TORTS Common Law Decisions of the United States Are an Appropriate

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

TORTS Common Law Decisions of the United States Are an Appropriate TORTS 1 TORTS Common law decisions of the United States are an appropriate source of guidance for this court for contract and tort issues unresolved by statutes, decisions of constitutional courts here, or custom and tradition within the Federated States of Micronesia. Review of decisions of courts of the United States, and any other jurisdictions, must proceed however against the background of pertinent aspects of Micronesian society and culture. Semens v. Continental Air Lines, Inc. (I), 2 FSM R. 131, 142 (Pon. 1985). Roughly stated, the general principle is that one person may be liable in tort to another only if the first intentionally or negligently violates a duty owed to the other, and the other is injured as a result. Semens v. Continental Air Lines, Inc. (I), 2 FSM R. 131, 142 (Pon. 1985). According to the Pohnpeian view of civil wrongs, if one damages another’s property, he must repair or replace it; if one injures another person, he must apologize and provide assistance to the injured person and his family; if one kills another person, he must provide the assistance that the victim would have provided and may have to offer another person to take the place of victim in his family. Koike v. Ponape Rock Products, Inc., 3 FSM R. 57, 70-71 (Pon. S. Ct. Tr. 1986). Primary lawmaking powers for the field of torts lie with the states, not with the national government, but the national government may have an implied power to regulate tort law as part of the exercise of other general powers. Edwards v. Pohnpei, 3 FSM R. 350, 359 (Pon. 1988). Although the FSM Supreme Court has often decided matters of tort law without stating explicitly that state rather than national law controls, there has been acknowledgment that state law controls in the resolution of contract and tort issues. When the Supreme Court, in the exercise of its jurisdiction, decides a matter of state law, its goal should be to apply the law the same way the highest state court would. Edwards v. Pohnpei, 3 FSM R. 350, 360 n.22 (Pon. 1989). Chuuk State has adopted common law tort principles as the law of Chuuk State where no specific constitutional or traditional impediment to its adoption exists. Epiti v. Chuuk, 5 FSM R. 162, 165 (Chk. S. Ct. Tr. 1991). Claims for torts that took place before 1951 accrued, at the latest, when the applicable Trust Territory statute took effect in 1951. Unless tolled, the statutes of limitation bar the FSM courts from adjudicating such claims. Alep v. United States, 6 FSM R. 214, 219-20 (Chk. 1993). Where a statute creates a cause of action and then places exclusive, original jurisdiction over all controversies arising from that cause of action in a particular court, another court will have no jurisdiction to entertain claims under that statute. Damarlane v. United States, 6 FSM R. 357, 360 (Pon. 1994). Various environmental acts that do not provide for a private citizen’s cause of action for monetary damages cannot be used to create a duty for the breach of which damages may be awarded. Damarlane v. United States, 6 FSM R. 357, 360-61 (Pon. 1994). Since state law generally controls the resolution of tort issues the duty of the FSM Supreme Court in a diversity case involving tort law is to try to apply the law the same way the highest TORTS 2 state court would. Nethon v. Mobil Oil Micronesia, Inc., 6 FSM R. 451, 455 (Chk. 1994). Common law tort principles from other jurisdictions have previously been adopted by the Chuuk State Supreme Court where there has been no constitutional or traditional impediment to doing so. Nethon v. Mobil Oil Micronesia, Inc., 6 FSM R. 451, 455 (Chk. 1994). A tort is a wrong for which the harm that resulted, or is about to result, is capable of being compensated in an action at law. The purpose is to afford compensation for injuries sustained by one person as the result of the unreasonable or socially harmful conduct of another. Primo v. Refalopei, 7 FSM R. 423, 430 n.13 (Pon. 1996). Any attempt to breathe new life into tort claims time barred by the relevant and analogous statutes should be approached with caution because they are the type of personal claims for money damages that become increasingly difficult of proof and difficult to defend with the passage of time. Ordinarily such claims are resolved by political and diplomatic efforts. Alep v. United States, 7 FSM R. 494, 498 (App. 1996). The defenses of estoppel, unclean hands and laches are all equitable defenses which do not apply in actions sounding in personal injury. Conrad v. Kolonia Town, 8 FSM R. 183, 193 (Pon. 1997). Should Pohnpeian custom and tradition not be determinative, the FSM Supreme Court will look to its earlier holding and decisions of United States courts for guidance as to relevant common law tort principles, and will evaluate the persuasiveness of the reasoning in these decisions against the background of pertinent aspects of Micronesian society and culture in Pohnpei. Mauricio v. Phoenix of Micronesia, Inc., 8 FSM R. 248, 253 (Pon. 1998). The general principle is that one person may be liable in tort to another only if the first intentionally or negligently violates a duty owed to the other, and the other is injured as a result. Pohnpei v. M/V Miyo Maru No. 11, 8 FSM R. 281, 293, 294 (Pon. 1998). United States common law decisions are an appropriate source of guidance for this court for contract and tort issues unresolved by statutes, decisions of constitutional courts here, or custom and tradition within the Federated States of Micronesia. United States courts have generally followed the provisions of the Restatement of Torts in situations where a plaintiff alleges that a defendant has negligently prevented a third party from rendering assistance. Pohnpei v. M/V Miyo Maru No. 11, 8 FSM R. 281, 293-94 (Pon. 1998). State law controls in the resolution of contract and tort issues. When the Supreme Court, in the exercise of its jurisdiction, decides a matter of state law, its goal should be to apply the law the same way the highest state court would. When no existing case law is found the FSM Supreme Court must decide issues of tort law by applying the law as it believes the state court would. Pohnpei v. M/V Miyo Maru No. 11, 8 FSM R. 281, 294-95 (Pon. 1998). A tort is a wrong for which the harm that resulted is capable of being compensated in an action at law. The purpose is to afford compensation for injuries sustained by one person as the result of the unreasonable or socially harmful conduct of another. Generally, one person may be liable in tort to another only if the first intentionally or negligently violates a duty owed to the other, and the other is injured as a result. Asher v. Kosrae, 8 FSM R. 443, 449 (Kos. S. Ct. Tr. 1998). TORTS 3 The states’ role in tort law is predominant. Phoenix of Micronesia, Inc. v. Mauricio, 9 FSM R. 155, 158 (App. 1999). A Kosrae state regulation that covers all persons wanting to fill in and construct on or over land below the ordinary high water mark does not provide any private right of action and cannot be the basis of a claim against the state for violation of law or regulation even if it did not have a specific plan for the seawall that was part of a road-widening project for which it had an overall plan. Jonah v. Kosrae, 9 FSM R. 335, 342-43 (Kos. S. Ct. Tr. 2000). The purpose of tort law is to afford a victim compensation for injuries sustained as the result of the unreasonable or socially harmful conduct of another. This is true whether the tort is statutorily created, as are the civil rights claims under 11 F.S.M.C. 701(3), or is a creature of the common law, as is a battery cause of action. Atesom v. Kukkun, 10 FSM R. 19, 23 (Chk. 2001). The statute, 30 F.S.M.C. 104, does not impose a duty upon the FSM Development Bank to provide technical assistance to debtors to whom it has already made a loan, nor to assignees of those debtors. Nor does it give rise to a private cause of action. FSM Dev. Bank v. Mudong, 10 FSM R. 67, 76-77 (Pon. 2001). United States common law decisions are an appropriate source of guidance for the Kosrae State Court for tort issues unresolved by statutes, decisions of constitutional courts here, or custom and tradition within the Federated States of Micronesia. Talley v. Lelu Town Council, 10 FSM R. 226, 234, 236 (Kos. S. Ct. Tr. 2001). State law generally determines tort issues, and the FSM Supreme Court in diversity cases must attempt to apply the law in the manner that the highest state court would. Amayo v. MJ Co., 10 FSM R. 244, 253-54 (Pon. 2001). A given for tort causes of action is that the alleged actor have some interest in or control over the instrumentality that brought about the tortious conduct. Kosrae v. Worswick, 10 FSM R. 288, 291 (Kos. 2001). The legislature has the power to modify or abolish common law rights or remedies and may supersede the common law without an express directive to that effect, as by adoption of a system of statutes comprehensively dealing with a subject to which the common law rule related.
Recommended publications
  • Expectation, Reliance, and the Two Contractual Wrongs
    Expectation, Reliance, and the Two Contractual Wrongs CHRISTOPHER T. WONNELL* TABLE OF CONTENTS L INTRODUCTION: THE PLACE OF EXPECTATION AND RELIANCE IN CONTRACTUAL DECISION MAKING ............................................. 54 A. Two ContractualDecisions in Need of Moral Assessment ................54 B. Six Motivesfor Making and Then Breaking a Particular Contract................................................................................................. 60 1. Taking Advantage of NonsimultaneousPerformances ................... 60 2. Making a Threat to Breach in the Face of Situational Monopoly Credible....................................................................... 62 3. Refusing to Carry Through on an Agreed-upon Allocation of Risk ......................................................................... 63 4. Seeking to AppropriateInformation Productively Brought to Bearon the Transactionby the Promisee..................... 66 5. Seeking to Avoid the Contract Because of a Mistake That Makes the ContractMore Burdensome to the PromisorThan Anticipated and Correspondingly More Profitableto the Promisee.................................................. 72 6. Seeking to Avoid the Contract Because of a Mistake That Makes the ContractMore Burdensome to the PromisorThan Anticipated Without Becoming CorrespondinglyMore Profitableto the Promisee........................ 75 * Professor of Law, University of San Diego School of Law. J.D. 1982, University of Michigan; B.A. 1979, Northwestern University. This Article was selected by
    [Show full text]
  • Why Expectation Damages for Breach of Contract Must Be the Norm: a Refutation of the Fuller and Perdue "Three Interests&Quo
    Nebraska Law Review Volume 81 | Issue 3 Article 2 2003 Why Expectation Damages for Breach of Contract Must Be the Norm: A Refutation of the Fuller and Perdue "Three Interests" Thesis W. David Slawson University of Southern California Gould School of Law, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.unl.edu/nlr Recommended Citation W. David Slawson, Why Expectation Damages for Breach of Contract Must Be the Norm: A Refutation of the Fuller and Perdue "Three Interests" Thesis, 81 Neb. L. Rev. (2002) Available at: https://digitalcommons.unl.edu/nlr/vol81/iss3/2 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law, College of at DigitalCommons@University of Nebraska - Lincoln. It has been accepted for inclusion in Nebraska Law Review by an authorized administrator of DigitalCommons@University of Nebraska - Lincoln. W. David Slawson* Why Expectation Damages for Breach of Contract Must Be the Norm: A Refutation of the Fuller and Perdue "Three Interests" Thesis TABLE OF CONTENTS 840 I. Introduction .......................................... Principal Institutions in a Modern Market II. The 843 Economy in Which Contracts Are Used ................ A. The Institution of the Economic Market: Contracts 843 as Bargains ....................................... Institution of Credit and Finance: Contracts as B. The 845 Property .......................................... 846 the Institutions' Needs ....................... III. Meeting 846 A. Providing a Remedy for Every Breach ............. Contracts Enforceable as Soon as They Are B. Making 847 M ade ............................................. Has Compensating the Injured Party for What He C. 848 ost ............................................... L 848 Damages Under the Expectation Measure ...... 1. 849 2. Damages Under the Reliance Measure ......... 849 a.
    [Show full text]
  • Reliance and Contract Breach
    RELIANCE AND CONTRACT BREACH JIM LEITZEL* I INTRODUCTION Actions taken in reliance on a contract, and court protection of such reliance in the event of a breach, have been analyzed from both legal and economic perspectives.' This article compares the legal and economic approaches to contractual reliance and develops a model for examining the protection of expenditures in reasonable reliance. The protection of reasonable reliance potentially involves circular arguments: Courts will protect the amount of reliance in which a reasonable person would engage, but a reasonable person would rely up to the extent that courts will protect.2 This article shows that the protection of reasonable reliance may be well defined, despite the potential circularity. The economic analysis that has been done on contractual reliance has noted that the protection of reliance expenditures, in the event of a breach, may render such expenditures riskless from the viewpoint of the party engaging in the reliance. 3 Since reliance expenditures are inherently risky, 4 their protection may result in overreliance from society's point of view. Overreliance can be avoided if contractual damages are invariant with respect to reliance. 5 Damage "measures can be interpreted as invariant with respect to reliance by limiting recovery on the basis of reliance to costs that are reasonably incurred." 6 This interpretation of damages, however, is subject to the circularity problem inherent in reasonableness standards. This article uses the bilateral contract 7 as the context for the examination of reliance. This article focuses on the different answers provided by the Copyright © 1989 by Law and Contemporary Problems * Visiting Associate Professor of Economics, Duke University.
    [Show full text]
  • The Purpose of Compensatory Damages in Tort and Fraudulent Misrepresentation
    LENS FINAL 12/1/2010 5:47:02 PM Honest Confusion: The Purpose of Compensatory Damages in Tort and Fraudulent Misrepresentation Jill Wieber Lens∗ I. INTRODUCTION Suppose that a plaintiff is injured in a rear-end collision car accident. Even though the rear-end collision was not a dramatic accident, the plaintiff incurred extensive medical expenses because of a preexisting medical condition. Through a negligence claim, the plaintiff can recover compensatory damages based on his medical expenses. But is it fair that the defendant should be liable for all of the damages? It is not as if he rear-ended the plaintiff on purpose. Maybe the fact that defendant’s conduct was not reprehensible should reduce the amount of damages that the plaintiff recovers. Any first-year torts student knows that the defendant’s argument will not succeed. The defendant’s conduct does not control the amount of the plaintiff’s compensatory damages. The damages are based on the plaintiff’s injury because, in tort law, the purpose of compensatory damages is to make the plaintiff whole by putting him in the same position as if the tort had not occurred.1 But there are tort claims where the amount of compensatory damages is not always based on the plaintiff’s injury. Suppose that a defendant fraudulently misrepresents that a car for sale is brand-new. The plaintiff then offers to purchase the car for $10,000. Had the car actually been new, it would have been worth $15,000, but the car was instead worth only $10,000. As they have for a very long time, the majority of jurisdictions would award the plaintiff $5000 in compensatory damages 2 based on the plaintiff’s expected benefit of the bargain.
    [Show full text]
  • The Phantom Reliance Interest in Tort Damages
    The Phantom Reliance interest in Tort Damages MICHAEL B. KELLY* TABLE OF CONTENTS L INTRODUCTION ................................................................................................... 169 IL THE RELIANCE INTEREST IN MISREPRESENTATION .............................................. 171 III. RELIANCE IN PERSONAL INJURY CASES ............................................................... 176 IV. WHAT DOES IT ALL MEAN? ....................................... ... .... .... .... .... ... ..... ... .... .... .. 189 I. INTRODUCTION The reliance interest has fascinated me for some time.' As a measure of damages for breach of contract,2 it seems theoretically unjustified and flawed in its implementation. In theory, it requires compensation for lost opportunities? In practice, such compensation is rarely provided'- * Professor of Law, University of San Diego School of Law. J.D. 1983, B.G.S. 1975, University of Michigan; M.A. 1980, University of Illinois. 1. Michael B. Kelly, The Phanton Reliance Interest in Contract Damages, 1992 WIS. L. REv. 1755. 2. My focus has been on contracts, full-fledged bargains, rather than promissory estoppel or other instances where the reliance interest might be applied. Much of my criticism of the reliance interest has been limited to this context. This Article will expand somewhat the scope of my criticism. 3. L.L. Fuller & William R. Perdue, Jr., The Reliance Interest in Contract Damages: 1, 46 YALE LJ. 52, 55, 60-61 (1936); Mark Pettit, Jr., PrivateAdvantage and Public Power: Reexamining the Expectation and Reliance Interests in Contract Damages, 38 HASTINGS L.J 417,420-21 (1987). unless one counts the expectation interest as a proxy for opportunities lost in reliance on a promise.5 In theory, it justifies recoveries that may exceed expectation.6 Yet, even its progenitors refused to endorse that implication.7 Why, then, does the reliance interest have continuing appeal? One explanation has emerged from discussions with academics: the reliance interest seems apt to some because it resembles tort remedies.
    [Show full text]
  • Paying for What You Get—Restitution Recovery for Breach of Contract
    Pace Law Review Volume 38 Issue 2 Spring 2018 Article 7 April 2018 Paying for What You Get—Restitution Recovery for Breach of Contract Jean Fleming Powers South Texas College of Law Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.pace.edu/plr Part of the Contracts Commons Recommended Citation Jean Fleming Powers, Paying for What You Get—Restitution Recovery for Breach of Contract, 38 Pace L. Rev. 501 (2018) Available at: https://digitalcommons.pace.edu/plr/vol38/iss2/7 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the School of Law at DigitalCommons@Pace. It has been accepted for inclusion in Pace Law Review by an authorized administrator of DigitalCommons@Pace. For more information, please contact [email protected]. POWERS.DOCX (DO NOT DELETE) 5/8/18 10:33 PM Paying for What You Get—Restitution Recovery for Breach of Contract By Jean Fleming Powers* I. INTRODUCTION Many contracts casebooks, in dealing with contract remedies, include the case Sullivan v. O’Connor,1 a case dealing with an unsuccessful nose job.2 While a case about the results of surgery at first blush seems more fitting for a torts book, Sullivan, like its iconic counterpart Hawkins v. McGee3 uses a vivid fact pattern in an atypical contracts case4 to illustrate important points about contract remedies.5 Sullivan has the added benefit of providing a launching point for a discussion of the three contracts measures of recovery: expectation, reliance, and restitution.6 If the approach of the Restatement (Third) of Restitution and Unjust Enrichment7 [hereinafter referred to as “the Restatement of Restitution,” or just “the Restatement”] * Professor of Law, South Texas College of Law Houston; J.D., University of Houston Law Center, 1978; B.A.
    [Show full text]
  • The Troubles with Law and Economics
    Hofstra Law Review Volume 20 | Issue 4 Article 2 1992 The rT oubles with Law and Economics Leonard R. Jaffee Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarlycommons.law.hofstra.edu/hlr Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Jaffee, Leonard R. (1992) "The rT oubles with Law and Economics," Hofstra Law Review: Vol. 20: Iss. 4, Article 2. Available at: http://scholarlycommons.law.hofstra.edu/hlr/vol20/iss4/2 This document is brought to you for free and open access by Scholarly Commons at Hofstra Law. It has been accepted for inclusion in Hofstra Law Review by an authorized administrator of Scholarly Commons at Hofstra Law. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Jaffee: The Troubles with Law and Economics THE TROUBLES WITH LAW AND ECONOMICS Leonard 1? Jaffee* In this Article's first Part, the author sets Law and Economics' own devices against its fundamental proposition: In free contractual pursuit of personal wealth, we find the best means of serving nearly all of our legitimate interpersonaland social interests. Using the classic "efficient breach" case as paradigm, Profes- sor Jaffee argues that all contracts cases defy judgment of whether agreement or breach is efficient-that every such case is intractably ambiguous and threatens inefficient or vagrant costs, profits, or demoralization. He offers instead specific performance as the pre- ferred remedy for breach of contract. He argues that neither ex ante nor ex post contractual adjustments-whether toward an agreed remedy like liquidated damages or modification of obliga- tion-sufficiently resolve such cases or stay their threats, since we cannot ever know what is needed to compensate properly.
    [Show full text]
  • Valuing Man's and Woman's Best Friend: the Moral and Legal Status of Companion Animals
    University of Arkansas · School of Law · Division of Agriculture [email protected] · (479) 575-7646 An Agricultural Law Research Article Valuing Man’s and Woman’s Best Friend: The Moral and Legal Status of Companion Animals by Rebecca J. Huss Originally published in MARQUETTE LAW REVIEW 86 MARQUETTE L. REV. 47 (2002) www.NationalAgLawCenter.org VALUING MAN'S AND WOMAN'S BEST FRIEND: THE MORAL AND LEGAL STATUS OF COMPANION ANIMALS REBECCA J. HusS· I. INTRODUCTION .............................................................................48 II. PHILOSOPHICAL BASIS FOR THE MORAL STATUS OF ANIMALS ..............................................................................................52 A. Historical Views .......................................................................53 1. Greek History ...................................................................53 2. Religious Traditions .........................................................55 B. Modern Theories on Animal Rights ......................................60 1. Contractualism..................................................................60 2. Utilitarianism ....................................................................62 3. Inherent Valuation ...........................................................65 4. Other View Points ............................................................67 III. CURRENT LEGAL STATUS OF ANIMALS ..................................68 A. Property ....................................................................................68 B.
    [Show full text]
  • The Eleventh Circuit Reaffirms Validity of Waiver of Consequential Damages Provisions in Contracts
    The Eleventh Circuit Reaffirms Validity of Waiver of Consequential Damages Provisions in Contracts By E. Tyron Brown Hawkins Parnell Thackston & Young LLP Atlanta, Georgia 30308 [email protected] The Eleventh Circuit Court of Appeals, in Silverpop Systems, Inc. v. Leading Market Technologies, Inc., 2016 U.S. App. LEXIS 196 (11th Cir. January 5, 2016) enforced a contractual waiver of consequential damages provision, thereby reaffirming the validity of such provisions in Georgia. In that case, the Plaintiff Silverpop Systems, Inc. (“Silverpop”) provided digital marketing services to businesses such as the Defendant Leading Market Technologies, Inc. (“LMT”). The parties entered into a service agreement whereby LMT was authorized to access Silverpop’s web-based e-mail marketing program and upload digital advertising content and recipient e-mail addresses. The advertising content was then sent to the e-mail addresses. The list of e-mail addresses from LMT was stored on Silverpop’s marketing program. Silverpop’s program eventually had a list of nearly 1/2 million email addresses from LMT. Then, a data breach occurred to Silverpop’s program and the hackers gained access to the information stored on the program by 110 of Silverpop’s customers -- including LMT. Silverpop said it could not confirm that the hackers exported the data files out of the system. Subsequently, Silverpop filed a declaratory judgment action against LMT seeking a judgment declaring, inter alia, that LMT was not damaged by the data breach or that LMT incurred only consequential damages which were barred by a waiver of consequential damages provision in the contract. LMT counterclaimed against Silverpop asserting several claims.
    [Show full text]
  • The Efficacy of the Negative Injunction in Breach of Entertainment Contracts, 46 J
    UIC Law Review Volume 46 Issue 2 Article 1 2013 The Efficacy of the Negative Injunction in Breach of Entertainment Contracts, 46 J. Marshall L. Rev. 409 (2013) Eliot Axelrod Follow this and additional works at: https://repository.law.uic.edu/lawreview Part of the Contracts Commons, Courts Commons, Entertainment, Arts, and Sports Law Commons, and the Legal Remedies Commons Recommended Citation Eliot Axelrod, The Efficacy of the Negative Injunction in Breach of Entertainment Contracts, 46 J. Marshall L. Rev. 409 (2013) https://repository.law.uic.edu/lawreview/vol46/iss2/1 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by UIC Law Open Access Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in UIC Law Review by an authorized administrator of UIC Law Open Access Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Do Not Delete 3/12/2013 5:35 PM THE EFFICACY OF THE NEGATIVE INJUNCTION IN BREACH OF ENTERTAINMENT CONTRACTS ELLIOT AXELROD* I. INTRODUCTION Many aspects of the entertainment business are highly speculative and entertainment firms are known to invest heavily in developing and marketing the various products they create. While revenues from successful entertainment projects can be enormous, these successes are frequently offset by other expensive flops. As performers become more individually successful, they become generally more concerned with maximizing their own personal profits than with helping to subsidize development of entertainment projects to benefit their successors.1 When it comes to remedies for breach of entertainment contracts, it is a constant battle to find a fair balance between the interests of entertainment entities seeking to make a profit—or at a minimum, recoup their investments—and performers seeking artistic autonomy and financial leverage.
    [Show full text]
  • Reexamining the Expectation and Reliance Interests in Contract Damages Mark Pettit Jr
    Hastings Law Journal Volume 38 | Issue 3 Article 2 1-1987 Private Advantage and Public Power: Reexamining the Expectation and Reliance Interests in Contract Damages Mark Pettit Jr. Follow this and additional works at: https://repository.uchastings.edu/hastings_law_journal Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Mark Pettit Jr., Private Advantage and Public Power: Reexamining the Expectation and Reliance Interests in Contract Damages, 38 Hastings L.J. 417 (1987). Available at: https://repository.uchastings.edu/hastings_law_journal/vol38/iss3/2 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law Journals at UC Hastings Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Hastings Law Journal by an authorized editor of UC Hastings Scholarship Repository. Article Private Advantage and Public Power: Reexamining the Expectation and Reliance Interests in Contract Damages by MARK PETTIT, JR.* Introduction Fifty years ago Fuller and Perdue asked why it is that in cases of breach of contract courts usually award "expectation" damages rather than "reliance" damages.I The authors defined these damages measures by their purposes.2 The object of the expectation measure "is to put the plaintiff in as good a position as he would have occupied had the defend- ant performed his promise."'3 The object of the reliance measure, on the other hand, is to "undo the harm" caused by reliance on a promise that was later broken, that is, "to put [the plaintif] in as good a position as he was in before the promise was made."'4 Fuller and Perdue concluded * Professor of Law, Boston University. A.B.
    [Show full text]
  • Contract Basics for Litigators: Illinois by Diane Cafferata and Allison Huebert, Quinn Emanuel Urquhart & Sullivan, LLP, with Practical Law Commercial Litigation
    STATE Q&A Contract Basics for Litigators: Illinois by Diane Cafferata and Allison Huebert, Quinn Emanuel Urquhart & Sullivan, LLP, with Practical Law Commercial Litigation Status: Law stated as of 01 Jun 2020 | Jurisdiction: Illinois, United States This document is published by Practical Law and can be found at: us.practicallaw.tr.com/w-022-7463 Request a free trial and demonstration at: us.practicallaw.tr.com/about/freetrial A Q&A guide to state law on contract principles and breach of contract issues under Illinois common law. This guide addresses contract formation, types of contracts, general contract construction rules, how to alter and terminate contracts, and how courts interpret and enforce dispute resolution clauses. This guide also addresses the basics of a breach of contract action, including the elements of the claim, the statute of limitations, common defenses, and the types of remedies available to the non-breaching party. Contract Formation to enter into a bargain, made in a manner that justifies another party’s understanding that its assent to that 1. What are the elements of a valid contract bargain is invited and will conclude it” (First 38, LLC v. NM Project Co., 2015 IL App (1st) 142680-U, ¶ 51 (unpublished in your jurisdiction? order under Ill. S. Ct. R. 23) (citing Black’s Law Dictionary 1113 (8th ed.2004) and Restatement (Second) of In Illinois, the elements necessary for a valid contract are: Contracts § 24 (1981))). • An offer. • An acceptance. Acceptance • Consideration. Under Illinois law, an acceptance occurs if the party assented to the essential terms contained in the • Ascertainable Material terms.
    [Show full text]