005).Thispotentiallybooststhetechnologyflowsbetween MNEsandlocalsuppliersorlocalinstitutions,suchasuniversities. Thesevariationsinfluencetheeffectivenessofgovernmentdesigningpoliciesaimedto attractFDI.Theliteratureshowsthatpoliciesoughttoconsiderexplicitlywhattypeof FDI wouldbenefitthehosteconomy,ratherthanfocusingonquantitativetargetsfor FDI.Moreover,evaluationofpoliciesshouldanalyzewhattypesofinvestors,andwith whattypeofprojectswouldconsiderthelocalenvironment(incl.politicalinstitutions) attractive. D. Age of the Firm A large literature (e.g., Djankov and Murrell, 2002) attests to the argument that in transitioneconomies, denovo entrantsmaybemoreefficientthanexistingfirms.This isbecausenewfirmsdonotcarrytheheritagefromtheSovieteraofhoardedlabor, antiquatedcapitalandweakmanagement.Aswehavenotedabove,privatizationmay improve corporate governance of former state owned firms, but former state owned enterprises (SOEs) may, for some years, face problems in their attempts to enhance performance.ThisisbecauseSOEsmaytakeconsiderabletimetoreduceemployment to appropriate levels and to invest in new equipment. New firms will not face the problems of restructuring to the new market environment that is at the heart of the transition problem for SOEs. Being created from scratch, they do not inherit the structural problems overmanning, underinvestment, poor quality control, weak marketingandfinancialcontrolandalltheotherdifficultieswhichbesetSOEsand former SOEs. “Firms” under socialism did not have many of the functions of independent Western enterprises; sales, marketing, distribution, supply, finance or investment. In many cases, the inherited structures, attitudes and organisational culturesoftheoldstateownedfirmsaresostrong that such radical restructuring is

impossibleoratleastveryslow.Thisimpliesthatitmaybeeasierandmoresuccessful to satisfy the demands of the market economy in entirely new organisations (e.g., Estrin,MeyerandBytchkova,2005).Moreovertheselectionprocessthatdetermines the foundation of new firms may also ensure that more market focused and entrepreneurialpeoplewillleadthemfromtheoutset.Wearenotabletoexplorethis issueusingourArmeniasample.

2.3 Findings from the Literature on Productivity in Transition Economies Theliteratureonthedeterminantsofproductivityintransitioneconomiesishuge,and thereareanumberofmajorsurveysincludingDjankovandMurrell(2002)andEstrin etal, 2007.Thesepaperseachcitemorethanonehundredworksrespectively.Most papersintheliteraturefocusontheeffectsofTFPofownershipandespeciallyforeign ownership. Thus the Djankov and Murrell concluded that the effect of private ownershipwaspositiveinCentralandEasternEurope(CEE)butinsignificantinthe CommonwealthofIndependentStates(CIS). Therearearound20morerecentstudiesthatanalyzetheimpactofownershiponTFP orrateofchangeofTFPinthetransitioneconomies,usingvalueadded,totalproduct or sales revenues as the dependent variable and either dummy variables or percent shareownershipasmeasuresofdifferenttypesofownership(e.g.,Estrin etal .,2007). Anumberofthesestudieshavesimplyexaminedthedifferentialeffectofstateversus private ownership, while others examine the effects of other subcategories of ownership.ThestudiescoverboththeCEEandCISregions. With the possible exception of Russia, studies usually find the effect of private ownershiponTFPtobepositiveornonnegative.Moreover,studiesthatbreakprivate ownership into several categories show that the overall private v. state ownership dichotomy includes different private ownership effects. Except for two of the three studiesofSlovenia,allstudiesuniformlysuggestthatprivatizationtoforeignowners’ increases efficiency. The effect of foreign ownership is strong and robust across regions.Thisis a veryimportant finding for policymakersinArmeniatowhichwe returnintheconclusions. TheeffectofdomesticprivateownershiponTFPisbyandlargealsofoundpositivein the CEE region and in Ukraine, but it is quantitatively much smaller than that of foreignownership.ThisisprobablybecausethecountriesofCEEaremoreadvanced onthetransitionpath(seee.g.EBRDTransitionReport Indicators and World Bank Doing Business Indicators). Russia appears to be different from Ukraine in that Sabirianova, Svejnar and Terrell (2005) and Brown, Earle and Telegdy (2006) find withlargedatasetstheeffectofdomesticprivateandmixedownershiptobenegative orinsignificant.Similarly,CommanderandSvejnar(2007)usealargefirmleveldata setfrom26transitioneconomiesandfindaninsignificantaverage (across countries) effectofdomesticprivateownershiprelativetothatofthestateownership.Ingeneral, theeffectofdomesticprivateownershipappearstobemorepositiveintheCEEregion thanintheCISanditseemslikelythatthisisaconsequenceofthegreaterprogress made in institutional development. Thisconfirms the results from findings for other emerging markets. Once again this is an important conclusion for Armenian policy makers.

Itisalsoimportanttounderstandthefactorsdrivingtechnicalprogress;thechangein company TFP. Studies that examine the change in productive efficiency show that foreignownedfirmsimprovedefficiencyfasterthandomesticprivateandstateowned firmsinthe1990sandearly2000s.Thisdifferentialeffectisnotdetectable,however, inCommanderandSvejnar’s(2007)studyofthe20022005paneldatafromthe26 transitioneconomies.Itishencepossiblethatforeignownersbroughtaboutasizable increaseinefficiencyintheperiodimmediatelyafteracquiringthelocalfirmsinthe 1990s,butthatlaterontherateofchangeinefficiencyhasbeenonaveragesimilarin alltheprincipaltypesofownershipoffirms. ItisalsointerestingtoconsidertheexperienceofChina,wheregrowthhasproceeded at high levelsfor several decades,arguably on the basis of both increases in factor inputsandrisesinTFP.Thereareanumberofimportant studies of TFP in China. ProbablybecauseprivatizationisarelativelyrecentphenomenoninChina,anumberof studies,includingJeffersonandRawski(1996),addressTFPissueswithfirmleveldata but do not examine differences in TFP related to privatizationor ownership.Studies that address these issues find diverse results, with the effect of nonstate ownership beingmostlypositivebutsometimesstatisticallyinsignificantandsometimesnegative. ThusJeffersonandSu(2006)usealargesampleoffirms(N>20,000)andshowthat theeffectofprivatejointstockownershiponthelevelofTFPispositive.Hu,Song, andZhang(2004)inturnuseamuchsmallersampleoffirmsinselectedregions(N> 700) and find the effects of cooperative as well as domestic and foreign private ownershiptohaveapositiveeffectonthelevelofproductivity.Yusuf,Nabeshima,and Perkins(2006)usearelativelylargesampleoffirms(N>4,000)andfindtheeffectof domestic private, collective and complete foreign ownership on the level of productivity to be statistically insignificant, theeffectofforeignjointventurestobe positive,unreformedstateownershipnegative,andreformedstateownershippositive. Finally,Dong,Putterman,andUnel(2006)usefirmleveldatafromNanjing(N=165) to examinetheeffect on the rate ofchange of TFP, and theyfindtheeffect of state urbanownershiptobepositive,whiletheeffectofstateruralandbothprivateurban andprivateruralownershipisfoundtobeinsignificant. TheTFPstudiesofCEE,CISandChinahencegenerateafairlyclearoverallpicture which is highly relevant to Armenia. There is clear evidence that foreign ownership raises productivity. In China and CEE, the estimates suggest that private domestic ownership also raises TFP relative to state ownership but the effect is quantitatively smallerthanthatofforeignownership.RussiaandelsewhereintheCISisdifferentin that the performance effect of privatization to domestic owners is found to have a negativeorinsignificanteffectonTFP,andthatisprobablybecauseofweaknessesin the institutional framework. In addition, concentrated (especially foreign) private ownershiphasastrongerpositiveeffectonperformancethandispersedownershipin CEEandCIS.DatafromCEEandCISsuggestthatnew firms are equally or more productivelyefficientthanfirmsprivatizedtodomesticowners. Inviewoftheaboveresults,thequestionnaturallyarisesastowhytheTFPeffectof privatization to domestic owners has been much smaller than the TFP effect of privatization to foreign investors. Discussions with managers, policy makers and analystssuggestthreeleadingpossibleexplanations.Thefindingmayreflectinpartthe limited skills and access to world markets on the part of the local managers. Domestically owned privatized firms are also the ones where performancereducing

activities such as looting and defrauding of minority shareholders have been most frequent. Finally, in a number of countries the nature of the privatization process initially prevented large domestic private owners from obtaining 100% ownership stakesandinsidersorthestateoftenownedsizeableholdings.Itoftentooktheselarge shareholdersseveralyearstosqueezeoutminorityshareholdersandintheprocessthe large shareholders sometimes artificially decreased the performance of their newly acquiredfirmsinordertosqueezeouttheminorityshareholdersatlowshareprices.

III. CORPORATE ECONOMIC BEHAVIOR IN ARMENIA Thepreviousdiscussionindicatesthatitwillbeimportanttofocusonthefollowing determinantsofTFPinArmenia: • Competition • Foreigndirectinvestment • Institutionaldevelopment In this section we briefly review the situation in Armenia, where possible against potentialcomparatorsamongtransitioneconomies. 3.1 Competition ThereislittledirectinformationaboutmarketstructureinArmenia.Asnoted,inthe empirical work which follows we control for market power effects by the use of industry dummy variables. However, there is some encouraging evidence on this subject.AscanbeseeninTable3.1,Armeniahasmadeconsiderableprogressinthe areasofpriceandtradeliberalization,relativetoothercountriesintheFSUandthe Balkans. Table 3.1 Price and Trade Liberalization in Armenia and Comparators, EBRD Transition Indicators in 2007

PrivateSector PriceLiberalization TradeSystem CompetitionPolicy ShareofGDP Armenia 75 4+ 4+ 2+ Bulgaria 75 4+ 4+ 3 Estonia 80 4+ 4+ 4 Georgia 80 4+ 4+ 2

Russia 65 4 3+ 2+ Ukraine 65 4 4 2+ Source:EBRD,TransitionReport.

Thustheprivatesectorshareisamongstthehighestinthesample,andforbothprice and trade liberalization, Armenia joins the more advanced transition economies in achievingthehighestpossibleranking.However,thepossibilityofseriousmonopoly problemsisindicatedbythelowscorewithrespecttocompetitionpolicy,thoughthe levels are not out of line with other countries in the sample. We return to this issue below. 3.2 Foreign Direct Investment and Ownership

ItcanbeseeninTable3.2thatFDIinflowsintoArmeniahavebeenrelativelylowin comparison with the sample of FSU economies. It should be noted that in fact the levelsofFDIhavebeenevenhigherforthetransitioneconomieswhichhaveacceded totheEU,forexampleCzechRepublic,HungaryandPoland.

Table 3.2 FDI Inflows into Armenia and other economies (ratio to GDP, percent) 2007 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 Estimate Geo rgia 2.5 3.6 8.4 8.1 8.3 14.3 15.5 Estonia 5.5 2.1 7.8 5.9 15.9 3.4 4.5 Armenia 3.3 4.7 4.3 6.1 5.1 5.3 5.2 Ukraine 2.0 1.6 2.8 2.6 8.7 5.4 6.6 Russia 0.1 0.0 0.4 0.3 0.0 1.1 0.8 Source:EBRD,TransitionReport . TableA.1showstherateofFDIinflowsandGDPgrowthinRussia,Ukraine,Poland andBulgariafrom1992to2007.ItcanbeseenthattherehasbeenanupswinginFDI levelsintheFSUeconomiesandBulgariafromalowbase,andthisisassociatedwith anaccelerationofeconomicgrowth(oneshouldbecarefulnottoinfercausalityhere– thetwophenomenaarecorrelatedbutthecausality is not clear). However,it canbe seenthattheincreaseingrowthinArmeniasince1999isnotcorrelatedwithchangesin FDI, indeed, FDI levels remain very low throughout. Table A.2 highlights that FDI flowsremainlowinArmenia,evenbythestandardsofmanyeconomiesoftheFSU. 3.3 Institutional Development AccordingtotheEBRDTransitionReports,Armeniahasmadeconsiderableprogress in termsof institutionaldevelopment.The average scoreacross the EBRD indicesis around3.1,whichisthehighestintheCISthoughbelowLithuania(3.7),Latvia(3.64) andEstonia(3.75).ItisabovepossiblecomparatorstateslikeGeorgia(3.05)andalso RussiaandUkraine(3.0). A richer framework can be developed from the Heritage Foundation that provides indicationsof“economicfreedom”onascalefromzeroto100(best).Accordingtothis assessment, Armenia’s situation in the key measures with respect to FDI and productivity look strong with respect to business and investment freedom and the overallindicatoralsosuggeststhatthepolicyenvironmentisratherbenign.However, theassessmentalsoindicatessomedeeprootedproblemsinArmeniawithrespectto theenforcementofpropertyrightsandcorruption.AsindicatedinSection2,theseare likelytohavehadanegativeeffectontheflowsofFDI. 3.4 Summary Theliteratureonproductivityindevelopedandtransitioneconomiesplacesemphasis on three determinants: competition, foreign direct investment and institutional development.Inthissection,wehaveconsideredArmenia’sperformanceinthesethree areas,incomparisonwithothertransitioneconomies.Wefindthatreformswithrespect topriceandtradeliberalizationhavebeenveryeffectivebutArmenialagswithrespect toCompetitionPolicy.SincetheWesternliteraturestressestheroleofcompetitionin

TFPdetermination,thismaybeasourceofdifficulty.However,themostsignificant issueisthelowlevelsofFDIinArmenia.Thesehaveremainedatalowlevelfora number of years, despitefastgrowthandamodestly good institutional environment amongtransitioneconomies.ItseemslikelythatthiswillhindertheevolutionofTFP inArmenia.

IV. ESTIMATION METHODS AND DATA 4.1 Estimation Methods

Astochasticfrontierframeworkisemployedtomeasurethetechnicalinefficiencyof theeconomicagents,eitherfirmsorindustries,whicharetheobjectsoftheassessment. Thismethodologyallowsustoevaluatetheperformanceofeachagent,relativetoa commonestimatedbestpracticefrontierofproduction. Theestimates ofthis frontier arebasedontheperformancesoftheotheragentsintheeconomy.Infact,accordingto theclassicalmicroeconomictheory,functioningmarkets do not tolerate inefficiency. Butthisaxiomiseasilycontradictedbyanyempiricalanalysis.Intheempiricalcontext therefore,efficientproducerswillbethosewhoproduceasmuchaspossiblewiththe employedinputs. Since the analysis concerns a single output production, we can think of technical efficiency in terms of TFP. That is the ratio between actual output and the optimal valueasspecifiedbyatheoreticalproductionfunction.Theproductionfunctionisthe mechanism through which the firm transforms inputs into outputs. There can be differentspecificationsoftheproductionfunctionthatreflectdifferentrestrictionson itsproperties. It is important to point out that, given this definition of technical inefficiency, the correct specification of the theoretical production functionandthe list of inputs are decisiveinavoidingerrorsinitsmeasurement. Theoutputofthefullyefficientfirmcanbeexpressedas: (1) yi=f(X i,β)exp(v i) wheref(X i,β)isthetheoreticalproductionfunction,βisthevectorofparametersofthe productionfunctiontobeestimated.iindexesthei th firminthesampleofNfirmsand exp(v i)isanunrestrictedidiosyncraticandstochasticcomponentofthemodel.Thislast componentembodiesmeasurementerrorsandanystatisticalnoiseandrandomshockof thefrontier. Theoutputofthelessthanefficientagentis: (2) yi=f(X i,β)ξ iexp(v i) where0<ξ i<1istheactualtechnicalefficiencyofthefirm. The empirical analysis carried out with stochastic frontier models was originally proposedbyAigner,LovellandShmidt(1977)whomadedistributionalassumptions on the composed error ε i = v i ui defining it as the sum of a symmetric normally distributed variable (the idiosyncrasy) and the absolute of a normally distributed variable(theinefficiency): (3) vi~N[0,σ v] (4) ui=|U i|whereU~N[0,σ u] Thisisthehalfnormalspecificationofthemodel.Bothcomponentsareassumedtobe independentandidenticallydistributedacrossobservations. Theanalysisusuallyfocusesonthemeasurementofξ imorethanontheestimatesof thetechnologyparametersanditiscarriedoutin a linear formafter thelogarithmic transformationofthepreviousmodel: (5) lny i=lnf(β‘X i)+v iui whereu iis–lnξ iandisalwaysnonnegativeandcanbeinterpretedasthepercentage variation of observed performance from the firm’s own frontier performance (or efficientperformance). The empirical analysis of inefficiency that arises from this framework requires two steps.Inthefirststeptheestimatesofthetechnologyparametersβ,σ vandσ uallowto constructestimatesofthecomposederrorε.Inthesecondsteptheestimateofξ icanbe calculatedusingtheformulaproposedbyJondrow etal .(1982): (6) ξi=E(exp(ui|ε i)]. Theassumptionofhalfnormalityfortheinefficiencytermconstrainsthemeanofthis stochastic component to beequal to zero. However this assumption can be relaxed. Some authors such as Stevenson (1980) extended the model to a truncated normal distributionforuithatallowsthemeantobenonzero.Thisnewandlessrestrictive distributionimplies: 2 (7) ui=|U i|whereU i ~N[,σ u ] Themeanoftheinefficiencycomponentofthemodelcannowbemodelledtovary withsomefactorsthattheresearcherconsidersdecisivesuchasindustry,locationand soon.Formally,theinefficiencycanbespecifiedasalinearfunctionofthesefactors: (8) i= 0 +θ’Z i Aswillbeshownlater,theparametersoftheunderlying distribution ofu i providea mechanismtointroduceheterogeneityintheproductioninthemodel. The available data for our analysis of Armenian firms consist of a sample of N economicagentsobservedoverTyearssothemodelcanbenowwrittenas: (9) lny it =lnf(β‘X it )+v it uit whereeachobservationconcernsfirmiinperiodtandt=1,2,…,T.

Thegreateramountofinformationcontainedinthepanelstructureofthedatacanbe exploited in the estimation oftheproduction function parameters and the efficiency scores.However,whileincreasingtheavailableinformation,paneldatacanexacerbate the presence of heterogeneity. The large variation of characteristics between all the sectorsandfirmsoftheArmenianeconomyproducesalargeamountofmeasuredand unmeasuredheterogeneity. Asdescribedearlier,instochasticfrontieranalysistheultimateobjectiveistoobtain estimatesofu it .Thefirststepistoestimatethetechnologyparametersβ,σ vandσ u.If theseestimatesareinappropriateorinconsistentthentheestimationofε iandtherefore uiislikelytobeproblematicaswell.Heterogeneityintheproductionfunctionandin theinefficiencydistributioncanbeacauseofinconsistencyinthestructuralparameters estimation.Heterogeneitycanbeeitherobservable(ifwehavesomemeasureofitor variables which capture it) or unobservable (suchas the individual effects and time effectsinpaneldata). When heterogeneity is observable, it is important to understand how it enters the model:thatiswhetheritaffectstheproductionfunctionortheinefficiencydistribution, oritscalesthemintheformofheteroskedasticity.Whenheterogeneityisunobservable andthereforeunmeasured,itisimportanttouseanadequatepaneldataestimator. Inordertoaddressalltheseheterogeneityissues,twodifferenttreatmentsofstochastic frontierswithpaneldatahavebeencarriedoutinordertofindthespecificationofthe model that better fits the described data. The first treatment is pooled crosssection estimation to be performed within the stochastic frontier framework. Even if this estimation could appear restrictive because it assumes that all observations are independentanditdoesnotexploitthewithinvariationofpaneldata,itcouldbean interestingstartingpointfortheanalysis. With this specification, when the assumed underlying distribution is the truncated normal,itispossibletointroduceheterogeneityintothedistributionofefficiencyby modellingthemeanas: T (10) it = 0+θ Zit whereZ it canincludeallthefactorsthatarelikelytoaffecttheunderlyinginefficiency distribution, such as binary indicators for employees training and innovative firms. Moreover this specification allows the heterogeneity to be introduced in the model throughtheheteroskedasticityofbothrandomcomponentsv it andu it as,forinstance, depending on dimensional variables. Modelling the mean of the inefficiency distributionandthevariancesoftherandomcomponentsgivesmoreflexibilitytothe estimationandallowstheintroductionoffullheterogeneityinthemodel.Moreoverthe estimatesofefficiencyaretimevarying. The secondtreatmentof stochasticfrontiers thatisfeasible withpanel data isthe so called“truefixedeffect”modelputforwardbyGreene(2002): (11) yit =α i +β‘X it +v it uit inwhichindividualeffectsareintroducedsimplybyplacingindustrydummiesinthe classical stochastic frontier model. There are two advantages of this technique: the industryeffectsareallowedtobecorrelatedwiththeexplanatoryvariablesofthemodel andtheestimatedefficiencyistimevariant. InourempiricalworkonArmenia,weemployedmanyofthesetechniquestocalculate themeasuresoftechnicalefficiency.Inparticular,ouranalysisprovidedestimatesof technical efficiency (u it ) aswellasthetechnologyparametersβ,σ v and σ u. Wealso addressedtheheterogeneityissuesusingthepooledcrosssectionapproach. 4.2 Data Theempiricalworkisbasedonasurveyof300enterprisesinArmeniacoveringthe period2003to2005.Itfocusedonindustrialfirmsin11sectors,includingchemicals, textiles,jewelryandbeverages(includingjuices)aswellasservices.Itwasdesignedto providethebasisforanalysisoftrendsincompanybehaviour,includingproductivity. Thus, it collected information about output, labor input and factors influencing productivity such as ownership, legal status, privatization and competitive pressures (e.g.exports).Thedatafromthequestionnairewassupplementedbyinformationfrom thedatabaseoftheAnnualAdministrativeandRegulatoryCostSurveyofArmenia(on thebusinessenvironment)andofficialstatisticsfromtheNationalStatisticalServiceof Armenia.Thelatterwasusedtoprovideinformationoncapitalinput. V. ESTIMATES OF TFP AND ITS DETERMINANTS IN ARMENIA

In this section, we discuss the results of a large number ofeconometricexercisesto estimateTFPinArmenia,toanalyzethewaysthatitvariesacrossindustries,ownership and time and to understand the forces that drive the determination of levels of productiveefficiencyinArmenia. 5.1 The Stochastic Frontier Production Function in Armenia

The estimationmethodsused in thisstudy arediscussed inthe previous section.We first report the findings based upon the estimates of TFP using stochastic frontier methods.Infactnumerousspecificationswereusedbuttheresultsofinterestdidnot vary to any significant degree. The particular specification on which this section is basedusesatruncatednormalmodelandtheresultsoftheestimationarereportedin Table5.1. Table 5.1 Stochastic Frontier Production Function Dependent variable: log Output in 2005

Standard Standard Variables Coefficient Variables Coefficient Error Error lnCapital(k) .13 .03 Equipment 1.02 .36 lnLabor(l) .89 .05 Food .07 .35 Year2 .07 .13 Furniture .63 .44 Year3 .96 .13 Jewelry .25 .45 Cloth ing ,Shoes 1.32 .37 Juices,mineral .26 .40 Construction .16 .41 Mining .26 .42 Constr uction Services .06 .36 .49 .36 Material Textile .79 .42

Standard Standard Variables Coefficient Variables Coefficient Error Error _cons 7.58 22.97 sigma_v2 1.18 .47 Mu chi2(1) =0.13 Any_training .08 .14 Prob>chi2=0.71 Any_new_pr .39 .17 chi2(1)=0 .00 _cons .20 22.97 Prob>chi2=0.99 /lnsigma2 .17 .07 Numberof 458 /ilgtgamma 6.25 204.70 observations sigma2 1.18 .08 Waldchi2(15)860.14 gamma .00 .39 Prob>chi2 0.00 sigma_u2 .00 .46 Loglikelihood 687.94 Theestimatedequationisstronglysignificantandthecoefficientsonlaborandcapital are plausible and highly significant. 1 An important test of whether the results are “sensible” is given by the “Test for CRTS”. The test asks whether the estimated coefficientswhenaddedsumtounity,implyingconstantreturnstoscale.Theestimated coefficientsadduptoalmostpreciselyunity,andthetestconfirmsthattheestimates are notsignificantly differentfrom unity. This allows one to place some faith in the findingssincemostotherstudiesfordevelopedanddevelopingeconomiesalsotendto find the coefficients summing to around unity. The economic interpretation is that futuregrowthinArmeniaderivingfromincrementsoffactorinputslaborandcapital will not be constrained by the onset of diminishing returns. One should not place excessiveemphasisonthisfinding,however,sincemoresophisticatedspecificationsof technologyhavenotbeentestedandwouldbehardtofitonadatasetofthissize. 5.2 Measuring Differential Performance in Armenia

GiventhestochasticfrontierreportedinTable5.1,onecancalculatethevariationin efficiencyaccordingtoanumberofcriteria.Inthissubsection,wefirstconsiderTFP overall,andthenanalyzethevariationaccordingtotheprincipaldriversdiscussedin theliteraturesummarizedinsection2,aswellastheArmenianliterature.Theseinclude year,activity,legalstatus,foreignownership,regionandsector. A. Overall TFP OurestimatessuggestthatproductivityintheaveragefirminArmeniaiscalculatedto be78.12%ofthelevelfoundinthemostefficientfirminthecountry.Thestandard deviationaroundthisestimateisfoundtobearound20%,whichsuggeststhattheleast efficientfirmsareprobablyoperatingatapproximately60%oftheproductivityofthe mostefficientfirms(ifthedistributionoftheerrorswerenormal). We do not know whether the most efficient firms in Armenia are efficient by internationalstandards.Weonlyknowthattheforcesofcompetitionandopennessto

1 These results are preliminary and not entirely comparable with those in the literature. First, TFP estimatesareusuallyundertakenatthesectorallevelandwithcarefulcontrolforthequalityoflaborand capitalinputs.Thedatasetwastoosmalltopermitdisaggregationatthisstage,thoughitishopedto undertake finer estimation in the future. There are also some concerns about the quality of the data concerningcapital,whichwasmeasuredathistoriccost. international trade, for example, have acted to keep the dispersionefficiency among Armenianfirmslowbyinternationalstandards.Perhapsthemostimportantpointisthat these estimates for Armenia are broadly comparable with those for developed and transitioneconomies,andcertainlywellwithinthestandardrange.Thisgivesussome confidence when considering the results with respect to the determinants of productivity. B. Growth in Productivity ThefindingswithrespecttoproductivitygrowthovertimearereportedinTable5.2 TheinfluentialCaucasianTigerstudystressedthepotentialroleoftechnicaladvance andincreasesinTFPasthebasisforfutureArmeniangrowth.Inthiscontext,themean levelsofTFPbyyearreportedinTable5.2mayseemtobedisappointing.Theyshow that while the estimated mean level of TFP in Armenian firms was 0.7812 (78.1 percent) of the most efficient firms, this mean value did not vary to any significant extentacrossthethreeyearsofthestudy.Indeed,ifthemeanwaschangingatall,it was in a downward direction. This implies that we havenotbeenabletoidentifya positivesignificanttechnicalprogress(increaseinTFP)overtheperiodofourstudy.

Table 5.2 Mean Values of TFP (te1)

Byyear ByExport ByIndustry ByRegion Category (Marz) 2003 0,80 0 0,79 Chemic als 0,72 Arag. 0,77 2004 0,79 1 0,78 Clothing,Shoes 0,79 Ararat 0,78 2005 0,76 Constr uction 0,77 Arma. 0,79 ByActivity ByForeign Construction 0,78 Gegh. 0,82 Ownership Material Industry 0,78 0 0,78 Equipment 0,77 Kot. 0,79 Services 0,78 1 0,79 Food 0,77 Lori 0,77 Other 0,77 Furniture 0,82 Shirak 0,78 Jewelry 0,82 Syun. 0,82 Juices,mineral 0,80 Vay.Dzor 0,81 Mining 0,81 Yerevan 0,78 Services 0,79 Textile 0,75 Total 0,78 Total 0,78

However,itshouldbenotedthatthetimeperiodisshortandoneshouldnotexpect greatchangesinTFPoversuchashortperiod.Theinternationalcompaniesreportedin Caves (1982)alsofailed to identify dynamiceffects in TFP estimates. Even so, we mustconcludethatinthistimeperiodproductivitygrowthasmeasuredbyTFPhasnot been significantly different from zero, which highlights the need for policies to accelerateitsgrowthinthefuture. 5.3 Determinants of TFP in Armenia WereportthevariationinTFPbyactivityinTable5.2.Theresultssuggestthatthereis no significant difference in TFP on average between the industrial and service

industries. There is thus nothing in our findings to favor selecting industry over servicesorviceversaasabasisforagrowthstrategyfoundedonproductivitygrowth. Thereishowever,somewhatmoreusefulinformationwhenoneconsidersthevariation inTFPacrosstwelveindustriesinTable5.2,thoughthesemustbetreatedwithcaution becausethestandarddeviationofthetechnicalefficiencyislargerthantheestimated differences.Wenotethat,measuredatthemean,technicalefficiency isfoundtobe highestinthejewelry,furnitureandjuicesectoraswellasmining.Itislowest,onthe otherhand,inchemicals,textilesandconstruction.Theservicesectoroperatesmoreor lessexactlyatthemeanoftechnicalefficiencyacrosstheeconomy. Onemusttakecareininterpretingtheseresults.Theydonotprovideinformationabout whether the most efficient firms, at the frontier, are more efficient in the jewelry or furnituresectorthaninthechemicalsortextilesectors.Wedonothaveinformationon the relative efficiency of the most efficient firms. The results inform us about the dispersioninefficiencywithindifferentsectors.Theytellusthatdispersionisgreater inchemical,textilesandconstructionthaninjewelry,furnitureandjuices.Thismaybe becausethelattersectorsaremoremonopolistic,forexample,sothatinefficientfirms emergeandsurviveinamannerthatisharderinmorecompetitivesectors. A. Exporting Itmightbepredictedthatfirmssubjecttohigher levels ofcompetition,for example becausetheyaresellinginoverseasmarketswhicharehighlycompetitive,wouldhave higherlevelsofproductivity.HoweverthishypothesisisnotconfirmedinTable5.2.In fact,wefindvirtuallynodifferenceinaveragelevelsofTFPbetweenfirmsthatexport and those that do not. This appears to suggest that competitive pressures in export marketshavenotactedtoraiseproductivityinArmenianfirms.Giventhediscussionin section 2 about FDI and horizontal spillovers, this is a troubling finding for the Armenianeconomy.Indeed,themeanlevelofTFPinexportingfirmsisveryslightly smaller than that found in nonexporting firms. However, it is also possible that the appreciation of the Armenian currency is reducing the value of exports relative to domesticgoods,andthereforeinourfrontierfunctions,whichmeasureoutputbysales, reducingtheproductivitymeasuredindramsofexportingfirms.

B. Foreign Direct Investment and TFP Wenoted in section3 that levels ofFDI werevery lowin Armenia– itistherefore perhaps unsurprising that the impact of FDI on TFP is not discernable. We find in Table 5.2 that the mean estimated values of TFP are virtually identical in foreign ownedanddomesticfirms.Thisrunsstronglycountertotheresultsintheliteraturefor othertransitioneconomies,andindicatestheremayremainseriousweaknessesinthe institutional environment which prevent foreign owned firms from transferring their technologyandknowhowtoArmeniancompanies. 1Thisnegativeresultisprobably ourmostimportantfinding,andwereturntothepolicyimplicationsintheconclusions. 1Howeverthesamplecontainsveryfewforeignownedfirms,only4outofmorethan300.Thefactthat the sampling method identified so few foreign firms is indicative that foreign ownership has not yet penetratedverydeeplyintotheArmenianeconomy,andthatthisshouldbehighasanobjectiveofa secondphasereformagenda.

C. Regional Effects

The analysis reveals considerable variation in technical efficiency on average across regions,thoughonceagainthedifferencesinmean TFPare not greatin comparison withthestandarderrors.WeobservethatTFPishighestonaverageinfirmsoperating inGegharqunik,SyunikandVayotsDzor,andthelevelsaresome3or4percenton average higher than those found in the least productive regions; Aragatsotn, Lori, ShirakandYerevan. 5.4 Solow Production Function Results

Asanalternativetotheabove,wenextestimateaSolowtypeaugmentedproduction functioninordertounderstandthedeterminantsoftheresidual,technicalefficiency. Theseresultsarereportedbecausetheyallowadirectcomparisonwiththetransition literature.However,becausetheestimationmethodiscompletelydifferent,theresults cannotbecompareddirectlywiththoseoftheprevioussubsection. Weestimateaproductionfunctionusingfirmfixedeffectsinwhichlogoutputisthe dependentvariableandtheindependentvariablesareloglabor(l),logcapital(k),year dummiesandanumberofvariablesthatareoftenidentifiedintheliteraturewithhigher levelsofTFP.Theseincludeexportcategory(asanindicatorofcompetitivepressurein productmarkets),foreignownershipandexpenditure on training of labor.We report theresultsofthefixedeffectsestimationinTable5.3. The estimated function islargelyconsistent with our results using stochasticfrontier methods.Wefindthatthesumofcoefficientsonlaborandcapital,isnotsignificantly differentfromunity,whichprovidesa“commonsense”checkontheestimation.We alsoconfirminasingleequationmostofthefindingswithrespecttovariationinTFP discussedabove.Thus,thedummyvariablesfortime(year2and3respectively)are notstatisticallysignificant,indicatingthatTFPdidnotincreaseoveroursampleperiod. We cannot test for activity or industry effects using this method because all such variationisremovedbythefixedeffectsestimation.However,inthisapproachwefind averyweakbutpositiveeffectofcompetition,viaexportcategory,onTFP,thoughitis onlysignificantatthe10%level.Onceagain,wearenotabletoidentifyanypositive impactofforeignownershiponTFPintheseequations.

Table 5.3 Augmented Production Function Estimate (Fixed-Effects) Dependent variable: log Output in 2005

Variables Coefficient StandardError lnCapital(k) .22 .09 lnLabor(l) .65 .11 export_category| .27 .16 fdi_category .11 .33 any_training .04 .23 year2 .03 .08 year3 .08 .09 _cons 6.70 .88 sigma_u 1.10 Sigma_e .60

Rho* .77 Ftestthatallu_i=0:F(127,222)=6.56;Prob>F=0.0 0 Numberofobservations=359 Numberofgroups=128 Observationspergroup:minimum=1(max=3;average=2.8) F(9,222)=6.94;Prob>F=0.00 Groupv ariable(i):id Rsq:within=0.22 between=0.57 overall=0.55 corr(u_i,Xb)=0.08 *fractionofvarianceduetou_i VI. POLICY CONCLUSIONS

Inthispaper,wehavesummarizedthetheoreticalframeworksandempiricalfindingsin theliteratureonthedeterminantsofenterpriseproductivityindevelopedandtransition economies.Intheempiricalsection,weemployanewdatasetonArmenianfirmsto measuretotalfactorproductivityandexploreitsdeterminants as well as examineits variationacrosssectors. Thus,thestrongmacroeconomicperformanceoftheArmenianeconomyisprobably basedprimarilyonthesuccessfulimplementationofreformsatthestartoftransition, notablypriceliberalization,openingtheeconomytotradeandrelianceontheprivate sector.However,thetimehasprobablycomeforasecondphaseofreformstoenhance the institutional environment, increase competition in the economy and encourage deeperpenetrationofforeigndirectinvestment.Thisviewisstrengthenedbythefact that in our empirical analysis, we were unable to identify a significant relationship betweenproductivityandthequalityofthelaborforce,asindicatedforexampleby levels of education. This indicates that productivity growth was probably largely determinedbydemandratherthansupplysidefactors. Ourresults obtained from asurveyof 300manufacturing and service firms provide plausibleandrobustestimatesofproductiontechnologyinArmenianenterprises.Our principalfindingsare: 1. TheaveragefirminArmeniaoperatesatsome78%ofthelevelofproductivity (TFP)ofthemostefficientfirms.Theselevelsarecomparabletothosefoundin bothdevelopedandtransitioneconomies.Thestudy suggests that Armenia is not experiencing any growth in technical efficiency, and possibly in TFP, contrarytotheargumentsofmacroeconomicpapers.Thustechnicalprogressat theleveloffirmsseemstobeplayingnopartintheArmeniangrowthprocess. Thisindicatestheurgentneedforpolicytoensurefasterdisseminationofnew technologiesandknowhowandtheimprovementoflaborskills. 2. Thereisatbestmixedevidencethatcompetitionishavingapositiveeffecton TFP.Thisisprobablybecausecompetitivepressuresarenotyetstrongenough in Armenia to influence managerial decisions, for example forcing firms to improvetheirefficiencytothelevelsofbenchmarkfirms.

ThereisnoevidencethatFDIactstoincreaseproductivityinArmenianfirms.Foreign ownershipinArmenianfirmsremainslowbythestandardoftheregion,andperhaps theeconomicandinstitutionalenvironmentisnotadequatetoensureeitheradequate FDIinflowsorthatthebenefitsofFDIarereapedbyrecipientfirms. The empirical analysis therefore reveals some divergencebetween thesituationwith respecttoproductivityinArmenianfirmsandinternationalexperienceintransitionand developedeconomies.Takentogether,thecomparisonofthesituationinArmeniawith international experience suggests that the Armenian economy may benefit from a secondstageofreformssothateconomicdevelopmentcanbecomemorefirmlybased onproductivitygrowthattheenterpriselevel. A comparison of Armenia with the international experience highlights three inter relatedareaswherepolicydevelopmentcouldimprovetheenvironmentinamanner consistentwithattainingthisobjective:(i)policiestoimprovedomesticcompetition; (ii)policiestoimprovefurthertheinstitutionalenvironment,especiallywithrespectto theenforcementofpropertyrightsandthereductionofinvestorrisk;and(iii)policies to encourage foreign direct investment, targeted to sectors where the horizontal and verticallinkagescouldbemaximized. ItisveryimportantthatasoundCompetitionPolicyisputinplace,thatitisoperated byanagencywhichisindependentofthegovernment,andthatitisquicklyseentobe effectiveintheimplementationoftheLaw.Thefirstissuecanbeaddressedquiteeasily bytheadoptionoflegislation,forexample,basedontheregulationsoftheEuropean Union.ThiswasthemethodadoptedbytheEUAccessioneconomiesofCentraland EasternEurope.Thelattertworequirementscanbemoredifficult,becausetheyrequire governments foregoing considerable discretionary power in the development of industrialpolicy.Nonetheless,theArmenianauthoritieswouldbewelladvisedtolook totheexperienceofothertransitioneconomies,perhapsnotablytheBalticStateswhich havealsoemergedfromthelegalstructuresoftheformerSovietUnion. Turningtotheinstitutionalenvironment,wenotedearlierthatArmeniahasperformed ratherwellintermsoftheEBRD’sTransitionIndicatorsofinstitutionaldevelopment, butthatwhenoneconsideredthedeeperquestionsraisedforexamplebyinternational investorsandconsideredintheHeritageFoundationIndex,therewasstillconsiderable progresstobemade.Thecriticalissuesseemtobearoundprotectionofpropertyrights via the legal system, and these concern less the nature of the laws that have been enacted than the consistency of their enforcement. Once again, there is very considerableexperience,notablyinthemultilateralagencies,onhowtomakethelegal system operateinsuchaway asto giveconfidence to investors, especially foreign investors. This brings us to the third and most important area for policy development; encouraging foreign direct investment. The most striking difference between the experienceofArmeniaandtheothertransitioneconomiesstudiedisthat,inthelatter, FDIhasbeenpivotalinproductivitygrowth.InArmenia,productivitygrowthhasbeen veryslowattheenterpriselevelandFDIinflowshavebeensmall.Itseemslikelythat these two facts are correlated. In terms of policy, one should distinguish between activitiestoimproveinstitutionalandenvironmentalfactorslikelytoencourageFDI,

factorsthatwillencouragethebestsortofFDI(intermsofproductivity)andpoliciesto encourageFDI.

Appendix

Table A.1 GDP real growth rates and Net FDI inflows as percent of GDP, selected countries

Armenia Russia Ukraine Poland Bulgaria Year GDP FDI GDP FDI GDP FDI GDP FDI GDP FDI 1992 41.8 0.0 14.8 NA 9.7 0.8 2.6 0.3 7.3 0.5 1993 8.8 0.2 8.7 NA 14.2 1.4 3.8 0.7 1.5 0.4 1994 5.4 1.2 12.7 0.1 22.9 0.4 5.2 2.0 1.8 1.1 1995 6.9 2.0 4.0 0.5 12.2 0.7 7.0 2.6 2.9 0.8 1996 5.9 1.1 3.6 0.4 10.0 1.2 6.2 2.8 9.4 1.4 1997 3.3 3.2 1.4 0.4 3.0 1.2 7.1 3.1 5.6 4.9 1998 7.3 11.7 5.3 0.6 1.9 1.8 5.0 3.5 4.0 4.2 1999 3.3 6.6 6.4 0.6 0.2 1.5 4.5 4.3 2.3 6.2 2000 5.9 5.5 10.0 0.2 5.9 1.9 4.3 5.4 5.4 7.9 2001 9.6 3.3 5.1 0.1 9.2 2.0 1.2 3.0 4.1 5.9 2002 13.2 4.7 4.7 0.0 5.2 1.6 1.4 2.0 4.5 5.6 2003 13.9 4.3 7.3 0.4 9.6 2.8 3.9 2.0 5.0 10.4 2004 10.1 6.1 7.1 0.3 12.1 2.6 5.3 4.8 6.6 11.7 2005 14.0 5.1 6.4 0.0 2.7 8.7 3.6 2.3 6.2 14.7 2006 13.4 5.3 7.4 1.1 7.3 5.4 6.2 2.9 6.3 23.2 2007 Est. 13.7 5.2 8.1 0.8 7.3 6.6 6.5 3.8 6.2 20.6 Source:EBRD,TransitionReport.

Table A.2 Net FDI inflows as percent of GDP in CIS countries

2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007Est. Armenia 3.3 4.7 4.3 6.1 5.1 5.3 5.2 Ukraine 2.0 1.6 2.8 2.6 8.7 5.4 6.6 Estonia 5.5 2.1 7.8 5.9 15.9 3.4 4.5 Tajikistan 0.9 3.0 2.0 13.1 2.4 2.3 2.0 Latvia 1.4 2.7 2.3 3.8 3.6 7.5 7.9 Georgia 2.5 3.6 8.4 8.1 8.3 14.3 15.5 4.6 6.2 3.8 5.0 5.0 7.2 6.4 Lithuania 3.6 5.1 0.8 2.3 2.6 5.2 3.5 Russia 0.1 0.0 0.4 0.3 0.0 1.1 0.8 Kazakhstan 12.9 8.8 7.2 12.6 3.7 8.2 4.9 KyrgyzRepublic 0.1 0.3 2.4 5.9 1.7 6.4 6.0 Source:EBRD,TransitionReport.

REFERENCES

Aigner,D.,K.LovellandP.Schmidt(1977),Formulationandestimationofstochastic frontierproductionfunctionmodels, JournalofEconometrics6,2137 Aitken,B.J.andA.E.Harrison(1999), Dodomesticfirmsbenefitfromdirectforeign investment?EvidencefromVenezuela ,AmericanEconomicReview89(3),605618 Aitken, B.,G. Hanson,and A.Harrison (1997), Spillovers, Foreign Investment, and ExportBehavior, JournalofInternationalEconomics,43,10332[30] Altenburg,T.(2000),Linkagesandspilloversbetweentransnationalcorporationsand small and mediumsized enterprises in developing countries: Opportunities and policies,ProceedingsoftheUNCTADXSpecialRoundTable,TNCSME Linkages forDevelopment,Bangkok,February Balasubramanyan,V.N.,M.Salisu,andD.Sapsford(1996),Foreigndirectinvestment andgrowthinEPandIScountries ,EconomicJournal106(434),92105[14] Bartels,F.L.(2005),UNIDO’scontributiontotechnologicaldevelopment:enhancing developing countries’ ability to absorb and master technology , Technology Paper Series,No.4/05(Vienna:UNIDO) Battese, G. and T. Coelli (1995), A Model for Technical Inefficiency Effects in a StochasticFrontierProductionforPanelData, EmpiricalEconomics20 Blomström,M.andH.Persson(1983),Foreigninvestmentandspilloverefficiencyin anunderdevelopedeconomy:EvidencefromMexicanmanufacturingindustry, World Development11,493501 Borensztein,E.,J.Gregorio,andJ.Lee(1998), How does foreign direct investment affecteconomicgrowth?, JournalofInternationalEconomics45,115135 Brown J. D., J. S. Earle, and A. Telegdy (2006), The Productivity Effects of Privatization: Longitudinal Estimates from Hungary, Romania, Russia, and Ukraine, JournalofPoliticalEconomy,114(1),6199 Caves,R.E.(1974), Multinationalfirms,competitionandproductivityinhostcountry markets, Economica41,176193[18] Caves,D.W.,L.R.Christensen,andW.E.Diewert(1982a),MultilateralComparisons of Output, Input, and Productivity Using Superlative Index Numbers, Economic Journal,92,7386 Chenery, H., Sh. Robinson and M. Syrquin (1986), Industrialization and Growth , OxfordUniversityPress Commander, S., and J. Svejnar (2007), Do Institutions, Ownership, Exporting and CompetitionExplainFirmPerformance?Evidencefrom26TransitionCountries,

Cornwall, Ch.,P.Schmidt and R.C.Sickles (1990), Production frontiers withcross sectionalandtimeseriesvariationinefficiencylevels ,JournalofEconometrics,46(1 2),185200 Djankov,S.,andB.Hoekman(2000),ForeignInvestmentandProductivityGrowthin CzechEnterprises, TheWorldBankEconomicReview,14(1),4964 Djankov, S., and P. Murrell (2002) Enterprise Restructuring in Transition: A QuantitativeSurvey, JournalofEconomicLiterature,40(3),73992 Dong, XiaoYuan, L. Putterman, and B. Unel (2006), Enterprise Restructuring and Firm Performance: A Comparison of Rural and Urban Enterprises in Jiangsu Province,JournalofComparativeEconomics,34(3),608633 Estrin, S., K. E. Meyer, and M. Bytchkova (2005), Entrepreneurship in Transition Economies,inOxfordHandbookofEntrepreneurship,ed.MarkCasson etal .Oxfrod, OxfordUniversityPress Estrin, S. (2002), Competition and Corporate Governance in Transition , Journal of EconomicPerspectives16(1),101124 Estrin,S.,J.Hanousek,E.Kocenda,andJ.Svejnar (2007), Privatization in Central EastEuropeandtheCIS, Mimeo,UniversityofMichiganLSECERGEEI Good, D., I. Nadiri, L. Roller, and R. Sickles (1993), Efficiency and Productivity GrowthComparisonsofEuropeanandU.S.AirCarriers:AFirstLookattheData, TheJournalofProductivityAnalysis4 Görg, H. and Strobl, E. (2001), Multinational Companies and Indigenous Development:AnEmpiricalAnalysis,EuropeanEconomicReview46,13051322[18] Greenaway, D., N. Sousa and K. Wakelin (2004), Do Firms Learn to Export from Multinationals? ,EuropeanJournalofPoliticalEconomy20,10271043[17] Greene,W.(2002),FixedandRandomEffectsinStochasticFrontierModels, Working Papers0216,NewYorkUniversity,LeonardN.SternSchoolofBusiness,Department ofEconomics Grosse, R., ed. (2005), International Business and Government Relations in the 21 st Century, Cambridge:CambridgeUniversityPress Haddad, M. and A. Harrison (1993), Are there positive spillovers from direct foreign investment?EvidencefrompaneldataforMorocco,JournalofDevelopmentEconomics 42,5174[24] Hirschman,A.(1958),InterdependenceandIndustrialization, Chapter6ofTheStrategy ofEconomicDevelopment , NewHaven,YaleUniversityPress,98119[20]

Yifan, H., F. Song, and J. Zhang (2004), Competition, Ownership, Corporate GovernanceandEnterprisePerformance:EvidencefromChina, HongKongInstitute ofEconomicsandBusinessStrategyWorkingPaper1111 Javorcik, B.S. (2004) Does foreign direct investment increase the productivity of domestic firms? In search of spillovers through backward linkages, The American EconomicReview,94,605627 Jefferson, Gary H., Thomas G. Rawski (1996), Chinese Industrial Productivity: Trends, Measurement Issues, and Recent Developments, Journal of Comparative Economics,23(xxx),146–180 Jefferson,G.H.andS.Jian(2006),PrivatizationandrestructuringinChina:Evidence fromshareholdingownership,1995–2001,JournalofComparativeEconomics,34(1), 146–166 Jondrow,J.,C.A.KnoxLovell,I.S.Materov,andP.Schmidt(1982),Ontheestimation oftechnicalinefficiencyinthestochasticfrontierproductionfunctionmodel,Journalof Econometrics19,233238 Jorgenson,D.W.,GollopF.MandB.Fraumeni1987,ProductivityandUSEconomic Growth, HarvardUniversityPress Schumpeter,J.A.(1942), Capitalism , SocialismandDemocracy ,London,Unwin Lall, S. (1980), Vertical Interfirm Linkages in LDCs: An Empirical Study , Oxford BulletinofEconomicsandStatistics42,203226[24] Li, X. and Liu, X. (2005), Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth: An IncreasinglyEndogenousRelationship ,WorldDevelopment33,393407[15] Markusen, J.R.and A. Venables (1999), Foreign direct investment as a catalyst for industrialdevelopment, EuropeanEconomicReview,43,335356[22] Meyer, K. E. (2004), Perspectives on Multinational Enterprises in Emerging Economies, JournalofInternationalBusinessStudies34,no.4,259277 Meyer, K.E. and E. Sinani (2007), When and where does foreign direct investment generate positive spillovers? A meta analysis, mimeo , University of Reading and CopenhagenBusinessSchool,July Perez, T. (1997), Multinational enterprises and technological spillovers: an evolutionarymodel,JournalofEvolutionaryEconomics7,169192[24] Sabirianova K., J. Svejnar, and K. Terrell (2005), Foreign Investment, Corporate Ownership, and Development: Are Firms in Emerging Markets Catching Up to the WorldStandard?,WilliamDavidsonInstituteWorkingPaper734 Schmidt,P.(198586),FrontierProductionFunctions,EconometricReviews4,289 328

Shahid Yusuf Kaoru Nabeshima Dwight H. Perkins (2006), Under New Ownership PrivatizingChina’sStateOwnedEnterprises, WorldBankPublication Stevenson, R. (1980). Likelihood Functions for Generalized Stochastic Frontier Estimation. JournalofEconometrics,13(1),5866 The World Bank (2007), The Caucasian Tiger; Sustaining Economic growth in Armenia,TheinternationalBankforReconstructionandDevelopment

COMPETITIVENESS OF THE ARMENIAN PRIVATE SECTOR : MOVING TO THE NEXT STAGE *

ManukHergnyan,EconomyandValuesResearchCenter GagikGabrielyan,EconomyandValuesResearchCenter AnnaMakaryan,EconomyandValuesResearchCenter

Abstract: The paper examines Armenia’s economic achievements, and explores the anatomy of Armenia’s competitiveness by studying its underlying factors and causal links.ItcontrastsArmenia’seconomicperformanceandmicroeconomicfoundationsof competitivenesswithpeerorcomparatorcountries.The“synthesis”partofthepaper advancesasetofrecommendationsandthoughtsonthefuturedevelopmentofArmenia andenhancementofnationalcompetitiveness,andcoverssuchissuesasthecontextof futurepolicies,frameworksandmechanismsforsettingprioritiesanddesigningshort tolongtermdevelopmentstrategies,approachesforpositioningArmeniaintheregion andglobally. JELClassification:O11,O12,O19,O29,O30 Keywords:Armenia,businessenvironment,competitivenessandregionalpolicies, internationallinkagesandinternationalization

*ThispaperisbasedonthecontentofthefirstNationalCompetitivenessReportofArmenia,EV,2008.

I. INTRODUCTION

Currently,competitivenessisamajorchallengefacingArmenia’sdecisionmakersin both the private and public sectors. While Armenia’s economic growth rate is exceptionallyhigh,ithasonlyrecentlyrecoveredtoGDPlevelsseenin1990andwage levelsarestilllessthanhalfoflevelsseenin1990.Economicperformancehasbeen largely dependent on external factors (e.g. remittances, assistance from international financial and donor organizations). Large and increasing regional disparities and continuedpovertyamongsomesegmentsoftheArmenianpopulationcreateasenseof urgencytobringeconomicdynamismtoallgeographicareasandtoallsegmentsofthe population. Armenia’s disadvantage as a landlocked country increases the need for repositioningArmeniatowardshighvalueproductsandservicesthatarelesssubjectto transportation cost disadvantages. Attaining higher levels of competitiveness will determinewhetherArmeniacanachievesustainableandharmoniouseconomicgrowth beyondthatbolsteredbyremittances,foreignassistanceandresourceexploitation. Competitiveness, which we define here as high and rising levels of productivity, is determinedmorebycreatedfactorsthanitsresourceendowments.Itisafunctionofthe nation’sabilitytodevelopanenvironmentenablingfirmsandindividualstoutilizethe nation’sresourcesandfactorseffectivelyandefficiently.Itisabouttheabilityofthe nation,itsfirmsandcitizenstodesign,adopt,andimplementsophisticatedstrategies andoperationswhichallowefficientutilizationofavailableresourcesandfactors.In otherwords,competitivenessisabouttheabilitytobeproductive. Various benchmarks of competitiveness exist. Those generally considered most authoritative are provided by the World Economic Forum (WEF), International Institute for Management Development (IMD), and the Institute of Industrial Policy Studies (IPS). However, only WEF currently includes Armenia in its reports. Therefore,thepaperwewillheavily(butnotexclusively)relyonWEF’sindexesfor assessingrelativecompetitiveness. II. ARMENIA ’S RECENT ECONOMIC ACHIEVEMENTS

Prosperity is ultimately a choice. A nation’s welfare or prosperity depends on its choicesregardinghowefficientlyandeffectivelythenationutilizesandallocatesits resources,orinotherwords,onhowproductiveorcompetitivethenationis. WestartbylookingatwhattheeconomicsystemofArmeniahasyieldedtodate.First, we lookattheachievement measures prosperity toassessthe performance ofthe economic system and its results. Then we look at its key driver – productivity measures,and,after,twomajorenablersthatstimulatetheproductivitygrowth,namely – internationalization and knowledge, skills and creativity measures. These are four closelylinkedindicatorsofeconomicachievementofacountry.Prosperitydependson theproductivityofanationandonthewaywealthiscreatedanddistributedinsociety. Innovativecapacityisanimportantindicationofeconomicachievement,andalsoan engineforproductivityincrease.Knowledge,skillsandcreativepotentialconstitutethe innovativecapacityofanation,acluster,afirmandanindividual.Internationalization illustratesthedegreetowhichacountryissuccessfullycompetinginforeignmarkets forgoods,servicesandcapital.Usually,highproductivityisaccompaniedbyincreased

levelsofinternationalization,andtheytogetherarestrongsupportersofknowledgeand skillscreationandupgrade. Figure 2.1 Economic Yields and Competitiveness

Prosperity

Knowledge, Skills and Productivity Internationalization Creativity Source:AdaptedfromMichaelPorter(1998);EV,2007 Armenia’s economic performance is viewed in the international context, i.e. in comparison with regional and international competitor and/or peer countries and benchmarkcountries.Forthispurpose,peerandcompetitorcountriesareselectedfrom the following regions: (a) Eastern Europe (EE), which includes Central and Eastern European (CEE) and Baltic countries (Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Slovak Republic, Slovenia) and Southeastern European (SEE) countries (Albania, Bulgaria, BosniaHerzegovina, Croatia, FYR Macedonia, Montenegro, Serbia,and Romania); (b) Commonwealth of IndependentStates(CIS), which includes Russia, Belarus, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan, , Tajikistan, Turkmenistan,Ukraine,);and(d)theregionswhichwerefertoasEurasian Crossroad Region between the Black, Mediterranean and Caspian Seas, of which ArmeniaisapartandwhichalsoincludesAzerbaijan, Georgia, Jordan, Iran, Israel, Lebanon,Syria,andTurkey. Thisregionalcoverageallowsafairlycomprehensivecomparisonandabroadviewon Armenia’spositionbasedongeographicalandhistoricalaswellassocialandeconomic factors.CountriesofEasternEuropeandtheCISarealltransitioncountrieswithawide rangeofsimilaritiesinheritedfromcommunistregimes.TherecenthistoryofArmenia iscloselylinkedtoCIScountries,andtherearestillcloseeconomicandtraderelations with many CIS countries. Comparison with European countries is also in line with currentprioritiesinArmenia’sforeignpolicytoachievecloserintegrationwiththeEU, andwiththefactthattheEUisnowamajortradepartnerforArmenia.Atthesame time,Armeniahasmuchlongerhistorical,culturalandeconomictieswithcountriesof theMiddleEastandtheMediterranean,althoughtheywereinterruptedduringSoviet times.WerefertothisregionastheEurasianCrossroadregion.Afterthecollapseof theSovietUnion,EurasianCrossroadcountriesbecameimportanteconomicandtrade partners for Armenia, and this region provides broad, but still unexploited market opportunities. 2.1 Prosperity

Aftermorethan50percentdeclineinGDPbetween1991and1993,Armeniarecorded 5.4percentgrowthin1994,andsincehasgrownatanannual compound rateof 8.2 percent.Thegrowthratehasbeenremarkablyhighduringthelastsixyears,attwodigit levels.In2004,afteradecadeofeconomicgrowth,theGDPlevelsurpassedthe1990 level(Figure2.2).Armenia’sGDPgrowthrateoutpacedalmostalltransitioncountries inEE,theCISandtheEurasianCrossroadregions(Figures2.3)in2006.Anexception was Azerbaijan, where a 34.5 percent GDP growth rate was registered versus 13.2 percentinArmeniafortheyear2006(and13.8percentin2007).1 Azerbaijan’s high growthratewasstronglydrivenbytheenergysectorwhichbenefitedfromincreasing oilandgaspricesworldwide. Figure 2.2 Armenia GDP and Wage Growth Rates (1990-2006)

Source:NSS,variouspublications TherehasbeenasimilartrendwithregardtogrowthratesofGDPpercapita.Between 2000and2006,Armenia’scompoundannualgrowthrate(CAGR)ofGDPpercapita was 12.9 percent, outpacing neighboring countries, as well as its regional peer/comparator countries, although lagging behind Azerbaijan (15.8 percent). With thisgrowthrate,Armenia’sGDPpercapitainPPPtermssurpassedUSD5000in2006, placingArmeniainthegroupoflowermiddleincomecountries according to World Bankcriteria. Economic growth has brought about considerable improvements in the population’s welfareintermsofrealwageincreases,povertyreduction,andincreasedspendingon socialservicesandtransfers.However,acloserlookshowsthatinabsolutetermsthe levelofArmenia’sGDP,basedonpurchasingpowerparity(PPP)aswellasGDPper capita,stillremainslowandlagsbehindmostofitscompetitorandpeercountries.In 2006, Armenia’s GDP per capita (PPP) was higher than that of Georgia, Moldova, Kyrgyzstan, Uzbekistan, Tajikistan, Syria, Egypt, Lebanon and Albania, but was significantlylowerthanotherEE,CISandEurasianCrossroadcountries.Althoughthe country’s economyhasbeen growing annually bytwo digits, this growth should be viewedagainstaverylowGDPbase.

1NationalStatisticalServiceofArmenia(NSS),2008

Figure 2.3 Comparative Economic Performance (2000-2006)

Source:WB,WDIOnline,2007(lastaccessedOctober2007);Authors’owncalculations. Note:ThedataforIsraelisfor2005.YellowbubblesindicatecountriesofEasternEurope,darkblue– CIScountries,pink–EurasianCrossroadcountries. Additionally, economic growth in Armenia has not resulted in corresponding wage growth;wagelevelsreachedonlyaround40percentof1990levels(Figure2.2).Real unemployment levels (over 30 percent) and poverty (circa 26 percent in 2006) still remain quite high; the distribution of wealth in society is highly inequitable; and disparities between regions in terms of economic and social development are significant. 2.2 Internationalization

A. Export Performance

WelookatArmenia’sexportperformanceasanimportantindicatorformeasuringa country’s comparative productivity and ability to compete in world markets. For a country like Armenia (with a small internal market) export performance is a crucial factorforeconomicdevelopment,asitpermitstheachievementofeconomiesofscale and concentration on those sectors where the country is more competitive. The Government of Armenia has indicated that export promotion is one of its main priorities. Since 2000 Armenia’s share of world exports has more than doubled, although in absolutetermsitremainsverysmallandlagsbehindmostoftheEE,CISandEurasian Crossroadcountries(Figure2.4).Armenia’stotalshareofworldexportsisslightlyless thanitsshareofworldGDP.Thisisanindicationthateconomicgrowthhasnotbeen exportdriven,buthasbeenattainedprimarilythroughimportsubstitution,growthof domesticdemand,andgrowthofnontradedsectorsoftheeconomy.Thisisawarning signforArmenia’sinternationalcompetitivenessgiventhesmalldomesticmarketand, hence, the need for exportled growth as a longterm sustainable strategy. The differencebetweenArmenia’sshareofworldexportsandshareofworldGDPisbetter thanthatofTurkey,Lebanon,andAlbania,butisworsethanthatofothercountriesin EE,theCISandEurasianCrossroadregions.

Figure 2.4 Export Share in World Export (2000-2005, percent)

= difference between shares in world exports and world GDP; white collor- negative size

Source:WB,WDIOnline,2007(lastaccessedOctober2007);Authors’owncalculations. Note: Bubble size indicates the difference of shares of world exports and world GDP. White color indicatesthattheshareofnation’sexportintheworldexportsislessthanthenationGDPshareinthe WorldGDP.Thesearegenerallyconsideredunderperformers.DataforSyriaisfor2004. Armenia’s exports are largely resource intensive. The latter represented about 64 percent of the country’s total merchandise exports in 2005 which increased to 69.5 percentin2006;thisisquitehighcomparedwithindicatorsofmostcountiesinEE,the CISandEurasianCrossroadregions(Figure2.5).Itshouldbenotedthatin20022004, the indicator of resource intensity of Armenia’s exports was higher still at over 70 percent(2002at75,2003at77,and2004at71percent)2.Thedropoftheindicator in2005wasduetothedropintheexportofdiamonds(in2002theshareofdiamonds among all merchandise exports was 48 percent compared with only 30.9 percent in 2005). High resourceintensity also means low valueadded of Armenian exports. Higher valueadded products and services are required to attain higher levels of productivityandcompetitiveness.

2ResourceintensiveproductgroupsweredefinedusingtheLall(2000)classificationofexportbytheir technological intensity. Two groups of products were treated as resource based products: primary products(freshfruit,meat,rice,cocoa,tea,coffee,wood,coal,crude,petroleum,gas)andresourcebased manufacturesagro/forestbasedproducts(preparedmeats/fruits,beverages,woodproducts,vegetable oils))andotherresourcebasedproducts(oreconcentrates,petroleum/rubberproducts,cement,cutgems, glass).Source:ChamiBatista,2004;UNCTAD,2004;Mahmood,2004

Figure 2.5 Resource Intensity of Merchandise Exports (2006)

Source: WB, WDIOnline (last accessed: October 2007); UNCOMTRADE online database (last accessed:October2007);Authors’owncalculations. Note:PPPadjustedGDPpercapitaofIsraelisfor2005.

B. Investment Performance Foreigndirectinvestment(FDI)isanimportantfactorthatcancontributetoeconomic performance and to productivity in several ways, including: (a) introduction of new technologies, managerial competences, and knowledge; (b) enhancing the business climate; (c)improving domestic competition;(d) job creation; and (e) increasing the qualityofhumanresources.FDIdrivengrowthhasbeenamodelforeconomicgrowth inmanycountries(e.g.Hungary).Inmostsuchcountries,thebulkofinvestmenthas beendomestic,butFDIcreatesaleadingedgeandtriggersnewdomesticinvestments. Itislogicaltoexpect,andtherecenthistoryofFDIhasdemonstrated,thathighlevels ofFDIarerecordedincountrieswithprimaryextractiveindustries,withasuperiorcost position, with large domestic markets, or in countries that can supply highly skilled scientistsandengineersforhighvalueaddedprocessingandR&Dactivities.Giventhe constraintsinnaturalresourceendowments,sizeandgeopoliticalsituation,inorderto attract large and high quality FDI it is vital for Armenia to enhance knowledge intensiveindustries.Thiswouldboostthecompetitivenessofthenation,andovertime would allow establishing or bringing high value processing elements of the global valuechainsofmultinationalstoArmenia. Between 2003 and 2007, the CAGR of inward FDI to Armenia was 52.9 percent, which,however,wasdrivenmainlybyreinvestments(Figure2.6).Thelargestinflow ofequityinvestmentswasobservedin2006,peakingat216.7million.Thetremendous growthofFDIwasduetotheriseofreinvestedprofitsandotherinvestments.In1998 through2007,themajorFDIrecipientswereelectricity, gasandwatersupply (25.2 percentageshare),postandtelecommunications(19.8), miningandquarrying (14.6), andfoodproductsandbeverages(7.7)sectors 3.Ifthecurrenttrendscontinue,Armenia willsoonexhaustitspotentialtoattractevenresourcedrivenFDIintonewsectors.

Figure 2.6 Inward FDI, Armenia (2001 - 2006)

Sour ce:NSSofArmenia,BalanceofPayments,variouspublications

2.3 Knowledge, Skills and Creativity Sinceindependence,theR&DandinnovationperformanceofArmeniahasbeenrather disappointing. Once an important center for scientific research and hightech production in the former Soviet Union 4, Armenia has lost most of its scientific and technological(S&T)resourcesandhasyettoexploititsS&Tpotential.Untilrecently, the promotion and development of innovation were, practically, out of the Government’spolicyagenda. Armeniahasa highertertiaryeducationexpenditure/GDP per capita ratio than most othercountries,butinabsolutetermstertiarystudentexpenditureislowerthanthatof most countries. Government expenditure on R&D has been extremely low and negligibleandbelowthatofmostcompetitorandpeer countries in EE, the CIS and EurasianCrossroadregions(bothasapercentageofGDPand,moredramatically,in absoluteterms).In2006,R&Dexpendituresaccountedfor0.22%ofGDP.In2005, GovernmentR&Dexpenditurewasonly0.12%ofGDP,andtherehasbeenasimilar ratiointhepreviousfiveyears.Armenia’sprivatesectorbusinessesalsohadverylow expenditureforR&Dandforemployeetraining(lessthanGovernmentexpenditure).In 2005,totalR&Dexpenditureinthecountrywasonly0.23%ofGDP.5 3NationalStatisticalServiceofArmenia,2008. 4Armeniahad25,000scientistsandengineersin1990vs.6,700in2005(Arzumanyan,2006). 5NSS;UNESCOonlinedatabase,2007.

2.4 Productivity Armenia’s prosperity measuredinterms of GDPpercapita reflects both thelevel of labor force utilization and the productivity at which labor is employed. Labor productivity is an important measure of economic performance. However, ensuring higher labor participation in the economy also is a crucial economic and social achievement.Laborproductivitycanbeincreasedbycuttingthelaborforce,however, thiswillnotbringaboutrealincreaseinprosperityofthesocietyorthecompetitiveness ofthecountry. Laborforceutilizationdependsonlaborforceasashareoftheworkingagepopulation, employmentrate(shareofworkingagepopulation)andhoursworked(peremployee). Armeniahasalowlaborforceparticipationrate(59percent)laggingbehindmostof theEE,CISandEurasianCrossroadcountries(Figure2.7).Thisreflectstheeffectsof massive emigration of mostly young people since the early 1990s. Official unemployment has been decreasing since 2000 from 11.7 percent in 2000 to 7.5 percentin2006.But,officialfiguresforunemployment(orregisteredunemployment) differ significantly from real unemployment in the country. Real unemployment still remainsquitehigh–in2006theunemploymentratewasabout30percent.6Moreover, there is a quite high level of underemployment in the economy, particularly in the agricultural sector, where more than half of the labor force was underemployed and expressedreadinesstoworkmorehours.Intheindustrialandservicessector,thelevels of underemployment in 2004 were 37.9% and 36%, respectively. 7 The level of underemploymentintermsofworkinglessthan40hoursperweekwas30.2%,39.4% and73.4%intheindustrial,servicesandagriculturalsectors,respectively. Figure 2.7 Labor Force Participation Rate and Labor Productivity per Employee (2006)

6NSSSurveydata(ILOmethodology);ILO. 7NSS,SocialSnapshot,2004.

Source:WB,WDIOnline(lastaccessedOctober,2007),ILOLaborsta(lastaccessed October2007); IMF,InternationalFinancialStatisticsMay2007;Authors’owncalculations. Note:DataforEgypt,Georgia,Iran,IsraelandKyrgyzRepublicarefor2005 Based on official data, the most productive sector of the Armenian economy was constructionin2006(2.7%ofthetotalemployment,and26%ofgrossvalueadded). 8 Theminingandquarryingsectorsalsohadrelativelyhighproductivity(increaseddue to the rising base metal prices worldwide, which suggests that this may not be a sustainable source of productivity). The productivity level is particularly low in the agricultural sector which employed 46% of the total labor force in 2006, but representedonly20%ofgrossvalueaddedinthecountry(Figure2.8). Whiledevelopmentoftheconstructionsectorcanhaveanimportantmultipliereffect foreconomicgrowthintheshortrun,itisnotexportable and, given the small local market,inthelongrun isunlikelytomaintainits leadership position. It is essential therefore, that Armenia in the medium to longrun relies on the promotion and development of export oriented, high valueadded sectors, if it is to enhance its internationalcompetitiveness.

Figure 2.8 Shares of Main Sectors - Employment and Value Added (2006)

8AlthoughitisobviousthattheconstructionsectoristhemostproductivesectorinArmenia,itmaybe arguedthatthereportedlevelofemploymentand,thus,therealproductivityintheconstructionsectoris muchlessthatthereallevelduetononregisteredemployees.

Source:NSS,2007. III. ARMENIA ’S COMPETITIVENESS POSITION AND ITS CAUSES In the GCR 20072008, Armenia ranked 93 rd out of 131 countries in the Global Competitiveness Index (GCI), i.e. Armenia was in the 8 th decile of countries a relatively low ranking, indicating that there is still much room for improvement if Armenia is to become a globally competitive country. 9 The GCI provides a holistic overview of around 110 factors that influence productivity and competitiveness of countries, grouping these factors into “twelve pillars” that are arranged into three broader categories, namely, basicrequirements,efficiencyenhancers,andinnovation andsophisticationfactors ,aspresentedinFigure3.1:

Figure 3.1 GCR’s Twelve Pillars of Competitiveness of a Nation

9 The rankings and scores in this section are those of the Global Competitiveness Report 20072008 (GCR)ifnototherwisenoted.ThecomparisonsarewithGCR20062007rankingsandscores,ifnot otherwisementioned.

COMPETITIVENESS 95 99 110 104 104 40 111 57 87 96 – – 111 94 Institutions ialmarketefficiency Infrastructure Macroeconomy Goodsmarketefficiency HealthandPrimaryeduc. High.education&training Labormarketefficiency Technologicalreadiness Marketsize Businesssophistication Innovation Financ

BasicRequirements EfficiencyEnhancers Innovation& SophisticationFactors 91,downby14points 101,downby10points 103, downby18points

Source:WorldEconomicForum,2007. Note:RankingsarethatofGCI200708comparedtoGCI200607.

Comparedtothepreviousyear,Armeniaimproveditsscoresmodestlyinseveralareas, butsawitsrankingsfallbecausemanyothercountriesachievedfasterprogress.This highlights the fact that we are living in a highly competitive and integrated world, wheretrivialimprovementswillbeinadequatetostand the competition and achieve sustainableprosperity. Armenia’s rankingintheGCRacknowledgesthat Armenia did well in the areas of macroeconomicstability,labormarketefficiencyandsecurityfordoingbusiness.The Government of Armenia should be commended for its notable efforts aimed at: ensuring macroeconomicstability, including good governmentdebtmanagementand low inflation; facilitating procedures for starting a business; establishing a flexible labormarket;andensuringsecurityforbusinesses. However, Armenia’s solid macroeconomic performance is not backed by adequate progressinotheraspectsorpillarsofcompetitiveness,whicharenecessaryforensuring thesustainability ofeconomicgrowth.Thereareseriousshortcomingsorweaknessesin anumberofareas,especiallyatthemicrolevel,whichsignificantlylowerArmenia’s competitiveness in the global context and endanger the sustainability of economic development. Areas of concern are so wide that they point out to the need for a comprehensivereformofpublicandprivatesectors.Theyspanfromgeneralqualityof the business environment, especially the financial sector, the lack of judicial independence and the prevalence of favoritism in government decisions to weak performanceinhighereducationandtrainingandlowlevelofinnovation. Thesustainabilityofeconomicgrowthandtheabilitytotransformitintoasoundbasis for economic development in the future depends greatly on the ability of both the publicandprivatesectorstoreshapeandbuildtheirpoliciesonatrulyprodevelopment

context.WhilemuchemphasisisrightlyplacedontheneedforGovernmentreforms, there is also a pressing need for the private sector to improve its operational and strategicperformance. The current situation with high rates of economic growth, but low and regressing competitiveness is not balanced and sustainable. It’s a specific situation that can be characterized as a “growthcompetitiveness paradox”. This is another impetus for comprehensively understanding the architecture of Armenia’s economic growth, its current and future drivers as well as possible sources of improving its competitive position.

3.1 Micro-level Foundations of Competitiveness WewillevaluatethemicrolevelfoundationsofArmenia’scompetitivenessthroughthe lensoftheBusinessCompetitivenessIndex(BCI)oftheGCR,andusethe“Diamond Model”(Figure3.2)developedbyM.Porterasanintellectualframeworkforanalyzing thebusinessenvironment.TheBCIisbasedlargelyonExecutiveOpinionSurveydata and, in broad terms, measures two broad determinants of the microeconomic environment: (a) quality of national business environment, and (b) sophistication of company strategies and operations. The “Diamond Model” depicts the business environment as a system of four interrelated areas: (a) the quality of factor (input) conditions,(b)thequalityoflocaldemandconditions,(c)thecontextoffirmstrategy andrivalry,and(d)thepresenceofrelatedandsupportingindustries.Ithasprovedto beaverypowerfultoolinanalyzingindustryandcountrycompetitiveness. Overall,Armeniahasfallen17spotsintheBCIin2007(i.e.BCIindexinGCR2007 2008)relativeto2006(i.e.BCIindexinGCR20062007), falling from 91 st rank to 108 th among127countries.

Table 3.1 Armenia’s Business Competitiveness Rankings in the GCR

BusinessCompetitivenessIndex 2007 Rank108,Lost17points 17points QualityofNationalBusinessEnvironment, SophisticationofCompanyStr ategiesand Lost17Points Operations,Lost23Points 2006 2007 2006 2007 89 106 92 115 Source:WorldEconomicForum,2007. The quality of the national microeconomic business environment is an important determinantofthelevelofsophisticationanindividualcompanycanreach.Nomatter howcapablefirmsare,inordertoemploysophisticatedoperationsandstrategies,they need developed administrative and physical infrastructure, access to financial resources, and a highly skilled labor force. They need also suppliers of necessary services and materials to produce sophisticated goods; demanding customers urging themtoinnovateandupgradetobuildcompetitiveedgeovertime;andstringentlocal competitiontoenhanceproductivity. However,afirm’sabilitytoreachanincreasedlevelofsophistication,uponwhichthe nation’s productivity depends, is also partly a function of its own strategy and operations.Nomatterhowfavorableordevelopedanation’smicroeconomicbusiness environment is, a nation needs companies that are able to design and employ sophisticatedoperationsandstrategies.Ultimatelywealthiscreatedbybusinessesand asageneralrule,productivecompaniestendtohaveahighdegreeofsophistication, withmoreefficientoperationalprocessesandstrategies.Competitivecompanieshave professional management who are able to design winning strategies and drive the company; employ efficient and innovative ways to produce and market unique and sophisticated goods; collaborate and make effective use of services and “unusual efforts” of skilled engineers and scientists; invest in R&D adopt sophisticated technologies to upgrade their current competitive position; and hire and train high qualityprofessionals. The assessment of the “national diamond” of the business environment is provided belowinFigure3.2:

Figure 3.2 National Business Environment (Diamond Model)

Context for Firm Strategy and Rivalry

Alocalcontextandrulesthat determinetheextentof investmentsandsustained upgrading(e.g.,IPRprotection), thetypesofcorporatestrategies, Factor andtheintensityofcompetition Demand Conditions (Input) Conditions amonglocallybasedrivals.

Sophisticationoflocaldemandandthe Thequalityandspecializationofinputs pressureoflocalcustomerstoupgrade availabletofirms: productsandservices. • Humanresources • Capitalresources • Physicalinfrastructure • Administrativeinfrastructure • Informationinfrastructure • Scientificandtechnological Related and Supporting infrastructure Industries • Naturalresources

Theavailabilityandqualityof localsuppliersandrelated industries,andthestateof developmentofclusters. Source:MichaelPorter,1990. Since 2001, recognizing the need for improving the business environment in the country,theGovernmentinitiatedanumberofreformsincludingtheconsolidationand reduction of business inspections, simplification of administrative procedures, reductionoftimeforbusinessregistration,andstreamlining of the licensing regime. Thegovernment’sconsultationmechanismswiththeprivatesectorwerestrengthened andahighlevelBusinessCouncil,chairedbythePrimeMinister,wasestablished.In 2007 the government also created a National Competitiveness Council to boost the competitivenessofthecountry.

AccordingtothemostrecentWorldBank’sDoingBusinessReport2008,Armenia wasranked39 th among179countries,andwasaheadofmostcountriesoftheEE,CIS and Eurasian Crossroad regions, but lagging behind Estonia (17 th ), Georgia (18 th ), Latvia(22 nd ),Lithuania(26 th ),Isprael(29 th )andtheSlovakRepublic(32 nd ).InDoing Business2008,therewasasignificantpositivechangerelatedtotheimprovementof legislationaimedateasingaccesstocredit.However,undertheGCR(whichmeasures actual practice rather than a formal regulatory framework), Armenia had a disappointingshowingintermsofthedifficultyinobtainingabankloan(123 rd outof 131countries). Table 3.2 Ease of Doing Business in Armenia, 2007-2008 (among 179 countries)

Easeof... DoingBusiness2008 DoingBusiness2007 ChangeinRank Rank Rank DoingBusiness 39 46 +7 StartingaBusiness 47 44 3 DealingwithLicenses 73 72 1 EmployingWorkers 48 48 0 Re gisteringProperty 2 2 0 GettingCredit 36 62 +26 ProtectingInvestors 83 81 2 PayingTaxes 143 137 6 TradingAcrossBorders 118 133 +15 EnforcingContracts 64 64 0 ClosingaBusiness 42 43 +1 Source: World Bank, 2007; http://www.doingbusiness.org/ExploreEconomies/?economyid=10 (last accessedOctober,2007) A. Management The lack of professionally trained and globally experienced management and the unwillingness to delegate authority to professionals are significant impediments for Armenianbusinessesingainingtheabilitytochoosethemostefficientoperationsand effective strategies and, hence, to increase the productivity and competitiveness of companies.Thissituationmayinparticularbecausedby(a)alackofawarenessofthe importanceofprofessionallytrainedmanagers,which,inturn,couldbearesultofthe lackofknowledge,orofimperfectionsincompetitiveenvironmentdueandabsenceof strongpressurestowardsincreasingefficiencyandmanagementcapacities(b)lackof trust;(c)a“nonmeritbased”cultureofhiringmanagersandotherkeyprofessionals, i.e. managerial and other key positions in companies are most frequently held by relativesorfriendsindependentlyoftheirprofessionalqualifications.Poormanagement andanonmeritbasedsystemofhiringemployeesarepriorityproblemsthathavetobe tackledifArmeniancompanieswanttobecomeproductiveandcompetitiveinglobal context. IV. TOWARDS A COMPETITIVE ECONOMY WebelievethatArmeniahasyettoadoptadevelopmentdrivenpolicycontext.Today Armenia faces a serious challenge of rethinking and reshaping the context of its policiesinordertointroduceatrulydevelopmentorientedagenda,whichwouldenable thecountrytobecomeacompetitiveplayerintheglobalmarketplace. Immediately following independence, Armenia undertook comprehensive reform efforts toward establishing a market economy and democratic society. This was a periodcharacterizedbydramaticeconomicdecline,disruptionoftrade,theNagorno Karabakh conflict and transportation blockade, shortage of energy, food, and other consumer products, , and high levels of unemployment and poverty. Under these circumstances, the government grew accustomed to governing in “crisis mode”,forcedtofindquicksolutionstourgent,shorttermproblems.Armenia’spolicy contextbecamea“survivalcontext”,whichresultedinashortsightedviewofpolicy and a general lack of policy coordination and of an overall strategy toward policy development.Thishasbeenexacerbatedbyveryweakpublicandprivateinstitutional capacities. AfterachievingeconomicstabilityandreachingaceasefireintheNagornoKarabakh conflictinthemid1990s,thenatureofArmenia’spoliciesbecamemoreredistributive. The underlying context of economic reconstruction was the redistribution of the country’swealthamongitscitizens.Massprivatizationofsmallandmediumentities wasthemajordirectionofreforms.Theprivatizationhasbeenhighlyinequitableand resultedintheconcentrationofthecountry’sproductiveassetsinthehandsofafew groups.Thecontextcontinuedtobecharacterizedbya“firefighting”approach,with remaining elements of the “survival context”. The “redistribution context” implied better,butstillweakcoordination. At the beginning of this decade, Armenia adopted a poverty reduction approach (“social context”). In 2003, for instance, Armenia adopted the Poverty Reduction StrategyPaper(PRSP),whichbecameanoverarchingstrategicdocumentbasedupon whichtheGovernmentdevelopeditspoliciesandprograms,anddesigneditsmedium term budgetary expenditures. The PRSP has become a single comprehensive frameworkthatestablishedlongtermmeasurableobjectivesandestablishedimportant linkagesbetweendifferentaspectsofsocial,economicandinstitutionallife. Incontrastwithpreviousapproachestopolicydevelopment,policiesduringthisperiod havebeencharacterizedbytheintroductionofelementsofstrategicthinking,longer term planning, better coordination of policies and operations, improved institutional capacities, and an attempt to set out priorities. However, policies have remained primarily“inwardlooking”,withoutregardtotheinternationalcontextinwhichthey arebeingmade. Additionally, the government’s policies have not made economic development a centerpieceoftheirapproach.WhilethePRSPcontainsobjectivesrelatedtoeconomic development, it remains unclear what the drivers of Armenia’s competitiveness and economic development are. It fails to deal with fundamental questions, such as the sectorsinwhichArmeniacansuccessfullycompeteglobally,whatitsvalueproposition is,orwhatitscompetitivestrengthsandweaknessesare. We believe that these can be best addressed if Armenia adopts an economic developmentfocused strategy. Policiesandprojects should beviewed and measured againsttheirimplicationsforeconomicdevelopment.Thiswillrequireahigherlevelof

coordination of the country’s policies and projects and clear linkages and concerted interactionbetweennumeroussectorsandaspectsofeconomy. Suchastrategyshouldbebasedonarealisticand honest assessment of the nation’s capabilities and its opportunities in the global marketplace, which would permit Armenia to identify the unique strengths upon which the country can compete internationally,andwhichwouldsetoutaroadmaptodevelopment,enablingeffective coordinationofactivitiesandestablishingpriorityareasorsectors.Thiswouldallow formoreefficientuseofscarcefinancialandotherresources. We propose a structured approach to enhancing Armenia’s competitiveness distinguishing two layers of action, namely “Quick Wins” and “Strategic Breakthrough”.TheQuickWinsaretargetsthatareachievableinashorttimeperiod withinthelimitsofcurrentresourcesandcompetencies,whileactionsintheStrategic Breakthrough sections define factors that may move Armenia to the next level of competitivepositionvisàvisothercountriesanddirectcompetitors. 4.1 Strategic Breakthrough Armeniaisinneedofnewgrowthdriversbasedonsustainablesourcesofcompetitive advantage.Givencurrenttrends,thiscallsforrealstrategicbreakthroughwhichleaves thedecisionmakerswithtwofundamentalquestions: 1.WhatshouldbetheroleofArmeniaintheregionalandglobaleconomy? 2.Whatarethetoolstoachieveit? A. Strategic Positioning of the Armenian Economy Theexperienceofmanyresourcescarcebuthighlysuccessfuleconomiesthatmanaged to transform their early acceleration into sustainable economic growth suggests that clearpositioningofacountryisakeyingredientofsuccess.Suchpositioningimplies defininga unique and sustainable setoflocalconditions,skills,productsandservices thatwillleadtothecreationofcompetitiveadvantages.Attheheartofthepositioning isthedefinitionofacountry’s valueproposition .Acorevaluepropositionpointstothe specificrolethecountryplaysintheworldorregionaleconomy.Thesecanincludeits valueasabusinesslocation,therangeofbusinesses, functions andcompetencesfor which the country can become a base for globally competitive companies. Value propositioninherentlyincorporatesthenotionofcompetitivearena–theregion,range ofcountries,competitorsortheentireworld. Given theinterplay ofthe factors mentionedearlierinandaroundArmenia,ithasa narrow menu of possible choices for its positioning and value proposition. Unique humancapitalrepresentsoneofthekeyingredientsforsuchavalueproposition.Atthe sametime,humancapitalcanhardlyrepresentacompetitiveadvantageunless it has unique characteristics. For a country like Armenia, a few unique characteristics of humancapitaldeployedinareasproducinghighvalueaddedproductsandservicesmay become an economywide source of advantage and key differentiating feature. For that, the targetedareasneedtobenarrow enough to enable focused efforts, greater leverageandlargerimpact.

Armenia may strive to become an R&D center at the regional level and use it to becomealeaderinafewareas.Thoseareascouldbeeithertechnologyintensive(such as selected segments in software programming or “green” mining and metallurgy), network and knowledgeintensive (for example selected niches in financial and educationalservices),orcreativityintensive(includingselectedareasofculturerelated commercial activities (cultural tourism centered around key established cultural events/artifactsofglobalorregionalsignificance).BecominganR&Dcenterrequires developmentofkeycompetenciesandskillsthatmayhavebusinessappealforregional and global players to attract investments and technologies into Armenia. The effort shouldcapitalizeonpasttradition,selectedfunctioningR&Dandscientificinstitutes andemergingtrendsinsomeareas(suchasIT). SuchpositioningwillrequireredefinitionofanotionofregionasArmenia’sperceived positioning arena. Redefining “competitors” should become a core theme for the country’s branding and image building. That theme should dominate all key communicationeffortsandbesharedbythegovernment,privatesector,academiaand societyatlarge. Currently,itismostcommontoconsiderArmeniaasapartoftheSouthCaucasus,CIS orEasternEurope.However,noneofthesegroupsofcountriesaloneprovidefavorable positioning settings for Armenia. An unfavorable location and the conflict with AzerbaijaninthecaseofSouthCaucasus,dominanceofRussiaandlackofperception asaregionincaseofCIS,andimpossibilitytoattainleadershiprolesincaseofEastern Europemaketheseregionsnotwellsuitableforpositioningpurposes. Armenia may consider building its communication strategy utilizing the notion of “Eurasian Crossroad”. While the latter is not a well defined region in the political, economicorgeographicsense,ithasmultilayeredandmeaningfulconnotationswhich are exploitable for positioning purposes. The concept of “Eurasian Crossroad” has deep cultural, historic, economic and political roots. It appeals to the idea of intersection of civilizations, cultures, religions and political systems. While the interpretationastoitsgeographicfrontiersmaybevoluntary,itprovidescountrieswith greaterflexibilityforpositioningandcommunicationpurposes.Theregionwillprovide moreeffectivepositioningplatformsifitincludescountriessuchasTurkey,Georgia, Azerbaijan, Armenia, Iran,Iraq, Syria, Jordan,LebanonandIsrael(CentralAsianor Gulfcountriescan be considered a part of the region ina much broader sense). The strategicpositioningbasedontheconceptofacrossroadwillalsohelpovercomethe perceptionofArmeniaasacountryinalandlockedlocationwithoutsignificantnatural resources.TheregiondefinedinthiswayprovidesopportunitiesforArmeniatocapture leading roles in a few selected areas that demand highly developed human capital, accesstoglobalnetworksandatraditionofscienceandtechnology.Thisoptionwill implypositioningArmeniaasanR&DcenterinskillintensiveareasintheEurasian crossroadregion.Assuchaclaimorvisionishighlyambitiousgiventhecompetitive positionsandclaimsbydirectcompetitorsintheregion,thiswillrequireanorganized effortwithanintegratedstrategyframeworkandidentificationanddeploymentofkey levers. B. Key Levers for Breakthrough

Strategic breakthrough refers to the creation, nurture and development of internationallycompetitive industriesthatwillmakeArmenia’svaluepropositiontothe worldwellshapedandvisible.Asresourcesarescarce,thiscallsforidentificationofa fewselected strategic levers thatcould be deployed to attain high impact. The latter does not eliminate the need for broadbased public and private sector reforms, improvement ofgeneralbusiness environment,provisionofgeneralprodevelopment economicpolicy,etc.Insteadthesetwostreamsneedtoreinforceeachother. Asinmechanics,leversaredeployedusingabaseorplatform.Baseinthiscasemaybe aneffectivesectorspecific,microlevelpolicyplatform.Suchaplatformwilldirectthe levers’ energy and impact to specific sectors, technologies and locations. The combination of levers and the bases can be called a leverage system. The leverage systemthathasbeenidentifiedforthepurposesmentionedabovewillhaveathreetier hierarchyasdescribedinFigure4.1TheLeveragePlatformwillconsistofthreesetsof policies and initiatives – cluster policy, innovation policy (which is related to and mutuallyreinforcesclusterpolicy)andregionaldevelopmentpolicies.TheKeyLevers aretargetedforeigndirectinvestment(FDI),formationanddevelopmentofDiaspora entrepreneurialnetworksandstrategicinitiativesineducation. Figure 4.1 System of Levers ThecentralroleinshapingtheleverageplatformwSystem of Leversillbelongtoclusterinitiatives(or policies). This will be called the policy nexus . The cluster initiatives in potentially internationallyLeverage competitive Platform clusters will be enhanced by supportiveKey Levers innovation and regionaldevelopmentpolicieswhichcanbecalled policyaddins .Thecombinedand integratedapplicationofthisplatformisintendedInnovationPolicy tocreateanefficientandconduciveFDI contextforapplyingthelevers.

Diaspora Networks ClusterInitiatives

Regional Education Development Policy Leverage Platform

Policy Nexus - Cluster Policies. Theconceptofclustershasbecomeverypopularin manycountriesduringrecentyears.Asitspracticalmanifestation,alargenumberof clusterinitiativesatnationalandregionallevelshavebeeninitiatedwithmassivepublic supportandresourceinfusions. Theclusterpoliciescancreateanoverarchingpolicycontextwheredifferentfunctional orsectorspecificpoliciescanbeincorporatedandimplemented.Atthecurrentstage themosturgentcompetitivenesspolicyingredientswithstrongsynergiesareseentobe innovationandregionaldevelopment.Theregionaldisparityimpedescompetitiveness by skewing the benefits of economic growth. Fortunately, regional policy is an emerging policy priority for the Armenian government; however, it should be incorporatedintotherightmixofmeasuresandbroadereconomicdevelopmentpolicy context. Another emerging policy domain is innovation policy that is supposed to energize Armenia’s potential to become a location for producing high valueadded products.Theeffectivenessofthesetwopolicyprioritiesisdependentontheiroptimal combinationandcoordinationaswellastheirtargeteddeployment.Theclusterpolicies can provide an appropriate context to assure these two aspects, as clusters are the ultimatedevelopmenttargetsincorporatingbothgeographicalaswellastechnological dimensions. Generally, well designed frameworks of collaboration can be worked out by the governmentsothatdifferenteffortsdon’toverlapandresultinawasteofresources. However, it should be noted that different clusters require different strategies and differentsetsofinterventions;therefore,thoseframeworksshouldbeflexibleenoughto capturethesedifferences.Theymustalsotakeintoaccountlocationbasedspecificsof theclusterswhichcanbepartofregionaldevelopmentpolicies. Inadditiontothis,averyfocusedandintensiveclusterdevelopmenteffortisrequired inselectedareastoraiseArmenia’sinternationalcompetitiveness.Currently,fromthe perspectiveofcompetitiveness,oneofArmenia’skeychallengesisthedevelopmentof a few internationally competitive industries that will set the economy on the path to innovation. No country can be competitive in all industries. Specialization is at the heartofcompetitiveness.OnlyahandfulofindustriescanbecomedriversofArmenia’s internationalcompetitiveness.Givenalsothelimitedpublicandprivateresourcesthat canbemobilized,theeffortsshouldbehighlyfocusedanddeliberatelydesigned. Whilethereisaneedforthoroughresearchforshortlistingthepromisingclustersthere isalreadyahighdegreeofconsensusaroundsomeclustersamongkeystakeholdersas totheirpotentialaspriorityareas.TheArmeniangovernmenthasalreadyprioritized IT and tourism; however, despite some strategic approach is emerging, this still requiresapoliticalwillandcompetencetocommitnecessaryresources.

Innovation Policies. As Armenia strives to build a knowledgebased economy, the creation and development of innovationsupporting infrastructure becomes a critical challengeforthenext510years.TheinternationalcompetitivenessoftheArmenian economydependsgreatlyonitscompanies’abilitiestocreateand market innovative productsandservicesinforeignmarkets.Whilestillsporadicandinconsistent,thereis anemergingdebateaboutthecreationofelementsofanationalinnovationsystemin Armenia.Thegovernmenthasadoptedaprogramontheformationofaninnovation system for 20052010; however, the committed funds are extremely small, the frameworkisnotyetdevelopedandthereisnoadequateunderstandingofitsroleand placeintheoverallpolicycontext. Thegeneralclusterapproachtoorganizingandstimulatinginnovativeandproductive entrepreneurship can become a coherent platform for innovation policy in Armenia. Underthisapproachtheclusterprioritieswillbecomeprioritiesforinnovationpolicy basedontheneedforsupportofinnovativeprocessbyspecificclusters.Theselection of tools may include: (a) critical infrastructure development, (b) knowledge and informationcenters,(c)incentiveschemes,(d)procurementpolicies.

Regional Development Policies. Despite the fact that the government has already prioritizedthisissue,thereisstillavagueunderstandingofhowtocombattheproblem. Thekeypitfallhereisthatitmaybedealtwithas if it is a purely social problem. Sustainabledevelopmentispossibleonlyifitisdrivenbycommerciallyviableprojects based onkeyspecializationsof eachregion. Specializations should be based on the rightmixofcomparativeadvantagesofregionsthatcanbegraduallydevelopedinto competitiveadvantages.Specializationnaturallycaterstotheconceptofclusters.Thus, instead of current infrastructure building projects implemented in isolation without complex development plans, this approach calls for highly coordinated, deliberately craftedpublicprivatecollaborativeeffortstocreateregionalclusters.Onthepartofthe government this may still include infrastructure development; however, in this case welltailoredtotheneedsofemergingbusinesssectorintheregionandenhancedby privateinvestments. The approach will require development of strategic profiles of each region. The strategicprofilesandactionplansofeachregionshouldbesynthesizedandintegrated intothegeneralclusterbasedeconomicdevelopmentpolicy.Thisapproachwillhelp introduce elements of a bottomup and topdown, businessoriented process to the designofeconomicpolicies.Itwillalsoensurea shiftfromamacroeconomicfocus towardamicroeconomicfocus,whichisanabsoluteimperativeforpublicpolicyinthe economicareainArmenia.

Key Levers The threecomponent leverage platform will create a probusiness economic development policy context, within which different reform initiatives can be implemented.However,therearethreekeyfactorsthatcanbedeployedtobringatrue breakthrough.InthecontextofArmeniatheseare:(1)technologicalFDI,(2)Diaspora networksand(3)superioreducation.Thesefactorsweredeterminedtakingintoaccount three criteria: (1) Armenia’s possible value propositionalternativessuggestedinthis paper, (2) Armenia’s comparative advantages that can be developed into unique competitiveadvantages,and(3)theneedformobilizationandprioritizationofprimary toolsforstrategicbreakthrough FDI. DespitethefactthatArmeniadeclaredanopendoorpolicytoFDI,thishasnot become a majordriver of technological upgradeand specialization in the Armenian economy. In order to achieve this, Armenia should pursue a clearly targeted FDI attractionstrategy.Thebuildingblocksofsuchaneffortshouldbe: • welldefinedtargetmarkets–rightmixoftargetmultinationals; • clear priorities deriving from policy context (fit with cluster priorities, applying innovationincentives); • initial “seed” public investments in creating fundamentals/basic infrastructure in targetedclusters(inmanycasesspeciallytailoredtocertainmultinationals’needs); • aggressive marketing and targeted promotion plans supported by an adequate budget; • involvementofafewworldrenownedtopexecutives(preferablynonArmenians) asleadersinpromotionandcommunications; • utilizationoftheDiasporaexecutivesholdingkeypositionsattargetedcompanies; • upgradeofinstitutionsinvolvedinFDIattraction.

Diaspora. The Diaspora may become a unique source of competitive advantage for Armeniathatcanbematchedonlybyafewothernations.Aneffectivepartnershipcan bebuiltona“hubandspoke”model.WithinthatmodelArmeniashouldbeviewedas acenter(hub)forglobalArmenianbusinessandotherpartnershipflows.Thegradual move of HQs, coordinating units, information centers and other resources of pan ArmenianorganizationsandnetworkstoArmeniaisonlyoneofmanywaystocreate such a model. Connections and competences are the most critical resources that DiasporacaninvestintoArmenia’seconomy.Itisauniquesourceforcreatingtraining and innovation centers, bringing in worldclass expertise, and accessing the most soughtaftercorporateleadersofglobalcompanies.Thiscallsforasetofcoordinated activitiesaswellashighlyefficientinstitutionalformsofengagement. Education. EducationmustbemadeapriorityifArmenia’scompetitivenessistobe based on knowledge and skillintensive characteristics and if its regional value propositionwillbebasedonuniquehumancapital.Thisleadstoseveralpreconditions (principles) that need to be satisfied for a successful deployment of education as a competitivenesslever: 1. Very high standards of primary education matching the best international practices. Basiceducation shouldnotbebiasedtowards any specialization, but should provide comprehensive knowledge, creative thinking and high ethical values. However, mathematics (and some natural sciences) should be a high priorityasabasicdisciplineforallnaturalsciences. 2. Basiceducationshouldbecomeakeycommunicationchannelofnationalideals and major aspects of national identity. Such values will constitute the fundamentals ofcompetitiveness thinking asthey will define common national goalsandaspirations. 3. Stress on specialization in special and higher education congruent with cluster developmentpreferences.Thoseareasshallreceivemostoftheresources. 4. Leadership aspirations in 23 areas of specialization in the region. Armenia shouldstrivetobecomealeaderintheprovisionofspecialeducationalservicesin afewareaslinkedwithoverallclusterandspecializationpreferences. 5. Creation and development of a few “centers of excellence”, scaling them up, leveraging them and replicating them on a larger scale to achieve spillovers throughouttheentiresystem. Quick Wins Wedevelopedaspecialanalyticaltooltoidentifyshorttermprioritiesandselectthe quick wins. The tool has been entitled the “Prioritization Filter”. The competitive disadvantages or areas where Armenia trails most nations are assessed from the viewpoint of feasibility of rapid improvements given the current resource and competence constraints as well as its overall impact on the entire economy. The Prioritization Filter incorporates four key criteria applied to assess and prioritize differentcompetitiveareas.Thus,thementionedfourcriteriaare: - ResourceRestrictions - CompetenceGap - TimeSpan

- SpilloverEffect. Thefactorof“ResourceRestrictions”assessestheavailabilityofalltypesofresources (excludinghuman)necessarytoaddressacertaincompetitivedisadvantageintheshort term. The “Competence Gap” factor assesses the existence or lack of required knowledge, expertise, experience, and will to mitigate a specific disadvantage. The “TimeSpan”isthemostimportantfactorasitassessesthefeasibilityofimprovement ofacertainissuein23years,whilethe“SpilloverEffect”providesanassessmentof thepotentialpositiveeffectssuchimprovementsmighthaveontheentireeconomyat thecurrentstage,i.e.positiveexternalitiesofspecificactions.Eachcriterionisassigned aweightandassessedusinga15scale. Figure 4.2 The Logic of the Prioritization Filter to Identify Quick Wins

PriorityFilters

ResourceRestrictions

Weight–0.2 Competitive QuickWins Disadvantages CompetenceGap Weight–0.2

TimeSpan Weight–0.35

SpilloverEffect Weight–0.25 Using this methodology, 10 factors have been identified as possible quick wins, groupedintothreedistinctareas: –Energizingfinancialsector –Improvingselectedelementsofbusinessenvironment –Promotingtechnologyusage(seeTable4.1).

Table 4.1 Identified Quick Wins

EnergizingFinancial 1. Easingaccesstoloansandexpandingcreditactivitybybanks Sector 2. Reductionofinterestratespread 3. Raisingeffectivenessofantitrustpolicy ImprovingSelected 4. Improvingtheeffectoftaxation(creatingtaxincentives,total ElementsofBusiness taxrate,burdenofcustomsprocedures,nonwagelaborcosts) Environment 5. IntroducingincentivesforFDIinprioritizedareas 6. Spreadingtheuseofcellulartelephones 7. Encouragingtheuseofpersonalcomputers PromotingTechnology 8. EncouragingInternetusage Usage 9. RegulatoryframeworkencouraginguseofICT 10. Governmentprocurementoftechnologyproducts

V. CONCLUDING REMARKS

Armeniastillhasalongwaytogoinordertocreateahighlycompetitiveeconomy.It hasalreadyrecordednotableachievementsinensuringbasicconditionsforeconomic development.However,thenextstagerequiresmorefocusedefforts,greaterskillsand higheraspirations.Successwilldependonthenation’s firmchoice, its ability to set cleargoals,achieveconsensus,mobilizeresourcesandworkdiligentlytowardsthose goals.Theenergizingforcewillhavetobethecountry’s leadership since “if a man knowsnotwhatharborheseeks,anywindistherightwind”(Seneca).

REFERENCES Arzumanyan, T. (2006), CurrentIssuesofResearch,DevelopmentandInnovation in Armenia ,InternationalJournalofForesightandInnovationPolicy,Vol.2No.2,pp. 133145 Chami Batista, J. (2004), Latin American Export Specialization in ResourceBased Products:ImplicationsforGrowth ,TheDevelopingEconomies,Vol.42No.3,p337 370 InternationalLaborOrganization(2007),LaborstaInternet,Geneva International Monetary Fund (2007), International Financial Statistics, Washington D.C. Lall,S.(2000),TheTechnologicalStructureandPerformanceofDevelopingCountry Manufactured Exports, 1985–1998 , Queen Elizabeth House Working Paper Number 49,OxfordUniversity Mahmood, A. (2004), Export Competitiveness and Comparative Advantage of Pakistan’s Nonagricultural Production Sectors: Trends and Analysis , the Pakistan DevelopmentReview,Vol.43No4,p541561 NationalStatisticalServiceofArmenia(2008),Yerevan,Armenia(www.armstat.am) Porter, M. E. (1990), The Competitive Advantage of Nations, New York: The Free Press. Porter, M. E. (1998), On Competition , the Harvard Business Review Book Series, Boston,MA,UnitedStates UNESCOInstituteforStatistics(2007),OnlineDatabase,Paris UnitedNationsConferenceonTradeandDevelopment(2007),UNCTADHandbookof StatisticsOnline,NewYorkandGeneva,UnitedNations United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (2004), Development and Globalization:FactsandFigures,NewYorkandGeneva,UnitedNations WorldBank(2007a),DoingBusiness2008 ,WashingtonDC WorldBank(2007b)WorldDevelopmentIndicatorsOnline,WashingtonD.C. World Economic Forum (2006), The Global Competitiveness Report 20062007: CreatinganImprovedBusinessEnvironment ,Hampshire:PalgraveMacmillan World Economic Forum (2007), The Global Competitiveness Report 20072008 , Hampshire:PalgraveMacmillan,NewYork,UnitedStates

ARMENIA ’S MILLENNIUM CHALLENGE ACCOUNT : ASSESSING IMPACTS ON ECONOMIC GROWTH AND POVERTY REDUCTION IN RURAL ARMENIA KennethFortson,Mathematica EsterHakobyan,MCAArmenia AnahitPetrosyan,MCAArmenia AnuRangarajan,Mathematica RebeccaTunstall,MCC * Abstract: The Millennium Challenge Corporation’s $236 million Compact with Armeniaaimstoreduceruralpovertythroughinvestmentsinirrigationinfrastructure, ruralroadrehabilitation,andfarmertraining.Thispaperdiscussesthedesignfora rigorous impact evaluation of the farmer training project, which focuses on water management and cultivation of highvalue crops. The evaluation uses a random assignmentdesign,wherebyruralcommunitiesarerandomly assigned to atreatment group,whoareofferedagriculturaltrainingearlyintheCompact,oracontrolgroup, whoarenot.Wewillthencomparefarmers’outcomesintreatmentgroupvillagesto farmersincontrolgroupvillages.Theresultsoftheevaluationwillassessthefarmer trainingprogram’ssuccessinaccomplishingitskeyobjectives:Increasingadoptionof effectiveagriculturalpractices,increasingcultivationofhighervaluecrops,improving farmproductivity,increasingagriculturalprofitsandhouseholdincome,andreducing poverty rates. Moreover, the lessons learned in this contextcan be appliedto other countrieswithsimilareconomicclimatessothatfutureinvestmentscanbeefficiently allocatedtointerventionswithproveneconomicimpacts. JELClassifications:O12;O13;Q12 Keywords:Poverty;Agriculture;Training;RandomAssignment;Armenia

*ThisprojecthasbenefitedgreatlyfromthehardworkofnumerouscolleaguesatMCC,MCAArmenia, and Mathematica. We are especially grateful to Emily Andrews, Sergey Balasanyan, Randall Blair, Barry Deren, Katherine Farley, Melik Gasparyan, Mary Grider, Ara Hovsepyan, Julie Ingels, Lusine Kharatyan,SergeyMeloyan,DanielPlayer,StephanieRoueche,PeterSchochet,andSonyaVartivarian for their input throughout the project. We also thank VISTAA and ACDI/VOCA for facilitating a rigorousevaluationastheyimplementtheirprograms,andAREGforimplementingthebaselinesurvey offarmerhouseholdsthatservesasthekeydatasourcefortheevaluation.

I. INTRODUCTION InMarchof2006Armeniasigneda$235.65millionagreement(the“Compact”)with theMillenniumChallengeCorporation(MCC)withthegoalofreducingruralpoverty throughimprovedperformanceofthecountry’sagriculturalsector.Armeniaplansto achievethisgoalthroughafiveyearprogramofinvestmentsinruralroads,irrigation infrastructure, and technical and financial assistance to support farmers and agribusinesses. This paper will focus on the technical training in agricultural practices provided to Armenian farmers through the Compact’s WatertoMarket Activity (WtM), and particularly,theaccompanyingimpactevaluation. The MCC program aims to train sixtythousand farmers in regionspecific water management techniques. These methods will help farmers to use water more efficiently, which can promote both cost savings (through water conservation) and increased quantity andqualityofcrops. Many farmers who will be trained in water managementtechnologieswillalsoreceivetraininginhighervalueagricultural(HVA) methods. The combination of these activities is expected to increase beneficiaries’ averagenetincomebyabout25percent. The Compact provides funding for an innovative impact evaluation to test the assumptionsusedinthepreCompacteconomicanalysisbyassessingtheimpactofthe agricultural training on farmer productivity and income. The key research questions guidingthedesignoftheevaluationfortheagriculturaltrainingare: • Did the program affect the irrigation and agricultural practices of Armenian farmers? • Didtheprogramaffectagriculturalproductivity? • Did the program improve household wellbeing for the targeted farmers, includingincomeandpoverty? Thebackboneofourresearchdesignistheuseofrandom assignmenttocreate two statisticallyequivalentgroupsoffarmers,withtheonlydifferencebetweenthembeing thatonegroupcanparticipateintrainingwhiletheothercannot.Thisresearchdesignis consideredthemostrigorousmethodologicalapproachforestimatingprogramimpacts. Randomassignmenthasbeenimplementedtoestimatetheeffectsofprogramsinmany contexts,andisespeciallywidespreadindevelopedcountries(Michalopoulous,2005; Kling,2007).Recentresearchhasalsoexpandedtheuseofrandomassignmentinto studies of programs in developing countries (Duflo and Kremer, 2004). To our knowledge,thisevaluationoftheCompact’sWtMtrainingprogramisthefirstlarge scalerandomassignmentevaluationinArmenia. ThenextsectionprovidesasummaryoftherecenthistoryofruralArmeniaascontext (SectionII),followedbyanoverviewoftheCompactprograms(SectionIII).Section IVprovidesadetaileddescriptionoftheWtMactivity.Withthisasbackground,we describe the evaluation design, beginning with the random assignment design in SectionV.Wethendiscussthemainsourceofdata, the Farming Practices Survey (SectionVI),followedbytheIrrigationPIUdatathatcouldbeusedasasupplemental datasource(SectionVII).Lastly,wediscussindetailour econometric approach for estimatingprogramimpactsinSectionVIIIbeforeconcludingwithasummaryofthe nextstepsinSectionIX. II. RECENT DEVELOPMENTS IN ARMENIA InJanuary1991,Armeniabeganimplementingacomprehensivelandreformprogram. Rapidprivatizationin19911992,whenonethirdofallagriculturallandand70percent ofarablelandweretransferredtofamilyfarmsand the Sovietstyle collective farms wereabolished,createdabaseforastablerecoveryofthesector.Thedecisiontomove rapidly reflectedthefactthat implementation oftheland reform had thepotential to boostarapidsupplyofagriculturalproducts,thusincreasingthespeedofmovingtoa market economy. In parallel with the land privatization, a set of reform measures designedtoliberalizeagriculturewasimplemented.Pricecontrolswereremovedand food subsidies were abolished. The major support measures to local agricultural producersincludedVATandlandtaxexemptionsaswellassubsidiesforirrigationwater. After the sharp decline of agricultural output at the beginning of the 1990s, the economyofArmeniastartedtorecoverbeginningin1994.Theagriculturalsectorhas continued to register steady growth since that time. However, agriculture has lagged behindothersectorsoftheeconomysuchastheindustrial,service,andconstruction sectors;asnotedinTable2.1,agriculturerepresentsashrinkingshareofGDPinspite ofincreasedratesofgrowth. Table 2.1 GDP and Agricultural Product

Average Average 19941999 20002007 GDPGrowthrate,percent 5.4 11.8 AgricultureProductGrowthrate,percent 3.2 6.8 ShareofAgricultureProductinGDP,percent 35.5 22.5 Source:ArmeniainFigures,NationalStatisticalServiceoftheRepublicofArmenia AnotherfeatureofArmenianagriculturehadbeentheunfavorablechangesinrelative prices. Average annual growth of agricultural pricesin19951999wasmuchslower thanincreasesinindustrialandconsumerprices(Table2.2).Asimilarpattern,though dampened,wasregisteredduring20002007.Infact,laggingagriculturalpricesreflect both weaknesses ofdemand, which steadily improved during recent years,and weak market power of farmers compared to wholesales and food processors. The disproportionatepricedevelopmentindicatesthatthegrowthinagriculturewasmostly beneficialtoconsumersandthefoodprocessingindustry. Table 2.2 Changes in Price Indices Annualaverage Annualaveragefor for19951999 20002007 ConsumerPriceIndex 143.6 103.2 IndustrialPriceIndex 166.5 105.3 AgriculturalPriceIndex 127.3 102.4 Source:ArmeniainFigures,NationalStatisticalServiceoftheRepublicofArmenia

Thelowergrowthrateoftheagriculturalsectorcomparedwithothersectorsreflectsthe relativelylowerproductivityoftheagriculturethatisexplainedbydifferentfactors: • Small,fragmentedfarms(averagelandholdingperfamilyis1.4ha)limitthe use of agricultural machinery. As a result production is labor intensive, and laborproductivityislowrelativetocapitalintensiveproduction; • Thepoorconditionofirrigationsystemscombinedwithclimaticconditionsof Armeniadecreasesefficiencyofagriculturalproduction; • Becausealargeshareoftheruralpopulation,previouslyworkinginthenon agriculturalsector,becamesubsistencefarmersinthe1990s,manyfarmersare inexperiencedandlackbasicknowledgeaboutfarmingpractices; • Inadequateuseandavailabilityofimprovedinputssuchasseed,pesticidesand appropriatefertilizerapplicationsreducestheproductivityofthesector; • Limitedopportunitiesforstorage,grading,packaging,andevenprocessingof agriculturalproductionreducesthevalueaddedandlimitsthesupplyoffresh producethroughoutayear,andalsomakesagriculturalpricesvolatileduringa year; • Farmers have limited knowledge of the markets or access to information on demand; • Inadequatefinancialservicesareavailablefortheruralsectorandfarmershave limitedaccesstothefinancialresources;and • Collaborationamongfarmersinproductionandmarketingoftheirproductsis limited. III. MCA-ARMENIA PROGRAM The Compact is designed to address many of the above issues and to increase agriculturalproductivityandreduceruralpovertyinArmenia.MCAArmeniaProgram is addressing these obstacles through two projects: Rural Road Rehabilitation and IrrigatedAgricultureProjects. The first project implemented under the MCAArmenia Program is the Rural Roads Rehabilitation Project. The implementation of the Project will expand the access of ruralcommunitiestoagriculturalmarketsandsocialinfrastructure,aswellasincrease nonfarmincomeopportunitiesbyimprovingtheconditionofruralroads.TheCompact wasdesignedtoincludeMCCfundingtorehabilitateupto943kmoftheruralroads from ‘very poor’, or ‘poor’, to ‘good’ condition. The project is expected to benefit hundredsofthousandsofruralArmenians. Thesecondproject,theIrrigatedAgricultureProject, willincreasetheprofitabilityof theagriculturalsectorbyextendingandimprovingtheirrigationnetwork,strengthening irrigation entities to better manage the network, and supporting farmers to commercialize their production. For these purposes two types of activities will be implemented under the Irrigated Agriculture Project. The first activity, Irrigation Infrastructure Rehabilitation, will improve existing infrastructure in order to increase irrigatedareaandtoimprovetheefficiencyandsustainabilityofsourcinganddelivery of water. It is expected that the Project implementation will result in expansion of irrigatedareas,conversionofselectedirrigationareasfrompumptogravityirrigation toreduceenergyconsumptionandmakewatermoreaffordable,aswellasreducewater lossesintheirrigationnetwork.Theprimaryprojectbeneficiariesareexpectedtobe morethan115,000farminghouseholds(orabout40percent of all rural households) whowillbeabletoincreasetheproductivityoftheirirrigatedland. ThesecondactivityintheIrrigatedAgricultureProject,theWatertoMarketActivity (WtM), will accelerate the transition to more profitable, commerciallyorientated agricultural production by introducing and encouraging best practices in irrigated agriculture,fosteringtheadoptionofimprovedwatermanagementtechniques,shifting or expanding to higher value crops, strengthening the postharvest and processing enterprises linking producers to their markets, both domestic and international, and strengtheningthecapacityofcreditproviderstofund viable proposals in production andpostharvestactivities. IV. WATER -TO -MARKET TRAINING The focus of the paper is on the WatertoMarket Activity, specifically, how this activity impacts agricultural productivity and how the impact of the activity will be evaluated.TheWtMActivityisdesignedtoensurethatMCCFundingtotheIrrigation Infrastructure Rehabilitation will contribute to a sustainable increase of agricultural productivity and incomes from farming. The WatertoMarket Activity includes four types of subactivities covering the whole chain from irrigation to the delivery of agricultural products totheconsumers.MCA has contracted with ACDI/VOCA and theirpartners,VISTAAandEuroconsult(hereafterreferredtocollectivelyasACDI)to implementtheWtMactivitiesthatincludetrainingfarmersinwatermanagementand highvalueagriculture,aswellascreditandpostproductionservices.

Introduction of New On-Farm Water Management Technologies. The objective of thesubactivityistoimprovefarmers’skillsinonfarmwatermanagementtechniques andtheiraccesstofarmequipmenttoenhancetheefficiencyofwateruseinirrigation. The objective will be reached through implementation of the integrated program includinginclasstrainingandonfielddemonstrationsoftheadvancedandlocation appropriateonfarmirrigationpractices.Traininganddemonstrationswillbeprovided to 60,000 farmers, of whom approximately 65 percent are expected to adopt water savingandproductivityinnovationsthatwillincreasethenetbenefitoftheirfarming operations.

The demonstration farm is a critical part of the initial training and also can help reinforcethelessons even after training is completed. Farmsare selectedtoserve as demonstration sites based on their proximity to other farmers in the village and the demonstration farmer’s willingness to adopt new technologies and facilitate other farmers’ understanding. ACDI provides equipment for the demonstration farms; in exchange,thedemonstrationfarmsareusedasthesiteofthepracticaltraining,andalso a resource where farmers in the village can go to see the technologies in practice, beyondtheofficialtrainingsession. Demonstrationfarmswillserveanywherefromonetofivevillages,dependingonthe numberofeligiblefarmersinthosevillagesandtheirproximity.Somedemonstration farms exist from previous activities, and these will be supplemented with new demonstration farms. Most demonstration farms will be new. The trainers will be agricultural experts who come from the same region so as to ensure that they are familiar with the local climatic and agricultural conditions, and so that they are

availablefortechnicalassistancebeyondthetrainingsessions.Onceademonstration farmisestablished,ACDIwillprovideseveralroundsoftrainingatthatdemonstration farmtosaturatetheassociatedvillagesasmuchaspossible,becausehighparticipation rateswillmaximizetheuseofasingledemonstrationfarm.

Coordinators will target farmers who are members of Water User Associations (WUAs).Theywilluseposterstoadvertiseatvillagecentersandworkwithmayorsto mobilizefarmerstoparticipate.Insomevillages,mayorsmayalsobeabletoidentify farmerswhoareparticularlylikelytoparticipate,andthesefarmerscouldbetargeted foradditionalrecruitmentefforts.

Transition to Higher Value Agriculture. Theobjectiveofthissubactivityistosupport thefarmers’transitiontomoreprofitableagriculturalproductionthroughacombination ofcropsubstitution,increasedcroppingintensity,andtheuseofhigheryieldgenerating plantingmaterialsandrelatedinputs.Liketheonfarmwatermanagementtraining,the objective of this subactivity will also be reached through implementation of the integratedprogramincludinginclasstrainingandonfielddemonstrationsofadvanced, locationappropriate farming practices. 30,000 farmers will be trained in HVA to increasethecommercialvalueoftheirfarms’output.BytheendoftheProgram,itis expectedthatapproximately7,800hectaresoflandwillbeconvertedintohighervalue agricultural cultivation as a result of increased access to water combined with an effectivetrainingprogram.

Post-Harvest, Processing and Marketing. The objective of this subactivity is to introduce and expand postharvest operations that best preserve the quality of agricultureproductsandaddvaluetoproduction.Forthispurposenewstrategiesand technologies for storage, sorting and packaging, transportation and processing of agriculturalproductswillbeintroduced.Improvedsupplyrelationshipsbetweenpost harvestenterprisesandtheirfarmsupplierswillbeanotherimportantaspectofthissub activity. The assistance to 12 firms includes diagnostic analysis of enterprises and providing recommendations for improvements, conducting food safety and hygiene training,providingweeklymarketinformationonfreshfruitsandvegetablesaswellas other related activities. Reliable information on market conditions and opportunities will contribute to the better positioning of fresh and processed food products in the domestic,regionalandinternationalmarketsandcreatetraderelationships.Foodsafety and quality assurance issues such as Hazard Analysis and Critical Control Point (HACCP) and International Standards Organization (ISO) certification will also be addressedthroughthissubactivity.BytheendoftheProgram,itisexpectedthatthese activitieswillimpact300agribusinessesand15,000farmers.

Improved Access to Credit. Theobjectivesofthissubactivityaretwofold.Improved irrigationandruralroadswillpresentnewopportunitiesfor farmers and agricultural related businesses. However, improved irrigation and rural roads will create new opportunities for financial institutions as well. Therefore, the objective of this sub activityistoincreasetheavailabilityoflongerterm,affordablecredittobeneficiaries oftheProject.Toreachthisobjective,thesubactivitywillprovideUSD8.5million onlending resources to banks and credit organizations. The subactivity will also developthecapacityofbanksandcreditorganizationstolendefficientlyandprudently intheagriculturesector.Thesubactivitywillprovideassistanceinapplyingforloans tothepotentialloanapplicantsaswell.Theassistancewillimprovetheabilityofthe farmerstoaccessfinancialresourcesandincreasetheirawarenessandunderstandingof credit. These actions will facilitatethe intermediation process and reduce transaction costsandriskforcreditprovidersbydevelopingbetterinformedandbetterprepared borrowers. Table 4.1 summarizes WatertoMarket Activity’s training and adoption targets for these four subactivities. Through these activities, the direct impact of the WtM Activitywillbetogeneratenewemploymentopportunitiesandincreaseincomeamong farmsandruralbusinesses.Thesynergybetweenruralinfrastructuredevelopmentand agribusinessdevelopmentisdesignedtoresultinasignificant,sustainablereductionin ruralpoverty. Table 4.1 WtM Adoption Targets

OnFarmWaterManagementTraining 60,000farmers HigherValueAgricultureTraining 30,000farmers Post harvestEnterprisesTechnicalAssistance 300enterprises BankLoansprovidedtoprojectbeneficiariesan drelatedbusinesses $8.5millioninloans Adoptionofimprovedon farmwatermanagement 38,350farmers HectaresConvertedtoHighValueAgriculture 7,845hectares TheimplementationoftheprogramstartedinFebruaryof2007.Theimplementation processincludestwomajorstages.Thefirststage,thepilotstage,coveredFebruary September2007andithadaveryspecificpurposetoprovidelessonslearnedforfull scale program implementation. The first stage was mostly focused on onfarm water managementtrainingasastrategictooltoimprovefarmers’skillsintheonfarmwater management and irrigation techniques, as well as their access to new irrigation technologytoenhancetheefficiencyofwateruse.Throughdemonstrationandtraining, farmers are encouraged to adopt new or improved irrigation methodologies and methods which are effective and affordable for different categories of farmers. Therefore,theactivitiesindemonstrationsiteshavetosuitallcategoriesoffarmersin terms of size and show a wide range of system improvements from the simple and inexpensivetothemorecostlyones.Thegeneralemphasisisonsavingwaterandlabor through proper irrigation scheduling, more uniform distribution of water within the farm and more effective delivery to the field. Development of skills and improved farmers’knowledgeareviewedasthemostcrucialfactorsforachievingasatisfactory levelofadoptionandsustainabilityoftheexpectedchanges. FullscaleimplementationoftheWatertoMarketprogramstartedinOctober2007.By the end of March 2008 the number of participants completing the OnFarm Water Management training reached 8,186 farmers. Besides the training on onfarm water management techniques, other activities were implemented as well. The number of participants completing training in High Value Agriculture, which helps farmers identify more profitable crops for their specific regions and best practices for cultivatingthosecrops,totaled495farmers. V. USING RANDOM ASSIGNMENT TO ESTIMATE IMPACTS

Theidealmethodforseparatingprograminfluencesfromotherfactorsistocompare outcomesforthegroupwhoareprovidedtheintervention with theoutcomesfor the same group if they were not offered the intervention. However, once persons or communities are offered the intervention, it is not possible to know what their outcomeswouldhavebeeniftheywerenotgiventheopportunitytoparticipate.Itcan only be approximated by comparing their outcomes to the outcomes of some other group. Randomassignment,themostrigorouswaytomeasureprogramimpacts,isfrequently referredtoasthegoldstandardofevaluationdesigns.Essentially,whenimplemented carefully,randomassignmentleadstothecreationoftwovirtuallyidenticalgroupsat baseline,withthe onlydifferencebeing thatonly one group (the treatment group) is exposed to the intervention, while the other group (the control group) is not. As a result,anychangesobservedbetweenthetwogroupsovertimecanbeattributedtothe effects of the intervention with a known degree of statistical precision. (Michalopoulous,2005;Kling,2007;DufloandKremer,2004) Unit of Random Assignment. Ideally,wewouldrandomlyassignindividualfarmersto receivetrainingornot,andcompareoutcomesforthetwogroups.However,because these training sessions are community level interventions, making it difficult to excludeindividualfarmers,suchanapproachisnotfeasibleinthiscontext.Ourbasic approach is to randomly assign villages to the treatment group of farmers, who are eligibleforonfarmwatermanagementtrainingandHVAtraining,orthecontrolgroup offarmers,whoarenot.ACDIhasgroupedvillagesintoclusters.Mostclustersinclude onlyonevillage,butsomeincludeasmanyasfivevillagesthatareinclosegeographic proximity.AllfarmerswhoareWUAmembersandliveinaclusterofvillagesselected forthetreatmentgroupwillbepermittedtoparticipateinwatermanagementtraining. Farmerswhoareinthecontrolgroupofvillageclusterswouldnotbeofferedwater managementtraininguntilseveralyearslater.Allvillageswillultimatelybeprovided training,andrandomassignmentisusedtodetermine when theyareofferedtraining. Randomlyassigningentirevillageclustersinthisway,ratherthanindividualfarmersor villages,guardsagainstcontaminationofthecontrolgroupthepossibilitythatcontrol groupmembersgetthesameservicesasthetreatmentgroup.Therearetwotypesof contamination.Thefirsttypeofcontaminationisiffarmersincontrolgroupvillages nonethelessparticipateintraining.Thiscouldbeproblematicifcontrolgroupmembers hearaboutthetrainingactivitiesandshowuptotrainingthemselves.Adifferenttype ofcontaminationcouldoccuriffarmerswhoparticipateintrainingteachfarmersinthe controlgroupaboutthetechniquestheylearned.Eitherofthesetypesofcontamination wouldbeproblematicfortheevaluationbecausewewouldbeunabletocomparethose whowereofferedtrainingtothosewhowerenotofferedtraining;withcontamination, both the treatment and control group have access to or benefit from training. Generally, ACDI has chosen village clusters that are sufficiently far apart geographically to ensure that there is little chance that farmers in a control group village cluster would either participate in the training or learn about the water managementtechniquesthroughothermeans. However, in some areas particularly the Ararat Valley region many villages are located in close proximity. While we cannot completely eliminate the possibility of contamination here, it willbe importantfor theplanned implementation to strive to avoidsuchcontaminationproblemsby,forexample,ensuringthatrecruitingtechniques for the training attract treatment group farmers without influencing control group farmers.TheWtMtrainingprogramexitquestionnairewillalsoinformusaboutwhere farmersreside,whichwillhelpusassesstheextenttowhichcontrolgroupfarmersare “crossing over”andreceiving training in spiteof beingrandomlyassignedtonotbe eligible. Implementing Random Assignment. Randomassignmentwasconductedforthesubset of villages that have adequate water and could potentially be served early in the Compact.Werandomlyassignedvillagestooneofthreegroups:thosewhowouldbe servedinthesecondyearoftheCompact;thosewhowouldbeservedineitheryear3 oryear4oftheCompact;andthosewhocanbeservedinthefinalyearoftheCompact. The earliest group constitutes our treatment group, and the latest group our control groupimpactswillbemeasuredafterthetreatmentgrouphasbeenprovidedtraining butbeforethecontrolgrouphas.Themiddlegroup,thosewhoareservedinthethirdor fourth year, will not be included in the impact evaluation. Only villages that were consideredreadyforWtMtrainingwereincludedintherandomization;somevillages currentlyhavepoorsourcesofwater,andthus,wouldnotbenefitfromtraininguntil their irrigation systems are rehabilitated. Such villages may receive training in the future,buttheywillnotbeincludedintheimpactevaluation.Wealsoexcludedfrom therandomassignmentallvillagesthatwereincludedinthepilotphaseoftheWtM trainingorwhereACDIhasalreadydevelopeddemonstrationfarms. Random assignment was conducted within strata defined by WUAs to preserve regional balance, which created balanced treatment and control groups along this dimension.Thedistributionofvillagesbytreatmentstatusforeachagriculturalzoneis reportedinTable5.1Theprobabilityofavillagebeingassignedtothetreatmentgroup wasapproximatelythesameforallWUAs,withmostofthedeviationsoccurringdue to rounding. An exception, however, is the Mountainous Zone, where a smaller proportionofvillageswereselectedfortheresearchgroups(years2and5),whilemost villageswereassignedtothenonresearchgroup.Thiszonewasundersampledlargely becauseMCCanticipatesverylowimpacts,sotheevaluationwillfocusmoreonthe otherzoneswhereMCCismoreoptimisticaboutthe prospectsfor improvement. A totalof120clusterswereassignedtothetreatmentgroupand80tothecontrolgroup, withthese200clusterscontaining223villagesintotal.(Forsimplicityofexposition, wehereafterrefertovillageclustersas“villages.”)

Table 5.1 Distribution of Village Clusters by Year of Training and Agricultural Zone

Yearly AraratValley PreMountainous Mountainous SubTropical Total Year2:Treatment 44 58 12 6 120 Years3and4:Nonresearch 18 19 38 2 77 Year5:Control 28 38 10 4 80 Total 90 115 60 12 277 Toensuretheprocesswastransparenttoallvillagesthatwillbeservedinthecoming years,randomassignmentwasconductedinpublicusingaspeciallydesignedcomputer programthatrandomlysortedvillagesintothethreegroups.

VI. FARMING PRACTICES SURVEY The Farming Practices Survey (FPS) will serve as the primary data source for the impact evaluation. Approximately 25 interviews will be completed in each of the villages in the treatment and control groups, with fewer in the smallest villages and moreinthelargest.MCAArmeniahascontractedwithAREGtofieldtheFPSinthe first, baseline year, and the FPS will subsequently be conducted each year of the followupperiod,attheendof2008,2009,and2010. Sample Frame. With the help of village mayors, the FPS targets the households of farmers who are most likely to benefit from the training programs: those who are activelyengagedinfarmingandhavebeentiedtothe community for several years. These farmers are identified through an iterative process. First, MCAArmenia requestedthattheWUAsworkwithvillagemayorstocompilealistoffarmersmeeting ourspecificcriteriaineachvillage.Thenumberoffarmersrequesteddependedonthe sizeofthevillage,butaveragedabout60.Thesamplewasthendrawnfromtheselists. Pretestingrevealedthattheselistswereofmixedquality,however,oftenbecausethe WUAshadnotconsultedwiththemayorsincompilingthem.Thus,thesamplewas updatedwiththeassistance ofvillage mayors andmarz officials, either at the marz officesorinthevillageitself.Themayorsreviewedtheliststodeterminewhetherthe farmersindeedmetourcriteria.Ifaninsufficientnumberoffarmersfromthelistswere eligiblethatis,incaseswheretheWUAhadfailedtoconsultwiththemayorthen the mayor helped AREG update the list in accordance with our survey eligibility criteria. Relyingonmayorstoidentifyeligiblefarmersineachvillageisnotideal,asthelists they provide may not be representative of the village as a whole. Unfortunately, a reliablesampleframewasnotavailable,andthecostofconductingacensusinproject communitiesisprohibitive.However,asthemethodAREGusedmirrorsthemannerin whichACDIidentifiesfarmerstoparticipateintraining,thesamplewillstillprovide good coverage of the population most likely to benefit from training. Moreover, becauseoftherandomassignmentdesign,treatmentandcontrolvillagesshouldstillbe comparable(onaverage),preservingtheinternalvalidityoftheevaluation. Intermediate Outcomes. Whilemostoftheoutcomesofprimaryinterestarelonger term outcomes, such as economic improvements, these outcomes may not be immediatelyobservable.Consequently,wewillcloselyexamineintermediateoutcomes throughwhichthetrainingprogramsareintendedtoimprovehouseholdincome.We wouldexpectanimpactonhouseholds’incomeonlyifweobservethatasubstantial proportionof the targeted farmersareactually participating in training, and perhaps most importantly, are then applying the techniques they learn. Examining the intermediateoutcomesalsoestablishesthecounterfactualwhatservicesthevillages wouldhavereceivedandwhatpracticestheywouldhaveadoptedevenintheabsence oftheWtMprograms.Table6.1summarizesthekeyintermediatethatcanbeexamined usingtheFPSdata. Table 6.1 Intermediate Outcome Measures

IntermediateOutcomeMeasures TimeFrame

ParticipationinAgriculturalTraining.Whetherattendedanyirrigationor agriculturetraining(includingtrainingsponsoredbyothersources);type LastYear oftrainingattended(e.g.,classroom,video,orpractical);whetherreceived acertificateindicatingthefulltrainingwasattended. AdoptionofHVAandIrrigationPractices.Whichirrigationpractices wereused,focusingonthosetaughtintrainingsessions;whetherthose LastAgriculturalSeason practiceshadperceivedtimeorlaborsavings. InvestmentinAgriculturalTechnologyorEquipment. Ownershipof personalreservoirorwaterpump;ownershiporrentaloftrucks,tractors, LastAgriculturalSeason combines,seedplanters,andsprayers. CroppingPatterns. Specificcropsgrown,especiallyhigh valuecrops; amountoflanddevotedtocultivationofeachcrop;totalhectaresofland LastAgriculturalSeason devotedtocrops;whetherhouseholdcultivatesakitchenplot;reason(s) forchangesincroppingpatterns. Final Outcomes. The ultimate goal of the MCAArmenia programs is to increase householdincomeinruralArmenia,andhence,theseoutcomesareanimportantfocus oftheFPSinstrument.Becauseafullaccountingofallsourcesofhouseholdincome wouldrequirefarlongertoadministerthantheallotted time for each interview, the surveyconcentratesonsourcesofincomethataremostdirectlyaffectedbythetraining programs,specifically,incomefromagriculturalproductionandfromemploymentby thefarmerandhisorherimmediatefamily.Wecanalsousetheaveragesalepriceof specificcropsforotherfarmersinthevillagetomonetizecropsthatareconsumedby thehouseholdorbartered.Additionally,theFPSasksforestimatesofexpenditureson key categories of consumption, and for income from other sources. Table 6.2 summarizesthekeyfinaloutcomesthatcanbeexaminedusingtheFPSdata.

Survey Nonresponse. All interviews are conducted in person, and a limited span of time is available for interviews in the majority of villages. Therefore, survey nonresponseisaconcern.Substantialsurveynonresponsecandamagethevalidityof impact estimates. Nonresponse weights can account for some of the differential nonresponse, but only to the extent that nonresponse is explained by household characteristicsthatareknownforbothrespondentsandnonrespondents.Intheworst case, survey nonresponse might be different for treatment and control villages, contradictingthecoreassumptionsofarandomassignmentdesign.Morecommonly, however,surveynonresponseaffectsboththetreatmentandcontrolgroupsequally.In this scenario, the impact estimates remain internally valid, but may not generalize beyond the select group of survey respondents. As a salient example, if farmers’ absencesareduetotripstothemarketstoselltheirproduce,thentherespondentsmay haveadisproportionateshareofthelessengagedfarmers,forwhomprogramimpacts couldbeminimal. We have instituted several safeguards against survey nonresponse. Working with mayorstocleanthelistsinadvancecanhelpinthisregard.Wheneverpossible,village mayorswouldalsocontactthesampledhouseholdsinadvancetoensuretheywouldbe availableforinterviewsonthedayAREGvisitedtheir village. In instances wherea household is not available on the first attempt, interviewers would return to the householdthroughouttheirtimeinthatvillage.AREGalsohasreservelistsoffarmers which they can draw on to help them reach their targets for completed interviews withineachvillage.

Table 6.2 Final Outcome Measures FinalOutcomeMeasures TimeFrame ContinuingUseofHVAandIrrigationPractices.Sameasabove,but focusingonchangesinthesepracticesrelativetotheinitialfollowup LastAgriculturalSeason years. AgriculturalProduction . Totalamountofspecificcropsgrown;amountof LastAgriculturalSeason cropsgrownpersquaremeter;totalvalueofallcropscultivated. Livestock.Numberofcows,pigs,andsheepowned. AsofSurveyDate RevenuefromAgriculturalProduction.Valueofcropssold;totalvalueof LastAgriculturalSeason allcrops(includingthosesold,bartered,orconsumed). AgriculturalCosts. Expendituresonfertilizers,pesticides,irrigation LastAgriculturalSeason water,hiredlabor,rentedequipmentandtaxes(individuallyandintotal). ProfitfromAgriculturalProduction. Revenuesminusc osts —theincome LastAgriculturalSeason fromagriculturalactivities. IncomefromEmployment. Whetherhouseholdhead,spouse,andany grownchildrenwereemployed(besidesworkonthefamilyfarm);total LastMonth earningsfromemployment. Incomefrom Pensions,Remittances,orSocialPrograms. Canalsobe addedtoprofitsandemploymentincometoconstructaroughmeasureof LastMonth totalincome. HouseholdConsumption. Expenditureonpurchasedfood,healthcare, housingproducts,utilities,andtransportation;costofpurchasedgoods LastMonth/LastYear (convertedfrommonthlytoannual)plusvalueofcropsconsumedbythe household.

Follow-up Surveys. Ideally,eachroundoftheFPSwouldinterviewthe same set of households, yielding a longitudinal data set. Analytically, longitudinaldataallow for the cleanest estimation of program impacts, and also provide the most statistical precision, because changes from the baseline to the followup period are not confoundedwithsamplingvariability.Asapracticalmatter,however,itmaynotbeas easytotrackspecifichouseholdsfromyeartoyear.Ourplanistosurveythesameset ofhouseholdsinsubsequentroundsoftheFPStothe extent possible, but given the nonresponse issues described previously, we anticipate that these will need to be supplementedwithadditionalhouseholds,yieldingamixedlongitudinalrepeatedcross sectionaldataset.Thesampleframewillremainconsistent;soastoavoidhavingthe samplesfortreatmentandcontrolvillagesdivergeovertime. VII. IRRIGATION PIU DATA TheIrrigationPIUhasanimpressivedatabaseforasubsetoftheWUAs,andbythe endoftheCompact,itisplannedthatinformationonmembersofallWUAswillbe includedintheirdatabases.Thesedatacouldbeusedtosupplementthesurveydatain two important ways. First, they provide some outcome measures that would not be obtainablefromfarmers,suchasenergyuseandwaterdistribution.Second,theywill providedataonsomeoutcomemeasuresfortheentirepopulationofregisteredWUA members in Armenia. These data items are defined in more general terms than the surveydataforexample,theamountoflandtheWUAmemberplanstogrowwheat on, but notactualproduction buttheycanstill be used to inform us about broad nationalandregionaltrends.

VIII. ESTIMATING PROGRAM IMPACTS Random assignment ensures that, on average, treatment group villages and control groupvillagesarethesame,withtheexceptionthattreatmentgroupvillagesareoffered WtMtraining.Hence,thedifferencebetweenthemeanoftheoutcomeofinterestfor thetreatmentgroupandthemeanforthecontrolgroupyieldsanunbiasedestimateof the WtM program’s impact. The precision of the impact estimates can be improved, however, by controlling for other covariates in a regression model. Regression adjustmentcanalsohelpalleviateanydifferencesbetween the treatment and control groupsinbaselinecharacteristicsthatarosebychance. Core Specification. Thesurveydatawillbecrosssectional,withanewcrosssectionof respondentsdrawneachyear. 1Giventhisdatastructure,oureconometricspecification isdesignedtocomparehowtreatmentgroupvillageschangedovertimetohowcontrol groupvillageschangedovertime,controllingforidiosyncraticdifferencesinthetwo groups.Thebasicmodelcanbeexpressedasfollows:

(1) yivt=β′ x iv + λ TFF v ×+ t θηε t ++ v ivt , where yivt istheoutcomeofinterestforhousehold iinvillage vattime t(where Ft=0 in the baseline year and 1 in the followup year); xiv is a vector of timeinvariant characteristicsofhousehold i invillage v; taccountsforanytimetrendsbetweenthe baseandfollowupyears; Tvisanindicatorequaltooneifvillage visinthetreatment groupandzeroifitisinthecontrolgroup; ηvisavillagespecificerrorterm(avillage “randomeffect”);and εivt isarandomerrortermforhousehold iinvillage vobservedat time t.Theparameterestimatefor λistheestimatedimpactoftheprogram. The vector of baseline characteristics xiv will include both household and village characteristics. Ataminimum,we willcontrol for village characteristics suchas the geographicregion,WUA,andthebaselinewaterconditions.Wewillalsocontrolfor household size and composition, and characteristics of the household head, namely, education level, gender, age, and number of years farming. In the framework of a repeatedcrosssectionalmodel,however,thecharacteristicsthatareincludedmustbe restrictedtothosethatareunaffectedbytheWtMprograms.Wemustbecarefulwith land holdings, for example, as the WtM program could conceivably induce some farmerstocultivatemoreland,andcontrollingforitwouldthereforeunderstatethefull programimpact. Themodelinequation(1)isdesignedtoanswerthegeneralresearchquestion,“How havevillagesintreatmentgroupchangedfromthebaselineyeartothefollowupyear, relativetovillagesinthecontrolgroup?”Thiscoremodelcanbetweakedinavariety ofwaystoexplorealternativespecifications.Asimpleexamplewouldbetoallowthe 1Asdescribedpreviously,therewillbesubstantialoverlapinthehouseholdsamplesfromthebaseline yearandsubsequentyears,butthesampleswilllikelynotbeidentical.If,however,thesurveyin subsequentyearsusesthesamesample,wewillbeabletoemploypanel(longitudinal)datamodels.The intuitiveinterpretationofpaneldatamodelsissimilartomodelsofrepeatedcrosssectionaldata,butthe estimationtechniquesdiffersomewhatfromthosedescribedhere.

time trends to vary across regions. The specification also (implicitly) weights all respondentsequally,whichcouldbemodifiedtoeithergiveallvillagesequalweight, orweightsequaltothevillagepopulations. Suchexplorationswouldnotchangethegeneralinterpretationoftheimpactestimate, buttheycanprovideinsightsontwoimportantissues.First,andofmostdirectinterest, wecanexplorehowrobusttheimpactestimatesaretothesealternativespecifications. Beyondthis,however,theotherregressioncovariatesmaybeofindependentinterest, andmayalsoprovidecontextforinterpretingtheimpactestimates. Pooled Model. Insteadofusingdatafromonlythebaseyearandonefollowupyear, wecanalsopooldatafrommultiplewavesoffollowupyearsurveys.Theeconometric specificationwouldbeverysimilarto(1),butwithaseparateimpactestimateforeach ofthe n followupyears:

(2) yivt=βλ′ xTFTF iv +×+1122 v t λ v ×++ t... λ n TFFF v ×+ nt θθ 1122 t + t ++ ... θηε n F nt ++ v ivt , where Fnt =1if t=n and0otherwise. These impact estimates can then be compared to one another to see how program impacts changed over time, and could be particularly important to see whether any impacts on farming practices that are observed early on persist, and also whether impactsonlongertermoutcomes,suchasagriculturalproductivity,growafterfarmers havehadmoretimetoimplementnewtechniquesandbenefitfromtheirinnovations. Clustering. The estimation techniques must take into account the correlation of outcomes for households in the same village, as they may be exposed to similar idiosyncraticinfluencesthatarenototherwisecaptured in the regression model, and therefore,theindividualhouseholdscannotbeconsideredstatisticallyindependent.As anexample,aparticularvillagemighthaveabnormallygoodorbadweather,orcould experience other economic “shocks” that are unrelated to the training program but nonetheless affect the entire village. The econometric models will account for this clusteringwithmethodsthatallowflexibilityinthe correlationstructure of theerror terms.(Deaton,1997).

Impact on Participants Only. RandomlyassigningcommunitiestobeeligibleforWtM trainingprogramsprovidesanunbiasedestimateoftheimpactofofferingthistraining inthevillagesselectedfortrainingthe“intenttotreat”(ITT)effect.TheITTeffect combines the effect of the intervention on both participants and nonparticipants in treatmentvillages.Inmanycontexts,peoplewhoareofferedprogramservicesbutopt out of participating are unaffected by the program, while in other situations the programmaynonethelesshavewithinvillagespillovereffectsontheoutcomesofnon participants. By including questions about both participation in WtM training and adoptionofWtMtechniques,wewillbeabletodetermine whether there are sizable withinvillagespillovereffectspresent,andhowbesttoaccountforthem. Whenspillovereffectsareknowntobeminimal,asimplebutpowerfuladjustmentcan bemadetocalculatetheeffectofthetrainingprogramonparticipantstheeffectof “treatmentonthetreated”(TOT).ThisadjustmentknowncolloquiallyastheBloom adjustmentcalculatestheeffectofthetrainingprogramonparticipantsbydividingthe estimatedimpact(theITT)bytheparticipationrate.Theintuitionforthiselegantresult is that, if the effect of the program on nonparticipants is known to be zero, the estimatedimpactcanbeattributedentirelytotheproportionofthetreatmentgroupthat actuallyparticipatedintraining.Importantly,however,whiletheBloomadjustmentcan potentiallybeusedtoaccountfornonparticipation in the impact estimate, it cannot alleviate the problem nonparticipation introduces for the variance of the impact estimate.Ifparticipationratesarelow,wewillnotbeabletodetectimpactsthatare statisticallyreliable.(Bloom,1984;Angrist,ImbensandRubin,1996) Subgroup Analysis. For many of the outcome measures, it is conceivable that the effects of the interventions will vary by observable characteristics. Estimating differentialimpactsonfemaleheadedhouseholds,forexample,isofparticularinterest toMCC.Wewillexaminewhethertheinterventions’effectsdifferforkeysubgroups defined by the characteristics of the households such as gender, age, and level of education of the household head; size of the household; or size of farm holdings operated by the household. Similarly, we will also examine how effects vary by subgroupsdefinedbyvillagecharacteristics. Itisstraightforwardtoembedsubgroupestimatesintotheframeworkofequation(1). Todoso,weincludeaninteractiontermthatdistinguishestreatmentgroupmembersin subgroup Sfromthosewhoarenotinthesubgroup:

(3) yivt=βλ′ x iv + S=1 TFS v ××=+ t( iv 1) λ S = 0 TFS v ××=+++ t ( iv 0) θηε F t v ivt Inequation(3),theestimateof λS=1 represents theestimated impactfor members of subgroup S,andwecantestwhethertheimpactsdifferformembersofthatsubgroup comparedtoeveryoneelsebystatisticallytestingwhether λS=1 and λS=0 areequal. Distributional Effects. The implicitfocus of theanalysis plan outlined above is on examiningdifferencesonthemeanhousehold.Inconducting theanalysis, itis also importanttoexaminewhethertheinterventions’effectsvaryatdifferentlevelsofthe outcome distribution. For example, the impact on agricultural real income for households with very low or very high income may differ from the impact on householdsatthemean.Specifically,thetrainingprogramsmaybesuchthatonlythe higherincome households will benefit, if, for example, implementing the techniques taught in training requires investment in equipment that lowerincome households cannot afford. Conversely, the poor in the community might benefit more than the wealthyifthetrainingfocusesprimarilyontechniquesthatareusefulonlytosmaller scalefarms. As Armenia has among the highest levels of income inequality in Europe, this distinction is nota trivialone.Wewill use quantile regression analysisto determine whether the intervention effects vary at different points in the distribution. Quantile regressionsareanalyticallyappealingbecause,similartostandardregressionanalysis, the quantile regression coefficients have direct and simple interpretation, thereby makingitveryappropriateforcommunicatingimpactestimateswithpolicymakers. Estimatingimpactsforspecifiedquantilesstartswiththesameregressionmodelasa standardmodel.Thedifferenceisinthemethodology for estimating the parameters, which in turn, affects the interpretation of those impact estimates. While a standard

regression model compares the impact for mean households, a quantile regression insteadcomparestheimpactoftheinterventionsforaspecifiedpercentile,suchasthe 25thorthe75thpercentile.Quantileregressionsatthe50thpercentile,themedian,are alsomorerobusttotheinfluenceofextremeoutliersinthedata,andthuscanserveto validatethefindingsfromstandardregressionanalysis.(KoenkerandHallock,2001; Deaton,1997). IX. NEXT STEPS Theanalysesdescribedabovewillbeemployedinaseriesofreports.Thefirstreport willcoverthebaselineFPS,andwillbeashortreportfocusingonthecurrentstateof the villages in the evaluation. The second report willcoverthe second roundof the FPS, after the training programs have begun at least one round of training in most villages. This report will focus on the intermediate outcomes, to gauge participation ratesandpreliminaryadoptionratesforthenewtechnology and practices. The final reportwillfollowthefourthyearoftheCompact,thelastyearbeforethecontrolgroup villageswillbecomeeligibleforWtMtraining.Thisreportwillfocusonthelonger termoutcomes,butasdiscussed,itwillalsoexamineintermediateoutcomessuchthat we can assess not only whether there have been tangible impacts on poverty and householdincome,butalsowhetherthereisevidencefromtheintermediateoutcomes thatthefulleconomicimpactoftheWtMmaynothavebeenfullymanifestedyet. The results from these studies will directly inform MCC and other international agencies on the efficacy of this approach for training in agricultural practices, and whetheritisaneffectivepathwayforreducingpovertyinruralArmenia.Moreover,the lessonslearnedinthiscontextcanbeappliedtoothercountrieswithsimilareconomic climatesandwillhelpshapefutureMCCCompactswithothercountries.

REFERENCES Angrist, J., G. Imbens, and D. Rubin (1996), Identification of Causal Effects Using Instrumental Variables, Journal of the American Statistical Association, vol. 91, no. 434 Bloom, H. (1984), Accounting for NoShows in Experimental Evaluation Designs, EvaluationReview , vol.8 Deaton,A.(1997), TheAnalysisofHouseholdSurveys:AMicroeconomicApproachto DevelopmentPolicy, JohnsHopkinsUniversityPress:Baltimore,MD Duflo,E.andM.Kremer(2004), UseofRandomizationintheEvaluationof DevelopmentEffectiveness ,inO.Feinstein,G.Ingram,andG.Pitman(ed.) Evaluating DevelopmentEffectiveness,TransactionPublishers:NewBrunswick,NJ Kling,J.(2007), MethodologicalFrontiersofPublicFinanceFieldExperiments , NationalTaxJournal,vol.60 Koenker,R.andK.Hallock(2001), QuantileRegression ,JournalofEconomic Perspectives,vol.15,no.4 Michalopoulos,C.(2005), PrecedentsandProspectsforRandomizedExperiments,in Bloom, H.(ed.), LearningMorefromSocialExperiments,RussellSageFoundation: NewYork,NY NationalStatisticalServiceoftheRepublicofArmenia(MultipleYears). Armeniain Figures series,availableatwww.armstat.am

ՀՀՀոդվածներիամփոփագրերՀոդվածներիամփոփագրերոդվածներիամփոփագրեր Հայկական դրամի արժևորման ազդեցությունը տեղեկատվական տեխնոլոգիաներիտեխնոլոգիաների,,,,զբոսաշրջության և սննդամթերքի վերամշակման ձեռնարկություններիմրցունակությանվրաձեռնարկություններիմրցունակությանվրա Մհեր Բաղրամյան, Հայկական միջազգային տնտեսական հետազոտությունների խումբ Վահրամ Ղուշչյան, Հայկական միջազգային տնտեսական հետազոտությունների խումբ* Հայկական դրամը 20032006 թթ. արժևորվել է ավելի քան 40 տոկոսով: Լայնորեն տարածված տեսակետի համաձայն՝ անվանական փոխարժեքի այս կտրուկ փոփոխությունըբացասականազդեցությունէունեցելտեղականարտադրողներիև հատկապես արտահանողների վրա: Հետազոտությունում օգտագործվել են 58 հայկական ընկերությունների ընտրանքային հետազոտության արդյունքները` պարզելու, թե արժևորումը ինչ ազդեցություն է ունեցել Հայաստանում զբոսաշրջության, տեղեկատվական տեխնոլոգիաների և սննդամթերքի վերամշակման ձեռնարկությունների մրցունակության վրա: 20032006թթին ընկերությունների տեխնիկական արդյունավետության գործակիցները և դրանց փոփոխությունը գնահատելու համար օգտագործել ենք ստոխաստիկ սահմանային մոդելավորման մեթոդը: Արժույթի արժևորման հնարավոր ազդեցությունը ընկերությունների եկամուտների և արտահանման ծավալների վրա պարզելու նպատակով տեխնիկական արդյունավետության գործակիցները օգտագործվել են ռեգրեսիայիհավասարումըգնահատելուհամար: Հետազոտությամբ պարզվել է, որ փոխարժեքի փոփոխությունը հետևողական և վիճակագրորեն նշանակալի ազդեցություն է ունեցել ընկերությունների տեխնիկական արդյունավետության վրա: Պարզվել է նաև, որ փորձի կուտակումը տեխնիկական արդյունավետությունը պայմանավորող էական գործոն է հանդիսացել: Հետազոտությունում ուսումնասիրվել են փոխարժեքի և ընկերությունների տեխնիկական արդյունավետության, արտահանման ու եկամտաբերության միջև փոխկապակցությունները: Հետազոտությամբ պարզվել է, որ անվանական փոխարժեքիմեկկետովարժևորման դեպքումտեղեկատվականտեխնոլոգիաների ոլորտիձեռնարկություններիարտահանումըկրճատվումէտարեկանմիջինը66հզ. դրամով (կամ շուրջ 200 ԱՄՆ դոլարով), սննդամթերքի վերամշակման ձեռնարկություններինը` 12 հզ. դրամով (կամ շուրջ 40 ԱՄՆ դոլարով), իսկ հյուրանոցների ու ներգնա զբոսաշրջությամբ զբաղվող ընկերությունների միջին տարեկանհասույթը՝112հզ.դրամով(կամշուրջ340 ԱՄՆդոլարով):

ՓոխարժեքիդինամիկանՀայաստանումՓոխարժեքիդինամիկանՀայաստանում Վահե Հեբոյան , Ջորջիայի Համալսարան Լեվել Գանթեր , Ջորջիայի Համալսարան Տպավորիչ տնտեսական աճին զուգընթաց՝ հայկական դրամի փոխարժեքը և՛ անվանական, և՛ իրական արտահայտությամբ զգալիորեն արժևորվել է, ինչը հասարակությանտարբերհատվածներիմոտանհանգստություններիտեղիքէտվել: Հայաստանի կենտրոնական բանկը և կառավարությունը մի կողմից, տնտեսագետները, գործարարները ու քաղաքական գործիչները մյուս կողմից տարբեր, գերազանցաբար հակադիր մեկնաբանություններ են տալիս արժևորման պատճառների վերաբերյալ: Սույն հետազոտության նպատակն է պարզել Հայաստանում փոխարժեքի դինամիկան պայմանավորող տնտեսական գործոնները: Փոխարժեքի երկարաժամկետ դինամիկան մոդելավորելու համար կիրառվել է վարքագծային հավասարակշիռ փոխարժեքի մոտեցումը: Հետազոտությանարդյունքներըցույցենտալիս,որհայկականարժույթըշեղվելէիր երկարաժամկետհավասարակշիռուղղուց:Շեղմանչափիգնահատականըզգայուն է դիտարկվող փոփոխականների համախմբի նկատմամբ: Թեպետ գնահատված մոդելներում փոփոխականները վիճակագրորեն նշանակալի են, իսկ շեղման ուղղությունըմիանմանէ,սակայնշեղմանմեծությանգնահատականներըտարբեր են: Լրացուցիչ վերլուծություն է անհրաժեշտ արդյունքների զգայունությունը փոփոխականների ընտրությունից պարզելու, ինչպես նաև, հաշվի առնելով փոփոխականների մեծամասնության նշանների տեսական ոչ միարժեքությունը, ստացվածարդյունքներիցճշգրիցեզրահանգումներկատարելուհամար: Բանկային համակարգի արդյունավետությունը , շուկայի կառուցվկառուցվածքըածքը ևևև օտարերկրյա սեփականությունը . ինչով էէէ պայմանավորված ավանդների ներգրավման ևևև վարկերի տրամադրման տոկոսադրույքների տարբերությունը ՀայաստանումՀայաստանում Էռա Դաբլա Նորրիս , Արժույթի միջազգային հիմնադրամ ՀոլգերՖլյորկեմայեր,Արժույթիմիջազգայինհիմնադրամ * Չնայած բանկային համակարգի լայնածավալ բարեփոխումներին, մակրոտնտեսական երկարատև կայունությանը և տնտեսական աճի բարձր տեմպին` ֆինանսական միջնորդության մակարդակով Հայաստանը դեռևս ետ է մնում այլ անցումային տնտեսությամբ երկրներից, իսկ ավանդային և վարկային տոկոսադրույքներիտարբերութունըավելիմեծէ,քան`ԿենտրոնականուԱրևելյան Եվրոպայի անցումային տնտեսությամբ երկրների մեծ մասում: Սույն աշխատությունը ուսումնասիրում է բանկերի բնութագրիչների, շուկայի կառուցվածքի, օտարերկրյա սեփականության և մակրոտնտեսական գործոնների դերը Հայաստանում ավանդային և վարկային տոկոսադրույքների տարբերության, ինչպես նաև զուտ տոկոսային եկամտի որոշման գործում: Հետազոտությամբ

պարզվել է, որ բանկային բնութագրիչները, մասնավորապես` բանկի չափը, իրացվելիությունը, դիրքը շուկայում, ինչպես նաև շուկայի կառուցվածքը բացատրումենավանդայինևվարկայինտոկոսադրույքներիտարբերությանևզուտ տոկոսայինեկամտիմիջբանկայինևմիջժամանակայինտատանումներիմեծմասը: Ի տարբերություն այլ անցումային տնտեսությամբ երկրների`ուղղակի կապ գոյություն չունի օտարերկրյա սեփականության ու ավանդային և վարկային տոկոսադրույքների տարբերության, ինչպես նաև զուտ տոկոսային եկամտի միջև: Սակայն, բանկերի արդյունավետության տեսանկյունից, նշանակություն ունի՝ արդյոքբանկըօտարերկրյասեփականությունէ,թե՝ոչ։ Արտադրողականությունըևձեռնարկությունների աաարդյունավետությանգործոններըՀայաստանումարդյունավետությանգործոններըՀայաստանումրդյունավետությանգործոններըՀայաստանում

Կարեն Գրիգորյան , Համաշխարհային բանկ ՎահրամՍտեփանյան,Համաշխարհայինբանկ *

Հոդվածում վերլուծվում են արտադրողականության աճի գործոնները Հայաստանում և առաջարկվում են ապագա կայուն աճի խրախուսմանը միտված միջոցառումներ: Ամփոփված են զարգացած և անցումային երկրներում ձեռնարկությունների արտադրողականության տեսական գործոնները և փաստական արդյունքները, առանձնակի ուշադրություն է դարձված այնպիսի առանցքային գործոնների, ինչպիսիք են մրցակցությունը, օտարերկրյա ուղղակի ներդրումները և ինստիտուցիոնալ միջավայրը: Հետազոտության առանցքը 2003 2005թթ–ին արդյունաբերության և ծառայության ոլորտների 300 հայկական ձեռնարկությունների ընտրանքային հետազոտության արդյունքների վերլուծություննէ`ընդհանուրգործոնայինարտադրողականությունըգնահատելու նպատակով: Հետազոտությամբ պարզվել է, որ Հայաստանում տեխնիկական արդյունավետության և նաև ընդհանուր գործոնային արտադրողականության նշանակալի աճ տեղի չի ունենում` ի հակադրություն որոշ հետազոտությունների արդյունքների: Ձեռնարկություններում տեխնիկական առաջընթացը, ըստ երևույթին, Հայաստանի տնտեսական աճի էական գործոն չի հանդիսացել: Հետազոտության արդյունքները վկայում են, որ ընդհանուր գործոնային արտադրողականությունը արդյունաբերության և ծառայության ոլորտների ճյուղերում էապես չի տարբերվում: Գրեթե որևէ տարբերություն չի բացահայտվել նաև արտահանող և արտահանում չիրականացնող ձեռնարկությունների ընդհանուր գործոնային արտադրողականությունում, ինչը վկայում է, որ արտահանման շուկաներում մրցակցային ճնշումը չի նպաստել հայկական ձեռնարկությունների արտադրողականության աճին: Վերջինը ցույց է տալիս, որ նոր տեխնոլոգիաների և գիտելիքի տարածմանը ու աշխատուժի հմտությունների բարելավմանը միտված քաղաքականության հրատապ անհրաժեշտություն կա:

Ընդհանուր գործոնային արտադրողականության միջին գնահատված արժեքները գործնականում նույնն են նաև տեղական և օտարերկրյա սեփականությամբ ընկերություններում,ինչըցույցէտալիս,որինստիտուցիոնալմիջավայրումառկա են լուրջ թերություններ, որոնք արգելակում են օտարերկրյա սեփականությամբ ձեռնարկություններից տեխնոլոգիաների և գիտելիքի փոխանցումը տեղական ձեռնարկություններին: Անորոշ է նաև մրցակցության դրական ազդեցությունը ընդհանուր գործոնային արտադրողականության վրա, քանի որ Հայաստանում մրցակցային ճնշումները դեռևս բավականաչափ ուժեղ չեն` կառավարչական որոշումներիվրաազդելուհամար: Հայաստանում մակրոտնտեսական նշանակալի առաջընթացը թերևս պայմանավորված է անցման սկզբնական փուլում իրականացված հաջող բարեփոխումներով , հատկապես ` գների ևարտաքին առևտրի ազատականաց ٳٵ և մասնավորեց ٳٵ : Սակայն « եկել է երկրորդ սերնդի բարեփոխումների ժամանակը ` ինստիտուցիոնալ և մրցակցային միջավայրը բարելավելու և օտարերկրյա ուղղակի ներդրումները խթանելու համար : ՀայաստանիՀայաստան իիիմմասնավորհատվածիմրցունակությունըմմասնավորհատվածիմրցունակությունը.ասնավորհատվածիմրցունակությունը .անցումհաջորդփուլ.. անցումհաջորդփուլանցումհաջորդփուլ ՄանուկՀերգնյան,“Տնտեսությունևարժեքներ”հետազոտականկենտրոն ԳագիկԳաբրիելյան,“Տնտեսությունևարժեքներ”հետազոտականկենտրոն ԱննաՄակարյան,“Տնտեսությունևարժեքներ”հետազոտականկենտրոն Հոդվածում ուսումնասիրվում են Հայաստանի տնտեսական ձեռքբերումները և վերլուծվումէՀայաստանիմրցունակությունը`այնպայմանավորողգործոններիու պատճառահետևանքային կապերի հետազոտության միջոցով: Հայաստանի տնտեսական նկարագիրը և մրցունակության միկրոտնտեսական հիմքերը համադրվում են նման կամ մրցակից երկրների հետ: Հոդվածում ներկայացված են առաջարկություններ` Հայաստանի հետագա զարգացման և ազգային մրցունակության բարելավման վերաբերյալ։ Առաջարկությունները առնչվում են ապագա քաղաքականությունների համատեքստին, նախապատվությունների սահմանման ու կարճաժամկետ և երկարաժամկետ զարգացման ռազմավարությունների մշակման մեխանիզմներին, տարածաշրջանում և գլոբալ տնտեսությունումՀայաստանիդիրքավորմանմոտեցումներին:

Հայաստանի Հազարամյակի մարտահրավեր հիմնադրամհիմնադրամ. ...գյուղական բնակավայրերում տնտեսական աճի և աղքատության կրճատման ազդեցությանգնահատազդեցությանգնահատումումումում ԿեննեթՖորստոն,«Մաթեմատիկա–քաղաքականությանհետազոտում» ընկերություն ԷսթերՀակոբյան,Հազարամյակիմարտահրավերհիմնադրամ–Հայաստան ԱնահիտՊետրոսյան,Հազարամյակիմարտահրավերհիմնադրամ–Հայաստան ԱնուՌանգարաջան,«Մաթեմատիկա–քաղաքականությանհետազոտում» ընկերություն ՌեբեկաԹանսթալլ,Հազարամյակիմարտահրավերներկորպորացիա*

Հազարամյակի մարտահրավերներ կորպորացիայի 236մլն. ԱՄՆ դոլար արժողությամբ ծրագիրը Հայաստանում նպատակ ունի կրճատել աղքատությունը գյուղական բնակավայրերում` ոռոգման ենթակառուցվածքում ներդրումների, գյուղական ճանապարհների վերանորոգման և ֆերմերների վերապատրաստման միջոցով: Հոդվածում քննարկվում է ֆերմերների վերապատրաստման ծրագրի ազդեցության գնահատումը` ջրի կառավարման և բարձրարժեք մշակաբույսերի մշակման բնագավառում: Գնահատման համար կիրառվում է պատահական ընտրության սկզբունքը, որի համաձայն գյուղական համայնքները պատահականորենընտրվումենորպեսազդեցությանխումբ,որոնցառաջարկվում էհամապատասխանվերապատրաստում,կամորպեսստուգիչխումբ,որոնցնման վերապատրաստումչի առաջարկվում:Այնուհետևհամեմատվում ենազդեցության և ստուգիչ խմբերում ֆերմերների ցուցաբերած արդյունքները: Գնահատման արդյունքներըկօգտագործվենվերապատրաստմանծրագրիարդյունավետությունը, իր հիմնական նպատակների տեսանկյունից, գնահատելու համար: Այդ նպատակներից են արդյունավետ գյուղատնտեսական արտադրության ներդնումը, բարձրարժեքմշակաբույսերիցանքատարածություններիընդլայնումը,ֆերմերային տնտեսությունների արտադրողականության և եկամուտների բարձրացումը, աղքատությանկրճատումը:Ստացվածարդյունքներըկարողենօգտագործվելնաև նման տնտեսական միջավայր ունեցող այլ երկրներում, այնպես, որ ներդրումները արդյունավետորեն տեղաբաշխվեն այն ոլորտներում, որոնց տնտեսական ազդեցությունըհայտնիէ: