Experimental Law and Economics.Pdf

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Experimental Law and Economics.Pdf I. INTRODUCTION This paper reviews a new research technique in law and economics-- experimental law and economics. Although some economists have used laboratory techniques to study and develop economic theory for more than 20 years, researchers have only recently started to use these techniques specifically in law and economics. In this paper we review the literature in economics relevant to law and economics and then show how the technique makes it possible to both test theories and examine the effects of alterna• tive legal policies without costly social experiments. Finally, we discuss the few experimental studies dealing directly with propositions in law and economics and suggest some appropriate directions for future research. II. INTRODUCTION TO EXPERIMENTAL ECONOMICS A. A Brief Introduction to Experimental Technique In the sections which follow we will review in some detail the tech• niques and results of a substantial amount of experimental work. However, to prepare the reader who is completely unacquainted with experimental procedure to understand the discussion below, we will first very briefly sketch the techniques and methodological motivations for using experiments. First, what are "experimental techniques"? An experiment in economics almost always includes at least four important features. First, the ex• perimenters observe the behavior of human subjects--often college students- -who are following a set of instructions. The instructions ask the subjects to make certain decisions and promise to pay them money at the conclusion of the experiment. The amount of money each subject ia paid depends on the decisions he makes. Second, the instructions place the subjects in an abstract version of some naturally-occurring economic environment, in which they are required to play the roles of specific economic agents, such as consumers or firms. These instructions also provide the social institutions within which the subjects may interact. An experiment must abstract from the naturally- occurring environment because the "real world" subjects of economic in• quiry, such as stock exchanges or disputes between landowners, are often tremendously detailed and complex. To analyze these complex subjects, 1 economists build theories which abstract from many of these details. Laboratory experiments abstract in an entirely analogous fashion. Third, the payoffs to subjects are structured so as to induce preferences in any subject who prefers earning more money to earning less money. For example, if an experimenter wishes to study a "seller's" be• havior, the instructions might inform a subject that he may purchase a "commodity" at a fixed price from the experimenter ('p'), that he can sell the commodity to another subject at any price he can persuade the other subject to agree to ('a'), and that the experimenter will pay the subject In exchange for the loss of detail in the theories, economists (hope to) gain theoretical tools which, can, in many circumstances, predict behavior. Such economic theories commonly presume that an "environment" contains utility-maximizing consumers who have various amounts of wealth and differing preferences, and profit-maximizing firms, each with its own ability to turn raw materials into valued goods and serv• ices. There are abstract versions of social institutions, such as the law of tort end contract, which enable these consumers and firms to interact. This interaction produces goods and services, which are distributed to the consumers. 3. the difference between sale and purchase price (s-p). Under these cir• cumstances, any subject who prefers to take home as much money as he can will also prefer to make his sale at as high a price as he can. In this way, the experimenter can induce subjects to try to "sell high, buy low," just as real sellers and buyers try to do. Fourth, the experimenter observes both the subjects' decisions and the associated cash payouts to subjects. Then, he uses the data to infer some• thing either about an economic theory, or about the real world subject of 2 that economic theory. What does one need to assume in order to make laboratory experiments a valid source of data about naturally-occurring environments? The literature 3 on the philosophy behind the use of experiaental techniques in economics has focused on three crucial assumptions. First, one must assume that subjects will prefer more money (in payoffs) to less money. In this way, the use of reel money payoffs can be used to induce preferences in the 4 subjects in a predictable fashion. Second, one must assume that the same general rules of human behavior apply in both the laboratory and the 2 This last step is discussed in much greater detail, below. 3 Charles R. Plott, Industrial Organization Theory and Experimental Economics, 20 J. Econ. Lit. 1465 (1982) Vernon L. Smith, Experimental Economics: Induced Value Theory, 66 Am. Ec. Rev. 274 (1976) and Microeconomic Systems as an Experimental Science, 72 Am. Ec. Rev. 923 (1982); Louis L. Wilde, On the Use of Laboratory Experiments in Economics, in J.C. Pitt (ed.) Philosophy in Economics 137 (1981). 4 Smith (1976), Id. Actually, subjects must prefer more money to less money in just the same way that people prefer more to less in real life--not always, but to an overwhelming degree and in certain regular, predictable ways. This is enough to make experimental data useful. 5. just as people occasionally do in the natural world. The second and third assumptions are far aore difficult to test. Although, with sufficient comparative naturally-occurring data it may be possible to test for paral- 9 lelism. However, because these assumptions are often difficult and costly to test, scholars in the field tend to rely upon peer consensus in evaluat• ing experimental design. This "consensus" evolves out of the standard academic institutions for quality control -- workshops on the papers before critical audiences, and referred journal acceptances (in all but legal, publications). What are the basic allocations for using experimental techniques? We can cluster the uses into five groups. First, experiments can provide the 10 cleanest possible tests of fundamental theories in economics. Economic theories often specify little institutional detail, and can be mimicked ('modeled') quite easily in the laboratory. By inducing in subjects preferences that conform precisely to a model's specification, and by excluding all of the 'noise' of the natural world which the model does not include, the experimentalist can produce an environment in which a theory has, on its own terms, the very best chance to predict behavioral outcomes. If the theory fails under these circumstances, there is little reason compared to both predictions to see which model predicts the results bet- ter. Fourth, experiments may stimulate the creation of new theory. This can occur when en experiment produces results that no existing theory can explain. Under such circumstances, theorists may be lead to create new theories which explain the data, and which also have a great deal to say 14 about naturally-occurring situations. And fifth, laboratory experiments are relatively inexpensive, compared to some ways of testing competing theories or policies in naturally- occurring environments. If the naturally-occurring data have already been collected end summarized, then econometric work on those data is likely to be less expensive than experiments. However, if a new data series would have to be collected, or if a completely new policy for which naturally- occurring data do not yet exist is being considered, then experiments are likely to be far cheaper. Collecting a lengthy data series can be quite expensive. To collect any data on a previously untried policy would require tinkering with important natural institutions as part of a potentially costly social experiment. New alternatives can be considered much more See, e.g., Arlington W. Williaas, The Formation of Market Forecasts: Experimental Evidence, Xerox (1984), for an illustration of this tech• nique. On pp. 22-26, we discuss another set of studies which illustrates this technique. See, e.g. David Easley and John Ledyard, A Theory of Price Formation and Exchange in Oral Auctions, Northwestern University Hath Center Working Paper #461 (1983) and Daniel Frledman, Price Formation in Double Auction Markets, An. Econ. Rev. (forthcoming) for an illustra• tion of the use of experimental results in theory development. On pp. 40-41, we discuss another set of studies which illustrates this technique. a. efficiently in the controlled laboratory setting, without disrupting 15 natural institutions. B. Competitive Markets: An Example of the Use of Experimental Economics 16 In a series of papers in the 1960's, Vernon Smith defined the basic methodology of experimental economics, as outlined above, and illustrated the utility of experimental techniques to studying basic economic ques- 17 tions. In this section we will review not only the early Smith market experiments, but also the more recent work which was inspired by Smith's efforts. This review should provide some specific examples of the concepts 13 See e.g. James T. Hong and Charles R. Plott, Rate Filing Policies for Inland Water Transportation: An Experimental Approach, 13 Bell Journal of Economics 1 (1962) for an illustration of the use of experiments for policy comparison. This study is discussed on pp. 31-32, Infra. A word of caution would be mentioned at this point. Experimental techniques are quite useful for screening out unhelpful theories from the set of all theories which policy analysts must consider, and can do so at low cost. However, these techniques will not screen out all unhelpful theories, and may actually fail to weed out many such poor theories. What experiments do well is to cheaply raise the proportion of helpful theories among those which must be considered further. 16 Vernon L. Smith, An Experimental Study of Competitive Market Behavior, 60 J. Pol. Econ. 111 (1962); Experimental Auction Markets end the Walrasian Hypothesis, 73 J.
Recommended publications
  • ECLAC WORKSHOP NEW TOOLS and METHODS for POLICY-MAKING 19 May 2014, Paris
    OECD - ECLAC WORKSHOP NEW TOOLS AND METHODS FOR POLICY-MAKING 19 May 2014, Paris 21 March 2014 Dear Madam/Sir, We are pleased to invite you to the Workshop on New Tools and Methods for Policy-making, co- organised by the United Nations Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (ECLAC) and the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). The workshop will take place at the OECD headquarters in Paris on Monday 19 May 2014. The workshop represents a unique opportunity for policy-makers, academics, researchers in economics and representatives of international organisations to meet. Discussions will focus especially on how recent advances in methods and tools in economics could contribute to devise more effective policies to foster growth, employment and improved income distribution. Leading economists will present their views on these advances in the four following fields: • complexity and network theory; • agent-based modelling; • behavioural and experimental economics; and • big data. These approaches hold promise to redefine the toolkit which experts, academics and policy-makers could use for their analyses in the coming years. The preliminary programme of the workshop is attached. We kindly invite you to register on our dedicated website at http://www.oecd.org/naec/workshop.htm by 25 April 2014. Should you require additional information, please do not hesitate to contact Mr. Romain Zivy at ECLAC and Ms. Elena Miteva at the OECD via the meeting website. We look forward to welcoming you at this workshop. Yours sincerely, Alicia Barcena Angel Gurría Executive Secretary Secretary General ECLAC, United Nations OECD ECLAC, Av.
    [Show full text]
  • Field Experiments in Development Economics1 Esther Duflo Massachusetts Institute of Technology
    Field Experiments in Development Economics1 Esther Duflo Massachusetts Institute of Technology (Department of Economics and Abdul Latif Jameel Poverty Action Lab) BREAD, CEPR, NBER January 2006 Prepared for the World Congress of the Econometric Society Abstract There is a long tradition in development economics of collecting original data to test specific hypotheses. Over the last 10 years, this tradition has merged with an expertise in setting up randomized field experiments, resulting in an increasingly large number of studies where an original experiment has been set up to test economic theories and hypotheses. This paper extracts some substantive and methodological lessons from such studies in three domains: incentives, social learning, and time-inconsistent preferences. The paper argues that we need both to continue testing existing theories and to start thinking of how the theories may be adapted to make sense of the field experiment results, many of which are starting to challenge them. This new framework could then guide a new round of experiments. 1 I would like to thank Richard Blundell, Joshua Angrist, Orazio Attanasio, Abhijit Banerjee, Tim Besley, Michael Kremer, Sendhil Mullainathan and Rohini Pande for comments on this paper and/or having been instrumental in shaping my views on these issues. I thank Neel Mukherjee and Kudzai Takavarasha for carefully reading and editing a previous draft. 1 There is a long tradition in development economics of collecting original data in order to test a specific economic hypothesis or to study a particular setting or institution. This is perhaps due to a conjunction of the lack of readily available high-quality, large-scale data sets commonly available in industrialized countries and the low cost of data collection in developing countries, though development economists also like to think that it has something to do with the mindset of many of them.
    [Show full text]
  • Behavioral & Experimental Macroeconomics and Policy Analysis
    Working Paper Series Cars Hommes Behavioral & experimental macroeconomics and policy analysis: a complex systems approach No 2201 / November 2018 Disclaimer: This paper should not be reported as representing the views of the European Central Bank (ECB). The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the ECB. Abstract This survey discusses behavioral and experimental macroeconomics emphasiz- ing a complex systems perspective. The economy consists of boundedly rational heterogeneous agents who do not fully understand their complex environment and use simple decision heuristics. Central to our survey is the question under which conditions a complex macro-system of interacting agents may or may not coordinate on the rational equilibrium outcome. A general finding is that under positive expectations feedback (strategic complementarity) {where optimistic (pessimistic) expectations can cause a boom (bust){ coordination failures are quite common. The economy is then rather unstable and persistent aggre- gate fluctuations arise strongly amplified by coordination on trend-following behavior leading to (almost-)self-fulfilling equilibria. Heterogeneous expecta- tions and heuristics switching models match this observed micro and macro behaviour surprisingly well. We also discuss policy implications of this coordi- nation failure on the perfectly rational aggregate outcome and how policy can help to manage the self-organization process of a complex economic system. JEL Classification: D84, D83, E32, C92 Keywords: Expectations feedback, learning, coordination failure, almost self- fulfilling equilibria, simple heuristics, experimental & behavioral macro-economics. ECB Working Paper Series No 2201 / November 2018 1 Non-technical summary Most policy analysis is still based on rational expectations models, often with a per- fectly rational representative agent.
    [Show full text]
  • Experimental Methods: Measuring Effort in Economics Experiments
    Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 149 (2018) 74–87 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jebo Experimental methods: Measuring effort in economics experiments ∗ Gary Charness a, , Uri Gneezy b,c, Austin Henderson b a Department of Economics, University of California, Santa Barbara, United States b Rady School of Management, University of California, San Diego, United States c CREED, University of Amsterdam, United States a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t Article history: The study of effort provision in a controlled setting is a key research area in experimental Received 4 November 2017 economics. There are two major methodological paradigms in this literature: stated effort Revised 24 February 2018 and real effort. In the stated-effort paradigm the researcher uses an “effort function” that Accepted 26 February 2018 maps choices to outcomes. In the real-effort paradigm, participants work on a task, and outcomes depend on their performance. The advantage of the stated-effort design is the JEL codes: control the researcher has over the cost of effort, which is particularly useful when testing B49 theory. The advantage of the real-effort design is that it may be a better match to the C90 field environment, particularly with respect to psychological aspects that affect behavior. C91 An open question in the literature is the degree to which the results obtained by the two C92 paradigms differ, and if they do, why. We present a review of methods used and discuss the results obtained from using these different approaches, and issues to consider when Keywords: Stated effort choosing and implementing a task.
    [Show full text]
  • Economics Working Paper Series Teaching Microeconomic Principles
    Economics Working Paper Series Teaching Microeconomic principles with smartphones -lessons from classroom experiments with classEx Marcus Gianmattei Humberto Llavador October 2017 Barcelona GSE Working Paper Series Working Paper nº 996 Teaching Microeconomic Principles with Smartphones – Lessons from classroom experiments with classEx* Marcus Giamattei†‡§ and Humberto Llavador**†† October 2017 Abstract Classroom experiments as a teaching tool increase understanding and especially motivation. Traditionally, experiments have been run using pen-and-paper or in a computer lab. Pen-and-paper is time and resource consuming. Experiments in the lab require appropriate installations and impede the direct interaction among students. During the last two years, we have created fully elaborated packages to run a complete course in microeconomics principles using face-to-face experiments with mobile devices. The experiments are based on Bergstrom-Miller (2000), and we used classEx, a free online tool, to run them in the classroom. The packages were used at Universitat Pompeu Fabra with over 500 undergraduate students in the fall 2016. This paper presents our experience on classEx and the Bergstrom-Miller approach working in combination, and the lessons learned. Keywords: experiential learning; microeconomics; mobile devices; classroom experiments; classEx JEL-Classification: A22, C72, C90, D00 * We are grateful to Ted Bergstrom, Johann Graf Lambsdorff, John Millner and Rosemarie Nagel for all their support and extremely helpful suggestions. We thank Katharina Werner and Susanna Grundmann for their feedback. We also want to thank the many instructors who have participated over the years in testing and discussing the experiments and the classEx packages at Pompeu Fabra University and at the University of Alicante.
    [Show full text]
  • Experimental Economics and the Law *
    EXPERIMENTAL ECONOMICS AND THE LAW * Sean P. Sullivan† Federal Trade Commission Charles A. Holt‡ University of Virginia June 8, 2014 is chapter surveys the past and future role of experimental economics in legal research and practice. Following a brief explanation of the theory and methodology of experimental economics, the chapter discusses topics in each of three broad application areas: (1) the use of experiments for studying legal institutions such as settlement bargaining and adjudica- tive functions, (2) the use of experiments to explore legal doctrines, and (3) the use of experiments in litigation and trial strategy. e general theme of this material is a broad and versatile relationship between law and experimental economics. * Pre-print version of Sean P. Sullivan & Charles A. Holt, Experimental Economics and the Law, in 1 OXFORD HANDBOOK OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 78 (Francesco Parisi ed., Oxford University Press 2017). † Federal Trade Commission. is chapter reflects the prsonal views of the author and does not necessarily represent the views of the United States Government or Federal Trade Commission, which have neither approved nor disapproved its con- tent. Contact Sean Sullivan at [email protected]. ‡ A. Willis Robertson Professor of Political Economy, Department of Economics, University of Virginia. Contact Charles Holt at [email protected]. Table of Contents 1 INTRODUCTION ......................................................................................... 1 2 THE METHODOLOGY OF EXPERIMENTAL ECONOMICS .............
    [Show full text]
  • Monetary Theory in the Laboratory
    S EPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1998 John Duffy is an assistant professor of economics at the University of Pittsburgh and a visiting scholar at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. The author thanks Jack Ochs, Michael Pakko, and Joseph Ritter for helpful comments, Nick Meggos for research assistance, and Denise Hazlett and Shyam Sunder for permission to reproduce figures from their papers. that the scale of macroeconomic phenomena Monetary is perceived to be too great to be tested in controlled laboratory experiments with small Theory in groups of subjects. That would almost cer- tainly be the view, for example, among the Laboratory applied macroeconomists working with field data. Today, however, most macroeco- John Duffy nomic theorists work with models that build on explicit microfoundations for the behavior of individuals. These models often INTRODUCTION impose artificial restrictions on individuals’ behavior that are not embodied in any avail- uring the past few decades, an able field data. Consequently, it often is not increasing number of economists possible to empirically test the aggregate Dhave begun conducting controlled predictions that emerge from these models. laboratory experiments with paid human Even in those cases where the aggregate subjects in an effort to test theories of eco- predictions of microfoundation models can nomic behavior. Economists have turned be tested using field data, it is not always to laboratory experiments because in many possible to use field data to verify whether instances they lack the appropriate nonex- behavior at the individual level adheres to perimental field data that are required to the predictions or assumptions of these models.
    [Show full text]
  • Econometrics for Experimental Economics
    The Empirical Econometrics and Quantitative Economics Letters ISSN 2286 – 7147 © EEQEL all rights reserved Volume 2, Number 3 (September 2013), pp. 37 - 40. Econometrics for experimental economics Komsan Suriya Faculty of Economics, Chiang Mai University E-mail: [email protected] ABSTRACT In tradition, experimental economics uses non-parametric statistics to compare means between groups of attendants who attend experiments with different settings to investigate the effect of anticipated mechanism or policy. This statistical analysis limits itself to the effectiveness of the interventions without explanation why attendants response to the mechanism or policy in such the ways. Econometrics especially the panel data analysis can extend the analysis by adding explanatory variables into models with the panel data set constructed from the experiments in order to explain why the attendants behave as being observed. This paper introduces the idea and guideline how to use panel data analysis in experimental economics. Keywords: Experimental economics, non-parametric statistics, panel data analysis JEL Classification: C51, C23, C70 1. Experimental economics Experimental economics is an alternative way to collect data for economic research. Apart of survey and time series, an experiment aims to get a data set on issues that are difficult or impossible to find in reality (Royal Swedish Academy of Science, 2002; Chaudhuri, 2009; Chakarvaty et al, 2011). For example, people don’t act or show cheating behavior, selfishness or strategic moves in a common field survey. These behaviors do not appear in time series data too. The only way to collect these data is to observe through experiments conducted in laboratories that guarantee total privacy to attendants.
    [Show full text]
  • Experimental Economics: Past and Future
    Experimental Economics: Past and Future Guillaume R. Fréchette,* Kim Sarnoff,† Leeat Yariv‡ August 2021 Abstract Over the past several decades, lab experiments have offered economists a rich source of evidence on incentivized behavior. In this article, we use detailed data on experimental papers to describe recent trends in the literature. We also discuss various experimentation platforms and new approaches to the design and analysis of the data they generate. Keywords: Experimental Economics, Time Trends, Experimental Platforms, MTurk, Replication *Department of Economics, New York University. †Department of Economics, Princeton University. ‡Department of Economics, Princeton University, CEPR, and NBER. 1 1 Introduction Experimental economics has come of age over the past five decades. The field has assembled a large body of evidence on human behavior in the face of incentives. Its insights have affected the progress in many fields of economics, from microe- conomics, to labor, to finance, to macroeconomics. Over that period, publications based on experimental research have become commonplace in general-interest and field journals. In addition, two journals ded- icated to research based on experimental work were initiated: Experimental Eco- nomics in 1998 and Journal of the Economic Science Association in 2015. Nonethe- less, Nikiforakis & Slonim(2019) report several trends in experimental publica- tions from 1975–2018 and point to a significant decline in top-5 publications over the last decade of that period. Indeed, Figure1a replicates this
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Experiments and Econometrics Daniel E. Houser “Experimetrics” Refers to Formal Procedures Used in Designed Investigations
    Experiments and Econometrics Daniel E. Houser “Experimetrics” refers to formal procedures used in designed investigations of economic hypotheses. Fundamental experimetric contributions by Ronald A. Fisher provided the foundation for a rich literature informing the design and analysis of economics experiments. Key components of this foundation include the concepts of randomization, independence and blocking. Experimetric analysis plays a central role in advancing economic models, and will gain further importance as scholars adopt increasingly sophisticated designed research programs to illuminate positive economic theory. 1. Introduction “Experimetrics” refers to formal procedures used in designed investigations of economic hypotheses. A series of pathbreaking experimetric contributions by Ronald A. Fisher, written largely during the 1920s and early 1930s, elucidated fundamental concepts in the design and analysis of experiments (see, e.g., Box, 1980 for a survey). He was first to obtain rigorous experimetric results on the importance of randomization, independence and blocking, and he created many powerful analysis tools that remain widely used, including Fisher’s non-parametric Exact Test (Fisher, 1926; see also Fisher, 1935). Controlled experiments allow compelling scientific inferences with respect to hypotheses of interest. Many economic experiments inform hypotheses regarding primitives assumed to be constant within an experiment (e.g., preferences or decision strategies), or the effects on economic outcomes of changes in institutions (e.g., 1 comparing different auction rules or unemployment regulations, see Vernon Smith entry on Experimental Economics). One conducts controlled experiments to inform economic hypotheses because relevant naturally occurring data typically include noise of unknown form and magnitude outside the investigator’s control. Econometric procedures can go some distance towards solving this problem, but even sophisticated approaches often allow only limited conclusions.
    [Show full text]
  • Inflation and Welfare in the Laboratory∗†
    Inflation and Welfare in the Laboratory∗y Janet Hua Jiang Daniela Puzzello Cathy Zhang Bank of Canada Indiana University Purdue University This version: January 2021 Abstract We develop an experimental framework to investigate the quantity theory of money and the effect of expected inflation on output and welfare based on the Rocheteau and Wright (2005) model of monetary exchange. We compare a laissez-faire policy with a fixed money supply and three policies with constant money growth where newly issued money is used to finance government spending, lump-sum transfers, or proportional transfers, respectively. The experimental results are largely consistent with theory. The quantity theory of money holds and higher money growth leads to higher inflation. Relative to laissez-faire, output and welfare are significantly lower with government spending, output is significantly lower with lump-sum transfers, while there are no significant real effects with proportional transfers. A substantial deviation from theory is that the detrimental effect of money growth depends on the implementation scheme and is weaker with lump-sum transfers relative to government spending. JEL Classification: C92, D83, E40 Keywords: money, monetary policy, inflation, experimental macroeconomics ∗We thank John Duffy, Ricardo Lagos, Gary Richardson, Guillaume Rocheteau, Randall Wright, Sevgi Yuksel and seminar and conference participants at U.C. Irvine, King's College London, Virginia Common- wealth University, Midwest Macro Meetings at Michigan State, SED Meetings in St. Louis, ESA World Meeting in Vancouver, Workshop on Theoretical and Experimental Macroeconomics in Ottawa, Money, Banking, and Finance Summer Workshop in Ottawa, Conference on Theory and Experiments in Monetary Economics in Arlington, Jordan-Wabash Workshop in Experimental Economics at Purdue, and the South- west Search and Matching Conference at U.C.
    [Show full text]
  • Unclassified DAF/COMP/GF(2008)6 Global Forum on Competition
    Unclassified DAF/COMP/GF(2008)6 Organisation de Coopération et de Développement Economiques Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development 14-Feb-2008 ___________________________________________________________________________________________ _____________ English - Or. English DIRECTORATE FOR FINANCIAL AND ENTERPRISE AFFAIRS COMPETITION COMMITTEE Unclassified DAF/COMP/GF(2008)6 Global Forum on Competition THE ECONOMICS OF COMPETITION AND CONSUMER POLICIES Contribution by Mr. Ian McAuley -- Session V -- The attached paper drafted by Mr. Ian McAuley (Lecturer, University of Canberra) was prepared for the consideration of the Committee on Consumers Policy. It is now submitted FOR INFORMATION under session V of the Global Forum on Competition to be held on 21-22 February 2008. Contact: Hélène CHADZYNSKA, Project Manager of the Global Forum on Competition [Tel: 33 1 45 24 91 05; email: [email protected]]. English - Or. English JT03240448 Document complet disponible sur OLIS dans son format d'origine Complete document available on OLIS in its original format DAF/COMP/GF(2008)6 THE ECONOMICS OF COMPETITION AND CONSUMER POLICIES -- Background Note --(*) Confident, informed and empowered consumers are the motor of economic change as their choices drive innovation and efficiency1 1. Introduction 1. The OECD Committee on Consumer Policy has hosted two one-day Roundtables, in 2005 and 2006, to hear from academic researchers and public officials from OECD countries about developments in economic research and public policy relating to the demand side of markets. In particular they were informed about developments in the emerging discipline of behavioural economics, with a focus on the study of consumer behaviour in market transactions. 2. The main points to emerge from the Roundtables are: that public policy should ensure that markets operate to deliver outcomes which are beneficial to consumers and to the economy as a whole; that competition policy is a means to an end, not an end in itself.
    [Show full text]